View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
BOARD
OF GOVERNORS
OF THE

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
WASHINGTON

March 26, 1963.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR)
TO:

Federal Open Market Committee

FROM:

Mr. Young

SUBJECT:

Additional staff paper.

Supplementing my memorandum of March 1, 1963 transmitting
a group of staff papers on effects of changes in monetary policy,
there is enclosed another paper, prepared by Mr. Reynolds of the
Board's Division of International Finance under date of March 25,
1963, commenting on the U. S. balance of payments situation in
early 1963. As indicated in my earlier memorandum distributing
these papers, two copies are being given to each Reserve Bank
President, one for his own use and one for the use of his chief
economist.

Enclosures

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR)

March 25, 1963.
The U.S. Balance-of-Payments Situation in Early 1963, with
Tentative Notes on the Outlook

There seems to be general agreement that a change in U.S.

monetary policy towards less ease might produce some improvement
in the U.S. balance of payments, but would involve some domestic
risks and costs.

Even if the possible gains and risks and costs,

under specified conditions, can be agreed upon within a tolerably
narrow range, no judgment can be made as to whether the game is
worth the condle except in the light of a careful appraisal of the

current situation and of prospective developmentd, both in the
balance of payments and in the domestic economy.

This note appraises the international payments situation.
It argues that, as of the first quarter of 1963, the U.S. payments
deficit is certainly not increasing, and may well be shrinking.
It suggests that there is a good possibility of significant improve-

ment during 1963 and into 1964.
as a possibility.

So far, this can only be described

The uncertainties are large, and underlying trends

have been temporarity obscured in recent months by U.S. longshoremen's strikes, by a bunching of capital inflows and outflows of

several kinds, and by an exceptionally severe winter in Europe.
Nevertheless, it seems to the author of this note (who should be

classified as relatively optimistic) that there are considerably
greater possibilities for improvement than for deterioration,
independent of any monetary action that might be considered as

potentially helpful.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
- 2 The Rationale of U.S. Policy to Date
The U.S. payments deficit first became a recognized
problem in 1958, and was not explicitly attacked by the Government
until 1960-61,

although the policies most essential to its reso-

lution were those adopted earlier to end inflation.
U.S. policy to deal with the payments problem since 1958
has always assumed that the elimination of the deficit would have

to come gradually, over a period of several years, and would come
mainly through changes in relative prices and costs,

and in the

relative attractiveness of investment opportunities here and abroad.
There has been reason to hope that these changes would come about
as a result of gentle inflation and heightened uncertainty as to
investment returns in leading foreign countries while U.S. prices

and costs were held stable.

While drastic changes in internal or

external policies (including exchange rate policy) might theoretically
provide alternative -- and quicker -- ways of getting the required
adjustments, such changes have not represented practical alternatives
that the United States could adopt without causing disruption much
worse than the cure.

A long series of more narrow and specific remedies has
also, of course, been set in motion, including tying of aid, negotiation of increased foreign military procurement in this country,
and export promotion drive, and support of the U.S. Treasury bill
rate. .But the competitive adjustment, both for its effects on

current transactions and on investment incentives, has been relied
upon as the fundamental one.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-3Recently increased concern about the payments situation
has reflected disappointment at the slowness which which that adjustment is occurring, and even doubts as to whether it is occurring

at all.
Recent Doubts

The sources of these doubts are many.

First of all, the

1962 payments results were disappointing to all observers.

The

deficit on transactions other than debt prepayments and special
Treasury financing was $3.6 billion --

higher than 1961's $3.1

billion and only slightly below the $3.9 billion of 1960.

The dis-

appointment has been particularly keenly felt by those who had
erroneously supposed, during the summer of 1962, that the deficit
was already diminishing rapidly.

Doubts have been sharpened by

the painful U.S. official withdrawal from an earlier prediction of
payments balance by about the end of 1963.

If not then, when?

Will another year of substantial deficit so undermine confidence

in U.S. policies as to lead to larger gold losses, to still larger
capital outflow, and even, perhaps, to a crisis run on the dollar?
Secondly, doubts have arisen because of growing recognition
of the possibility that even if the U.S. competitive position were
to improve substantially, the beneficial effects of that improvement
on current and capital transactions could be swamped by increased
capital outflows, related less directly to competitiveness than to
such other factors as interest rates and confidence.

These doubts

have recently been sharpened by the insistent urging of some
Continental European officials, in Working Party 3 and elsewhere,

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

and of many other observers, that a rise in U.S. interest rates was
essential.

They have also been accentuated by the continued heavy

volume of capital outflows from the U.S. in the fourth quarter of
1962 and probably also in the early months of 1963, in which a record
volume of new foreign bond issues has attracted particular attentions
A third element in recent doubts has been some second

thoughts about policy prospects, and especially their timing.

Last

year, it was possible to argue that a tax cut was needed, that its
enactment would stimulate the domestic economy, and that the stimulus
would itself produce, or be allowed to produce, credit tightening
which could reinforce the dampening effect on net capital outflow
that would come from improved U.S. profit prospects and investment
incentives.

But the form which the Administration's tax proposals

finally took, together with the nature of Congressional action,
makes it unlikely that any tax cut can be enacted before September
1963.

Hence, many people (e.g., the OECD Secretariat) now see the

balance-of-payments effects of th e tax cut and associated credit
tightening coming almost a year later than they had been supposing
as recently as last fall.

They have new cause to wonder whether

other action will be needed in the interim..
Recent Balance of Payments Developments
The increase in the U.S. payments deficit, adjusted for

special Government transactions, from the year 1961 to the year 1962
occurred mainly during 1961.

The swing in transactions with Canada

during 1962, associated with the Canadian exchange crisis and
stabilization, was so large that it accounted for about all of the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

increase in the over-all U.S. deficit from the first to the second
half of 1962.

Thus, as will be seen from Table 1, the underlying

deficit (i.e., aside from special Government transactions and this
Canadian swing) did not change appreciably from the first half year
to the second.

It was significantly smaller than in the second half

of 1961 and in the second half of 1960.

What made the year 1961

as a whole better than the year 1962 was the sharp recession in

U.S. imports in the first half of 1961 which was so obviously
temporary that it makes that period a very poor base for any
comparisons.

Table 1. U.S. Payments Deficit, 1960-62
(billions of dollars, semi-annually, seasonally adjusted)

1961

1960

Over-all deficit, published

1962

1st
half

2nd
half

1st

2nd

lst

2nd

half

half

half

half(p)

1.46

2.41

.18

2.18

.71

1.47

.63

.04

.08

.59

Debt prepayment receipts

--

Special U.S. Treasury borrowing
Reclassification of military accts.

Deficit on all other transactions

.23
1.46

2.41s

.81

2.22

Temporary effects of Canadian
crisis and stabilization, 1962

.81

1.46

(Memo:

(.14) (1.56) (.20) (.66)

2.41

unadjusted for seasonal variation)

(p) Preliminary.

2.54

+.7(e)-.7(e)

Deficit on all other transactions

decline in U.S. gold stock,

1.02

.25
.23

(e) Very rough estimate.

2.22

1.7(e)1.8(e)

(.42)

(.47)

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-6-

Thus, the 1962 figures do not support the view that the
payments deficit increased in a significant sense during 1962.
Instead, they are consistent with the hypothesis of a gradual
corrective process over a period of years.
show a disappointingly slow improvement.

It is true that they
Partly, however, this

resulted from adverse net effects in 1962 of Canadian actions (in
addition to the swing assumed to have washed out within the year).

The Canadian dollar was devalued sharply further in May 1962, to
6-1/2 per cent below its average 1961 value in terms of U.S.
dollars, and to 11 per cent below its average 1959-60 value.
Temporary surcharges on imports were imposed.

Canadian policy was

temporarily and deliberately aimed at attracting a very substantial
capital inflow from the United States.

Canadian reserves increased,

net of special assistance received from the IMF, by $300 million
during 1962.

If one is relying on a gradual adjustment in relative

prices, costs, and investment incentives, one must not be surprised
if a currency devaluation and capital-import drive by a major trading partner set the process back a little.

During January-February 1963, the over-all deficit (again
on transactions other than special Treasury borrowing) was about
$630 million (preliminary).

Weekly indicators (incomplete and

preliminary) for the 3 weeks from February 28 through March 20

showed a surplus of $70 million.

The deficit for the full quarter

may tentatively be guessed at about $600 to $700 million.

If no

large special influences had to be allowed for, that would be an
encouraging result, significantly below the average $900 million
quarterly deficit in 1962.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-7In fact, several special influences were present in the
first quarter of 1963 and do have to be allowed for in judging

the representativeness of the first quarter results.

And unfor-

tunately their various quantitative effects can be only very
roughly appraised now. Nevertheless, those effects seem likely
to have been roughly offsetting; they may not have had much net
impact on the over-all first-quarter payments results.

(1) The longshoremen's strike probably had a
sizeable net adverse effect on U.S. trade during the
first quarter, perhaps of $100 to $200 million;
but it may not have had very much net effect on
payments.

While more exports than imports were

moved up from the first quarter of 1963 into
December 1962, in anticipation of the strike, we
do not know whether payments were similarly

affected, or to what extent.

(This uncertainty

may never be clearly resolved.)

(2) Outflows of U.S. capital into new foreign
security issues were very heavy during the first

quarter, and included take-downs of $225 million
on two unusually large Canadian issues. At roughly
$400 to $500 million, the total of such outflows
may have been $100 to $200 million above the
average quarterly rate for 1963 as a whole.

(3) On the other hand, foreign official institutions made unusually large repayments of U.S.
bank loans; the Bank of Japan repaid about $180
million and the Government of Venezuela prepaid
about $60 million.

This favorable element may

have roughly matched the unfavorable element in
item (2) above.

(4) Bear raids on the pound sterling at the
end of January and in the middle of March probably
benefitted the U.S. balance of payments; the

weekly indicators showed exceptional U.S. payments surpluses of over $100 million in each of
the weeks (January 31 - February 6 and March 14-20)
when such raids were heavy. But it would be

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

- 8 surprising if the total favorable effect for the
quarter was nearly as large as $200 million. Total
British official reserve losses may have been
about $300 million. Of this amount, we know

(confidentially) that more than $100 million
represented a shift of Spanish reserves out of
sterling into dollars. Some further portion is

thought to have swelled private British holdings,
official French reserves, and perhaps the reserves
of other European countries.

(5) The net seasonal factor is small in the
first quarter; seasonal inflows representing the
unwinding of year-end window-dressing are largely
offset by unfavorable seasonal movements in other

flows.

In summary, tentative first quarter payments results
now available, even after rough allowance for special influences,

suggest a deficit running at or below $3 billion at an annual rate,
compared to $3.6 billion in 1962 and a rate of over $4 billion in
the second halves of 1960 and 1961.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-9Related Economic Developments
The cost-price adjustments relied upon in the basic
rationale of U.S. policy have in fact been occurring since about

1959.

Since then, prices and costs have been stable in this

country, and they have been rising in almost all leading industrial
countries abroad, as Table 2 indicates.

So far, foreign costs

have apparently risen more than prices, with a resulting squeeze

on profits.

But that does not necessarily frustrate the inter-

national payments adjustment.

It need only mean that the adjust-

ment comes less in current account transactions and more in
capital account transactions as relative profit prospects change.
Table 2. Prices and Wages in Leading Countries
(Percentage changes, year 1959 to December 1962)
Cost of

United States
United ingdom
Canada 1/

living
+ 4
+10
+ 4

Wholesale

prices
0
+ 7
+ 5

Hourly earnings

in manufacturing
+ 1
+20 (Oct.)
+13

4

Germany 2/

+ 8

+

France 2
Italy
Netherlands 2/

+15
+13
+ 9

+10
+ 7
- 3 (Nov.)

Sweden

+12

+ 8

Japan

+20

+ 7

+35 (Aug.)

h/ +28 (Oct.)

'/

+28

J/ +31
+28 (Nov.)

/

+29 (Nov.)

1/ Not corrected for devaluation of Canadian dollar by 11 per

cent in 1961-62.
2/ Not corrected for revaluation of German mark and Dutch guilder
by 5 per cent in 1961.
3/ The French franc was devalued by 29 per cent in 1957-58.
4/ Hourly wage rates; earnings rose more than rates.
Sources:
Note:

OECD Statistical Bulletins and IMF International Financial
Statistics.

The indexes used are not closely comparable; in particular,
wholesale price indexes differ greatly in the weights given to
imported goods and to agricultural products and raw materials.
Nevertheless, the figures are believed to be reasonably
indicative of broad trends.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

- 10 The Committee on Balance of Payments Information, in
its recent sobering report to Mr. Dillon on the outlook for 1963,
noted that the effects of improved U.S. competitiveness, if any,
had been slow in showing up in international transactions, and
could not safely be relied upon to help us much this year.

But

it seems to the present writer that (a) they are bound to show
up sooner or later, (b) they could not have been expected to show
up very strikingly before about now, and (c) some of them have
already become evident.
We have the dramatic case of autos, by now a cliche
but still important.. This was perhaps a problem more of design
and marketing than of prices and costs, but it illustrated well
the time lags involved in market adjustments and also the fact
that such adjustments do occur,

US. auto companies took about

two years (1957-58) to see the need, and another two years (1959-60)
to meet the challenge.

Sales of imported autos rose to 10 per

cent of total U.S. sales in 1959, but have since declined to less
than 5 per cent.

One should probably expect a time-lag as long

as this, or longer, in most competitive adjustments affecting
trade in industrial products.

Competitive pressures must be felt,

products redesigned, new customer relationships developed,and
so forth.

Relative cost-price changes that occur only slowly are

even more slowly perceived and acted upon.
In the case of investment incentives, time lags are also
long.

For example, U.S. corporations that decided to establish

operations in Common Market countries after the restoration of

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

- 11 convertibility in 1958 and after the fact that the Common Market
was a going concern became apparent in 1959, may well not have
completed their plans until 1960 or 1961, and in many cases are
still carrying them out.

The profit squeeze was not felt acutely

in most Continental European countries until some time in 1962;
it could have been foreseen in 1961, but could not much have
affected planning before 1961.
Cost and price inflation in Europe is continuing.

It

has recently been dramatized in France--by the extension of paid
vacations for Renault workers, and by the coal minerst strike and

related strikes in public service industries in defiance of the
Government.

Inflation appears recently to have been about as

rapid in Italy as in France, and continues in Germany to an extent
that the German authorities find very disquieting.
these cases,

(In some of

inflation may already have gone about far enough to

produce--ultimately--the kind of payments adjustment needed.
Therefore,

current attempts by the authorities in those countries

to restrain inflation are not necessarily incompatible with

restoration of international balance.
inflation in France, for example,

It

is highly important that

be stopped well short of the point

where yet another currency devaluation begins to seem attractive.)

Some observers have been disappointed that inflation
in foreign countries with payments surpluses does not seem to be
correcting international imbalances.

Part of the answer lies in

the necessarily long time-lags in the adjustment process, noted

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-12

above.

-

But an important second part of the answer is that the

payments situations of several leading countries have been changing,
and are changing now.
(1) The German payments surplus disappeared a year ago
and has not re-emerged.
(2) The Italian surplus is now much diminished, or
perhaps eliminated.
(3) In Spain, South Africa, and Australia, substantial
surpluses in late 1961 and much of 1962 have apparently now ended.

(4)

Japan's surplus in 1962, following a large deficit

in 1961, was precariously based on short-term borrowing abroad

and on inventory liquidation; its continuation this year is doubtful.
(5)

The United Kingdom is generally regarded as facing

more difficult payments problems this year than last, when its

external accounts were roughly in balance.
(6) France--the country with the largest surplus--is
perhaps the biggest question mark.

Through February, official

reserve gains continued to be very large; their size is explainable
only by capital inflows which cannot yet be analyzed in detail.

Most

observers (e.g., the OECD Secretariat, the U.S. Embassy in Paris)

expect some shrinkage of the French surplus from 1962 to 1963,
perhaps from $1.2 billion to

9 billion.

Some observers (e.g.,

M. Kozul of the Bank of France, M. Ferras of the BIS) have a
feeling that the French surplus could evaporate fairly rapidly if
the French Government should prove unable to bring inflationary

pressures under control.

They remember that the large French

payments surpluses of 1954 and 1955 gave way to deficits overnight early in 1956.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-

(7)

13 -

Canada experienced a huge swing from deficit to

surplus between the first and second halves of 1962, but seems
unlikely to realize or seek a continuing large over-all surplus

in 1963, given its large monetary reserves and its domestic need
for economic expansion and reduction of unemployment.
The prospects sketched in these capsule summaries do
not, of course, rule out continuation of a large U.S. payments
deficit.

New surplus countries could appear, or some less

developed countries could swing from deficit towards balance--a
development much to be hoped for.

But there is at least a real

question, worth exploring carefully, as to who will have the
payments surpluses in 1963 and 1964 to match a continuing large
U.S.

deficit.

John E. Reynolds