View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee
March 28,

1995

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in
the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System in
Washington, D.C.,
PRESENT:

on Tuesday, March 28, 1995, at 9:00 a.m.
Mr. Greenspan, Chairman

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Ms.
Mr.
Ms.
Ms.

McDonough, Vice Chairman
Blinder
Hoenig
Kelley
Lindsey
Melzer
Minehan
Moskow
Phillips
Yellen

Messrs. Boehne, Jordan, McTeer, and Stern,
Alternate Members of the Federal Open Market
Committee
Messrs. Broaddus, Forrestal, and Parry, Presidents
of the Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond,
Atlanta, and San Francisco, respectively
Mr. Kohn, Secretary and Economist

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Bernard, Deputy Secretary
Coyne, Assistant Secretary
Gillum, Assistant Secretary
Mattingly, General Counsel
Baxter, Deputy General Counsel
Prell, Economist
Truman, Economist

Ms.

Browne, Messrs. Davis, Hunter, Lindsey,
Mishkin, Promisel, Siegman, Slifman, and
Stockton, Associate Economists

Mr. Fisher, Manager, System Open Market Account

Mr. Ettin, Deputy Director, Division of Research
and Statistics, Board of Governors
Mr. Madigan, Associate Director, Division of
Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Mr. Simpson, Associate Director, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Ms. Low, Open Market Secretariat Assistant,
Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Messrs. Goodfriend, Lang, Rolnick, Rosenblum,
and Sniderman, Senior Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of Richmond, Philadelphia,
Minneapolis, Dallas, and Cleveland,
respectively
Messrs. Kos and Judd, and Ms. Rosenbaum, Vice
Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of New York,
San Francisco, and Atlanta, respectively
Mr. Thornton, Assistant Vice President, Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Transcript of Federal Open Market Committee Meeting
March 28, 1995
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
the minutes?

Would somebody like to move approval of

VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH.

So move.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. The Committee has
received a memorandum on the delegation of responsibility for appeals
of staff decisions to deny access to Committee records under the
Freedom of Information Act. The need for this delegation stems from
the vacancy that was created when David Mullins resigned from the
FOMC. The recommendation is to follow past practice and elect the
individuals who are involved in the similar function with respect to
the Board of Governors--Governor Phillips as the principal and
Governor Yellen as the alternate--to serve in that function for the
FOMC. Does anybody have any questions with respect to that
memorandum? If not, would somebody like to move it?
MS. MINEHAN.

So move.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. I turn to the Vice
Chairman for a nomination to elect a Deputy General Counsel from the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Ernie
Patrikis, who has been serving in that position, has been elected with
the approval of the Board of Governors to the position of First Vice
President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, effective June 1.
His successor as the General Counsel of the New York Bank and the
person we recommend as Deputy General Counsel of the FOMC is Thomas
Baxter. Mr. Baxter is 40 years old, even younger than most of us, and
a graduate of Georgetown University. His specialty has been
litigation. We consider him an outstanding attorney and a very fine
person, and we are proud to recommend him to you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
nomination?
MR. KELLEY.

Move it.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
MS. MINEHAN.

Would somebody like to move that

Would somebody second it?

Second.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. Next we move to the
election of an associate economist from the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago. President Moskow, would you like to address that?
MR. MOSKOW. Mr. Chairman, I would like to nominate William
Curt Hunter as the associate economist representing Chicago. He is
now Senior Vice President and Director of Research.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
like to move it?
SEVERAL.

So move.

Is there discussion?

Would somebody

-2-

3/28/95

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Moved and seconded and approved without
objection. The next agenda item is a review of the Committee's
Program for Security of FOMC Information. There are a number of items
in the memorandum you received. I don't want to go over them
necessarily. Does anybody have any questions with respect to them? I
thought they were pretty pro forma myself. There is the issue of
increasing from 4 to 7 the number of persons with access to Class I
FOMC materials within each Reserve Bank; that increase would square
the number with that for those who have access to Class II materials.
I gather that a number of the members have raised this issue. There
are a couple of other items of a similar nature. Does anybody have
any questions with respect to this matter?
MR. HOENIG. Mr. Chairman, since it is proposed to increase
the access to Class I from 4 to 7, that means the same number of
people can have access to Class I and to Class II as you noted. It
might be of some value, at least to us, if we could also move up by 3
the access to Class II. I don't know if there would be any problem
with that; at least I want to raise it as a possibility.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. The reason for the proposal to increase
staff access to Class I is basically that Jerry Jordan and I think
some others among you have raised questions about the current limit
and have suggested moving it up from 4. The Secretariat, I assume in
its exuberance, said "Well, 4 is an exotic number so why not try 7?"
I wonder whether 7 may be too high and whether we ought to back off
that to keep a gap between Class I and Class II. Suppose we did raise
Class I to 5. Is that a problem?
SPEAKER(?).

MR. KOHN.
to at least 6.

No.

President Jordan's,suggestion was to go from 4

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

How much higher do you want to go?

MR. JORDAN. I am not sure why it is helpful to have access
to Class I and Class II differ.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. The basic presumption is that there are
fewer people designated "top secret" than "secret." Now, whether that
is a valid judgment--[Laughter]
MR. HOENIG. I think it would be desirable to allow a few
more people to have access to less important information for the
experience of reading it and understanding it.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I think the issue here is basically not
the Class II; it's the Class I. Since the proposal is to give all
those who now have access to Class II access to Class I as well, is
there any status to having Class I clearance? I don't know. Mr.
Secretary, do you have any suggestions on this? I got away a very
long punt!
[Laughter]
MR. HOENIG.

I'm sorry I made my suggestion!

MR. KOHN. When it comes to returning punts, I am no Brian
Mitchell, I can tell you that! I would suggest that you let me poll

-3-

3/28/95

the rest of the Committee to see whether people really want to move
from 7 to 10 on access to the Greenbook. This is a pretty sensitive
document; that is what we are talking about. I don't know if Mike has
any views on this.
MR. PRELL.
MR. KOHN.

We are talking about Part I.
Yes, Part I of the Greenbook.

MR. PRELL.

Part I is classified as Class II.

MR. KOHN. Right. The number having access is now 7 and
President Hoenig's suggestion is to raise that to 10. I guess I'd
like to think about it and see whether there is a ground swell from
the rest of the Committee.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Why don't we bring this back then at the
next meeting? There is no urgency about it. Does anyone else have
any views that would be helpful?
MR. LINDSEY. I just pulled out a confidential Class II-FOMC
document here. It reports on exchange rates. I read the document
very carefully and I don't see why it is confidential.
MR. TRUMAN. The reason, Governor Lindsey, is that we often
do report intervention numbers in that document. We can't say it's
Class II when it has intervention numbers, and it's not classified
when it doesn't have intervention numbers because then we would be
revealing something. That is the point. That's why it's always Class
II regardless of whether or not it has intervention numbers in it.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. The presumption is that since it reports
the intervention numbers when intervention occurs, the absence of such
a report means intervention was zero, which also is classified
information. That is sort of putting it backwards!
Does anyone else want to raise any issues with respect to
this before we reconsider it at the next meeting? If not, the next
item on the agenda is a review of the Authorization for Domestic Open
Market Operations. There's a memorandum. Does anybody have any
questions? Incidentally, all of these items would ordinarily be on
the February meeting agenda and were moved forward for obvious reasons
relating to the crowded agenda for the February meeting. Are there
any questions with respect to that memo? If not, would somebody like
to move it?
MS. MINEHAN.

So move.

VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH.

So move.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. The next issue,
which also was moved from the February meeting, is the review of
(a) the Foreign Currency Authorization, (b) the Foreign Currency
Directive, and (c) the Procedural Instructions with Respect to Foreign
Currency Operations including a review of the "warehousing" authority
incorporated in (a) and (b).
These items were, of course, discussed
at great length at recent meetings and telephone conferences, and I am

-4-

3/28/95

just curious as to whether anyone has anything to add to the rather
exhaustive discussions that we have had.
MR. BROADDUS. Mr. Chairman, is this the time to say
something about warehousing if we have views on that?
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Yes.

MR. BROADDUS. I have just a few comments if I could make
them briefly. Ted Truman sent out a lot of background materials
regarding warehousing and I reread most of it and reread the
memorandum that Virgil and his colleagues did earlier. I think the
memo makes it clear that from a legal standpoint the Fed definitely
has the authority--or certainly that we can make a strong case that
the Fed has the authority--to warehouse foreign exchange for the
Treasury, and I understand that. But however defensible these
operations may be from a legal perspective, I just don't think the
case is very compelling when I look at the issue in a somewhat broader
context that takes account of the Fed's role in the government
generally and the independence we are supposed to have. As I see it,
warehousing is essentially a fiscal policy action or at least is fully
equivalent in its effect to a fiscal policy action. By that I mean
that in the end the warehousing operation has exactly the same final
effect as if Congress authorized the Treasury or the ESF to purchase
the foreign exchange and fund the purchase by issuing additional debt
in the market. The only difference when the transaction is done via
warehousing is that the usual Congressional appropriations process is
circumvented, and the purchase does not show up in the budget. I
really worry about the risk that we are taking over the longer term
with this practice.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Do you mean market risk?

MR. BROADDUS. No, I mean the risk to the institutional
position of the Federal Reserve. That is really the issue I am trying
to focus on, Mr. Chairman. I think we can get some sense of that in
the public's reaction to the Mexican support package. I don't want to
go into that in any detail. I just think it's an example that is very
relevant here. As we all know, the use of public funds to assist
foreign governments, however sensible that may be in particular
instances, is a highly charged political issue, especially when some
people see good alternative uses for the funds at home. The
Congressional leadership apparently supported the package in this
instance, but I don't believe Congress would have voted to authorize
the funds. I think a broad segment of the general public, rightly or
wrongly, opposes assisting Mexico so generously. The point here and
the risk as I see it is that if things go badly in Mexico going
forward, this could become an issue in the election next year. In
that event, our role would become more widely understood, and it is
quite possible that people could begin to raise questions about our
independence. It could come under much more careful scrutiny.
I would sum up the issue briefly this way:
Congress placed
the Fed outside the regular appropriations process to protect our
independence. If we are perceived as abusing this sort of off-budget
status, we run some serious risks over the longer run. Now, I
recognize the practical difficulty of trying to pull back immediately
from these operations. But I would hope that you, Mr. Chairman, and

3/28/95

this Committee would at least consider conveying our concerns
forcefully to the Treasury and then work with them hopefully to reach
an accord whereby we could withdraw from these operations over a
period of time, maybe by some defined target date. Again, I recognize
that there is a clear legal basis for doing these operations, but I
think the broader argument against doing them is really quite
persuasive.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. One of the reasons why I was very
careful to indicate to the Congress that we indeed had this
warehousing facility with respect to the Mexican deal was precisely to
put it up front. Now, some members of Congress may not have
understood it, but I must tell you that I got no negative responses,
and the types of questions they were asking suggested to me that at
least those who were asking questions had some idea of the nature of
this whole operation. On the issue of how we deal with the Treasury
in this government, as fiscal agent we involve ourselves in various
types of support for the Treasury and that does in one sense impinge
on the independence of this institution. The trouble, unfortunately,
is that we can not be fully independent because there is only one
government and there is an element here of trying to draw the line. I
think we are all somewhat uncomfortable about the warehousing
facility. I think we are all uncomfortable to a greater or lesser
extent about our own swap line facility, and in discussions with the
Treasury regarding all of these issues we basically have been to a
lesser or greater extent somewhat in opposition to the initiatives of
the Treasury. But we also recognize, as I think I indicated here a
number of months ago, that the central bank has very broad
responsibilities to ensure the safety and soundness of the financial
system. We could move ourselves back into a very narrow central bank
mode, and I would agree with you that in that respect there would be
less risk for us. But I am not sure whether we would be giving the
country something of value. I think we have to take some risks, but
certainly the issues that you raise are valid ones. I don't think
there is great disagreement about the need to be very careful on these
issues. I think we have been careful and I hope we will continue to
be.
MR. BROADDUS. I appreciate that and I am sorry to keep
raising these issues. I do think that this is not a short-term risk;
it's not the sort of thing that is likely to hit us in the face
immediately. But I worry that over time those who really would like
to compromise the position of this institution in the government, if
they are looking for an argument, this is I think the strongest
argument they would find.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
monetary policy.
MR. BROADDUS.

The strongest argument they have is

Okay.

MR. TRUMAN. Mr. Chairman, just to make a technical point on
the warehousing issue:
I don't want to comment on the political
aspects of it; that is not my role. But as a technical matter the
Treasury could conduct its warehousing transactions with the market or
with another financial institution. So the notion that warehousing as
a technical matter is an evasion of the fiscal authority of Congress I
think is not correct. I am not talking about perceptions. We have

3/28/95

worked hard and have changed the warehousing arrangement so that it is
now very clearly an arms-length, market-related transaction. We do it
on exactly the same terms that the Treasury could if it divided it all
up and did it with 150 institutions in the market. All we are doing
is to accommodate the Treasury as a convenience to them. This does
raise questions about our role and our role in assisting Mexico in
these kinds of things, which I perfectly well acknowledge. But as a
technical matter, the transaction could be done with the market.
Therefore, I don't think it's fair to say that this is an evasion of
the fiscal authority of Congress.
MR. BROADDUS. When it's done with us, though, basically it
does not show up in the budget, is that right?
MR. TRUMAN. It wouldn't show up in the budget either way.
What the Treasury does is to swap their DM or their yen with us. They
sell it to us spot and buy it back forward. They can do that on
exactly the same terms with Citibank or Chase or Deutsche Bank or the
Bank of Tokyo, whatever institution it might be. That would have
exactly the same impact on them fiscally.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. The fiscal effect occurs when the ESF
funds are created. At the moment the ESF has a big set of assets and
a big set of liabilities. Nobody is talking about expanding the size
of the ESF or increasing its capital through appropriations. What we
are talking about is refinancing its assets on a different basis and
that has no fiscal effects.
MR. BROADDUS. My feeling is that if it can be done with
private institutions and the market, we ought to see what we can do to
push the Treasury to do that. Whatever convenience the Treasury is
gaining from doing it with us is, from our standpoint at least, offset
by the longer-term risk of our continuing with these operations.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. That is a legitimate question. In my
view the issue essentially is that if the Treasury requests us to do
it, we have to give their request very serious consideration. Their
view may be that while the transaction is technically feasible in the
private market, the inconvenience involved in arranging relatively
large sums there raises questions as to the efficiency of the
operation. That is a reasonable consideration that we have to
confront. We have to be careful as to precisely how we get ourselves
intertwined with the Treasury; that is a very crucial issue. In
recent years I think we have widened the gap or increased the wedge
between us and the Treasury, as Ted was mentioning. In other words,
we have gone to a market relationship and basically to an arms-length
approach where feasible in an effort to make certain that we don't
inadvertently get caught up in some of the Treasury initiatives that
they want us to get involved in. Most of the time we say "no."
MR. BROADDUS. I understand those points. I just hope that
we can continue that process and widen that gap a little further.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I personally am not uncomfortable with
what we are doing. I am uncomfortable with the thought that we might
have to pick up the entire $20 billion warehousing, but that obviously
is a very remote contingency. President Jordan.

3/28/95

MR. JORDAN. All the things that Ted sent out ruined my
weekend as well! I read all this material before, one time or
another, but I always have to reread it because there is so much that
I can't remember all of it. I am satisfied that from a technical
standpoint and a legal standpoint there is not really an issue to be
discussed because the lawyers can always figure out a way to do
whatever it is we think is good public policy to do. So, the question
comes down to whether or not it is good public policy.
The current set of institutional arrangements was designed in
a totally different era for a different purpose. The ESF, swaps,
warehousing--all of that--were intended to give us access to
liquidity. The ESF was designed when the dollar was not even the
dominant reserve currency. The other arrangements came into being
when we had the Bretton Woods system. If we did not now have the ESF
and the capability of warehousing or have something like swap lines
and we were dealing with a situation such as the one that surfaced in
December with Mexico, these are not the institutional arrangements we
would have designed to address those issues. In today's world, given
the role of the dollar and our arrangements with other central banks,
we would establish a set of institutional arrangements to provide
liquidity to other countries such as Mexico or, in the future, Chile,
Costa Rica, whomever. We would not set up something resembling what
we have today.
What I would like to see happen is for Peter Fisher to work
with Board staff to think through what kind of institutional
arrangements we would like to have for the 21st century and produce
some kind of report by the time this issue comes up again next
February. At Fed speed I don't know if they could get that done
between now and February. In the private sector if they had such a
problem they would give staff a mandate and get it done by three
months from now. But at Fed speed, we could ask that the staff come
back with a set of proposals by next February as to the kind of
arrangements that would provide international liquidity to these
countries, especially those that are less developed and that
occasionally get themselves in a mess. The objective is for us to
carry out our central bank role without getting into this possibility
of people saying we are doing something that is not consistent with
foreign policy objectives or doing something that is subverting a debt
limit issue that may come up between the executive and legislative
branches of government. As in 1979 and 1980, we definitely don't want
to get ourselves, as a central bank, in between the executive and
legislative branches if they are playing a political game over
something like the debt ceiling. We want to be nowhere in sight if
something like that happens again. Warehousing leaves us open to be
in a position of getting caught up in something that we don't intend
to do. So, I would just like to see this whole issue rethought.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. The question really is whether or not
our role or central function is to provide dollar liquidity to other
nations on an ongoing basis or on an ad hoc basis. If you are going
to raise the argument that the international financial markets have
changed from where they were under the Bretton Woods structure, the
emergence of private global finance has to a very substantial extent
made much of the purposes of the Bretton Woods structure of dubious
merit in the current environment. The reason I raised questions
earlier about the use of swaps is that their role in the modern world

3/28/95

--especially the order of magnitude of the swaps if we look at them in
the context of the size and types of problems that seem to have
emerged in the EMS, Mexico and the like--seems to be an anachronism.
I am a little concerned, however, about setting up a study in the form
in which you suggested. That is an expensive undertaking. I do think
it might not be a bad idea, however, to have a couple of memoranda
that discuss the broader questions without getting into the
initiatives that you are suggesting. Your proposal strikes me as a
much larger project and use of resources than I think we are prepared
to get involved in until we get a clearer focus on how we view this
issue. The important question that I think you are raising, Jerry, is
how much of our post Bretton Woods structure at the Federal Reserve is
an anachronism and what our role is in today's environment. I would
much prefer to have a few short memoranda on that than spend a lot of
time trying to think of what type of structure we should go to from
here. So, unless someone has an objection to that, I will request Ted
to see whether or not we could have some short review of the history
of this issue. It would involve revisiting a lot of the material that
has been put together, but I think the central focus should be on the
question of what difference the emergence of private global finance
makes relative to the structure that we have had since it evolved in
the 1960s.
MS. MINEHAN.

Mr. Chairman?

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Yes.

MS. MINEHAN. I don't have any objection, but this is an
issue that has to have been discussed at tables like this around the
world, given what has happened in Mexico, Argentina, and other
countries. I am wondering what rethinking is going on internationally
with regard to how these sorts of things play out and what can be
done.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. On the basis of the meetings that I at
least have been involved in--and some of our colleagues have been in
similar meetings--I think there is a general recognition that the size
of the problem that emerged in Mexico and the size of the
international facility that was perceived to be necessary to address
it clearly rule out a generic facility. There is not enough cash in
the world to handle the problems without producing potentially large
inflationary pressures through use of SDRs, IMF quota expansions, and
all of that.
MS. MINEHAN.

The moral hazard is extraordinary.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Yes, including what I am sure the IMF
would like, which is for the IMF to become a world bank lender of last
resort. That is about the last resort I should think for anything.
This has led us to the question of whether it is possible to have
bankruptcy statutes for sovereign nations. As you know, at the moment
that does not exist and the question is whether there is a mechanism
that would make it possible to address the types of problems
confronting Mexico in a restructuring mode that is the equivalent of a
bankruptcy facility rather than by providing liquidity, which is
implicit in our swap and other relationships. That discussion is
going forward at the BIS. Ted, I assume there is some talk at the
Halifax Summit on this?

3/28/95

-9-

MR. TRUMAN. The Mexico situation, for better or for worse,
has clearly given the Halifax Summit something to focus on--something
more than just chit-chat about stable exchange rates, if I may put it
that way. Doing something in the bankruptcy or orderly workout area
is one of the ideas that is under some discussion. It's also fair to
say that other ideas under discussion include some that the Chairman
has tried to pour cold water on--that of vastly increasing the size of
the IMF and its capacity to deal with these kinds of situations. I
don't think there is a consensus among the various nations involved in
the G-7 on what to do at the moment. It appears that most options are
still on the table, though some people think that a few options have
been taken off.
MS. MINEHAN. I would think that whatever rethinking we do
about what the Federal Reserve's response should be and how we view
these things has to take place in the context of how the rest of the
world is thinking about these issues.
MR. TRUMAN. Yes, certainly there are big and small issues
involved and both types have been raised here in this discussion.
That's partly because we started with Mexico, which on the one hand is
a country-specific type of problem. On the other hand, Mexico is
regarded as symptomatic, as the Chairman has said, of the nature of
the international financial system and its functioning and the
potential problems and challenges as we move into the 21st century.
It's difficult to sort those things out. As far as country-specific
problems are concerned, it is fair to say that many other central
banks of the major industrial countries are in fact more involved in
this process than we are. The nature of their involvement is
different from ours. It might be useful to the Committee, as one of
the little studies that the Chairman requested, for us to describe
what other G-10 central banks do with regard to dealing with these
smaller--if I may put it that way--problems. Indeed, in most of the
cases where efforts have been made to help other countries we have not
been involved in terms of our own money, though the U. S. Treasury is
often involved whereas other central banks have been involved. An
example is the current effort to put together a bridge loan for
Argentina. You will find the other G-10 central banks backing the BIS
in that loan. In the case of United States participation, if that
goes forward, it will be done exclusively by the Treasury. Most of
those central banks in turn are supported by their treasuries in one
way or another, sometimes formally but not always formally. In some
cases there are central banks that take a degree of risk in a loan to
another country in a far corner of the world; an example is Sweden
relative to Argentina. The Federal Reserve has chosen not to do that.
So maybe it would be useful, at least as a background note, to try to
put together a study to describe what other countries do. That
doesn't touch the big issues but it might help deal with the little
ones.
MS. MINEHAN. It's probably not right to think that we can
dot every "i" and cross every "t" and have a set process that we
follow in all circumstances. But what you're suggesting would be
helpful, I think, in terms of our understanding this better.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Vice Chairman, you have been as much
involved with this as anybody.

-10-

3/28/95

VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Yes, Mr. Chairman. I think that a
very basic issue that exists even in light of the very changed
international financial markets is whether an individual country is
responsible for its own conduct, including paying the price for its
own mistakes. The debates that were very difficult on occasion in the
Mexican situation were those where some of our normal allies
questioned whether we were forgiving Mexico excessively for policy
errors. We took the view, as you know, that Mexico was unique, not
just unusual, and that there was very serious systemic risk involved.
That was not the easiest case to make as Alan Blinder and I discovered
at the January and February BIS Sunday night dinners and Mike Kelley
at the March dinner. Having been the permanent feature from the
Federal Reserve at all three meetings, I got to get my head bloodied
at all three!
I think one of the difficult questions in moving toward
elaborate discussions of the IMF becoming the lender of last resort,
which I think is a terrible idea as you do, and even whether we should
modify significantly the swap lines and the other central bank
relationships that exist from the Bretton Woods era is just that basic
question: Is it the responsibility of each country, including our
own, to manage its affairs in such a way that the market does not turn
and punish it severely? The main thing that the speed and size of
capital flows have changed is that the punishment is very quick and
very severe. It's not all that different; it's just faster and
deeper. There is great reluctance on the part of leading central
banks in Europe and Japan, and I think by and large those of us around
the table here, to think that we should shift to a world in which
everybody can misbehave and the world will take care of them. The
world doesn't have the riches or the resources to make that possible.
I think we have to be careful, including in meetings like the Halifax
Summit, not to be moving in this excessively and unrealistically
permissive direction.
The Federal Reserve, it seems to me, has been handling
brilliantly the very difficult balancing act involved in being
supportive of U.S. policy on Mexico, which we thought was basically a
good idea at least in substance--I say that as a compliment to you,
Mr. Chairman, because you had to do most of it--without getting
confused that it should be translated into something that is much more
broadly applicable. That policy was to consider the Mexican case
unique, which was very difficult for us to do because the next
deserving case in the view of many people was Argentina. One could
argue that the Argentines have had better policy and that they are
taking much more aggressive actions to fix themselves. And therefore
it was tough for us to say that we thought Mexico needed support,
including support from the Federal Reserve, but that we did not think
Argentina needed our support. I think the single best argument that
we had is that Mexico is unique. If it isn't, if it's only unusual,
God knows where you decide the line gets established.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. If there is no further discussion, I
would like to combine the three foreign policy instruments and move
them simultaneously. Would somebody like to make a motion?
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

So move.

Is there a second?

-11-

3/28/95

MS. MINEHAN.

Second.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. Let's move on
finally to our regular agenda and I call on Peter Fisher.
MR. FISHER.
Appendix.]

Thank you, Mr. Chairman.

[Statement--see

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Questions for Peter on either the
domestic or the foreign side?
MR. JORDAN. Peter, there's been some press commentary to the
effect that the dollar's role as the dominant international reserve
currency is on the wane, that we are following the pound sterling's
earlier slide. Yet the facts are, as you have reported, that central
banks around the world have substantially increased their holdings of
dollars and reduced their holdings of deutschemarks and other
currencies. These outside commentaries would suggest that central
banks around the world are now holding a lot more dollar reserves than
they really want. Is that your perception?
MR. FISHER. I think a number of central banks are holding
more dollar reserves than some people within those central banks think
they ought to be holding. I wouldn't pretend to say that is the
official posture of all the central banks, but I think the leakage
into the markets occurs as a result of that. There are a number of
central banks in Asia that both have accumulated large dollar reserves
and have a rather active approach to foreign exchange trading as a
potential source of central bank profit. In those central banks, some
people may have a view that they would rather hold fewer dollars, and
since the banks' foreign exchange desks tend to be somewhat active,
the market then is free to interpret that when they move one way that
must be a secular trend. It is more frequently just trading back and
forth, but that sort of activity certainly has provided some credence
to that general story.
MR. JORDAN. One final question:
In particular, do you know
how the Bundesbank and the Bank of Japan feel about the exchange
translation that has been eroding their dollar assets?
MR. FISHER. I talk to them from time to time about that.
They are not happy about it, but the Bundesbank is fully committed to
a single reserve currency--the dollar. They have no appetite for
diversifying their portfolio. I think the Bank of Japan at a policy
level is still more or less committed to a dollar reserve policy.
They have diversified somewhat and are holding a few more marks. It's
still a tiny, tiny fraction of their total reserves.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Parry.

MR. PARRY. This is a question for either Peter or Ted. In
terms of causes of the weakness in the dollar, you referred to the
change in expectations about future U.S. fiscal deficits. One way to
look at the effect of deficits is that if monetary policy has an
inflation objective, the impact of greater deficits is to increase the
real rate of interest. Very often that would lead to a higher value
of the dollar. In fact, there are many macro models that have that
type of linkage. For you to get a lower value of the dollar, I think

-12-

3/28/95

there has to be an assumption that the debt would be monetized. My
question is, of these two types of influences on the dollar, what
roles do you think they play over the longer term and what role have
they played in the most recent period?
MR. FISHER. I'll take the short term and leave Ted with the
long term! In the short term, I think the fiscal picture weighs on
the dollar as I mentioned principally in terms of the competence issue
as it relates to U.S. economic management, not in the sense of
forecasting a macro economic effect. Whether analytically correct or
not, market participants do in a sense add up the two deficits, the
current account deficit and the fiscal deficit, and say we can't
manage anything so they can't find any reason to buy dollars or hold
dollars. In the short run, at least in the last three months, I don't
think the markets have really tried to digest the implications, as you
have, on a much more sophisticated basis. But they are negative in
the short run. Now, I'll defer to Ted on the tougher question.
MR. TRUMAN. Well, on the tougher question, I think you are
absolutely right about the result that the standard macro models will
give you: A cut in the fiscal deficit will produce lower interest
rates and that in turn will translate through to reducing the external
deficit through lower interest rates and a lower currency. One way to
square that with the notion that the dollar should appreciate if the
fiscal deficit is cut, is to distinguish between real and nominal. To
the extent that there is a fear out there that the central bank will
seek at some point to monetize the deficit or float it away through
more inflation, then a country could have a stronger nominal currency
at the same time that it had a weaker real currency.
MR. PARRY. I guess the point I want to make is that it keys
off what monetary policy-MR. TRUMAN. There is one other argument for which there is
some support in the literature. It is a longer-term argument that
would run from a lower deficit to more investment, a more competitive
currency, and therefore an appreciation of the dollar. That is a very
long-run argument. A slightly different argument has a timing
feature:
If the fiscal deficit is cut, that will start to bring down
the current account deficit sooner than otherwise and less of a
depreciation will be needed in the long run than otherwise. That is a
sort of "compared with what" argument. In terms of the long run, much
of this argument does turn on the factors that Peter was talking
about--the notion that the fiscal situation has played on the dollar
more in terms of whether we, the United States, can manage our affairs
appropriately. That probably has been exacerbated again in the
psychological realm by the Mexican situation. Those two situations
have played off against each other more than any deep reading of the
macroeconomics involved.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Blinder.

MR. BLINDER. I want to make a comment on Bob Parry's point
and then pose a question. On Bob's point and the answers to it, isn't
it relevant that over the last three months, six months, nine months,
twelve months--pick your timeframe; it almost doesn't matter--surveys
of inflationary expectations in the United States have shown no
deterioration and long bonds here are trading at lower interest rates,

-13-

3/28/95

not higher interest rates? Those two things would seem to me largely
persuasive--although none of this is definitive with regard to the
state of long-term inflationary expectations absent an index bond, for
which all of us here at the Federal Reserve have been rooting for a
long time. But it is about the best information that we have, and it
seems to me that it speaks with one voice on the extent to which the
market expects the Federal Reserve to monetize deficits. I think--I
guess the opposite of "ahistorical" is "historical"--that is also an
historical observation because the Federal Reserve has not been
monetizing deficits. Whether one has rational or adaptive
expectations, I think it is sensible not to presume that the Federal
Reserve is going to monetize deficits. And I don't believe the
markets believe that the Federal Reserve is going to monetize them.
Do either of you disagree with that, Ted or Peter?
MR. FISHER.

No.

MR. TRUMAN.

No.

I only wish I had thought of it.

MR. BLINDER. Now the question I was going to pose:
Peter, I
thought you said--correct me if I just misheard what you were reading
--that the short end led interest rates down since the last FOMC
meeting. Did you say that?
MR. FISHER.
MR. BLINDER.

That is our sense that the short end-I am reading the Greenbook table--

MR. PRELL. I think Peter was referring to the shorter
intermediate term, the 1- to 3-year area.
MR. FISHER. I am very sorry if that was not clear.
referring to the 2-year maturity of the coupon curve.
MR. BLINDER.

Okay.

Fine.

I was

I have no question in that case.

MS. MINEHAN. Peter, you mentioned that the dealers were
surprised by the demand for Treasuries and that was what made the
difference in terms of the price and yield moves in the Treasury
market. Clearly, people are not buying dollars to get into the
Treasury market. Has there been a big change in the ownership of
these securities foreign vis-a-vis domestic? Or is it even
appropriate to ask that?
MR. FISHER. No, I don't think there has been a big rush of
foreign demand for Treasuries. The sense is that the money has been
coming out of the investment community, the mutual funds, and the real
money crowd into the dealer community. The dealers have been
surprised by that. Their tendency had been to play the market from
the short side during this period. It gave the market a bit of a
choppy feel from time to time, and in fact contributed to some of the
rise in prices. There was a phenomenon of the market doing better
during the afternoons, which was sort of curious. We feel that was a
bit the result of the dealers just catching up with their own
customers. But we don't have any sense of foreign demand. There is
constant chatter going on about how the capital flight from Latin
America is fueling the bond market. Capital flight from Latin
America, however defined, is not of a sufficient size to drive the

-14-

3/28/95

overall dollar exchange rate. It is large relative to the peso and
other Latin American currencies. It's hard to see if it is not big
enough to affect the dollar exchange rate overall how it is really big
enough to drive the bond market, which is rather large.
MS. MINEHAN.

It's not big enough to affect the Treasury

market.
MR. FISHER. So, these stories are more in the nature of
anecdotes floating around than anything we have been able to pin down.
MR. TRUMAN. There is one explanation that I'm not sure is
right, but it helps to answer the question of why the dollar was weak
relative to many of the European currencies over this period. One
story that can be told is that there has been some degree of flight
from emerging markets, or shifts in demand for emerging market
instruments. And emerging market instruments are dollar-denominated.
Ms. MINEHAN.

Right.

MR. TRUMAN. The most important of these are the Brady bonds.
Those bonds have taken a tremendous hit over the first quarter of this
year. Although U.S. investors hold some of the Brady bonds, they also
are held around the world by all kinds of investment funds. It's not
irrational for those funds, many of which are Japanese--after all
there is a lot of savings in Japan--to think that as investors move
out of Brady bonds that are dollar denominated instruments, they will
move into instruments denominated in the other two or three major
currencies, including the Swiss franc. So that seems to me to be the
one element one can point to that would help explain some degree of
rally in terms of our own bond market and some degree of weakness of
the dollar vis-a-vis the yen, the deutschemark, and the Swiss franc.
I am not sure it is quantitatively significant enough, but if you look
at what has happened to the prices of the Brady bonds, it has to mean
that there has been a big shift in the ex-ante demand for those
instruments over this period.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. One of the central banks that we ought
to be concerned about other than the Bundesbank and the Bank of Japan,
as large holders of dollars that they are not going to relinquish, is
the Bank of Taiwan. It holds close to $90 billion in Eurodollars and
direct claims against the U.S., largely in Treasury securities. They
are traders, needless to say. Whereas it is fairly difficult
politically and strategically in the context of the G-7 to have major
shifts in dollar holdings by either the Bank of Japan or the
Bundesbank, I am not sure there is terribly much inhibition in that
large sort of bloated stock of securities sitting out there. We have
some data; I haven't looked at it. What proportion of their holdings
of U.S. Treasuries are short-term Treasury bills? Do you know?
MR. TRUMAN. We wouldn't have the data unless they are held
at the New York Bank.
MR. FISHER. We have data on what they hold with us as
custodian, but that is only a portion of what most central banks hold.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Have you checked the data?

-15-

3/28/95

MR. FISHER.
those data here.

I don't have an exact view.

I don't have any of

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Peter, what has happened to the total
custodian holdings of Treasury securities in the last 10 weeks or so?
MR. FISHER. In the last 10 weeks they have gone up.
an extraordinary rise of $10 billion in one reporting period.
has been some back and forth movement in such holdings.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

We had
There

Is that because of the Caribbean--?

MR. FISHER. No, it didn't include the Caribbean. The market
all read it as entirely the Bank of Japan.
Ironically, it was to a substantial extent other Asian central
banks who were thought to be sellers of dollars.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
MR. FISHER.

Who in fact were buying dollars!

Who just happened to be shifting.

MR. TRUMAN. You have to remember that as a statistical
matter they can move investments from Eurodollar holdings to the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York and that will show up as custodian
holdings but it doesn't have any currency implications at all.
MR. FISHER. We did have a period when our custodial accounts
went down quite a bit, net, but I haven't looked at the figures.
There was a period where some of the Asian central banks---went into bills, came out of them, and went
back. That created some volatility in our custody holdings.
So those
holdings probably are a little higher over the past 10 or 20 weeks,
but not dramatically, I would think.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
I assume there is no concern about the
American dollar in the context of our holding dollars as custodians
for foreign official accounts!
I only got a chuckle out of the Vice
Chairman!
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. That was with my President of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York hat on. That's why I chuckled.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

I realize that.

MR. FISHER. If I could comment, going back to the reserve
currency status issue, it is interesting that the markets all chatter
about how the dollar is losing its reserve currency status. Yet, the
dollar bill is in heavy demand around the world.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

You mean the hundred dollar bill?

MR. FISHER. The hundred dollar bill, yes. The greenback.
It's an interesting offset to the concept that the dollar is losing
its reserve currency status.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Any further questions for Peter?

-16-

3/28/95

MR. MCTEER. Peter, I understand that some Fed watchers, in
trying to decide whether to blame the Federal Reserve for the weakness
of the dollar, have pointed to the fact that the dollar price of gold
has not gone up very much while the mark and yen prices of gold have
gone down. On that basis they pretty much absolve us from blame and
say it's more of a mark and yen problem than it is a dollar problem.
Do you take any comfort in that view?
MR. FISHER.
[Laughter]

A tiny tiny bit.

I don't particularly!

MR. MCTEER. To what degree do you think we have a dollar
problem as opposed to a mark and yen problem?
MR. FISHER. I think we have a dollar problem, as I
mentioned, in the way the foreign exchange market looks at the
relationship between our interest rates and our current account. I
don't mean that should drive the policy decided around this table, but
that is the chain around our ankle, if you will, that we have to deal
with; it's the load we are carrying. The mark is at extraordinary
highs on a trade-weighted basis. The mark clearly is strong--however
defined--against us, against Europe, against everybody. There also is
a problem of an ever appreciating yen. Now, something may break that
at some point, but until it does I think there are problems in each
corner; each leg of this stool has its own problem. And that in my
view is how we get the historic lows or historic highs--when there is
something that is pushing the exchange rate on both sides in the same
direction.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Further questions for Peter? If not,
would somebody like to move approval of the actions of the foreign
Desk?
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
MS. MINEHAN.

So move.

Is there a second?

Second.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
transactions?

Without objection.

VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH.

The domestic Desk

So move.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Second?
MS. MINEHAN.

Second.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. Let's now move on to
what used to be called the Chart Show. Whatever happened to the chart

presentation?
MR. PRELL.

We didn't have it in February.

issue for July.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
MR. PRELL.

No.

We don't have it today?

It's an open

-17-

3/28/95

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
[Laughter]
MR. TRUMAN.

That sounds like a precedent to me!

Either that or an exception.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Messrs. Prell and Truman.

MR. PRELL. After we have gone on even briefly you may decide
that you don't want the full length Chart Show, but we'll see.
[Statement--see Appendix.]
MR. TRUMAN.

[Statement--see Appendix.]

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Questions for either gentleman?

MR. PARRY. Mike, in terms of the growth rates for the
baseline forecast of real GDP, it looks like almost a perfect soft
landing in some respects. But as one focuses more on what the economy
looks like in 1996, it seems to me that there are some very troubling
aspects, particularly if one considers what a simulation for 1997
might produce. For example, we see that at the end of the year the
unemployment rate is below conventional estimates of the natural rate.
That suggests to me that if we were to simulate through 1997 we
probably would have higher inflation. Therefore, the conclusion is
that on the baseline forecast we not only are making no progress
toward reducing inflation, we actually are going to see a period of
three years in which inflation at best would stay about flat, but in
terms of models most likely would worsen. Is that a correct
assumption?
MR. PRELL. Reading the numbers as precisely as they are
written down, the thrust of the baseline forecast is that we think we
have a modest degree of financial restraint that will hold growth
slightly below potential and have the unemployment rate creep up. But
we are at a point where we think high levels of resource utilization
will begin to foster very gradually some momentum toward higher
inflation. So, yes, the most natural extrapolation from this would be
a slightly higher rate of inflation in 1997.
MR. PARRY.

Thank you.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Jordan.

MR. JORDAN. Mike, I guess I am a little surprised at your
answer to Bob, and that intrigues me some because my question related
to the almost "too good to be true" sort of pattern for nominal GDP
growth through the next two years and the composition of prices-whether the deflator or the CPI--and output. If I understand it, your
assumption is that the fed funds rate stays at 6 percent for the full
eight quarters.
MR. PRELL.

That is correct.

MR. JORDAN. You have long bond yields coming down somewhat
further. You don't say how much, but I assume you still have an
upward sloping yield curve through the whole two-year period.

-18-

3/28/95

MR. PRELL.
average dimension.
MR. JORDAN.
MR. PRELL.

Essentially, we would have an upward slope of

Some liquidity premium in there?
Yes.

MR. JORDAN.
So you have nominal spending rising at a rate of
less than 5 percent for eight quarters and pretty much a flat pattern
through 1996.
It's not much different from the last several
Greenbooks except that at least it's flat now whereas before it
dropped this year and rose later.
So, to decompose nominal spending
into its parts, you have real output rising a little less than 2-1/2
percent on average and prices also rising a little less than 2-1/2
percent, using the deflator anyway, to give you that nominal spending.
Yet, you have a structure of interest rates in which rates are 6
percent and higher throughout the yield curve for the whole eightquarter period. I look at that and say I don't know whether it's a
good forecast or a bad forecast.
I certainly don't have a different
one to propose, but in the sense of a "reasonableness" check, should I
expect nominal interest rates to be in the 6 to 7 percent range while
nominal spending is under 5 percent for a two-year period?
Comment?
MR. PRELL.
If you are asking whether the relationship of
nominal interest rates to nominal growth looks abnormal or
unreasonable here, I would say that there is not a very strong
regularity in the history of the relationship between nominal interest
rates and nominal GDP growth.
We have played around with some
econometric exercises to see whether there is any information to be
gained by looking at that spread as an index of restraint and
prospective real economic activity.
It is weak.
It can contribute a
little to explaining the prospects.
I don't feel uncomfortable with
this forecast.
I think the fact that the nominal interest rate is a
little higher than nominal GDP growth is consistent with our sense
that this is putting some drag on economic activity, just as the fact
that the real short-term rate, a bit above historical averages as we
perceive it, could be interpreted as being consistent with some modest
monetary restraint on top of what we believe to be some moderate
fiscal restraint.
That is very hard to say.
The real rate of
interest could vary considerably over a cycle or even a little longer.
MR. JORDAN.
If I could follow up--one thing implicit in both
the assumptions and the forecast and your responses to me and to Bob
Parry earlier is that either the financial markets are embodying and
maintaining a higher inflation premium for a sustained period of time
I take
than what we are observing or we have a higher real yield.
this as being a forecast of an economy that is operating for the next
We are
two years essentially at full employment or full capacity.
right at the ceiling over this whole period.
MR. PRELL. We are slightly above the ceiling now, drifting
back toward the ceiling.
MR. JORDAN.

MR. PRELL.

Okay, but at least not below it.

We are splitting hairs here.

-19-

3/28/95

MR. JORDAN. So you would say it is unlikely that the real
yield embodied in financial instruments is higher than what the
economy is actually churning out or capable of churning out. Unless
you have some sort of risk or uncertainty assumption in there, that
implies that the market is maintaining an inflation premium. Market
participants are still looking out beyond this forecast horizon at a
rate of inflation and that is still being embedded in nominal yields.
MR. PRELL. Let me separate these questions. In some simple
models, one can relate the observed real rate of interest to the
longer-term growth of the economy as a sort of equilibrium, steady
state condition. But if one starts elaborating those models, it can
get much more complicated. On the question of what we think is going
on with inflation expectations, yes, our presumption is that the
current inflation expectation for the shorter run is in the 3 percent
--3 percent plus--area for consumer prices. As we go out into the
intermediate-term--5 to 10 years--expectations are probably closer to
4 percent inflation.
MR. JORDAN.

Okay.

MR. PRELL. At this point, in our judgment, the notion of a
downward trend to inflation is not embedded in the markets. Rather,
there is some more inflation in the works, as President Parry was
suggesting. Our forecast is pointing toward some gradual pickup to a
higher level of inflation.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Other questions?

MR. BLINDER. I did have a question, but I am again picking
up on Bob Parry, especially on the answer to his question.
SPEAKER(?).

Picking on him or picking up on him?

MR. BLINDER. No, picking up on him--definitely not picking
on him. Inspired by him. Mike, referring to your answer to Bob, I
was reading the quarterly Greenbook numbers on the capacity
utilization rate. They peak at 85.1 and they go down every single
quarter through 1996 Q4, at that point reaching 82.9. I can't
imagine, though I thought I heard you say "yes" in your answer to Bob,
that if this page were another two inches wide and we saw the numbers
for 1997 on it, that the utilization rate would abruptly turn back up.
Again, I am reading this just the way you stated it, Mike, with the
economy gradually going back to its natural growth rate, which does
not lead to ever accelerating inflation.
MR. PRELL. Indeed. But in 1997, assuming gradual
convergence, we are as I said splitting hairs.
MR. BLINDER. You already have 5.8 percent unemployment and
82.9 capacity utilization by the end of 1996.
MR. PRELL. Exactly, and in 1997 on this trajectory, we would
get back to the NAIRU and a little lower on capacity utilization. In
theory at that point, the inflation rate would stabilize at just a
hair higher than we observe as the trend to 1996.
MR. BLINDER.

Okay.

-20-

3/28/95

MR. TRUMAN. Maybe this is cutting it too close, but if you
look at the two years together in the Greenbook, we have a little more
inflation this year because of what we have assumed about the dollar.
Therefore, the flatness produces a bit of a distortion. It suggests
that the trend is very gradual, but there may be more trend than the
numbers themselves suggest.
MR. PRELL. We are using the usual sacrifice ratios and a
NAIRU around 6 percent; and given our projected unemployment rate, we
are only talking about accelerations of a couple of tenths a year.
The convergence by 1997 implies that we may not even have that in that
year.
MR. BLINDER.

That was my point.

MR. PARRY. The point I wanted to make was that clearly your
projection does not show any improvement on inflation; we are not
making progress.
MR. LINDSEY.
MR. PARRY.
MR. TRUMAN.
MR. PRELL.
MR. BLINDER.

I understood it to be a deterioration.
Yes.
A slight deterioration.
Yes.
Thank you.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Further questions?
like to start the discussion? President McTeer.

If not, who would

MR. MCTEER. The Eleventh District has slowed somewhat over
the past few months, and most of the slowing seems to be in Texas
rather than in our parts of New Mexico and Louisiana. A member of our
Advisory Council on Small Business and Agriculture said with respect
to New Mexico that they had "hit the three cherries" there this past
year. I am not familiar with that terminology, [Laughter] but it
probably would apply to Louisiana whose rebound last year seems to
have a lot to do with the gaming industry. The picture in Texas is
mixed; employment declined in January for the first time in thirty
months, but it rebounded in February. The biggest negative for Texas,
of course, is the situation in Mexico, both actual and prospective.
Our staff has conducted three special Beigebook surveys on
expectations about the impact of Mexico's problems on Texas
businesses, and each of those surveys has gotten more pessimistic
about the overall impact on Texas. Dozens of retail establishments
have closed in most of our border towns. Unemployment is up all along
the border. With respect to Mexico itself, given that their economic
policies in recent years have been fundamentally sound, the austerity
program that this country apparently has been pushing on them seems
unnecessarily harsh to me and may prove to be counterproductive in the
long run.
As for the national economy, about the only straw in the wind
that I have picked up that others may not have picked up has to do
with retail sales. J.C. Penney, which I regard as the retailer to the

-21-

3/28/95

middle class, is having in March its second consecutive decline in
sales.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Minehan.

MS. MINEHAN. Both the statistical indicators and our
informal contacts suggest that the pace of expansion is slowing in the
First District. Since we never got into an expansionary phase to
begin with, this is not being met with great joy around the District.
Payroll employment in the region grew a little more slowly at the end
of 1994 than it had earlier in the year and then dropped in January.
Help-wanted advertising dropped. At the same time, our retail
contacts, which are really quite a diverse set, were almost unanimous
in reporting that sales were flat to down in both January and
February. Some attributed the disappointing performance to the
weather; again, we didn't have much snow this year. But there was
general agreement that the regional economy is slowing. On the
manufacturing side, our contacts are more positive than the retailers.
That has been the general pattern for the last several months. A
majority of our contacts reported increases over the year ranging from
quite modest to fairly strong--in the range of 30 percent or so. But
aircraft parts, medical
there are some notable areas of weakness:
equipment, and potentially the small volume of manufacturing in our
area that relates to the auto industry. The price picture remains as
before. Prices are generally stable but there are major exceptions in
the areas of paper, plastics, and leather in particular. Residential
construction has slowed in our region as it apparently has elsewhere,
but the potential for nonresidential construction is solid, both as we
see it happening right now and in the future. Vacancy rates in Boston
are now about 10 percent, which is a level that, at least earlier in
the 1990s, nobody predicted would happen over the next 10 years. It
may well be that we will see new office construction soon--if not in
downtown Boston, then on the circumferential highways of 128 and 495.
By way of contrast--and New England has really been an area of
contrasts throughout this recovery--Hartford vacancy rates are in the
mid-20 percent range and still rising.
Two major items of economic interest have dominated the
regional news. The first of these is the report of the commission on
military base closings--the defense industry in the New England region
is about 1 in 10 jobs--and the second is the proposed Fleet-Shawmut
merger. Hanscomb Air Force Base, which is in eastern Massachusetts,
was not on the closing list to the great relief of many in
Massachusetts. If the initial recommendations are approved and
Hanscomb continues in operation, it will add slightly to jobs in the
region rather than take away something like 11,000 jobs. The FleetShawmut merger has prompted at least two state attorneys general to
threaten some sort of action--we are not really sure what--over the
loss of jobs as a result of efficiency measures expected after the
merger. So far, Connecticut appears to have negotiated a deal to keep
certain jobs that would otherwise have been cut, and I am sure
Massachusetts has this in mind as well. We have not seen a draft
application, which I think is being held up because of the complexity
of some of the competitive issues involved in this merger.
Turning to the Greenbook, I must say that I have some
concerns along the lines that Bob Parry was suggesting. We find
ourselves in agreement with the basic GDP growth rates shown in the

-22-

3/28/95

baseline forecast. But when we use these growth rates, our own
projections of unemployment are slightly lower than the Greenbook's
and our estimates of inflation growth are a bit higher. More
importantly, we don't see the level of inflation stabilizing next
year. I know there is a tradeoff in terms of the impact from the
external sector, but we don't see that level of stability in terms of
rates of inflation growth in 1996. We see a gradual uptick, which is
consistent with our projections of unemployment. We believe that the
core trend is rising, which is discussed in the Greenbook. Therefore,
we think and maybe others believe as well, that there is a bit of
upside risk in the degree of inflationary pressure in the baseline
forecast, particularly as we take it out through 1996.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Parry.

MR. PARRY. Mr. Chairman, growth in the Twelfth District
economy as a whole remains moderately strong. The District's
unemployment rate has dropped 1-1/2 percentage points in the past 12
months. The intermountain states have experienced very rapid growth,
although we have seen some moderation recently. In California, the
modest recovery may gain some momentum this year. Revised payroll
employment data for California show that the recovery so far has been
characterized by a rebound in construction, recent strength in nonaerospace manufacturing, and continued growth in services. Payroll
employment in southern California now is growing at the fastest pace
among the regions in California after falling at the fastest rate
during the recession.
While overall conditions remain strong in the District,
several special factors will damp growth in some areas. In
California, the estimated damage from March rains and floods is
expected to reach $2 billion, including $400 million in crop losses.
The recent storms also will depress state employment, construction
activity, and retail sales. Recent developments in Mexico likely are
beginning to restrain growth in California and Arizona. Arizona's
dependence on trade with Mexico is about three times the national
average, while California's dependence is about 1-1/2 times the
nation's. To date, the anecdotal evidence confirms initial estimates
that developments in Mexico will reduce growth in U.S. real GDP by a
few tenths of a percentage point in 1995--Ted indicated roughly a
third of a percent in his forecast--which implies a moderate-sized
shock to both California and Arizona. However, I must admit there is
concern that a severe recession in Mexico could bring about more
substantial effects on these states, particularly as one gets closer
and closer to the Mexican border. In Washington State, the widely
publicized cutbacks at Boeing will hold down employment in the near
term. However, it appears to us that these cutbacks are more
indicative of a restructuring effort than of a downturn in the longerrun outlook for aircraft production in the state of Washington.
If I may turn briefly to the national economy, the broad
contour of our forecast is similar to that of the Greenbook, although
we seem to have differences that are very similar to those mentioned
by President Minehan. Throughout this year, the economy most likely
will remain above levels of labor and capacity utilization that are
consistent with steady inflation, despite a slowing of growth in real
GDP. Thus, we anticipate that inflation will increase a bit this year
and next. Of course, there is always considerable uncertainty in such

-23-

3/28/95

forecasts and this is a particularly important consideration at this
early stage of a slowdown in growth that now appears to be under way.
I find it interesting that several of the spending equations in our
model are predicting levels that are below the actual data in the
fourth quarter, suggesting that there may be some downside risks to
the real side of the forecast. Moreover, I guess we have all noted
that forecasts from a model often underpredict the amplitude of
cyclical movements in the economy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Moskow.

MR. MOSKOW. Mr. Chairman, Seventh District manufacturing
activity remained brisk in recent months, but there were signs of
moderation in some of the interest rate-sensitive industries, notably
autos and single-family housing. Sales of autos and light trucks in
January and February came in under a 15 million unit, seasonally
adjusted, annual rate, which was below industry forecasts as well as
our own forecast. Auto makers responded quickly by cutting first- and
second-quarter assembly schedules. In line with the Greenbook, we now
expect light vehicle output to add very little to first-quarter GDP
and probably subtract at least a full percentage point from secondquarter growth. It is important to keep in mind that April is a
critical month for the auto industry because that is when they
determine their model year build-out. Once they determine the number
of units produced, they then apply the incentives necessary to sell
them for the remainder of the model year. Recent reports from the Big
Three auto makers as well as from District auto dealers and
distributors suggest that light vehicle sales have improved in March,
perhaps to as much as a 15-1/2 million unit rate, with sales increases
concentrated among those models where incentives have been enhanced.
However, it will take another month or so
I emphasize, "as much as."
before we know whether the early 1995 softness in lighter vehicle
sales reflects what one industry contact called "the pause that
refreshes" or whether there has been a more permanent pullback on the
part of consumers.
Single-family housing is the other major industry that showed
outright weakness in early 1995. But this is being countered by
growing multifamily and commercial construction activity. In
addition, we have had a few reports that recent declines in mortgage
interest rates may have mitigated some of the softening in mortgage
demand and existing home sales. We are all aware that sales of
Michael Jordan's new number 45 Chicago Bulls jersey have been
exceptionally strong recently, [Laughter] but overall retail sales
growth in the District has slowed from the fourth-quarter pace.
District reports on March-to-date sales suggest no change from the
moderating pace set in January and February. Apart from apparel,
inventories are not seriously out of line with desired levels,
although an increasing number of retailers in our February Michigan
survey reported rising stocks. Price discounting continues to be
pervasive and competition intense.
The District's manufacturing sector outside autos continues
to expand at a robust pace. District steel production in the first
quarter will post its second largest year-over-year gain since the end
of the 1990-1991 recession. However, confidential information we have
on the Chicago Purchasing Managers Index, which will be released to
the public this Friday--I emphasize that this is confidential until

-24-

3/28/95

Friday--will indicate a significant slowing in the pace of expansion
during March as well as a slight easing in prices-paid inflation. I
would add that, on the other hand, the tone of our recent meeting of
the Advisory Council on Agriculture, Labor and Small Business was
quite positive, with representatives indicating that their small
business contacts still expect growth in 1995 to be in line with that
in 1994. The agricultural sector is stronger than we had expected.
Farm land values continue to rise. There was a 6-1/2 percent increase
in District farm land values last year, and that was the largest
annual gain in six years. January and February unit sales of farm
tractors and combines were the strongest since 1984 and were up nearly
10 percent from a year ago. On the employment front, labor markets
remain very tight. Help wanted ads continue to climb in the region,
and the survey of Midwest employers indicates further strengthening in
hiring plans. Virtually all of our contacts in the personnel supply
industry report difficulties finding workers to meet the needs of
their customers. Our directors as well as the members of our Advisory
Council express significant concerns about labor shortages,
particularly in the state of Indiana. One of our directors from
Indiana told of a help wanted ad being placed offering a sign-up bonus
of $200. By mistake, the ad ran with an extra 0, offering a $2,000
bonus, and it ran for two days before they realized it. They had a
total of three responses to the ad! Overall developments in the
Seventh District, while upbeat in many respects, are gradually
beginning to reflect some of the mixed signals observed around the
nation.
Our appraisal of the national economic picture is very
similar to the Greenbook's. In general, we concur with its forecast
of slower real growth combined with a modest but increasing rate of
CPI inflation.
MR. BOEHNE. Mike, when Hoosiers see something that is too
good to be true, they know it probably is.
[Laughter]
MR. FORRESTAL.

Spoken like a true Hoosier!

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Quick, President Broaddus.

MR. BROADDUS. Mr. Chairman, reports coming out of our
District, which I would remind you is the District where Michael
Jordan came from originally-- [Laughter]
MR. MOSKOW.

He's now in Chicago.

MR. BROADDUS. These reports continue to show some slowing in
the regional economy. We do, of course, conduct monthly manufacturing
and service sector surveys, and for the latest two months both surveys
are consistent with some general softening in activity in our region.
Our directors, while they are still broadly optimistic, are presenting
more balanced comments now on local and regional conditions than
earlier when almost all of their comments emphasized the strength in
business activity. Let me give you a couple of quick examples. The
central North Carolina area around the cities of Durham and Raleigh
has been the strongest local economy in our District, probably about
the strongest local area in the entire country. Activity there is
still strong, but we are seeing some signs of softening there. Home

3/28/95

-25-

sales are weaker than they were; automobile sales and sales of other
durables are also a bit weaker. As another example,
is on the board of a large national apparel retailer. In
that role, she watches consumer trends not only in the apparel
industry specifically but more generally, and she is not very
optimistic about the outlook for consumer spending either regionally
or nationally.
To summarize by sector in our District: Retail activity
clearly has weakened since the beginning of the year; manufacturing
also has moderated, although a good bit less; and both residential and
commercial real estate activity have been flat over recent weeks, but
some leasing agents have told us that the market for prime office
space has become a good bit tighter over the last few months. There
is some closing of the gap there.
The situation in our region, of course, is broadly consistent
with developments at the national level. Much of the national data
since our last meeting, as we all know, clearly suggests that the
expansion is beginning to moderate. I think the most compelling
evidence of that is in the retail sales data. Further evidence is
provided by some of the latest residential construction information,
especially the decline in single-family starts to the lowest level in
about two years. In my view these developments clearly have been
reflected in financial markets. Despite the recent acceleration in
core CPI, bond rates have come down. I think that certainly can be an
indication of some reduction in inflation expectations, presumably on
the grounds that slower growth will reduce the pressures on resource
utilization and hence on cost and prices going forward.
Against that background, the downward revision in the
Greenbook's projections for the first half of this year and, of
course, the substantial downward revision for the first quarter, are
reasonable. One can support the revised projection analytically in a
variety of ways. In particular, it is consistent with the permanent
income hypothesis, which is a model that many economists now find
persuasive in thinking about consumer behavior. As you know, even
though consumer outlays have diminished lately, income growth has been
well maintained. The saving rate rose significantly in the final
quarter of last year, and if current trends persist, we are going to
get the same kind of increase in the current quarter. The permanent
income hypothesis implies that households will save more if they
expect income to grow more slowly in the future, and of course, that
is consistent with the Greenbook's scenario. In that regard, I might
just note that one of our economists, Peter Ireland, recently
developed a projection for real disposable labor income for this year,
1995, using a VAR model that is really driven by the saving rate. His
projection is consistent with the Greenbook projection using a very
different model of the economy. So, again, I think the broad profile
of the Greenbook's near-term projections is certainly plausible.
Having said all of this, I think that the risks in the
outlook, while certainly more balanced than they were earlier, are
still skewed a bit to the up side. I think we have to keep in mind
that a lot of talk and focus has been on the softer data in some
areas, but not all the recent data have been soft. In particular,
employment has expanded sharply over the last three months. It is up
3/4 of a million jobs over that period. That is an annual growth rate

-26-

3/28/95

of 2-1/2 percent, which clearly is significantly higher than what is
consistent with longer-term noninflationary trend growth in
employment. Also, industrial production was strong enough in February
to push the capacity utilization index back up again. It is now at
the highest level since 1979, if my figures are right on that. And
perhaps most importantly, I am impressed by the continued strength of
business fixed investment, which is a forward-looking indicator, at
least in some sense. So, again, I think the upside risk is still
there and we should not lose sight of that. I just hope we keep that
in the back of our minds going forward.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Forrestal.

MR. FORRESTAL. Mr. Chairman, the economy in the Southeast
has continued to expand in the first quarter, although we are seeing
some signs of slowing from last year's very strong fourth quarter.
Employment growth accelerated in January, and preliminary February
data suggest both strong employment growth and a further decline in
the District unemployment rate. We are now forecasting an
unemployment rate in the District of 4.7 percent when we get the final
data. There are, of course, signs of deceleration as I have
indicated, although I don't view any of these as being signs of real
weakness in any sense. The slowing that we have had is pretty much
along the lines of what we have heard from others for the rest of the
country. Retail sales were quite disappointing to retailers in
February, but this was attributable to particularly wet weather, and
the early March data point to some recovery. Automobile sales have
been declining since 1994, and single-family home sales continued to
fall through early March and are now below year-ago levels.
Manufacturing activity as reported in our manufacturing survey
softened a bit in February--that is both in terms of production and
shipments--and some of this slowing has been attributed to the
situation in Mexico. But other reports suggest that inventory
shortages in several industries are contributing some strength. That
is especially true in chemicals, paper, and packaging. In Tennessee,
the auto plants are operating at full capacity as are the packaging
and paperboard facilities throughout the District. The strongest
increases reported to us are in communications equipment.
On the inflation side, there has been some abatement of raw
materials price increases, and as I have been reporting for several
months, where there have been materials price increases, they
generally have not been passed through to the intermediate or consumer
levels. We still are hearing stories of labor shortages and we too
have heard of signing bonuses, although not quite the size of that
erroneous figure reported by Mike Moskow. Wage increases are still
pretty spotty around the District.
Travel and tourism are quite mixed, with business and
convention travel to Florida, New Orleans, and the Gulf Coast of
Mississippi especially strong. But in general tourism in Florida
remains very lackluster. Tourism around the major baseball spring
camps has been in decline, as you would imagine. Traffic to Florida
from Latin America, again not unexpectedly, has slowed. And European
visitors are still scarce, but that is showing some hints of turning
around. One of our directors from Florida did report that German
visitors are not necessarily all tourists because they are buying the
high-priced homes in Palm Beach. The Germans are moving in very

-27-

3/28/95

aggressively and the $2 million and above houses are now flying the
German flag. In Atlanta, the Olympics are beginning to have an
effect, both in terms of infrastructure and construction for the
venues.
With respect to the national economy, we see underlying
momentum in the economy as still being pretty strong. The signs of
weakness or deceleration that we do have seem somewhat unpersuasive to
me in the face of the resilient fundamentals that seem to exist in the
economy. That is, employment and income are still quite strong, as Al
Broaddus just mentioned. New orders have been strong, as has been
business fixed investment. I am particularly impressed by the plans
that I see for more industrial capacity coming on line this year and
next. Of course, as I have indicated, we do see some moderation, but
less than in the Greenbook. And our differences with the Greenbook
are the same as they were last time. That is, we anticipate somewhat
stronger growth with somewhat higher inflation. We see the inflation
rate moving up in 1995 to 3.5 percent, but expect it to peak at that
level.
We have had some discussion about the dollar this morning,
Mr. Chairman, and I thought I would interject just one comment on that
subject. Although I found Peter's description of the reasons for the
dollar decline quite persuasive, I still am not entirely clear in my
mind what the real reasons are. There are probably many, but I don't
think we really know categorically what they are. More importantly
for us is the question of what impact the lower dollar will have on
the economy. It seems to me that there may be few tangible
repercussions for real activity and prices if the dollar stabilizes
around current levels. Perhaps this is preaching to the choir to some
extent, but I think as a matter of principle we should not be
adjusting policy to achieve some particular external value of the
dollar. In some sense, I believe this is one of the reasons we have a
flexible exchange rate. The dollar is a signal, although a noisy one,
but I don't think it should be a target. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Hoenig.

MR. HOENIG. Mr. Chairman, the Tenth District economy remains
strong, with strength evident throughout the region. Our directors
are uniformly reporting robust growth in all District states.
Moreover, recently revised employment data confirm the strength of the
District economy. Nonfarm jobs were up 4.2 percent in January over
the previous year. New Mexico, for example, continues to rank among
the top states in terms of job growth. Six of our seven District
states are experiencing job growth above the national average.
Manufacturing is a leading source of economic strength; factories in
the region are generally operating at high levels of capacity.
Durable goods makers have been adding jobs at a rapid pace. Retail
sales are generally buoyant across the region, although automobile
sales have shown some weakness recently. In the construction sector,
a recent surge in office construction has more than offset the slowing
in the housing sector. Notwithstanding the recent strength that I am
reporting, there are signs that overall activity is beginning to slow.
Our quarterly survey of manufacturers suggests that activity has begun
to cool somewhat. Fewer factory managers are reporting gains in
production and shipments than was the case last fall. Also, loan
growth in District banks has moderated lately from the rapid growth of

-28-

3/28/95

the fourth quarter last year. Manufacturers report steady increases
in prices of materials, with more of these hikes being passed through
to final product prices. Reports of wage pressures, however, are
still isolated.
Turning to the national economy, recent signs of moderation
in economic activity to a more sustainable level are, of course,
welcome. But whether that moderation will be sufficient to cap
inflation--to echo what others have said--is still an open question.
I believe that, on balance, there is upside risk to the forecast over
the year as a whole. I would like to mention some of the reasons.
The interest-sensitive sectors of the economy may show more strength
than was projected, particularly if the recent run-up in bond prices
is sustained. Notwithstanding Mexico and South America, export growth
may outperform our expectations, given the decline in the dollar.
Firms may be more aggressive in investing in new plant and equipment,
especially given their capacity levels, and less aggressive in paring
inventory growth than we currently believe. Moreover, recent national
bank lending data are consistent with an economy that is still growing
at a fairly strong pace. As for inflation, I agree that the core
level of the CPI is likely to move up to the 3-1/4 percent range this
year. But if the economy comes in stronger than expected and if the
dollar continues to weaken, I think inflation could move higher. I do
not look for much help on the labor cost side because traditionally
labor cost movements have lagged inflation movements, suggesting that
the best news on this front may be behind us. The implication in my
view is that the risks continue to lie on the side of inflationary
pressures. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Jordan.

MR. JORDAN. The Fourth District is operating at a very high
level of economic activity, though clearly the rate of change has
slowed. Directors and other contacts consistently report that
business is not growing as fast as last year, but there are very few
indications of anything declining in an absolute sense or even
concerns of such. Motor vehicles are quite strong. However, the
dealers are now telling us that they have as much in inventory as they
want, and they are sending messages back to the manufacturers to slow
the rate of shipments. How the manufacturers will respond to that in
terms of production is going to be determined in the months ahead. We
have a lot of exporting out of the District although, of course, a
great deal of it is to Canada. Ohio also has large exports to Mexico
--Kentucky does as well--of auto parts. So far, exporters in our
District are not raising any concerns about Mexico as being a
particular problem because, as our companies tell us, their other
markets for exports are quite strong. Canada continues to be a good
export market for us. Canada also is still, for better or worse, a
strong source of investment funds coming into the region. I am not
sure why the motivations are all that attractive from a Canadian
standpoint. Both director reports and direct contacts with some
retailing companies--these are companies that may be headquartered in
our District and operate all over the country--tell us that there has
been a slowing in the growth of retail sales, not absolute declines.
One area of absolute declines is in residential construction.
Generally, there is a pattern of new-start activity being below what
it was in the recent past. Inventories of "for sale" homes seem to be
lengthening. Commercial real estate construction activity has picked

-29-

3/28/95

up compared to last year. Also, industrial spending, for both
productivity and capacity increases, especially motor vehicle-related
capacity, is growing. Companies also tell us that steel capacity
through 1996 and 1997 will be very substantially increased. Since we
have already seen reports of declines in steel prices, they say that
we should look forward to some softness in the steel market in the
next couple of years. One area that is creating a lot of comment, but
to me more uncertainty as to what it all means, is health care
consolidation. We see very large companies getting together. People
talk about the consolidations resulting in job losses, but we have not
yet seen them materialize in any observable way.
As for the national economy, the Greenbook's projection that
nominal spending growth will slow to the range of something under 5
percent this year and next year looks to me like a very desirable
forecast, as I indicated earlier. I don't have any reason to quarrel
with that. If I didn't think that that was going to happen, and if I
thought that nominal spending growth was going to continue in the
range that it was last year, then I would be a lot more concerned than
I am about the prospects for inflation in 1996 and beyond. But if
that forecast of total spending does materialize, then the question
about inflation comes down to issues about productivity growth and the
ability of this economy to expand. I am not too disturbed about what
might happen in terms of reported rates of inflation for 1995. I
don't think that monetary policy can do much about that anyway. At
this point, I mainly would be interested in seeing that the rate of
inflation in 1996 and 1997 resumes decelerating a percentage point or
two from where it has been in the last couple of years. Right now, I
don't have any reason to believe that we are not on a track to achieve
that result. So I am comfortable with the national forecast.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Boehne.

MR. BOEHNE. There are some clear signs of moderating growth
in the Philadelphia District. Manufacturers in particular indicate a
slackening pace that is apparent in new and unfilled orders as well as
current shipments. Retailers report a slowing pace of sales,
especially in autos and other durables, although I think there is
considerable uncertainty among retailers as to whether this is just a
temporary slackening to be followed by a pickup or the beginning of a
slower trend. Residential sales and construction are in a lull and
there likewise I think most realtors are not sure whether this is just
a lull that will pass or the beginning of a long, dry spell.
Commercial real estate conditions are soft, but the cycle seems to
have bottomed out in areas of the District that show more strength.
Looking across the District, even in those areas where economic
activity is stronger than in others, there really is an absence of
wage and price pressures. They just remain subdued and are a
nonproblem. Increasingly in the District, the outlook for moderating
growth is becoming the conventional wisdom, following the fast finish
of last year, which temporarily raised spirits that 1995 might be a
very strong year. Since the Philadelphia District has been a laggard
during this expansion, there is some feeling that the good times could
have lasted longer--the same view that Cathy Minehan finds in New
England.
For the nation, I think we need more than the usual amount of
humility about our assessment of the outlook. To be sure, there are

-30-

3/28/95

increasing signs of slowing growth, but we could be surprised either
on the up side or the down side. Areas like inventories or net
exports or consumption expenditures all strike me as having more
potential than usual for surprises for reasons that have been
discussed. How much inventory accumulation is intended or unintended?
Certainly, the net export outlook has a number of crosscurrents.
Since the lull in consumption expenditures has been mainly in the
durables side, just how temporary is that or is it more permanent?
We are likely to have some increases in inflation in 1995.
We need to try to distinguish between cyclical increases that are
likely to moderate as the cycle matures and increases of a more
underlying or core character. In this context, a slowing of economic
activity makes credible the case that we may see more of a cyclical
increase than an underlying increase. But here too, we need to keep a
few upticks in inflation in the context of a cycle. This comes back
to the importance of gauging the strength of economic activity, and I
think this is a time for monitoring.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Stern.

MR. STERN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me comment first on
the national economy. I find myself a little more confident than I
normally am about the general contour of the Greenbook forecast in
part because, as many people have commented, the incoming data on the
national economy are convincing evidence to me that the pace of growth
has slowed. Those data are also consistent with the tenor of the
anecdotes that I have been picking up in the District lately. I take
some comfort from the incoming data and the Greenbook forecast and
indeed from our own forecast, because as recently as a couple of
months ago it was mostly a hope and a prayer that growth would slow to
something more consistent with trend. Now I think it is a little more
than that. I don't know where the risks lie, particularly; I do know
that the confidence bands around these forecasts, if one does it
rigorously, are very, very wide. I think that is worth bearing in
mind as we go forward.
With regard to the Ninth District and the anecdotes there,
first of all, I think it is worth saying that the District economy on
balance remains very healthy. But, and there are some "buts," there
is no doubt that auto sales, housing activity, and retail sales
generally have slowed perceptibly. The sellers are disappointed and
their attitudes have soured somewhat. I think they attribute this
slowing to the level of interest rates to at least some considerable
degree. On the other side of the coin, labor remains in quite short
supply in most of the District. This has not translated into any real
acceleration in the rate of wage inflation, but it does seem to be
affecting expansion plans and/or current production activity, simply
deferring those plans or limiting output; I think it has made a
difference. The final comment I would offer is that I have a sense
that we are in for some kind of inventory correction. I say that not
on the basis of a lot of rigorous analysis of how production has
matched up with consumption or other spending, but mostly as I listen
to stories about some of the disappointment that has occurred. That
suggests to me that there are some inventories around that people
would rather not be holding, whether they want to admit it or not.
Certainly, the incoming production data on the national economy have

-31-

3/28/95

been stronger than the spending data, consistent with the same story.
That suggests to me that an inventory correction will occur.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Melzer.

MR. MELZER. Thanks, Alan. My view is that the U.S. economy
continues to show strength even though there are now a few signs that
the pace of economic activity may be slowing. Real GDP grew at a 4.6
percent rate in the fourth quarter according to the most recent
estimate. Inventories were a net drag on output growth and domestic
demand was strong. This combination, which was not apparent in the
original advanced GDP report, is a plus for the first quarter since
there should be less risk of a quick slowdown due to a quick inventory
correction. Inventory-based stories of a slowdown have been
problematic in any event over the last several quarters, and the
inventory-to-sales ratio remains near a historic low.
The Eighth District economy remains strong, and at 4.5
percent, unemployment in major District states remains well below the
national average. Parts of the District continue to report very tight
labor market conditions. A recent survey of businesses in the
District shows that about as many plan to add employees in the next
three months as did at this time a year ago. Auto production in the
District for the second quarter is projected to be much stronger than
in either the fourth quarter or the current quarter. Taking these
facts together, I view the overall picture on the real side as one of
a healthy economy.
It is not nearly so easy to be sanguine about the inflation
outlook. In January and February core inflation averaged about 4.2
percent, up substantially from the 2.8 percent rate we saw in 1994.
Virtually all major forecasters expect inflation to rise in 1995. The
Blue Chip consensus, for example, puts the increase in the CPI at 3.4
percent in 1995 and 3.6 percent in 1996 as compared with 2.6 percent
in 1994. Longer-term forecasts of inflation are worrisome from the
perspective of this Committee because they indicate that market
participants expect inflation at or above its current level at
horizons as long as five years. A recent University of Michigan
survey put inflation expectations at just over 4 percent for 5 to 10
years from now. I might add that this troubling figure is actually
down from 5 percent late last year. This indicates that we are moving
in the right direction, but it is clear that few in the marketplace
believe our commitment to long-term price stability. In this
environment, it is particularly important that we ask ourselves what
our objectives are. Even if we have put a cap on inflation in the 3
to 4 percent range--and I am not sure that that is necessarily clear
at this point--we are a long way from our goal of stable prices and
the low long-term interest rates that would accompany such an
achievement. The U.S. government borrowed long term at 4 percent in
the late 1950s and the early 1960s when inflation was held to the 0 to
2 percent range in this country. The Japanese government can now
borrow long term at 4 percent when its inflation rate is comparably
low. We clearly have a long way to go to establish that kind of
credibility again.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Vice Chairman.

-32-

3/28/95

VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Mr. Chairman, the Second District
economy, which has been flat for about the last six months, had a
little positive flurry, mainly in New York State, in February with
retail sales and employment up a bit. However, the continuing
announcement of shrinkage by major employers, the difficulties on Wall
Street, and certain base closings would lead one to believe that for
the rest of the year the economy in the District is likely to be flat.
Regarding the national economy, we, like everybody else, are
uncertain as to where the economy is going--whether it has slowed
enough to sustain a reasonable level of growth and progress toward
price stability. On the positive side, we have consumer spending
moderating, retail sales down, auto sales down, a little fall in the
Michigan index of consumer sentiment, housing starts declining
substantially, exports to Mexico and Latin America decreasing, and
wage growth continuing to be moderate indeed. On the other hand, one
has to look at the fact that in recent years we have had a pattern of
a first-quarter slowdown followed by a strong rebound, and none of us
can be certain that that won't happen again. Employment growth is
still quite strong. The stock market is very strong indeed and the
long bond rates have declined. Capacity utilization is still above 85
percent and employment below 5-1/2 percent. CPI inflation has crept
up in recent months.
Regarding any differences with the Greenbook forecast, we do
have differences that are somewhat troubling in that we have the real
GDP growth rate slightly higher in 1995 and somewhat lower, down to
about 2 percent, in 1996. But the unemployment rate is still low, and
we are less sanguine about wage pressures. Consequently, we have the
CPI up 3.4 percent fourth-quarter-to-fourth-quarter in 1995 and up 3.7
percent in 1996. In the financial markets, the strong stock market
and the strong bond market would seem to reflect the notion in these
markets that we have in fact achieved the soft landing, which none of
us is quite sure is true, and that the Fed is about to declare formal
victory, given the number of comments by some members of the Committee
about having raised interest rates high enough. I think the financial
markets may have it right, but if they don't, they have it wrong by
being euphoric on the top side. If in fact we get a rebound in the
economy or any continued pickup in inflation, I think the Federal
Reserve would have to tighten even further because of this attitude in
financial markets, and perhaps in part because we have contributed to
this attitude in those markets. So in my view this is very clearly a
time for us to be attentive to what's happening in the economy but
perhaps attentive in the sense of looking for a demonstration of price
stability from the economy rather than looking hopefully for an
indication that we already have been successful. It seems to me it is
too early for that.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
this point.

Let's take a 10 minute coffee break at
[Coffee break]

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Kelley, you have the floor.

MR. KELLEY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would like to lean
into the wind a little here as several have done, particularly the
Vice Chairman when he spoke just a moment ago. I don't think there is

-33-

3/28/95

much question that the expansion seems to be slowing right now, and I
certainly respect the strong logic in the Greenbook about the
expectation for upcoming quarters. But I have to say that as of right
now, from what I can see today, I am agnostic about the course of the
upcoming quarters and the balance of the forecast period. While I am
not prepared to bet very heavily on it, I surely would not overly
discount the possibility that we are going to see a reacceleration
here or at least a considerably lesser degree of softening. I had a
list of factors here; almost all of them have been mentioned. One
that I would like to repeat was mentioned by the Vice Chairman a
minute ago. I have never known whether the old saying that history
never repeats itself is correct, or the one that says that those who
ignore history are doomed to repeat it. But we should keep in mind
that for the last two years in a row we have had a configuration of a
fourth quarter going into a first quarter that looks very much like
the one we have right now. Certainly, some things are a lot different
right at this point, most obviously interest rates, but we have had
this kind of configuration for two years-CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

I think it is three years.

MR. KELLEY. Three years? I'm sorry. I didn't go back far
enough in my research. The economy is still forming new jobs at a
rapid clip--500,000 or so in the first two months. The related
earnings will be kicking into the spending stream. I am not sure what
may happen on inventories, but certainly we still have a very low
historic inventory-to-sales ratio, which leaves a lot of room to build
inventories. Factory orders are still strong; backlogs are still
rising. Nominal rates all along the yield curve are well off their
highs, and real rates are certainly down from where they were. I
don't think we can call the real rates high by any reasonable standard
that I can see. That may reflect the slowing that we have right now,
but it also could set the stage for some reacceleration later. I have
been anticipating that the consumer would run out of gas before now,
and that has clearly been wrong. Now it seems that the consumer is
still quite solvent. With the stronger stock market and bond market
that we have had recently, I would expect that confidence will
continue to stay high. It is still high, maybe a little off its peak,
but nevertheless still quite strong. It will be interesting to see
how the lower dollar plays out. As Ted said a few minutes ago, the
band of uncertainty is very large. But a great many observers feel
that the dollar could easily go lower over time from where it is right
now, even if the decline may be somewhat overdone on a short-term
basis in the last couple of months. It seems to me that that could
give us an upside surprise on the export side. All in all, if you use
the baseline forecast in the Greenbook and ask yourself where the
risks are around that, at the moment it would seem to me that they are
still on the up side, with a meaningfully larger chance that we will
see a stronger economy versus the baseline forecast than a weaker
economy.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Phillips.

MS. PHILLIPS. Thank you. In December I thought a slowdown
was likely, or feasible, and the evidence is now becoming a bit more
definite that we are seeing that slowdown. I think everybody has been
pretty consistent in citing housing and retail sales--autos and
durables in particular--as the weakening areas. I guess consumers are

-34-

3/28/95

finally feeling the stress of higher interest rates as their ARMs were
repriced and as they took on increased amounts of consumer debt last
year. With wage increases flattening out, taking on additional
leverage to spend is not as advantageous. Like several others around
the table, I also would like to argue that in spite of the fact that
we are seeing a slowdown, I think it is likely to be quite mild.
Employment at fairly lofty levels implies that aggregate income will
continue to support consumption. Also, we don't have any very
significant balance sheet strains at the household level.
On the business side, I think the climate remains favorable
for continued investment at least in the near term. We are carrying
forward considerable momentum from 1994. With this kind of business
investment, we are going to have significant lead times on projects,
and that leaves a fair amount of expenditures in the pipeline. The
cost of capital in the aggregate is still relatively low. Business
commitments to cost control and increased productivity do imply
additional capital expenditures, although I would admit that the
impulse of those expenditures is mitigated by the fact that we are
seeing falling computer prices. Nevertheless, corporate profits and
cash flows are stronger than expected and this can support additional
investment. Balance sheets are stronger on the corporate side.
Again, this is supporting the opportunity for increased investment.
It is possible that the slowdown will ease the strain on
resource utilization, but in any case I think most people would agree
that the economic slack currently is either significantly diminished
or perhaps the economy is operating over capacity. I continue to
believe that it is difficult to interpret these capacity questions.
On the labor market side, it could well be that we have more
flexibility than 5.4 percent unemployment implies, and I would cite
the increased use of temporaries. I think the reengineering process
has left people employed but willing to relocate if better
opportunities come up. For various reasons, perhaps including
benefits, people are not moving to seek new employment in the same
patterns as in the past. On the manufacturing capacity side, there
have been several examples around the table today of capacity being
added. Technology, I think, is making it very difficult to ascertain
whether our old levels of capacity are even as relevant anymore.
Thus, with respect to resource utilization, although both product and
labor markets are fairly taut, those data are difficult to assess.
On the inflation front, there has been considerable progress
both in the numbers and the psychology, but we are continuing to see
pressure at the commodity and intermediate materials levels. We have
forecast a slight uptick in the CPI for 1995. But the difficulty of
interpreting capacity and measuring the NAIRU makes it difficult to
know how close we are to building more permanent inflationary
increases back into the economy. Perhaps in the near term, we are not
likely to see too much erosion of the progress that we have made
against inflation if the expansion does slow a bit and wages stay
under control. But I think it would be a stretch to see much room for
improvement on the inflation front under current circumstances,
particularly when we take dollar depreciation into account.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Thank you.

Governor Lindsey.

3/28/95

-35-

MR. LINDSEY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Like my colleague,
Governor Kelley, I am agnostic. The difference is that I am a scared
agnostic. Maybe I have to find the right church to go to or something
to make me feel better about the future. I am scared for two reasons.
First, with regard to the domestic economy, I think that the Greenbook
underestimates what I view as very likely fiscal contraction later
this year. It seems to me that the way the politics are stacking up,
we are going to have a contingent tax cut passed. The contingency
will be that we be on a steady and sure path of deficit reduction of
about $25 billion a year in order to reach balance by 2002. Now, one
can fantasize about how we will get to the out-year parts of that, but
we can easily understand why Congress would be interested in passing
such a near-term contingency in order to put dollars directly in
voters' pocketbooks. I would imagine that beginning in the fourth
quarter of this year, where we now have what is described as a change
in the High Employment Budget of roughly zero on a quarterly basis, we
would see about 1/2 percent of GDP on an annual basis, about $25
billion a year, knocked off. I think that will be a significant brake
on the economy. The reason that is a little frightening is that we
are also in a situation where the financial sector is in much more
precarious shape around the world than it is here. The problems with
the Japanese banking industry are well known in this room. They will
have to be marking to market on Friday, and that will be an
interesting exercise both at the Bank of Japan and at the private
financial institutions. I think there will be some interesting
activity between now and then. Similarly, the German economy seems to
have been slowing down. I think the pressure on the Germans to do
something about the deutschemark will become irresistible. Here
again, going back to Governor Kelley's analogy of history repeating
itself, this reminds me a lot of late 1992 or early 1993 where the
possibilities of strange things happening in currency markets seemed
high.
Back in this country, there is one other ghost on the horizon
and that has to do with the debt ceiling bill that will have to pass,
probably in September of this year. I have been through two of those
where the government shuts down and I went home as a Federal worker-or whatever we do. I went home anyway! [Laughter]
The difference
here is that the dynamic is slightly different. Previously it was a
failure of negotiations where the Executive was trying to restrain
spending and Congress was trying to increase it. That makes a lot of
sense. What we will have this time, I think, will be Congress trying
to restrain spending. The default in that situation really is a zero
spending game, and I think it is quite possible to have a protracted
period, unlike the 8 or 9 hours or in one case a 2-day period, when
the government is shut down. The ramifications of that for the
economy and financial markets could be quite interesting. There is a
good chance we will avoid it, but if we don't the effects in our bond
markets and world currency markets this fall will be very interesting
to observe. So, I am worried about the end of the year. I think we
are going to have a general drag on the economy from fiscal policy.
And with the Japanese, the Germans, and our Congress and
Administration, the capacity for something worse happening certainly
seems to be there.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. What I read mainly is that the variance
is rising. I couldn't quite figure out where the signs came out.

-36-

3/28/95

MR. LINDSEY.

That is why I am an agnostic.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Yellen.

MS. YELLEN. The data that we reviewed at our last meeting
provided inconclusive and, as we put it, tentative signs of slowing in
growth. The magnitude of any moderation in demand growth seemed
uncertain and the timing of the long awaited slowdown was also in
question. That certainly raised the concern that it wasn't going to
occur quickly enough to avoid a further reduction in labor market
slack, with future inflationary consequences. Since that meeting, I
think we have learned a lot, although I agree that not all doubts have
been erased. From my point of view, the Greenbook does an outstanding
job of digesting all the new information. The analysis it presents is
very well reasoned. I would say the evidence in hand now points to a
slowdown that is somewhat greater and more pervasive than previously
anticipated. The incoming data coupled, of course, with our recent
rate hike have led to downward revisions in the projected growth in
virtually every component of demand. I think the outlook for net
exports, at least beyond the current horizon, is the single modest
exception to that pattern. From my standpoint, what we are finally
seeing is the result of previous Fed tightening emerging through the
pipeline, with the interest-sensitive sectors, housing and autos,
leading the way exactly as theory and past experience predict. On the
down side, we are now seeing a significant inventory buildup in
automobiles leading to production cuts in the spring, and that
significantly weakens the forecast in the near term. Investment
growth also looks like it is slowing, not excessively but nevertheless
slowing. So, at the moment the economy looks to me like it is not too
hot, it is not too cold, it is just right.
The long-term inflation risk, it seems to me, is not entirely
absent. Therefore, we have to be vigilant to see how things progress
from here. But it does seem to me that the risk has subsided a
little. We now have a forecast embodying more labor market slack in
1995 and 1996 than our last Greenbook forecast, and a forecast of
significant new capacity coming on line. Most important, of course,
what we are seeing is, to my mind, surprising and continued moderation
in compensation growth and subdued growth in unit labor costs. If
wages continue to be, as Ed Boehne put it, a nonproblem, that suggests
that eventually we may have reason to question whether that the NAIRU
is 6 percent or .1 or so lower. I think we should keep an open mind
on that topic.
The Greenbook emphasizes that the dollar poses significant
risk to the forecast. I thought the simulations in the Greenbook did
a very good job of assessing the risk. I agree with President
Forrestal that the exchange rate should not be a target of our policy,
but it does have appreciable effects on output and inflation.
Nevertheless, it does seem to me that the risks from the dollar are
roughly balanced because, although we are told some interesting
stories about why the dollar is doing what it is doing, I think when
all is said and done that I would agree with Ted's conclusion that in
truth the recent movement in the dollar does not seem to be warranted
by any perceptible change in fundamentals. On balance, I would say
that in a market like this where psychology matters so much, random
walks work well. That is probably going to be the best forecast of
where things are headed. Certainly, the dollar could move a lot, but

-37-

3/28/95

it could go either up or down. The Greenbook assumption of a path
with the dollar staying where it is seems appropriate to me, on
balance. I take as the moral of those simulations that what we need
to do at this point is watch and wait and be prepared to adjust policy
in either direction if the exchange rate or any other risk factor in
this forecast changes significantly. On balance, I see the risks to
the forecast as being in both directions and roughly balanced at this
point.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Blinder.

MR. BLINDER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, I will be quite brief.
The scenario sketched in the Greenbook looks reasonable to me both in
broad outline and in most particulars. A definition of a reasonable
forecast is that there should be risks on both sides, and they should
be reasonably close to balanced. I think this one is, but I would
shade the risks slightly higher on the down side. Let me tell you
why. I could list 12 upside and 15 downside risks, but I'll list only
two on each side because I said I would be brief, and the other 13 are
already covered.
[Laughter] On the up side, I would mention net
export performance being better than thought, with or without further
depreciation of the dollar, and even more so if there is further
depreciation of the dollar--although on that issue I am a random
walker, exactly as Govenor Yellen is. The second one I would mention,
and it has been mentioned several times, is that this could indeed be
a false negative as we have had several times. I can remember,
prominently, developments last summer when the economy started to emit
a little feel of a slowdown. But the data that we have had in the
last two months, I think, are quite different from the two months'
worth of data that we had last summer. It is more pervasive. I think
it is much less likely that this is a false negative than some of
these other episodes that we have seen.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Why don't you repeat that; I want to get
all the signs right!
[Laughter]
MR. BLINDER. You want to get all the signs? I think it is
less likely that this is a false negative. That was two negatives; I
think I got three in the first go-around. On the down side, it seems
my role in this FOMC meeting is to keep echoing what Bob Parry said.
I agree very much with Bob's analysis. As I look at the pieces of the
Greenbook forecast, it is easier to tell stories component-bycomponent--consumer spending, business fixed investment, inventories,
etc.--coming in lower rather than higher. Of these, I think I would
put inventories on the top of the list. But these are hunches, after
all, and I have no major bone to pick with the Greenbook on any of
those details.
Much more important than that is the fact--and it really is a
fact--that forecasts tend to understate swings whenever they occur.
It doesn't matter which direction; they do it. Forecast revisions are
serially correlated; that is a statistical fact. There are several
reasons for that. I think it has to do with underestimation of
multiplier/accelerator interactions. I think it also has to do with
people always saying, "yes there are lags, yes, there are lags," but
not really internalizing it in their thinking--at least not in a
reasonably numerical way. And we all have this tendency to look out
the window and see how things are and generalize from that. So

-38-

3/28/95

changes are always underestimated.

To me, that is the major factor

suggesting there is a downside risk.
The other thing I would say, which is striking to me, is the
conjunction--as Governor Yellen mentioned--between what I like to call
the fundamentals and the tea leaves. The fundamentals--models, etc.-tell us that the monetary tightening should be just about hitting the
economy late in 1994 and into early 1995. That is exactly when we
start seeing the slowdown--almost too good to be true! We have no
right to think that these models are that good on timing.
Nonetheless, there are the fundamentals, and there are the tea leaves
coming in right on schedule--which gives me a lot more confidence than
I would have in either one in the absence of the other. At the same
time, I think there are very few signs of real deterioration in the
economy. When I say a downside risk, I do not mean a recession risk;
it does not look that way at all. The data really say to me that we
have a chance of achieving this soft landing. But I just want to
remind everybody that the reason soft landings are rarely achieved has
to do with what I was saying a moment ago about the downside risks.
People understate swings, forget about lags, and underestimate
multiplier/accelerator models. That is why we hardly ever achieve
soft landings.
In sum, I can hardly imagine circumstances--echoing now both
Ed Boehne and Janet Yellen--that argue more strongly that this is a
good time to wait and see if this negative really is a true negative,
as I guess it is. At this point it is only a guess. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Let's move on to Don Kohn.

MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The first sentence of my
briefing comes directly from Governor Blinder's comments. I expected
coffee in between! [Statement--see Appendix.]
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Don, we have revisited periodically the
issue of going back to some form of credit variable target to replace
the funds rate target. You sort of dismissed that in your statement.
MR. KOHN.

A credit variable or borrowing?

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Either. I use the word credit in a
generic sense so that it could be money, it could be borrowing, it
could be a credit variable, it could be a non-interest-rate variable.
Do you envisage that sort of target as even remotely realistic or are
you going to forecast that we will be saddled--I use the word
advisedly--with the federal funds rate, which I think everyone would
agree is a less desirable target than something directly related to
our central bank operations?
MR. KOHN. There are really two issues, Mr. Chairman, and I
would like to subdivide my response accordingly. One is the issue of
what Peter Fisher is looking at every day when he is adding or
subtracting reserves. We used to have a borrowing objective that was
really a proxy for what was going on in the money markets. It had a
little more flexibility in it than direct funds targeting. Now, Peter
really is keyed to the funds rate. When the Committee's target is at
6 percent he must react every time it is at 5-15/16--although that is
not quite true. I think going back to targeting borrowing by

-39-

3/28/95

depository institutions instead of the federal funds rate would be
very difficult because the borrowing is very low, and the borrowing
function itself has shifted around.
The other question that perhaps you are raising is how the
Committee keys its decisions about changing the federal funds rate
target that it gives to Peter. That is where the aggregates used to
play a role in the sense that if they were running very high or very
low relative to expectations or to the targets, they would weigh on
the scale on the side of the Committee changing its instructions to
the New York Fed. We have noted in the Bluebook the last several
times that M2 demand seems to have become a little more consistent
with our old models, although the whole level of M2 demand has shifted
down. With regard to M2, even when it was on model, it only gave a
broad longer-run perspective on policy. I think it would be much too
early to say that it was going to stay in its old configuration with
interest rates or opportunity costs and nominal income. M2 just keeps
chugging along at 1 to 2 percent, and the model now is predicting 1 to
2 percent. It may be that as soon as the model predicts something
else, M2 will just keep chugging along! I think we need much more
information that somehow the innovations in financial markets--the
availability of mutual funds and what not--have not altered
fundamental asset decisions by households.
On the other variables, there may be a little information in
the credit variables and even the broad money aggregates. Certainly,
we look at credit conditions in the sense of trying to see how willing
banks and other lenders are to make loans. This ought to show up in
some of these flows. So, in terms of broad flows of credit through
the economy, there might be something there that would provide a
little extra information--in addition to the kinds of information we
already have on spending and nominal income--that would give us a
little sense of what was going on in the financial markets. But I
would be very, very skeptical that we could ever put very much weight
on those data compared to the other more direct measures of spending.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

And certainly not abandon the funds rate

target-MR. KOHN. No, you couldn't really. There is no way of
targeting those broad money or credit variables directly.
It would
all be through interest rates and nominal income.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Well, we used to.

MR. KOHN. The only thing we ever targeted directly, more or
less, was M1. We did move reserves around to achieve M1 targets from
1979 to 1982.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

When I first arrived on the scene in

mid-1987, there were still remnants of different types of borrowing
targets.
MR. KOHN. Yes, but the borrowing targets were really proxies
for what was going on in reserve markets. They were not being changed
in direct response to, say, M1 or M2.
I think M2 played a role in
changing the borrowing target, as indeed we could see in the 1989
episode, but there wasn't a direct tie between the borrowing and M2.

-40-

3/28/95

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Other questions for Don?

MR. PARRY. Don, in your discussion of symmetry and
asymmetry, you indicated that if the Committee were to favor asymmetry
to the up side, it might be as a result of its concern about the path
that inflation is expected to take over the longer term. In your
discussion of symmetry, you talked about the Committee maybe
concluding that the risks are roughly balanced. I assume that this
primarily means risks in terms of economic growth. What do you think
the Committee would be communicating in terms of its views about
inflation if it were to favor a symmetric directive?
MR. KOHN. Obviously, it would depend on the Committee's
outlook for inflation. If the Committee were concerned that inflation
was more likely to rise than to fall and it wanted to resist that
rise, the asymmetry would tend to convey that. If the Committee felt
the risks on inflation were evenly balanced around the 3-1/4 percent
core CPI projected in the Greenbook but did not like that outcome,
then it seems to me the Committee also would want to tilt a little bit
toward the tight side.
MR. PARRY.

Thank you.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Stern.

MR. STERN. Don, in your discussion about inertia and what
might or might not work, you did not mention the monetary base. Is
that principally because of the currency component, especially the
currency held abroad, or do you have something else in mind?
MR. KOHN. No. I think first of all that the growth of
foreign holdings of our currency has distorted growth of the base
substantially. We have only the roughest notion of what proportion of
our currency is held overseas and how it changes month to month. We
have a lot of work going on here at the Board trying to estimate that,
and people are refining their estimates using all sorts of
sophisticated econometric techniques--comparing seasonals and things
like that. But in the end, we are still only part way toward knowing
what those holdings are.
The other point I would make is that even ignoring the
currency part, the reserves part of the base tracks Ml; that is what
it is. The velocity of M1 is extremely variable as we have seen. The
Committee itself abandoned M1 targeting back in the early 1980s
because M1 became very interest elastic once NOW accounts were
introduced and depositors began shifting funds between NOW accounts
and time deposits. That sort of thing also shows through to the base.
So, I would not put a lot of weight on movements in the base. For the
St. Louis conference on operating procedures a couple of years ago
that Al Broaddus was involved with, we cranked McCallum's rule for the
base through the MPS model. We found a distinct tendency for
instrument instability. McCallum has his base rule being adaptive to
changes in velocity, but even with the adaptation, we had huge swings
in interest rates and no clear gain over looking at nominal income or
other variables directly. We do have some work continuing on this and
hopefully we can circulate it to the Committee pretty soon.
MR. STERN.

Good.

-41-

3/28/95

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Vice Chairman.

VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Don, am I right in thinking that
one of the messages from your very interesting presentation is that we
may have reached a point at which quarter point changes in the funds
rates would be appropriate again? When we were going through the
tightening exercise, we went 25, 25, 25, then a couple of 50s, then
75, then 50. If we are as balanced as you say we are, and based on
your presentation, would you not feel that 25 basis point moves are
quite appropriate now?
MR. KOHN. I think they would be more appropriate now,
particularly if in order to make 50 basis point moves, the Committee
felt it had to wait for more information. I thought the lesson of my
sermon was that it is better to be a little flexible, and maybe even
have to reverse after going in one direction or another, than to get
stuck on a particular rate that gets harder to change the longer the
Committee is stuck on it. One can see a little of this in Germany and
Japan right now, I think.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Any further questions?

MS. MINEHAN. Don, do you also think that 25 basis point
changes could be implemented, as they were in the beginning, decoupled
from the discount rate?
MR. KOHN.

Sure, but they would be announced.

MS. MINEHAN.

Yes.

MR. KOHN. In fact, I saw a comment recently that suggested
it might be wise, if the Fed is going to tighten, to do it with the
funds rate rather than the discount rate.
MS. MINEHAN.

Right.

MR. KOHN. I think it was in one of the incoming Reserve Bank
letters on the discount rate. That would allow the spread to widen
and make it easier to reverse, because if the Committee started to
reverse in tentative steps, the discount rate would not have to be
cut. Now that both discount rate changes and funds rate changes are
announced, the difference between them has certainly narrowed. And
since the Committee is going to announce any funds rate change, it
would need to decide whether there is to be any distinction in the
type of announcement it would make between a plain open market
operations change and such a change accompanied by a discount rate
change.
MR. BROADDUS. I have a lot of sympathy with what you are
saying, Don, about the need to move the funds rate more flexibly. It
gives me an opportunity to underline a point I have made before. If
we just had some kind of clear long-term anchor, it would be a lot
easier to do that. Certainly, one of the reasons we are reluctant to
do that and one of the reasons the press focuses on it so much is that
that is really the indicator that they can key on to see whether or
not we are still moving in the long-term direction we say we are
moving in. If we could solve the longer-term question, I think it
would feed right into this kind of operating issue.

3/28/95

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
let me get started.

-42-

Further questions from anybody?

If not,

It is pretty obvious that the growth of the economy is moving
down in the direction that we had hoped. Indeed, if the evidence did
not show that, as I indicated at our last meeting, I think we would be
facing severe difficulties at this stage with serious instability
beginning to emerge. The extent of the weakness clearly is not
pervasive; it is still relatively spotty. We see it, for example, in
the interest-sensitive areas, as many of you have indicated. The
longer-term buttress to the system clearly has not been undermined.
The recent gains in backlogs of orders, for example, remain very
solid. One of the reasons is that a gap has opened up between orders
and shipments so that even when orders fluctuate a little, the gap is
still there; the second difference of the change in unfilled orders is
really not discernible on any particular charts. We are, however,
seeing initial claims beginning to edge modestly higher. And I don't
know whether it means anything, but C&I loans have flattened out in
the last two weeks after spiking up for a considerable period.
The question has been raised as to whether there has been a
change in the seasonals that explains why we are seeing weaker first
quarters relative to fourth quarters than we used to see. I think
this is a very questionable proposition in large part because it is
tough to find a change in temperature degree-days nationwide. It is
especially difficult, at least as best I can judge, to see a pattern
in the southern areas of the United States--where one would presume
that seasonality would be less of a factor--that differs from that
nationwide. We still get a big surge in the fourth quarter and
weakness in the first in that part of the country. Nonetheless, there
are reasons to suspect that weaker growth may in fact be emerging this
year, not because of seasonality but largely because of the operation
of the business cycle.
Gary Stern has raised an interesting question with respect to
inventories. It has always been the case that when business people
comment that "my sales have not done as well as I expected," that is
algebraically equivalent to "my inventories are higher than I
planned." The question is how important is that development. I think
it is important enough to raise the possibility that the second
quarter is going to be slower than the consensus expectation. The
Greenbook may be on track here. We probably have a mini inventory
recession under way, though not one that I would consider to be any
particular cause for concern. As I indicated at our last meeting, I
don't think any measures of inventory levels are pointing to a large
prospective overhang. Indeed, the inventory data have been revised
down. I don't mean necessarily for the fourth quarter, but as I
recall the annual revision for trade has actually brought the numbers
down so that we are dealing with an inventory level situation that is
very far from scary. Nonetheless, we do have a short-term inventory
cycle tending to emerge. As a consequence of this, I think we are
looking at the possibility that there is an element of euphoria about
a soft landing that probably mitigates against it happening for the
reasons that the Vice Chairman and a number of others have indicated.
I think the downside risks are basically coming from the
possibility of significant increases in stock and bond prices. If you
remember, some of our discussions about the necessity of moving in

3/28/95

-43-

early 1994 recognized that we were beginning to get wealth effects
that were unsustainable and potentially creating bubbles. Ironically,
the real danger is that things may get too good. When things get too
good, human beings behave awfully. I would be a little cautious about
what stance we take. In retrospect, I would change that sentence in
my Humphrey-Hawkins testimony where I stated hypothetically that we
might be easing rates. The reason I would change it at this stage is
not that I think the statement is incorrect. It is a correct
statement of policy, but I underestimated the degree of credibility
that the Federal Reserve has accumulated in the last year or so. As a
result of this, as the Vice Chairman observed, the markets truly
believe that we know what is going on in the economy to a degree that
no one else really does. Therefore, we got the largest swing in
2-year to 10-year maturities that I can recall in a long time. That
swing was basically the result of the disappearance from the markets
of an expectation of significant further tightening. The argument was
not that the Federal Reserve is wrong and we are going to have to
tighten. Their money was on the fact that we were right and we would
not have to tighten. Now, I worry about that, and I worry about that
basically because we could be our own worst enemies in this regard.
I think that this raises an interesting question of policy,
not about our fundamental policy but rather the symmetry/asymmetry
issue about which I have mixed views. Let me tell you what I think is
the relevant issue here. I think there is no alternative to "B" as
the fundamental choice. In an odd way, if it were not for this
credibility/noncredibility issue and the extent to which we are
affecting markets and therefore having wealth effects in the economy,
I would say this is a classic case of symmetry. It is very difficult
looking at current conditions to see anything other than a balanced
situation. I think, however, that the symmetry/asymmetry question is
really more appropriately a loss function issue. In other words, it
does not involve our best guess as to what we think the appropriate
policy is, but rather what the consequences are of our taking a
position on this matter, recognizing that it will be made public eight
weeks from now. My concern is that after the mini inventory recession
unfolds and what is still a relatively strong capital goods market
starts to create incomes and consumption, we may find that we wish we
had been somewhat tighter somewhere along the line. A change in our
rhetoric including the use of asymmetry may be the desirable thing to
do. I definitely do think we ought to change our rhetoric. I have no
really strong feelings on whether we should be symmetric or
asymmetric, and very honestly, I could go either way. My own marginal
preference is to go asymmetric, but I would find it perfectly
acceptable to use a symmetric directive here. One thing that concerns
me about what I just said is that it is almost too cute. It is taking
fine-tuning to the point of sharp pointedness that may be overdone.
But I must say that I line up with the concerns that the Vice
Chairman, Governor Kelley, and a few others have mentioned. I would
be inclined in that direction, but I am interested in getting everyone
else's view on this issue and call on the Vice Chairman first.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I find
myself in the awkward position of advocating asymmetry as a signaling
device, having spoken against the use of asymmetry for that purpose a
number of times in the past. But at this particular time--although
there is no question in my mind that "B" is correct, i.e., that we
should not change interest rates at this meeting--to the degree we

-44-

3/28/95

believe that our primary responsibility is price stability, I think
the inflation forecast that most of us have discussed is such that we
should be on record the Friday after the next meeting as having
indicated a concern about the trend in prices even though the use of
our directive for that purpose is a somewhat puny weapon. I think the
fact that those minutes would indicate that the Committee had decided
to maintain interest rates but had decided on an asymmetric directive
toward tightening would have a reasonable amount of merit in enhancing
our position as understanding our responsibility for price stability.
Therefore, while it is hard for me to throw my Celtic enthusiasm fully
into the ring for something that I usually think is not terribly
important, I do feel rather strongly that an asymmetric directive is
preferable.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Jordan.

MR. JORDAN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thought Don Kohn's
remarks were very useful concerning the problems we are going to be
facing in making policy decisions. I also found very useful your
remark right now on the interplay with the marketplace and the need to
change the rhetoric. I don't know how it can be changed in a positive
way. We almost need a heuristic model for the markets as well as an
econometric model to figure out what is going on. The sort of things
that you point to, these ideas about how we are seen as having some
sort of knowledge that others don't have, has led me to the conclusion
that at least for the time being it is impossible to say anything that
is going to be interpreted the way we want it to be interpreted.
If I thought that the New York Fed forecast that Bill
McDonough presented was correct about inflation in 1996--if I could be
convinced of that and I hope he is wrong on that forecast--I would say
that we ought to tighten policy now because inflation is definitely
going in the wrong direction. I would agree with Governor Kelley that
the risks in the forecast are more likely to be in the direction of
more inflation rather than less. What I don't know how to assess,
though, is an inventory forecast that is the inevitable mirror image
of last year's inventory cycle. What we really are talking about here
is that we are expecting sometime within 1995 to have inventory
effects that are the opposite of those that we saw in 1994. We won't
know and neither will the auto manufacturers nor all of these other
people such as retailers know as things unfold whether it is the
mirror image of last year or whether it is more of a cyclical
development.
I guess I am not far away from the use of monetary
aggregates. My own judgment is, as Don Kohn's remarks might suggest,
that in principle excess demand for and excess supply of money
balances can be translated into excess demand for and excess supply of
output. The problem is, given the imprecision of the econometric
models and all of that, that it requires a lot of judgment. We all
have different judgments, so we may come to different conclusions.
But what makes the current environment different for me is that we
have had a prolonged period of very slow growth in the various
monetary aggregates. We saw the narrow money measure not grow at all
last year even though commercial loan demand was extremely strong and
one would presume that compensating balances increased a lot. Leaving
out the growth of currency mainly for foreign usage and making
judgmental allowances for what might have happened to compensating

-45-

3/28/95

balances on the corporate side, we have had very weak money growth and
the Greenbook/Bluebook projections for 1995 imply to me that we are
going to have a further absolute decline in desired money balances on
the order of 5 or 6 percent or something like that.
I look at that and say that my main concern now is not that
there will be too much growth of output. I really never worry very
much about output and employment growing too fast, but rather about
the growth of output and employment slowing too fast relative to the
growth of demand. I come back to the issue of what is going to happen
to spending in the economy, the demand problem, whether it is for
current consumption purposes or for adding to capacity or improving
productivity. As long as we can see that whatever framework we use
tells us that we are getting a deceleration in the growth of demand, I
think we probably are going to come out okay. So, at this point, I
certainly would not be in favor of the "A" alternative. I think that
it is premature to think about that alternative. I am not
uncomfortable with no change, but because of perceptions on the
outside I think that the bias in the directive has to be that, if or
when we act, it is more likely to be to tighten than to ease.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Melzer.

MR. MELZER. Alan, in evaluating the current policy stance,
as I think you all know, I tend to look at reserve measures and
monetary aggregates. I think the current policy stance has a chance
of capping the recent rise in inflation, albeit probably at a somewhat
higher level than we are seeing right now. The decline in long-term
bond yields gives me some confidence that we can afford to wait and
watch for a while. As you notice, I said "chance." I am not
convinced; I would count myself among the agnostics. Certainly,
looking longer term, I am not at all sure that we have done enough to
reduce the trend rate of inflation, and I clearly feel that this 3 to
4 percent inflation range that we may be able to settle for here is
much too high.
With respect to the outlook for the economy, I personally
would not put too much stock in the forecast of an imminent rapid
slowdown. I think that we could well be surprised by the underlying
strength. I would associate myself with what Bill McDonough said
before in that it seems to me that financial market participants have
all rushed to one side of the boat here, and I don't know to what
extent comments by Fed officials have led to that. My feeling is that
market participants are looking at a broad range of indicators and
there is much more to their assessment than just Fed statements that
have been made. In any event, it seems they have all rushed to one
side of the boat. I think our focus in this Committee ought to be on
long-term price stability, not short-run fine-tuning of the real
economy. That is really what we ought to be thinking about--whether
we are on a course that is really going to achieve price stability.
The other thing I would say, and there has been surprisingly
little mention of it today at least in the context of the policy
discussions, is that we have to continue to recognize the constraints
put on policy by the weak dollar in foreign exchange markets. To the
extent that market participants perceive that our actions are not
consistent with long-term price stability, then we are courting the
possibility of, I think, very severe financial repercussions. I have

-46-

3/28/95

never believed that we ought to use policy to try to target a specific
exchange rate for the dollar, but I do think we have to recognize at
times like this that it can be a very significant constraint not only
on what we say but particularly on what we do. As I say, I think our
focus ought to be on long-term price stability.
With respect to the symmetry/asymmetry question, I don't have
any strong views about that. If the message were that this is
asymmetric toward tightening because we think it is more likely we are
going to have to tighten more to achieve long-term price stability, I
would clearly favor that. I could accept a symmetrical directive.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Minehan.

MS. MINEHAN. Unlike, I think, many of the other people who
have spoken already, I did not come to this meeting with a
predisposition in favor of staying pat. Rather, most of the work we
have done, and most of the people I have talked to, suggested that
further interest rate increases were necessary to keep inflation in
check and deal with the kind of capacity constraints, particularly on
the labor market side, that are being forecast both by us and by
private sector forecasters. My own bias would be to tighten sooner
rather than later because I think that ends up making for a better
situation overall. Increasing interest rates at this time does not
seem to be the main thrust of the argument here. I can certainly buy
into the argument that it doesn't matter whether we do it at this
meeting, or at another meeting, or in between. My own preference,
however, would be to indicate that the Committee would be more
inclined to increase interest rates in the future rather than to leave
them pat, or possibly decrease them, because I think that the trends
in inflation over the longer run are not what I would prefer.
With that in mind, when we discussed our stance toward
announcing decisions after meetings, we did discuss the possibility
that when there was no change, we might want to communicate more than
that we just left the room. That is a possibility that does not
require us to wait eight weeks, although it does run the risk of what
President Jordan referred to as the impossibility of saying anything
right. But it is at least a possibility that we could mention
something in our discussion of this meeting that was a little more
explanatory or a little bit more on the side of being concerned about
the upside potential for inflation in whatever we release after this
meeting. After saying all that, I guess it should come as no surprise
that I would be in favor of an asymmetric directive. I really do
think that there is more room to move interest rates up before we stop
doing so.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Stern.

MR. STERN. I think Don Kohn raised a couple of interesting
points, and I would like to start with comments on those. I do think
this problem of interest rate inertia is a real problem, potentially
at least. It may be that what we are seeing in the financial markets
now is a consequence of unsustainable euphoria for one reason or
another. But it may be on the other hand that the markets are telling
us something significant. I don't have a judgment about that, and I
believe we should be careful about rushing to a conclusion about that.
While it is not fully convincing, it is worth noting that some work

-47-

3/28/95

that we have done suggests that the monetary base might be a useful
indicator or maybe some sort of useful intermediate target, even
recognizing the problems with the currency component. I think that is
worth pursuing down the road.
With regard to the immediate situation, I certainly favor
alternative B. I don't feel all that strongly about the question of
symmetry versus asymmetry, but I come out on the side of favoring
symmetry. Part of that is my usual reluctance to go to an asymmetric
directive. In these circumstances, as I suggested already, we don't
know a lot about what the markets are telling us about recent interest
rate movements, at least I don't. But it is also true that the period
between now and the next meeting is relatively long, and we are going
to get a lot of incoming information. We don't meet again until
fairly late in May if I have the calendar right. I don't have a
feeling as to what the incoming information may tell us, and I would
like to be in a position of simply judging it as it comes in. Beyond
that, and maybe I am just being a little too cynical here, I am
certainly not pleased by the performance of the dollar, but I don't
think we ought to put ourselves in a position where we might want to
react to that. I am not persuaded that that would be appropriate at
this juncture or that it is something we can do very successfully.
So, I would be reluctant to go to asymmetry.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Parry.

MR. PARRY. Mr. Chairman, because I find the path for
inflation in the baseline forecast unacceptable, my first preference
would be for a small increase in rates. However, I could support
alternative B because of the significant uncertainties that we see in
the very short-term prospects for the economy. I also would strongly
favor asymmetry toward tightening, given the expected unsatisfactory
path for inflation for the next several years if the baseline policy
assumptions are accepted.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Forrestal.

MR. FORRESTAL. Mr. Chairman, as I look at the situation, I
think that the economy is in relatively good shape. Some might take
the position that the dollar would argue against that, but generally
speaking the economy looks good to me. We are getting some of the
deceleration that we had anticipated from our earlier policy moves. I
think policy has been very, very successful. It is true that this
deceleration may be temporary; nobody is certain as to whether it is
going to be permanent or not. Under these circumstances there is no
question at all in my mind that alternative B is the right alternative
to have at this time. With respect to symmetry or asymmetry, I don't
feel very strongly about it. I do think that the risks are fairly
well balanced, and so I would have some preference for symmetry. I
also wonder what we gain by going to an asymmetric directive at this
time because if the expansion does not slow down sufficiently between
now and May 23, we will probably make the next move then, be it 25 or
50 basis points. The minutes for this meeting come out shortly after
that meeting, so I don't really know what difference that makes. For
those reasons, I would support a symmetric directive. But if I had a
vote, I certainly would not vote against an asymmetric directive.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Hoenig.

-48-

3/28/95

MR. HOENIG. Mr. Chairman, given the data coming in, I can
wait as you are suggesting. But as I said earlier, I am concerned
about the upside risks especially for inflation, and I am concerned
about the inertia Don was talking about that can take place. With
that, I would very strongly support asymmetry toward tightening and
would encourage us to move sooner rather than later.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Moskow.

MR. MOSKOW. Mr. Chairman, I favor no change in the federal
funds rate today. However, I do think that the risks are more on the
up side than balanced at this point. In fact, our forecast for
inflation for 1995 is closer to 3-1/2 percent than to the 3.2 percent
in the Greenbook. It is appropriate to wait for more information on
the economy in the coming weeks, but I think we clearly should remain
open to further increases. It comes as no surprise that I favor the
asymmetric directive as well, not only for the reasons that you gave,
Mr. Chairman, but I think two of the points that Don Kohn made were
very well-taken. He said that if we were not happy with the 3.2
percent inflation rate that is forecast in the Greenbook, that would
be one argument for an asymmetric directive or if we thought the risks
were higher on the up side rather than balanced, that would be another
reason. I agree with both. So, clearly, I favor an asymmetric
directive.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Boehne.

MR. BOEHNE. I support alternative B because this is a waitand-see time, and I support an asymmetric directive for the reasons
that were well articulated by Bill McDonough.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Lindsey.

MR. LINDSEY. Mr. Chairman, in considering an asymmetric
directive, I am reminded of the spring of 1993. I have been here so
long that I am starting to look backward! In the spring of 1993, the
fear of a bubble was mentioned at this table. We actually had a
pretty good bubble develop in the bond market, and we paid a fairly
significant price for it in financial market instability later. As
you noted, that bubble gave an extra impetus to demand in late 1993
and early 1994. What we did, though, was to go asymmetric and then
back off. I have to conclude that doing that, if anything, cemented
the market's view that we were stuck at a particular rate. It only
built the market's confidence that they could borrow at 3 percent and
lend at 6 percent, which is literally what they were doing. I'll be
happy to vote for whatever the Committee majority favors. But if what
we fear is a bubble, we should not in my view go asymmetric unless we
really expect to raise rates. If people do want to raise rates and
want to send a signal that we might be doing so, I think a few
dissents would be a much more appropriate way of sending that signal.
Given what we did in 1993, going asymmetric and then backing off, I am
afraid we would only strengthen the conviction of the market and maybe
actually exacerbate the bubble. So I favor symmetric.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Blinder.

MR. BLINDER. Mr. Chairman, I think your strong
recommendation for alternative B, the fact that it is a crystal clear

-49-

3/28/95

decision at this meeting, and the reasoning leading to that conclusion
are all correct. I am happy to endorse them. On the
asymmetry/symmetry issue, I am certain that I am not certain
[Laughter] for the following reason. Before I was a member of the
Federal Open Market Committee, I thought I knew what the difference
between a symmetric and an asymmetric directive was. The longer I
serve--and today certainly has added to this immensely--the less I
know about what this distinction means. So, I actually would like to
request, before we vote on this, a specification of what we are voting
on. Let me elaborate on that slightly. If Bill McDonough and several
of the others are correct in the sense that inflation is likely to be
higher in 1997 than in 1994--and I think he probably is correct in
that--and if we are adamantly opposed to that, this Committee should
not be voting an asymmetric directive. We should be raising interest
rates, probably by 100 basis points today. I do not advocate that
policy, but I think that is the implication. That is not something
that leads to an asymmetric directive. At the end of this, I am going
to pose the question: What do we mean by an asymmetric directive?
On the signaling issue, I find that quite baffling. As I
think Bob Forrestal just said, on May 23 we either will raise interest
rates or we will do nothing. That will be major news. Three days
later, the kind of directive we adopted on March 28 will be announced
and nobody will notice it. So, I don't see that this has any
signaling value as long as it is not leaked, and I certainly hope that
it will not be leaked. Therefore, I raise the question of what
symmetry vs. asymmetry means. I thought a symmetric directive meant a
fairly strong conviction at this meeting that we would not be changing
interest rates one way or the other until the next meeting--leaving,
of course, the usual flexibility that something quite unusual could
happen and we could change our minds. So it is not a lock-in, but it
is a predisposition of the Committee to hold today's decision until
the next meeting. If I am right about that, and at this point I am
not sure that I am, I would strongly favor a symmetric directive.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I look at it as a question of
probabilities. In other words, the question really amounts to: What
is the probability in this long period that we will be moving rates up
or moving them down? I would say that we are more likely to move them
up, finding, for example, that the slowdowns we are seeing are
partially false or reversed as has happened many times in the past. I
find the probability that this slowing will cumulate into a
significantly weak economy that would induce us to move rates down is
very low. I think the major probability is that we will do nothing.
Since I think the likelihood of moving them higher is sufficiently
greater than moving them lower, I lean marginally, tentatively,
unsurely toward asymmetry, which is really a reflection of the fact
that I think the major probability is that we will do nothing. I read
asymmetry not as an overwhelming probability that we will move, but
merely a probability that one can basically identify.
MR. BLINDER. If I can clarify that: You are suggesting that
there are three probabilities. The middle probability is doing
nothing. If the up probability exceeds the down probability-CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.
MR. BLINDER.

By a sufficient amount.

Okay, I have it.

Thank you.

-50-

3/28/95

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. And each of us has to determine what
constitutes a sufficient amount.
MR. BLINDER.

Okay, thank you.

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Kelley.

MR. KELLEY. Mr. Chairman, I certainly think there is every
reason to "wait and see" today. I strongly support "B."
I did speak
earlier about my feeling that as of now the risks could be seen as
skewed to the up side. My understanding of the use of an asymmetric
or symmetric directive is exactly the same as you just articulated,
Mr. Chairman. On that basis, it would seem to me that the likelihood
of needing to go up further is strong enough that I would prefer an
asymmetric directive. However, let me say that I think that the
emergence of that upside potential, if it does develop, may well be a
meeting or two out in front of us. So we may really want to wait and
see today in the sense of adopting not only "B" but also a symmetric
directive. I could support that, although I would prefer asymmetric.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President Broaddus.

MR. BROADDUS. Let me first if I may, Mr. Chairman, associate
myself with Gary Stern's comments about the monetary base. I think
there is a lot to be gained by some additional research looking at the
possibility of using the base or perhaps something similar to it in
our operating procedures.
As far as policy is concerned, I can certainly accept not
changing the rate today, but I have a relatively strong preference for
asymmetry. As I said in my earlier statement, and I agree with a lot
of folks here, I think that while the risks in the outlook are more
balanced than they were earlier, they still are not fully balanced. I
believe there continues to be a significant upside risk, so I think as
a substantive matter asymmetry is a better statement. Also, I think
Governor Blinder is right that the significance of our statement on
symmetry as a signal can easily be over emphasized; I don't think it
is zero. We have already gotten some relatively high numbers on the
core CPI, for example, in the first couple of months of this year. If
that continues, even if we were to move and certainly if we were not
to move and let's say we were on the fence again at the next meeting,
asymmetry would just be one additional piece of evidence as to the
direction of our longer-term strategy and efforts. I don't think the
signal value is zero, and I think that is another reason for going
asymmetric.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

President McTeer.

MR. MCTEER. I agree with your recommendation for no change
in the federal funds rate. I agree with your recommendation for an
asymmetric directive, although I normally prefer symmetry, not only to
signal our leaning in regard to inflation fighting but also in regard
to the dollar.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Phillips.

MS. PHILLIPS. Given the evidence on the slowdown, I agree
that "B" is an appropriate directive--no change. I do think that it

-51-

3/28/95

is possible that additional tightening is going to be needed if we are
going to resume progress on reducing inflation. I have a slight
preference for asymmetry toward tightening because I do think that
there is some signaling value. But I would not vote against symmetry.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Governor Yellen.

MS. YELLEN. I agree with your proposal for alternative B for
no change today. Although I could live with asymmetric, I would
prefer symmetric for the reasons that have been explained by President
Forrestal and Governor Blinder. At the moment, it seems to me that
the economy, with some reasonable probability, is on track for a soft
landing. There are all kinds of uncertainties in the outlook.
Indeed, we may have a false negative; we may be learning that. There
remains a risk that inflation may not come down in the way we would
like. I certainly hold open the possibility that at some future point
we may need to raise rates more. But over this next intermeeting
period, when I think about what data are likely to come in, it seems
to me that the risks are balanced and that tends to call for symmetry.
Certainly, I agree with what Don said. We should not get stuck where
we are. I have no objection whatsoever to intermeeting changes. The
approach of possibly smaller changes, 25 basis points one way or
another, has a great deal of appeal at this stage. It is simply that
at this point, for the next month and a half, it seems to me that the
risks and likely information indicate risks in both directions and
that that calls for symmetry.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I think as I read the view of this
Committee, we would be at alternative B and mildly asymmetric. Would
you read the directive?
MR. BERNARD. The directive would read, and this is on page
14 of the Bluebook:
"In the implementation of policy for the
immediate future, the Committee seeks to maintain the existing degree
of pressure on reserve positions. In the context of the Committee's
long-run objectives for price stability and sustainable economic
growth, and giving careful consideration to economic, financial, and
monetary developments, somewhat greater reserve restraint would or
slightly lesser reserve restraint might be acceptable in the
intermeeting period. The contemplated reserve conditions are expected
to be consistent with moderate growth in M2 and M3 over coming
months."
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

Call the roll.

MR. BERNARD.
Chairman Greenspan
Vice Chairman McDonough
Governor Blinder
President Hoenig
Governor Kelley
Governor Lindsey
President Melzer
President Minehan
President Moskow
Governor Phillips
Governor Yellen

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

3/28/95

-52-

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Before we adjourn, Ted Truman has a very
minor change to recommend in the minutes for our previous meeting.
Ted, did you want to read it or shall I read it from here?
MR. TRUMAN. I apologize because I thought I had read the
minutes earlier, but I had not. Out thinking at the time of the last
meeting was that the Japanese earthquake would affect our imports but
not our exports. The truth of the matter at this point is that we
think the earthquake will affect neither. But that was where we were,
so I would prefer to take out the phrase in paragraph 14 that says it
will affect our exports. That shortens the sentence to the one fact
that we know pretty certainly--that the Mexican situation will affect
our exports.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection.
is our next meeting and we adjourn for lunch.
END OF MEETING

[Laughter]

May 23