View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
March 27, 1990
Sam Y. Cross
Since your last meeting, the dollar has strengthened. It is now
trading 3 percent higher against the German mark and 7 percent higher
against the Japanese yen, despite substantial intervention and the fact that
interest rate differentials have moved generally unfavorably for the dollar.
There has been both a positive and a negative element in the dollar's
strength--positive in that investors find the dollar more attractive because the
U.S. economy now looks a bit more robust than had been expected,
negative in that investors find the yen and the mark less attractive than
before because of problems that Japan and Germany face.
On the positive side, data on U.S. business activity released in
recent weeks, as well as revisions to fourth quarter GNP, have generally
been stronger than anticipated.

Comments by Federal Reserve officials

reflecting the continuing priority to be attached to reducing inflation,
particularly in the context of last week's release of February consumer price
figures, have also served to dispel any lingering hopes that the Federal
Reserve would soon lower interest rates. In these circumstances, sentiment

2
towards the dollar has tended to improve in the period since your last
meeting.
The more important influences have been on the negative side.
The dollar's sizable rise against the yen during the intermeeting period
reflected a continued deterioration in sentiment towards that currency.
Although the Liberal Democrats maintained control of the Lower House in
last month's elections the Japanese political situation is still seen as
unsettled, and as limiting the ability of the authorities to respond effectively
to changing circumstances. The Japanese monetary officials' prolonged
disputes and vacillation over raising the discount rate was seen as a clear
example of the political weakness that has developed, and the belated
1 percent increase in the official rate on March 20 did little to repair this
impression.

Investors, especially Japanese investors, have had their

confidence shaken and have responded to this discouraging situation not
only in their own financial markets--the Nikkei Dow has declined by
18 percent since the beginning of the year--but also in the exchange
markets.
In these circumstances, the Japanese have been most eager to
intervene to try to keep the yen from falling, and have strongly urged us to
join,

including at meetings with the President and Secretary Brady. They

are deeply troubled that further declines of the yen may be taken as

3
confirmation of political weakness or even of a fracturing of the power
structure that has held things together so well for so long in Japan. They
also worry that a depreciated yen will bring a reversal in Japan's progress
towards eliminating its international imbalance. And they are concerned
about the possibility that further interest rates increases might further
destabilize their stock market, given the already sharp rises in bond yields
and the contrast with the stock market when returns are so much lower. In
the circumstances the Japanese have relied heavily on intervention, selling
during the intermeeting period. In support of these operations, the
Desk sold just under $1 1/2 billion against yen, spread over 11 trading days.
The first six days operations were financed jointly by Treasury and the
Federal Reserve, but Federal Reserve operations were suspended after
March 2. At that time, System currency balances had reached a level which,
with anticipated interest receipts, would almost entirely use up our authorized
limit of $21 billion by the time of today's FOMC meeting.
In Germany attention has also focused on political issues and
inflationary concerns. When you last met, the mark was benefiting from the
view that developments in East Germany would provide major opportunities
for the West German economy, notwithstanding possible inflationary
pressures, and the mark was trading at its highest levels in almost two years.
Then, on February 7, the West German government announced plans for

4
immediate talks on German monetary union.

Market participants quickly

focused on the possible inflationary consequences of such a move.
Observers noted that monetary union could result in a worrisome increase
in the German monetary aggregates, and possibly unleash pent-up demand
among East Germans.

Moreover, Bundesbank President Poehl's initial

doubts and subsequent perfunctory endorsement of monetary union left an
impression that the Bundesbank's staunch stand against inflation might be
subverted by political imperatives. The German bond market experienced
a sharp sell-off during February with the yield on 10-year bonds rising by
more than 100 basis points to briefly surpass 9 percent. These conditions
weighed on the mark, which traded with a decidedly weaker tone.
In this environment, the Bundesbank has been firmly determined
not to allow significant weakening of the mark, which they felt would signal
a lack of confidence in their ability to deal with the inflationary pressures.
Thus in early March, when the downward pressures against the mark were
most acute, the Bundesbank and other European central banks intervened
to sell a total of about $1 billion against marks over four trading days. On
March 5 and March 7, the U.S. Treasury also intervened to sell a total of
$200 million against marks, in conjunction with its larger intervention
operations against the yen. At that time Treasury officials expressed the view
that such dollar sales would help reinforce its efforts to resist upward

5
pressure on the dollar/yen rate. We in the Fed were concerned that the
intervention in marks would be misconstrued as a more generalized effort to
reduce the dollar against all currencies. We were unable to convince the
Treasury of this view and the Desk intervened for Treasury account. After the
initial sale of $200 million, the Treasury has not pushed for further mark
intervention, although there were some other occasions of upward dollar
pressure against the mark.
In the circumstances, we did not intervene for Federal Reserve
account after March 2, pending the review of System foreign currency
operations that had earlier been scheduled for today's FOMC meeting, which
could provide the Committee with an opportunity for a comprehensive
discussion of System foreign currency operations.
To summarize the numbers,

Mr. Chairman,

during this

intermeeting period, the Desk sold a total of $1480 million against yen and
$200 million against marks. The Treasury financed all of the sales against
marks, and all but $325 million of sales against yen. Accordingly I request
the Committee's approval of the System's share, the sale of $325 million
against yen. I would note that our present currency balances are just below
the $21 billion authorized limit, and also that the Treasury has now
warehoused $9 billion of the $10 billion currently authorized.

PETER D. STERNLIGHT
FOMC NOTES
MARCH 27, 1990
Since the early February meeting, the Domestic Desk has
sought to maintain steady reserve conditions, associated with seasonal
and adjustment borrowing around $150 million and an expected federal
funds rate around 8-1/4 percent.

The borrowing allowance abstracted

from the special situation borrowing by the Bank of New England, which
was classified as adjustment credit through February 20, and then as
extended credit.

Actual seasonal and adjustment borrowing--again

abstracting from Bank of New England early in the period--averaged
about $180 million over the intermeeting period.

Daily amounts were

typically well below that level but some end-of-reserve-period
stringencies boosted the average.
The funds rate was a nearly rock-solid 8-1/4 percent
throughout the period--rarely varying by more than 1/16 to either side
of that well-entrenched central tendency, again apart from some endof-reserve-period firmness.

Moreover, as the interval progressed,

market participants seemed increasingly disposed to stretch out the
horizon over which they expect funds to remain at that level.
For the first third of the period, the Desk was still
draining reserves to deal with the typical seasonal over-abundance of
reserves early in the year.

This was handled through several rounds

of matched sale-purchase transactions in the market.

Then after a few

days on the sidelines, the Desk switched gears and turned to meeting
reserve needs, initially through outright Treasury bill and note
purchases from foreign accounts which totaled $800 million for the
interval, and then through a series of repurchase agreements for
customer or System Account.

Seasonal needs might have been met to a

greater degree through outright purchases but for the provision of
reserves through additional warehousing of $2 billion of foreign
currency for the Treasury, and, in the earlier part of the period,
small additional purchases of foreign currency for the System.
Market moves in interest rates were relatively modest on
balance over the period, with yields on short- and medium-term issues
closing some 5 to 20 basis points higher.

At the long end, though,

Treasury issues were slightly lower in yield.

The markets focused on

a variety of factors, including rising rates in overseas financial
markets, some sense of a little greater economic strength and greater
inflationary pressure at home, but also the rising dollar in foreign
exchange markets and particular foreign demand for long-term Treasury
zero coupon issues.
Market evaluation of the stronger economic news, notably on
employment and retail sales, was tempered by the realization that
weather-related or other temporary effects were having a distorting
influence.

Price data were recognized as having been affected by

temporary factors, also.

Still, after taking account of these

factors, analysts were left with a lessened sense of likelihood of
progressive economic weakening after the soft final quarter of '89,
and a bit greater sense of the stubbornness of underlying core
inflation rates.

At the same time, though, notice was taken of the

possibility that, unrelated to current monetary policy, some increased
restraint on the part of banks and other lenders could have a
dampening effect on activity and price pressures.
The predominant monetary policy outlook still called for no
change for a good while ahead, but one heard increasingly the
possibility expressed that when a change does come, it could just as
plausibly be to the firming as to the easing side.

Earlier, the

prevalent view was that further easing, while not imminent, was the
more likely direction when a change came.

Market observers also

seemed to be impressed by the firm restatements of the Federal
Reserve's determination to see inflation work lower over time, as
expressed in the Chairman's congressional testimony and in statements
by other Fed officials.
The market paid close attention to rate developments
overseas, especially in Germany and Japan, although there was not
always a lock-step response to the changes abroad.

Responses to

exchange rate changes also seemed to be spotty--often being cited as a
factor in the U.S. market but not always with great precision or
consistency.
A particular factor in the Treasury bill market, where rates
rose about 5 to 12 basis points despite rather steady fed funds and
dealer financing costs, was the increase in actual and prospective
supply from the Treasury as a result of funding RTC working capital
needs.

Supplies were also enlarged as foreign central banks lightened

their bill holdings in order to finance foreign exchange intervention.
In yesterday's Treasury bill auctions, the 3- and 6-month issues went
at 7.85 and 7.83 percent respectively, up from 7.83 and 7.72 percent
just before the last meeting.

The coupon equivalent yields on the

latest issues were 8.12 and 8.26 percent, closer than usual to the
prevailing fed funds rate.
Bucking the trend toward somewhat higher rates, yields on
long-term Treasury issues came down by a few basis points over the
period.

At least in part, this seemed to stem from a particular

demand for long-term Treasury zero coupon issues, reportedly from
Japanese investors who found the long zeros attractive, under Japanese
accounting rules, on swaps out of Japanese government bonds.

The long

end of our market also seemed to be helped by the strong dollar and
possibly by the sense that the central banks would resist inflation.
Investment grade corporate bonds ended about unchanged to
slightly higher in yield, and with some pickup in new issuance as the
period progressed.

In the case of junk bonds, the story is mixed,

with some issues showing little change while a number of others
registered an appreciable rise in yields in spotty trading, as the
markets coped with the demise of Drexel Burnham--the leading
underwriter and market maker in such paper during the 1980s.

There

was virtually no issuance of new high-yield paper.
More broadly, it can be said that the market coped well with
the unwinding of Drexel's operations and positions--a notable
achievement given that this was a major player in a variety of markets
with pre-bankruptcy balance sheet positions on the order of $28
billion, and similarly large interest rate swap positions off the
books.

Contributing to the orderliness of the unwinding were the

professionalism of the Drexel personnel, on-the-whole responsible
behavior by other financial market participants and a certain amount
of constructive monitoring and hand-holding by the regulatory
authorities.

Drexel's government securities affiliate is almost

totally wound down now, and while we went out of our way to affirm
their primary dealer status as the liquidation process began, we will
shortly be putting out a new primary dealer list which removes their
name.

Very substantial progress has also been made in winding down

other Drexel affiliates, although fair-sized holdings of high-yield
bonds remain, and there are still some unresolved questions about
certain commodity transactions in one of the unregulated affiliates.
As it turned out, only limited use was made of the liberalized
authority to lend securities from the System's portfolio during the

-5-

liquidation process, but it was useful to have this flexibility
available.
Part of our concern while monitoring the unwinding of Drexel
was that difficulties could spread to other firms with potentially
disruptive systemic consequences.

For a couple of weeks rumors did in

fact abound in regard to some other U.S. investment banking concerns,
with particular focus on those with appreciable junk bond or bridge
loan exposure.

These firms experienced a more cautious attitude--even

a pulling away--by some usual funding sources.

Thankfully, the rumors

have abated partly with the help of fresh injections of capital or
statements of support from well-regarded parent firms, but an
atmosphere of increased caution remains.
To be sure, the cautious or even "edgy" atmosphere stems not
only from Drexel but also from other developments such as the further
reverberations of Bank of New England, and commercial bank real estate
exposure more generally.

Several major bank holding companies saw

their credit ratings reduced during the period, and there was some
selective widening of spreads quoted on bank-related debt compared to
Treasury paper, especially in the Euro-bond market.

On the other

hand, the TED spread, which compares Treasury and bank-related paper
for very short maturities, and which has sometimes been regarded as a
measure of market confidence in bank paper, showed little change, and
a couple of major money center banks had rating upgrades.
With respect to primary dealer changes, I should mention that
when we put out a new list in a couple of days, in addition to
removing Drexel we will be adding Swiss Bank Corporation.

That will

leave the number of primary dealers at 44, while raising the number of
foreign-owned firms to 16.

-6-

Leeway
Mr. Chairman, although the Committee just voted at the last
meeting to increase the standard intermeeting leeway for changes in
outright holdings of government securities, it is projected that the
upcoming intermeeting interval will need an even bigger allowance for
change, essentially because of prospectively higher Treasury balances
after the April tax date.

Some estimates place the maximum need for

additional reserves as high as $20 billion.

Other estimates are

considerably lower, closer to around $10 billion, and in any event it
is not necessary or desirable to meet the whole need with outright
purchases.

To provide a reasonable cushion for flexible management, I

recommend that the standard leeway now set at $8 billion be enlarged
for the upcoming intermeeting period to $12 billion.

If the need

works out toward the high side of the projected range, the additional
reserves probably can be provided through repurchase agreements which
do not count against the leeway.

Michael J. Prell
March 27, 1990

FOMC BRIEFING -- ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

I suspect that most of you sensed, as your read the Greenbook,
that the staff found it exceptionally difficult to read the economic tea
leaves in this forecasting round.

Mother Nature and the Big Three

automakers seem to have led a conspiracy to make the monthly data on
business activity even noisier than they usually are. Moreover, lurking
in the background is the credit crunch story, whose ultimate importance
remains very hard to judge.
In the end, despite all the obvious uncertainties, we felt
there were sufficient grounds to make a few noteworthy changes in our
projections.
First off, we've raised the near-term level of economic
activity.

The Commerce Department revised fourth-quarter GNP upward by

a small amount.

Significantly, the mix of expenditures was altered,

with final sales being strengthened, and inventories being lowered--a
change in composition that tends to have positive implications for
activity in subsequent months.

With respect to the current quarter, the

huge increases in payroll employment in January and February may be a
bit suspect, especially the size of the gains in service sector jobs.
But a temporary jump in construction employment would seem plausible in
light of the warm weather and the stability of the unemployment rate
supports the notion that overall labor demand was indeed quite firm.
We therefore

feel reasonably comfortable in raising our prediction of

real GNP growth in the first quarter to a 2 percent annual rate.

FOMC BRIEFING-MARCH 1990

- 2 -

MICHAEL J. PRELL

The second change in the forecast I want to mention is the
sizable hike in the inflation rate for the current quarter.

At this

juncture, this is little more than a matter of arithmetic:

it would

take a substantial retreat in the March CPI to undo the damage done to
our previous first-quarter projection by the January and February data.
More important for the outlook, however, we've interpreted the recent
price developments as involving something more than transitory weather
effects.

On the energy side, the underlying supply-demand balance in

the world oil market looks to be somewhat tighter than anticipated in
previous projections, and we've raised our assumption for petroleum
prices about a dollar a barrel.

For food, new fruit and vegetable crops

should reverse much of the recent surge in prices, but the inflation
trend for food prices overall looks a shade higher.

And, finally, while

there are lots of special stories about individual items, the pace of
inflation for the CPI excluding food and energy has been faster in
recent months than we had anticipated; in an environment of higher
aggregate demand than previously expected, and with profit margins
having been squeezed, we've thought it reasonable not to project a full
offset in coming quarters to the upside surprise of January-February.
The higher level of activity, the lower unemployment rate, and
the stronger price pressures have led us to the third notable change in
the forecast--namely, the expectation that somewhat greater monetary
restraint may be needed in coming months to temper growth in aggregate
demand through 1991 and to set the stage for a renewed slowing of the
underlying trend of inflation.

As you know, we've built into the

forecast a rise in the federal funds rate of one percentage point,

- 3 -

FOMC BRIEFING-MARCH 1990

MICHAEL J.

occurring toward the end of this year and the beginning of 1991.
rates also are expected to move up, about half a point.

PRELL

Long

Under these

circumstances, as Ted will discuss shortly, the dollar is anticipated to
depreciate even less than in the last forecast.
I won't take the time to recite all the other details of the
recent data, or of our forecast.

I would just note that last Friday's

advance durable goods report was consistent with our expectation that
shipments of nondefense capital goods to U.S. and foreign customers will
be reasonably robust in the current quarter, but that manufacturing
activity will remain sluggish in the next few months.
Perhaps what might be more useful would be for me to take just
a couple of minutes to highlight some of the risks and uncertainties we
perceive from the domestic side.

One of these, which we didn't address

directly in the Greenbook, is the question of how slow GNP growth will
have to be in order to open up some additional slack in the labor
markets.

According to the existing GNP estimates, growth of drought-

adjusted output of 2 percent last year was sufficient to hold the
unemployment rate steady.

Given our assumption that the underlying

trend of potential output growth is on the order of 2-1/2 to 2-3/4
percent, the unemployment rate should have edged upward.

Recognizing

the short-run variability in that relation and the possibility of data
revisions, we've chosen in effect to ignore last year's disparity for
the time being.

But we shall be watching carefully for any further

signs that labor force participation rates are leveling off or that
underlying productivity trends are weaker than we've been assuming.

FOMC BRIEFING-MARCH 1990

- 4 -

MICHAEL J. PRELL

Another area of uncertainty--one that certainly is not new-centers on wage and price behavior.

Although we have raised our

forecast of prices, some analysts would argue that we are being
optimistic and that the recent news is evidence that, at current levels
of resource utilization, tendencies toward a pickup in inflation are
stronger.

We noted in the Greenbook one particular concern in this

regard, centering on the outlook for wages.

All other things equal, one

might have boosted the wage forecast for this year by an amount closer
to the hike in our price forecast--which was four-tenths of a percent
for the CPI.

However, we added only one tenth to our projection of

compensation.

This reflected, in part, our judgment that there has been

no discernible deterioration in wage trends recently, despite the
tighter than anticipated labor market conditions.

Again, I would

suggest that this is something that warrants close monitoring, and by
the May meeting we shall at least have the full complement of labor cost
data for the first quarter and monthly wage figures through April.
One might interpret my remarks as suggesting some bias in the
risks--toward the inflationary side.
considerations.

However, there are some offsetting

Perhaps the most obvious is the "credit crunch" issue.

There is plenty of smoke to attract our attention here, but,
unfortunately, there is little basis for assessing the intensity of the
fire beneath it.

I can't quantify it, but I would say that we've made

allowance in our projection for only a small restrictive effect of the
shift in credit supply conditions on aggregate demand.

If the effects

on spending are larger, then interest rates--at least those on risk-free
assets--would not have to be so high to produce the same GNP outcome.

FOMC BRIEFING-MARCH 1990

- 5 -

Interest rates also would not have been

MICHAEL J. PRELL

as high as they are in

this forecast if it were not anticipated that the external sector will
be providing some added impetus to domestic activity by next year.
has some remarks on that subject.

Ted

E.M.Truman
March 27, 1990

FOMC Presentation on International Developments
In preparing the external component of the latest staff
forecast, we have been influenced by a number of factors.
First, our assessment of economic developments in
central Europe has led us to raise our outlook for growth abroad;
everything else being the same, this has a positive influence on
our forecast for U.S. exports.

I will return to this topic in a

moment.
Second, as

Mike noted, developments in world oil

markets, in particular increased demand from the industrial
countries and reduced supply from the centrally planned
economies, have induced us to raise our assumption about oil
prices by about a dollar a barrel for the balance of the forecast
period.
Third, new data on U.S. international transactions in
the fourth quarter of 1989, especially in the area of net
investment income, showed a substantial improvement.

Most of

this improvement we think will persist and give us a brighter
current account outlook for 1990 and 1991 than we had previously.
Fourth, the projected higher level of dollar interest
rates, against the background of a somewhat better underlying
outlook for our external accounts, has led us to reduce our
projection of the dollar's depreciation in terms of the other G10 currencies.

Indeed, in this forecast the dollar's real

-

2 -

depreciation over the eight quarters starting from the fourth
quarter of last year has been cut almost in half.
On balance, our assessment of these factors has yielded
little change in the expected contribution of the external sector
to U.S. growth over the forecast period: That is, essentially no
net contribution to GNP for the balance of this year followed by
a substantial positive contribution in 1991.

The influence on

the forecast of more growth abroad is roughly offset by the
effects of the stronger dollar.

At the same time, the impact on

U.S. inflation of higher oil prices and more inflation abroad
largely, but not entirely, offsets the influence of a relatively
stronger dollar.

Finally, we now are projecting by the end of

the forecast period a current account deficit that narrows to
around $70 billion at an annual rate.
With a view to adding further to Mike's list of risks in
the forecast, aside from the familiar uncertainties associated
with exchange rates and oil prices, I'd like to expand briefly on
our assessment of growth, inflation and policies abroad; we
focussed our analysis for this forecast on the accelerated pace
of developments in Central Europe over the past six months,
recognizing that our judgments can hardly be definitive.
We believe that the West German economy will receive a
substantial fiscal stimulus over the next year and a half -perhaps, as much as one percent or more of GDP -- in connection
with the process of German economic and monetary union.

The

revitalization of the East German economy, especially a sharp
acceleration of investment expenditures, will add further to
demand in West Germany and pull in imports from outside the two

-

3 -

We envision a similar, but much slower, process of

Germanys.

economic change in the rest of Eastern Europe.

On balance,

anticipation of these developments has contributed to a higher
worldwide level of real interest rates by heightening uncertainty
as well as by raising expected returns to investment.
In addition, there are risks of rising nominal interest
rates abroad owing to greater inflation.

Our assumption is that

the Bundesbank will follow a relatively accommodative monetary
policy.

This should contribute to a higher overall level of

inflation and tend to push up the level of nominal longer-term
interest rates in Germany.

The impact on other countries is more

problematic; a rather robust result in most large-scale
econometric models is that changes in monetary policy in one
country, in an environment of floating exchange rates, has little
net effect on other economies.

However, it is more difficult to

assess the longer-term implications of a possible loss of
Europe's monetary anchor.
In Japan, the combination of higher interest rates and a
weaker yen has caused us to expect lower growth and more rapid
inflation.

We also have lowered our outlook for growth in Canada

in light of the stubborn persistence of inflation in that
country.

On balance, over the past six months, we have added

about a full percentage point on average to the level of economic
activity in the foreign industrial countries by the end of the
forecast period, and an equivalent amount to the average level of
consumer prices.
Mr. Chairman, that concludes our report.

March 27, 1990
FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

As Peter noted, markets are expecting the Committee to maintain
the System's current stance in reserve markets at this meeting--and indeed
seem to be looking for only minor changes in policy for some time to come,
judging from the relatively flat yield curve.

In a sense, they have al-

ready adjusted for the surprising strength in incoming data through the
upward movement in bond yields earlier this year.

And this increase,

together with the strength of the dollar and the reduction in credit
availability, apparently are seen as sufficient to contain inflation pressures within a range markets think the Federal Reserve will tolerate.

In

a sense, the market is at odds with the greenbook forecast, which, as Mike
discussed, put an upward tilt into the path of interest rates over the
forecast horizon--although that discrepancy may rest as much on the
perceived long-run goals of policy as on an assessment of the underlying
forces.
To be sure, bond yields, the dollar and changing credit standards
were taken into account in constructing the greenbook forecast.

But, in

light of their importance to the outlook for aggregate demand and price
pressures, as background for Committee consideration of its policy decision it might be useful to review recent developments in these areas in
some greater detail.
Bond yields were covered extensively at the last meeting.

As I

already mentioned, the increases since late last year seemed largely to be
an endogenous response to the prospects for stronger economic activity

than had previously been expected, rather than a lock step movement with
foreign rates.

The stronger outlook arose both from a re-evaluation of

domestic demand in the U.S. and, secondarily, from the likely pull on our
resources of the changes occurring in Europe.

As a consequence, the high-

er rates would not be expected to weaken the U.S. economy unduly, unless
the market's assessment of underlying demands was mistaken.
Events over the most recent intermeeting period have not contradicted this analysis.

Nominal interest rates in other countries have

risen substantially further over the last month or so--but this time
importantly out of concern about potential increases in their inflation
rates. And, U.S. rates did not follow.

Moreover, the dollar has been

firm, in contrast to the earlier period when the draw of increased real
returns on European investments appeared to put downward pressure on the
dollar.

The more recent upward pressure on the dollar seems to reflect

concerns that real returns abroad may fall as foreign monetary policy
fails to keep pace with inflation pressures, rather than a rise in real
rates here.

The continued increase of equity prices in the United States

is consistent with a relatively benign domestic real rate environment.

In

the context of possible upward revisions in expected inflation abroad, the
rise in the dollar probably is larger in nominal than in real terms; if
this is the case, it would be serving more to help insulate our price
level from greater price pressure abroad, than to damping real net
exports.
With respect to tightening credit standards, it is important to
delineate the information we have, while at the same time acknowledging
that the situation may be evolving rapidly and could show up in our data

only with a lag.

Bank survey results, beige book reports, yield spreads

on junk bonds, and reports from the commercial paper market all indicate
that riskier borrowers are having problems finding credit.

In particular,

lending for corporate restructuring as well as for certain types of real
estate transactions is more expensive, carries more stringent nonrate
terms, and is generally less available.

On the other hand, the credit

squeeze apparently has not extended to investment-grade borrowers.

Bank

survey responses indicate a continued willingness to lend to such borrowers for nonmerger purposes.

Spreads among investment grade yields or

between such yields and government securities are unusually low--and
inconsistent with past behavior prior to recessions, when they generally
had begun to widen.

Moreover, spreads between residential mortgage and

Treasury rates have even narrowed a bit since late last year, indicating a
continuing flow of funds to this market despite thrift cutbacks.
However, standard market yield spreads may not be a reliable
indicator of a reduction in credit availability from banks to smaller
businesses, who don't have alternative market source of funds.

Bank sur-

vey evidence suggests that the spread of rates on smaller business loans
over federal funds is fairly high, but did not widen between November and
February and remains within the range of spreads that has prevailed in
recent years.

Banks have indicated that they are tightening nonprice

credit terms for riskier businesses, which may disproportionately include
small businesses.

However, from the business side, a survey done in

January of smaller businesses showed no increased perception of reduced
credit availability.

From a quantitative perspective, credit flows slowed last year,
but do not seem to have decelerated further outside of the areas already
identified as facing credit constraints.

A substantial weakening in bank

business lending late last year and early 1990 appeared to reflect primarily a cutback in merger-related lending, as well as the effects of lagging
reduction in bank prime rates.

Excluding this lending, and taking account

of commercial paper issuance as well, short-term business borrowing has
been quite sluggish in the first few months of 1990, but this simply continued a trend that had been in place all of 1989.

The debt of all

pri-

vate nonfinancial borrowers is estimated on the basis of very partial data
to be growing in the first quarter at about the pace of last year, also
abstracting from the ups and downs of merger financing.
steadiness of debt growth may be misleading.

Still, the

Any cutback in credit avail-

ability, might be reflected first in commitments, and only later in flows.
Perhaps for this reason, bank credit flows do not seem to a be good leading indicators of business activity.
On the other side of the public's balance sheet, increases in M2
have been fairly robust, and are expected to moderate only slightly in the
months ahead.

This aggregate grew along the 7 percent upper end of its

long-run range in the first quarter, coming in only a little below Committee expectations.

With the slight slowing in M2 growth we are project-

ing over the coming three months under alternative B, this aggregate in
June would be 6-1/2 percent, at an annual rate, above its fourth quarter
average.

The slowing is premised on less rapid nominal GNP growth and

only modest narrowing of the unusually wide opportunity costs for holding
deposits that have opened up recently.

M3 growth is expected to pick up a

-5-

little from its recent depressed pace, but to stay within the lower half
of its range.
Several developments could shift the demand for money relative to
income and interest rates in coming months, complicating interpretation of
these indicators.

One is the tax season.

Frequently, the months of the

second quarter see pronounced swings in monetary data as the tax paying or
clearing process does not coincide with the patterns built into our seasonals.

We doubt that people will be as surprised this year as they evi-

dently were last by the size of their tax payments, so we have projected
smooth monthly growth rates.

Yet, tax payments are expected to be quite

high again this year, and whether anticipated or not, could result in a
greater drawdown of liquid balances than we have predicted.
source of uncertainty is the RTC.

Another

We have assumed a major increase in

activity by this organization--resolving institutions and replacing high
cost funds.
announced.

Yet we have not built in anything like the numbers publicly
Higher levels of activity would tend to depress M3, as borrow-

ing by the Treasury to carry thrift assets replaces deposits and RPs in
M3.

It could affect M2 as well, to the extent thrifts became even less of

a factor competing for funds, and banks find themselves even more flush
with cash, with greater incentives to hold down retail deposit rates.
However the Committee interprets all the economic and financial
evidence, the market is not expecting any changes in the stance of monetary policy, as I already noted.

An unchanged stance makes sense should

the Committee perceive the balance of risks about evenly distributed in
terms of the longer-run outlook for the economy and prices relative to a
desired path, recognizing that in the short-run such a path might involve

both modest growth and continued fairly strong price increases, given the
position of the economy.

An unchanged and balanced directive might be

considered an appropriate holding action in light of difficulties in sorting out weather and other special effects in first quarter data from underlying forces acting on the economy, and in assessing the credit supply
situation.

In addition, a steady monetary policy in the U.S. in the near

term might provide an appropriate background against which to work through
volatile conditions in foreign financial markets and discussions associated with the international coordination process.
However, steady policy would not be appropriate if it were seen
Concern

as clearly at odds with the appropriate course for the economy.

that the level of real rates, tightening credit conditions, and fragile
financial conditions could undermine the expansion might argue for a downward tilt in the directive, if not an actual easing of policy.

On the

other hand, a sense that the current course risked insufficient restraint
on inflation pressures and a lack of progress toward price stability over
time would weight toward consideration of a tighter policy at this time,
or for an upward tilt in the directive.

Any tilt would mark a shift from

the current balanced language in the directive and would not only

guide

policy until the next meeting, but would acknowledge, in a way that eventually will be made public, the Committee's assessment of the balance of
risks and priorities and the likely next step in policy.

E.M.Truman
March 27, 1990
Introductory Comments on
Task Force on System Foreign Currency Operations
Sam and I have no desire to add to the pile of words
that have been assembled for you by the Task Force on System
Foreign Currency Operations, and we see no need to do so, since
we hope the Task Force papers speak for themselves.

However, we

thought it might be useful briefly to review the procedures we
followed in putting together the material and to provide a few
introductory comments.
With respect to procedures, our aim was to put together
a comprehensive review of U.S. experience with respect to foreign
currency operations over the past three decades with an emphasis
on System operations.

Our objective in the 11 papers before you

and in our overview memorandum was to provide a consistent
treatment of the various topics; it was not to produce complete
convergence or consensus.

We recognized from the start that

there are some differences in interpretation of history, policy
and economic analysis in this area, and we knew we were not going
to settle those differences.

Our objective was to assemble a

reasonably faithful record that would assist the Committee in its
deliberations on these issues in the future.
Although our focus was retrospective, I believe that
certain themes usefully can be highlighted.
First, I was struck in the Task Force papers by both the
elements of consistency and the elements of change in the

-

2 -

institutional context of System operations in foreign currencies.
The basic relationship between the Federal Reserve and the
Treasury has been remarkably constant, but the structure and
functioning of the international monetary system has evolved in
many important respects since 1962.
The final authority to determine U.S. exchange rate
policy lies with the Treasury.

However, the System has

cooperated with the Treasury in the formulation and
implementation of that policy throughout the years, prior to and
following the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system, the adoption
of floating exchange rates, and the disenchantment with what some
see as the adverse consequences of floating exchange rates.

In

recent years, the Federal Reserve's cooperation with the Treasury
has included an involvement along with other major central banks
in a search within the G-7 process for greater exchange rate
stability and increased cooperation on economic policies.
I believe that the Federal Reserve's cooperation with
the Treasury in exchange rate matters, on the whole, has served
the System's and the nation's interest.

However, I also

recognize the existence of differences of view on the appropriate
role of central banks in this area, both in the abstract and for
the Federal Reserve.

Indeed, in the wake of events since the

Task Force was formed, this has become a central issue for the
Committee.
Second, over the years the influence of concerns about
dollar exchange rates on Federal Reserve monetary policy has
varied, but the potential influences always have been there.

I

-

3

-

would not deny the risk that exchange rate considerations could
dominate Federal Reserve monetary policy discussions, and they
may have done so in the past.

However, based on the Task Force's

review of our own experience and that of other countries, my
conclusion is that the probability that such considerations will
distort decisions is not increased by the active involvement of
the central bank in foreign currency operations.
Third, differences in view and interpretation about the
role of exchange rates, the effectiveness of intervention, and
the implications for monetary policy are inevitable.

They can be

traced to philosophical, policy and methodological differences as
well as to the failure of the economics profession to reach a
broad consensus on some of these issues.

Moreover, such

differences are likely to persist.
Fourth, while U.S. exchange rate policy is evolutionary,
I suspect that U.S. intervention in exchange markets will
continue for some time to be conducted under the rubric of
"countering disorderly market conditions", interpreted
elastically.

It is an open question whether, in the future, U.S.

exchange rate policy retains the ad hoc flavor of much of the
floating rate period or will evolve in the direction of target
zones for exchange rates or in the direction of broader
objectives such as fostering conditions for greater exchange rate
stability.

It follows that it is also an open question how often

U.S. intervention will be aimed at directing or guiding dollar
exchange rates, as opposed to resisting changes in rates.

Issues

for the Federal Reserve involve the implications of such choices

-

4

-

for monetary policy and how this institution most effectively can
influence U.S. policy on these matters.
Finally, the Task Force's papers underscore the
important role over the years of accountability -Committee, to Congress, and to the public --

Reserve's foreign currency operations.

to the

in the Federal

I hope that these papers

have contributed to that record.
Sam Cross will now complete our introductory comments.

[Secretary's Note:

There is no record of a statement by Mr. Cross at this

had
point. The staff's recollection is that Mr. Cross commented that he
nothing further to add.]