View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC Notes -- Peter Fisher

March 22, 1994
I will be referring to the two color charts distributed this
morning, and I will try to address two questions:
First, why is the dollar lower now against the yen and the
mark than it was at the time of your last meeting?
And second, what are some of the factors that triggered the
rapid and parallel backing up of interest rates in a number of
countries starting in mid-February?
The absence of a U.S.-Japan trade agreement, following the
Clinton-Hosokawa meeting, and the glacial pace of monetary easing by
the Bundesbank are the two factors that most directly contributed to
the dollar's decline. However, to understand the dollar's movements
and the extraordinary movements in bond yields, it is worth looking at
the expectations and the positions with which market participants
began 1994. Joan will be going over the events that directly affected
the U.S. government securities market. I will try to describe some of
the key events in the foreign exchange market and in other countries,
indicating some of the connections among markets.
The first chart shows the movements in dollar-yen, dollarmark, and "G-5" bond yields from last July through January. As 1993
came to a close, market participants expected that the weak Japanese
stock market and the deteriorating economy would force the Bank of
Japan to ease once again. Although the Bundesbank had fixed its
market operations at 6 percent from December to early January, it was
widely expected to resume the more rapid easing it had begun in
October, which would permit German and European interest rates to come
down quickly. While U.S. interest rates were expected to go up in the
first half of 1994, the timing and extent of this remained uncertain.
With these expectations, a wide range of market participants began the
year with quite similar positions: long Japanese government bonds,
long European government bonds, and long dollars against both the yen
and the mark.
The second chart shows the same exchange rates and yields from
December to the present, with indications for the dates of some of the
events--or "trip wires"--that successively undercut the assumptions
that supported these positions, resulting in an accumulation of losses
for market participants.
In early January the Nikkei rallied sharply on a large flow of
foreign money. This weighed on dollar-yen, both as a result of the
demand for yen and by reducing the likelihood of an easing by the Bank
of Japan. On January 13th rumors circulated in Tokyo that the Trust
Division of the Ministry of Finance would begin liquidating some of
its holdings of Japanese government bonds (JGBs), and the next day it
was announced that 900 billion of JGBs would be sold before the end of

the fiscal year. In the first half of the fiscal year the Trust
Division had been a net purchaser. This shift in stance, combined
with rising expectations for an increased supply of government debt
and the decreasing expectations for further ease, caused a rapid selloff in the JGB market, as indicated by the first "trip wire." By the
end of January, when the 10-year JGB had backed up by 75 basis points,
we began to hear the first rumors of large-scale losses at investment
banks and/or hedge funds.
On February 4th, the Committee's action led to a brief rise in
the dollar against both the mark and the yen. There was a brief
period of profit taking, while market participants awaited the outcome
of the Clinton-Hosokawa meeting and some signal of further easing from
the Bundesbank. In retrospect, the failure of the dollar to sustain
much more of a rally can be seen as reflecting just how long dollars
the market was.
Although the dollar-yen declined in the days running up to the
Clinton-Hosokawa summit on February 11th, market sentiment was
dominated by the view that the dollar would rise against the yen (and
also against the mark) once the meeting and the trade issue were "out
Some market participants extended their long dollar
of the way."
positions at "cheaper" prices as their Washington "listening posts"
assured them that a trade deal was in the works. With the emptyhanded outcome of the meeting, the dollar began to sell off in thin
Friday trading. On Monday, the liquidation of long-dollar positions
accelerated, and in New York in the afternoon the dollar traded down
to a low of 101.10 and closed at 102.60. The dollar also moved down
against the mark, as market participants sought an alternative means
of reducing their dollar holdings.
Attention then turned to the prospect for further Bundesbank
easing. In this setting, the dollar's post Valentine's Day weakness
encouraged market participants to hope that the Bundesbank would lower
rates at its February 17th Council meeting. After all, despite the
Fed having tightened, the mark was not weaker but stronger against the
dollar, giving the Bundesbank the opportunity to lower rates without
the mark suffering a double hit--or so hoped market participants.
On February 17th the Bundesbank lowered its Discount Rate by
50 basis points, but left its Lombard and repurchase rate unchanged.
The decrease in the Discount Rate, which acts as something of a floor
on the repo rate, provided a prospect of further easing in the coming
weeks, but this would be too late and too uncertain for market
participants who:
-- had already incurred mark-to-market losses on European bond
positions since the start of the year;
--were incurring the high cost of carry for these positions
under repo financing;
--had already suffered losses in either JGBs or long dollar
positions or both;

--in some cases also suffered mark-to-market losses in
"emerging market" equities and Brady bonds.
Although in subsequent weeks the Bundesbank has reduced the
repo rate, it has done so in successive baby steps of a 3, another 3,
and finally a 6 basis point move.
A number of market participants have described the period from
mid-February as a "liquidation crisis" but one which began not so much
with an abundance of selling as with limited buying capacity. In
particular, major market makers, who have suffered losses on their
strategic positions since the start of the year, were trying to limit
losses--or hold onto profits--for the first quarter. The risk
management systems used by hedge funds, investment banks, and the
major commercial banks typically specify a profit objective, a loss
tolerance, and volatility assumptions all for a given month or
quarter. As either losses or volatilities rise, these systems dictate
a reduction of risk over the remaining period and, thus, require the
closing of positions. As market makers reluctantly took on bond
positions from their customers, they were forced to head to the
futures markets to offset these additional exposures at the same time
they were trying to unwind their own positions. As prices moved
further and faster, volatilities increased and additional mark-tomarket losses were incurred, leading to further reductions in risk
tolerance and further reductions in positions. While this kind of
risk management discipline is obviously desirable in terms of an
individual firm's exposure, the pressure is shifted to the markets in
price movement and volatility.
The widespread use of "proxy hedging" also contributed to the
parallel movements in bond yields. An extreme example of this is
reflected in the movements of U.K. government securities (the green
line on the third panel of the second chart). Following the
Bundesbank's February 17th meeting, the futures contract on gilts was
sold as a proxy for a wide range of European government bonds, and as
a result U.K. 10-year interest rates backed up faster than others.
On March 1st the 7.5 percent U.S. GDP figure was released, as
was the NAPM survey. On March 2nd, the Bundesbank announced that
German M3 grew by over 20 percent in January. Both events contributed
to market volatility and to market anxiety about the course of
interest rates. Then on March 3rd two events occurred which helped to
calm at least some markets. First, the Bank of Spain cut its repo
rate by 50 basis points, which provided a reminder to market
participants that the trend for short-term European interest rates was
still downward. To some this reawakened the possibility for a
"decoupling" of U.S. and European bond yields. Also on March 3rd, the
Clinton Administration announced the reassertion of "Super 301" trade
sanction powers. To the surprise of some, this served to reduce
anxieties in the exchange market.
Following the Clinton-Hosokawa meting, the absence of concrete
actions by the Administration on the trade front contributed to the
view that the U.S. would rely principally on talking up the yen. The

. dollars
Bank of Japan's operations, which totalled
purchased from February 15th to March 4th, had stabilized the dollar
around 104, but anxiety remained about U.S. policy, and market
participants continued to perceive a risk that the dollar could fall
quickly to and through 100 yen. The Super 301 announcement indicated
that the U.S. did intend to use policy tools other than exchange
rates, and the next morning in Tokyo the dollar moved up quickly
through 105 and has recently traded around 106.
Foreign exchange market participants express the view that the
market has priced in a 25 basis point increased in the fed funds rate
resulting from this meeting. While clearly they expect such an action
from this meeting, I think it is extraordinarily difficult to assess
what is and what is not priced into the dollar at this point. There
has been a pronounced reduction in leverage and in positions over the
past month and, at some point, both are likely to increase. But
focusing on dollar-mark, my gut tells me that the dollar might rise by
a small amount on the fact of a further tightening but could then come
off as profits are quickly taken, much as it did in February.
Mr. Chairman, during the period we sold 600 million Swiss
francs and 34 million Belgian francs for a total of $417 million.
These operations, conducted in furtherance of our objective of
eliminating the System's non-mark and non-yen foreign currency
balances occurred on 5 different days and--as we intended--had no
impact on exchange rates. I note for the Committee that I expect to
complete these currency sales by Mid-April.
Mr. Chairman, I need the Committee's approval of these
operations. I would be happy to answer any questions either on my
report or on the currency sales.

A

July 1993 through January 1994
US Dollar/Japanese Yen Spot Exchange Rates

114
-

- - - -- -- - - -

- - - --

- - - -- - - -- - - - - - - -- -

---

-

- - -

- - - - 112
110

- -- - -- -- --- - - - - --- -- --- -- - -- ---

-- - -- -

-

--

-

-- -- - - - -

- -

- - -

- -

--

--

- -- - --- --- ----- -1n n,,

*-

''L' I '

II " ' ' '

Jul

'' '

Aug

.

--

--

''

''

-n' n

---- -

I

n '
'

''

- - - - - - - - - - -- - - - -- - -- 108
---- ----

- ----

- -

- -

- -

--

---- --

- -

I

' ' ' ' 'n "' ' '

Nov

Sep

- -

Dec

--

1.72
1.70
1.68
1.66
1.64
1.62

--

- -

--

- - 104

--

1
,,II"
"' '

' ' '"

- 102

''

I

Jan

100

1994

1993

1.76
1.74

- -

- - - - 106

US Dollar/German Mark Spot Exchange Rates

1.76
------------------------------------------------- ---- 1.74
S----------------------------------- -------- --------- 1.72
---- ---- ---------------------------- ------------- 1.70
------------------------------------------------------ 1.68
------------- ----------------------------- 1.66
--------------------------------------- ----------------------------------- 1.64
------------------------------------------ ------------- 1.62
------------------------------------------------------- 1.60

1.60
1.58
199II

..............

..............

Aug

I.....................

....................

...............

...................

Nov

Sep

Dec

I .................

1.58

Jan
1994

199 3

10 Year Government Bond Yields (%)
8.00

8.00
0 = period low

---------------------------------7.50

7.50

----------------------------------

7.00
6.50

S------

6.00

-

--

---

----

-

--

7.00
- 6-------.50

----

--------

-

6.00

5.50

--~---------5.00

-------

4.50

---- ------------1 5.50
-- - - - -- - - - - ---- - --- - -- ------- - - 5.50
5.00

--...--

4.00

---------------

-

----

-

------

4.50

-- -

4.00
3.50

3.50
3.00 u..
Jul

..

1993

Bryan P Bradley

Aug

Sep

C)ct

Nov

Dec

Jan

1994

Foreign Exchange Function: Federal Reserve Bank of NY
Source: Spot rates, FRBNY; Bond yields, Bloomberg Information Services.

B

December 1993 through March 1994
US Dollar/Japanese Yen Spot Exchange Rates
114

114

112 ---

--------------

-------------

110

108 -108

- - -- -- -----

---- -

-----

-----

^-

-

-----------------

106 --------------- ---------

------

I

.-----

-------

-

---

-------

---

-

----

---

|--

--

,-

------------------------

102

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- - - - -

bec

Jan

1993

1994

-

112

----------

110

--

-

- -----

l-

--------

-------------------

104

----------

- - - - - - -- - - - - Feb 4

11

-------

108
106

104

- - - - - - - - - - 102

-- - - - 17

-----

-

Mar

100

12

1.764

1.74
1.72
1.70
1.68

Dec
1993

1 2

1994

10 Year Government Bond Yields (%)

Feb

Bryan P. Bradley

4

11

17

Mar
12
Foreign Exchange Function: Federal Reserve Bank of NY
Source: Spot rates, FRBNY; Bond yields, Bloomberg Information Services.

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
MARCH 22, 1994
JOAN E. LOVETT

Desk operations were aimed at maintaining

the slight firming

in reserve pressures adopted at your last meeting, associated with
federal funds trading around 3-1/4 percent.
was raised by $25

million to $75

The borrowing allowance

million in conjunction with the

altered policy stance, and it was held at that level throughout the
interval.

Actual borrowing averaged $62 million for the full period.

Seasonal borrowing has been steady and quite low.

Meanwhile, the

funds rate remained near the new intended

area for the most

the effective rate averaging 3.24 percent

for the full period.

At the start of the interval,

a small estimated reserve need

in the period just underway was expected to
dimensions as
factors,

part, with

grow to moderate

a result of movements in currency and other operating

and in required reserves.

Net revisions to factors have

tended to enlarge reserve shortages in the past few periods.
We made frequent use of temporary operations to help meet
reserve needs.

A token round of customer RPs was arranged on February

4th when funds were tending to probe somewhat above the new level in
order to clarify the intended degree of firming adopted that day.
Since then, a total of 12 multiday System operations and 8 overnight
RPs have been arranged.
We also began to acquire securities

on a permanent basis,

buying $3.3 billion of coupon issues in the market
about

$1.6 billion of bill

accounts.

on March 15th, and

issues intermittently from foreign

These actions have narrowed by a considerable margin the

reserve need in the maintenance period currently underway.

Reserve shortages are expected to expand markedly further in
upcoming weeks as required reserves and currency grow seasonally, and
more outright purchases are contemplated.

Some very deep deficiencies

could eventually emerge if the Treasury balance bulges following the
April tax date, as it frequently does.

Given all the modifications to

the tax code over the past year and the apparent underlying strength
in the economy, this April-May tax season is shaping up to be a very
uncertain one.
Pricing of daylight overdrafts is scheduled to commence April
14th, adding another dimension of uncertainty.

We have been giving

careful consideration to how possible changes in market behavior
designed to limit these overdrafts could affect our flexibility in
arranging RPs.
inconclusive:

A recent test-period from daylight overdrafts was
collateral available to us was always sufficient for

the volume of RPs we planned.

But participants may have been too

focused on the turmoil in financial markets at the time to pay close
attention to daylight overdraft positions.

Of course, we will be

monitoring this impending development very closely.

Before leaving

the subject of reserve management, let me note that the reserve
estimates suggest that the normal intermeeting leeway may be
constraining ahead.

Against that background, Mr. Chairman, I would

like to request Committee approval of a temporary increase in the
leeway of $3 billion, bringing it to $11

billion, for insurance

purposes.
In the securities markets, interest rates have moved sharply
higher across the yield curve since early February.

Short-term rates

were already beginning to back up just ahead of and during your last
meeting when the slight firming in reserve pressures was announced.
Since that time, yields on two- to ten-year Treasury coupon securities

have increased a net 80 to 90 basis points, with rates on long-term
issues rising about 65 basis points.

Treasury bill rates have risen

some 45 to 75 basis points.
The intensity of the updraft in intermediate-and long-term
yields have surprised most market observers.

A variety of factors has

been cited, but disagreement about the relative.importance of each
contributes uncertainty to the interest rate outlook.

Thus, the

building in of a larger risk premium was certainly a factor.

A re-

assessment of the strength of the expansion has also played an
important role in this jump.

After abstracting from the effects of

harsh winter weather conditions, most analysts now believe that
economic activity has retained more momentum from late last year than
anticipated earlier.

This gave rise to apprehension that price

pressures could be intensifying as continued growth eats into the
remaining slack in the economy.

And the market is especially

sensitive to any hint of incipient inflationary pressures, scouring
the behavior of all available indices for use as leading indicators of
inflation.
Against this background, the outlook for monetary policy has
also undergone a re-evaluation, as the market asked how far and how
fast the Fed would have to move.

Last month's action was seen as the

first installment in a series of gradual policy adjustments away from
accommodation.

Longer-term yields have moved up as they began to

incorporate a higher expected trajectory for shorter-term rates.

In

explaining some of the market's response to this action, some analysts
have even suggested that the firming move itself may have contributed
to disquiet on the inflation front by suggesting the Fed knew
something the market didn't; and by taking only a limited step, the

Fed may have "fallen behind the curve" in forestalling price
pressures.
Several other developments also helped to unsettle markets at
various times.

Feedback effects from the upswing in interest rates

abroad over the past two months were an influence as was the
escalating war of words in U.S.-Japanese trade negotiations.

Many

investment funds hedged their foreign exposures by selling in the more
liquid U.S. securities markets.

The downward pressure on prices made

additional sales necessary amid rumored heavy losses for some large
accounts.

The backup in rates peaked in mid-March when Whitewater

rumors raised new concerns or provided yet another reason for market
caution.

The long-bond yield rose just shy of 7 percent at that time.
Amid all the volatility in rates, traders lacked confidence

about the market's ability to consolidate at any given level.

Having

been caught off guard by the Fed's move, many participants were also
caught with average maturities that were too long on February 4th.
They worked aggressively to shorten duration, while the decline in
mortgage refinancing exerted the opposite pull.

The extensive

adjustments to portfolios during the past two months sometimes lifted
trading volume to record levels, although involvement by retail
accounts was generally limited.

Last week's favorable set of PPI and

CPI reports provided some support to the market and helped yields pull
back a little from their highest levels.

Our recent coupon purchase

also may have been of minor technical benefit to the market.

But the

underlying tone in the market remains very nervous indeed.
At this point, most participants see further policy adjustments as a near-certainty, with the next move seen likely to come as
soon as today.

There is, however, some diversity of opinions about

the appropriate pace of further policy actions.

Another modest

firming at this time would probably be greeted with greater equanimity
than the initial move and, in fact, another 25 basis points is already
priced into the existing rate structure.

Some participants say the

Fed will take a measured approach to its firming in light of the
market's adjustment to date and because only modest steps are
warranted by the economy in any case.

Some feel the Fed should move

50 basis points in case it has fallen behind and to get ahead of the
"other shoe" syndrome with the market's jitters; judging its reaction
to such a move is difficult, and those suggesting the move are unable
to say whether this would stabilize the market or create additional
volatility.

E.M.Truman

March 22, 1994
FOMC Presentation -- January Data on Trade in Goods and Services
We had planned that I would say a few words about the
January data on U.S. trade in goods and services that were
released this morning as an hors d'oeuvre before Mike provides
the main meal.

As it happens, I can be very brief because the

data are very close to what we projected for the Greenbook, and
the revisions to the data for December are also minor.
January was the first month for which the Commerce
Department released data on a new comprehensive basis covering
estimates of trade on both goods and services and on a balance of
payments basis.

The nominal goods and services deficit was $6.3

billion for the month slightly smaller1 than the average monthly
deficit in the fourth quarter, but about $2 billion larger than
the deficit in December.

The merchandise trade deficit was $11

billion on the balance of payments basis (about $9.8 billion on
the more familiar Census basis).

Again, this figure was slightly

larger than the average for the fourth quarter but substantially
larger than the deficit in December.
Compared with December, both imports and exports in
January were lower, but the reduction in exports was larger.
Most of the decline in imports was in oil, due to lower
quantities and lower prices, but automotive imports also
declined.

Imports of capital goods increased.

The decline in

1. In the original oral presentation, the January deficit was
reported to be slightly larger; this was corrected later in the
meeting.

- 2 -2-

exports was more broadly based, including gold, agricultural
goods, and aircraft.
On balance, based on our quick look at the data, the
January data are remarkably close to what we had been
anticipating, implying at this stage no need to adjust our
outlook that net exports of goods and services resumed their
trend deterioration this quarter.
I turn now to Mike for the main event.

Michael J. Prell
March 22, 1994

FOMC Briefing

Examining the Greenbook economic forecast, one is reminded of
the warning that, if something looks too good to be true,
is.

it probably

Basically, we are projecting that, with an increase in the federal

funds rate of roughly a percentage point over the next year or so--a
rather mild rise by past cyclical standards, and perhaps less than the
markets are currently discounting--you can look forward to achieving
something akin to the mythic soft landing.

Real GDP growth, which was

almost 4 percent in 1992 and 3-1/4 percent in 1993,
percent this year and to 2-1/3 percent in 1995.

would slow to 2-2/3

Unemployment would

level out just above 6-1/2 percent, close to what we think constitutes
the "natural rate" in today's economy.
smidge below 3 percent.

And core inflation would be a

What, you might ask, is wrong with this

picture?
Clearly, if one's objective is solely the achievement of
further disinflation over the next couple of years, this scenario leaves
something to be desired.

But. within the logic of our projection.

there's an obvious solution to that problem:

Apply greater monetary

restraint than assumed in the baseline path we've presented.

From this

perspective, the bigger issues regarding the forecast may be said to
relate to the positive aspects of our analysis rather than the
normative.

That is, do we have the relationships right?

Would you get

the combination of growth, resource utilization, and inflation that
we've projected if, in fact, you followed the funds rate path we've
assumed?

-

Michael J. Prell

2

-

March 22,

1994

So, let me address those features of our forecast in sequence.
First, we think that real GDP this quarter probably will post another
substantial gain, our point estimate being 3-1/4 percent, at an annual
rate.

The confidence interval around this estimate is wider than it

might normally be at this stage, because the signals from the January
and February labor market surveys were distorted by storms and
methodological changes.

Still, a variety of indicators suggest that

employment has been growing and that industrial production has increased
appreciably--with a substantial boost from motor vehicle assemblies.
On the expenditure side of the ledger, the step-up in vehicle
production should show through partly in greater inventory accumulation.
Meanwhile, final sales appear likely to register only a moderate
increase--around 2-1/2 percent.

Consumer spending seems to be growing

at about that pace, judging from recent retail sales data and the
evident heavy outlays for heating and brokerage services.

In other

sectors, the early indications for business fixed investment and
residential construction are that gains in expenditure will be sizable
this quarter, but far less so than in the latter half of 1993.

And, as

Ted noted, this morning's trade data point in the direction of some
softening of net exports.

All this said, though, I would reiterate my

earlier comment that we're still on very shaky ground in estimating even
where we've been in the current quarter.
Which brings me to the uncertain prospects for the future.

As

you know, we are projecting a further deceleration in output during the
second quarter, to about 2-1/2 percent for GDP.

One might argue that

the second quarter should be boosted by earthquake recovery and a catchup in some types of activity for the weather-related losses in the
winter.

Indeed, we have factored such effects into our forecast.

they are more than offset by the scheduled drop-off in seasonally

But

Michael J.

- 3

Prell

-

March 22.

1994

adjusted motor vehicle production this spring--which will be deducting
about 1-1/2 percentage points, at an annual rate, from GDP.
a similar amount in the current quarter.

after adding

In addition, we think that

forces tending to moderate the underlying trends in demand growth will
be increasingly felt in coming months.
In the consumer sector,

spending will no longer be receiving

the boost it has been from extra cash flow freed up by new
refinancings;

mortgage

recent securities market developments have curbed the

growth of household net worth

and alerted naive investors to the risk

that today's asset values may not be sustained tomorrow; consumer credit
undoubtedly will become more expensive as increases in market rates feed
through to loan rates;

tax payments are rising:

and purchases of

consumer durables already have reached rates sufficient to accommodate
the gradual replacement of old vehicles and household furnishings as
well as some expansion of stocks.

In the residential construction

sector, while we still think affordability is favorable enough to
warrant a projection of starts well above what might be dictated by
longer-range demographic trends, the backup in mortgage rates will take
some toll on demand.

We've trimmed our projection of starts

significantly, and see them dropping off somewhat after a spring
resurgence.

And, in the business sector, with accelerator effects

waning, internal funds growing less rapidly, and external financing
costs higher, capital spending is likely to be less robust

than it has

been in recent quarters.
Obviously, this analysis involves a lot of difficult judgments.
one of them relating to the interpretation of the recent rise in
interest rates and. thus, where rates can be expected tc go from here.
It is our view that the run-up in bond yields likely has been
exaggerated by transitory trading dynamics, as well as by some excessive

Michael J. Prell

-

4--

March 22,

1994

fears of inflation stirred up by the year-end surge in activity and
rising materials prices.

Therefore, we are expecting bond yields to

come back down somewhat, that retracing being limited, though, by the
assumed increase in the funds rate.

When things settle out, we expect

that nominal long rates will run about a half percentage point above the
path in our last forecast, the increment being mainly attributable to
higher real rates that will tend to damp aggregate demand.
I must say that I'd feel more comfortable about our rate
projection if there had been at least some hint of a rally in the past
week.

It certainly would be folly at this point to rule out the

possibility that bond yields will reach even higher levels if and as the
funds rate rises further.

But, given the steepness of the yield curve

and our assessment of the other forces shaping demands in the economy
and financial markets, I still wouldn't want to rule out, either, a
bigger drop in bond rates than we've projected.

The uncertainties with

which one must contend here involve not simply the anticipations and
risk tolerance of securities market investors but also the difficult
assessment of what level of real rates is sustainable in light of
expected returns on physical capital here and, to at least an extent,
abroad.
On that confident note, let me turn to the other two issues I
noted earlier--the current and prospective degree of slack in the
economy and the outlook for inflation.

For a variety of technical

reasons, we believe that the published statistics have overstated the
decline in the unemployment rate in the past couple of months.

But the

higher level of output growth now indicated for late 1993 helps explain
the decline in joblessness registered through December, and some further
decline seems likely to have occurred this quarter.

We would think of

unemployment as having been around 6-3/4 percent in February--perhaps a

- 5 -

Michael J. Prell

quarter point below the fourth-quarter average.

March 22,

1994

Meanwhile, industrial

capacity utilization has risen a percentage point further.
The question is how much farther this can go without pressures
on resources becoming so great that wages and prices accelerate.
might argue that some warning signs have already emerged:

One

many

materials prices have risen, and--putting together the indications from
the Employment Cost Indexes and the monthly average hourly earnings--the
pace of increase in wages seems at least to have flattened out in the
past year.

We don't think that these are compelling signals of an

imminent pickup in the prices of finished goods and services, but we do
think that the economy may not have much room to run at this point
before pressing hard against its potential.
A range of representative econometric point estimates of the
NAIRU probably would extend from about 6 percent to 6-3/4 percent,
making a half-point adjustment to the old numbers for the change to new
household survey.

Our point estimate is 6-1/2 percent or a shade less.

If one allows for a reasonable confidence interval around these
estimates, it is clear that we may already be at the NAIRU or at least
close to it.

Even if one adopts a more optimistic view (say, the 6

percent NAIRU),

continuation of GDP growth at the pace of the past

couple of years probably would mean that we would run out of slack in
1995--a time span that is relevant, given normal lags, to monetary
policy decisions today.
One might well wish to take a broader approach to assessing the
prospects for inflation.

We can summon up without difficulty reasonable

stories supporting slower or faster growth of aggregate demand.
Favorable supply shocks are certainly possible--for example,
productivity improvements could prove stronger--but then, too, the
sideways trend of recent years in the labor force participation rate

Michael J. Prell

- 6

-March 22, 1994

might persist and speed the decline in unemployment.

Inflation

expectations could drop more into line with recent experience, but, if
anything, recent developments might be viewed as highlighting the
possible upside risks in this regard.

In the end, we think our

characterization of the inflation outlook reasonably balances the
forecast risks in a probabilistic sense.

We respectfully leave to you,

of course, the task of applying policy weights to those and other risks
in the economy.

March 22,

1994

FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

The question that would seem to be facing the Committee at
this meeting is should reserve conditions be tightened further at this
time, and if so by how much.

Recent developments in financial markets

undoubtedly complicate judgment on this issue.

Interest rates are

substantially higher and money growth weaker than anticipated at the
last meeting of the Committee, even after allowing for the firming of
reserve conditions on February 4.

Moreover, markets are quite skit-

tish, reacting strongly and somewhat unpredictably to new information.
The implications of these developments, along with an assessment of
the response of markets to further Federal Reserve action or inaction,
may have a bearing on your evaluation of the economic outlook going
forward and policy options.
The reasons for the extent of the rise in rates are not entirely clear, especially in the bond market.
action of February 4 played a major role.

Obviously, the FOMC's

It came sooner than many

had expected, and markets now see the Federal Reserve as tightening
much more rapidly than they had previously built into the yield curve.
This revision of expectations has had its largest effects on shortand intermediate-term rates, but the arithmetic of the yield curve
indicates that some has fed through to the long end as well.

An eval-

uation that the Fed was more willing to raise rates would increase
real rates, if anything damping inflation expectations.

The resulting

rise in rates would restrain aggregate demand relative to previous
forecasts--presumably the reason for undertaking the action.
However, expectations of faster tightening seemed to reflect
reassessment not only of the Fed's willingness to act but also of the

need for action.

In part, markets are said to have taken their cue

from the Fed--if we're worried they should be too.

More fundamen-

tally, incoming data on the economy indicated greater strength in
aggregate demand and lower unemployment than many had anticipated.
With less slack and greater demands, higher real rates would be needed
to keep the economy from overshooting.

In retrospect, interest rates

may have been below sustainable levels last fall, especially in light
of the increasingly accommodative lending posture of banks and other
intermediaries.

It would not be surprising if unanticipated strength

in aggregate demand led also to some upward adjustment in inflation
expectations as the economy was seen to approach potential output
sooner.

Higher inflation expectations may be evident in the continued

rise in commodity prices and the relatively small size of the stock
market decline; both suggest that real rates probably did not rise by
the full extent of the increase in nominal rates.
Finally, increased uncertainty--about Federal Reserve intentions and about a wide range of developments in foreign economies and
our relations with them--may have contributed to the upward movement
in rates.

And some may have resulted from attempts by major players

to head for the door simultaneously, with selling motivated less by a
sense of changing fundamentals than a need or strong desire to trim
long bond positions at whatever price.

Included in this last category

might be those new mutual fund owners awakening to the risk of their
investment.

These types of factors would increase liquidity premiums,

raising longer-term real rates.
Some of these influences may moderate over coming weeks, as
portfolios are better adjusted, as the Committee's intentions become
clearer, and as information on the economy confirms a moderate growth
path and continuing low inflation.

As a consequence, in the staff

forecast a portion of the recent runup in long rates is reversed, even
with rising short-term rates.

But not all of it.

Higher long-term

rates than in the last Greenbook are associated with about the same
outlook for inflation and the GDP gap.

In effect, information on the

performance of the economy has led the staff to see a slightly higher
natural long-run interest rate, at least for a time.

Short-term rates

need to rise further, validating to some extent expectations embedded
in the yield curve, to keep long-term rates from slipping significantly below the natural rate again, which, given the small amount of
slack, would allow inflation pressures to strengthen.
With regard to how fast short-term rates should rise, the
recent behavior of money and credit provides limited information.

The

growth of credit to nonfederal sectors did pick up over the second
half of last year and appears to be growing at its more advanced pace
in the first quarter.

At 5 percent or so, expansion of private credit

remains in a moderate range, but its acceleration seems indicative of
lessened restraints on the supply of credit and greater demand to use
it.

The more aggressive attitude of intermediaries is underlined by

our latest survey of interest rates charged by banks on business
loans, which was taken after the February tightening.

Not only, as we

know, was the prime unchanged, but the survey suggested that little of
the increase in rates was passed through to business borrowers whose
loans were not tied to prime.

In capital markets, quality spreads

remain low, P/Es high, and credit readily available.

As a conse-

quence, as federal borrowing has slowed, private borrowing has filled
the gap, keeping total debt growth mostly in the 5 to 6 percent area.
We see the rise in rates as having very modest effects on credit
demands, damping growth in private and total debt slowly over the
year.

All of the monetary aggregates--narrow and broad--were weaker
than expected in February, with M2 and M3 actually declining.

Our

assessment, however, is that this behavior arose primarily from particular short-run influences, rather than from an underlying constriction of financial flows or as a precursor of lagging income growth.
Some of the shortfall in money may have reflected an outsized reaction
to higher short-term interest rates--especially in the behavior of the
institution-only money funds in M3.

And a portion owes to large, but

temporary, effects of the back-up in long-term rates in depressing
mortgage prepayments and associated demand deposits.

M2 and, to a

lesser extent, M3 seem to be rebounding in March, partly as savers
reassess the risks of owning bond and stock mutual funds, and we are
projecting modest growth on the order of 2 percent plus for M2 and 1
percent plus for M3 through June.
cate

Data available this morning indi-

an even stronger rebound in March than in the bluebook.

Mea-

sures of money that include mutual funds have slowed substantially,
partly reflecting the effects of capital losses.
If weak money, or the mixed economic data in recent weeks,
were seen by the Committee as suggesting the possibility of a significant slackening in the trend of aggregate demand growth, there
would be a case for waiting to take any further action, as in alternative B.

If the economy were already slowing substantially, the recent

rise in long-term rates, which would damp aggregate demand further
over coming quarters, would only bolster that case.

Choice of this

alternative might embody a judgement that much of the rise in rates
was in liquidity premiums or resulted from perceptions of a more
aggressive Fed rather than a persisting shift in aggregate demand.
addition, the continued downtrend in consumer prices and in labor
costs may suggest the possibility of greater slack than in the staff

In

-5-

forecast and little risk in delaying action.

In effect, as has

happened repeatedly in recent years, markets may have built in a
steeper trajectory for policy action than is actually needed to foster
the Committee's objectives.

Holding federal funds at 3-1/4 percent

for a time would send a signal that the Committee was on a more
measured firming path than the market had assumed and real interest
rates should decrease.

While questions might be raised about the

intentions of the Committee and its commitment to containing inflation, if the economy were in fact on the more moderate path thought
consistent with the choice of alternative B, data emerging over time
would quiet inflation expectations and allow nominal as well as real
yields to decline.
If, on the other hand, the Committee saw the risks as skewed
toward greater inflation, additional tightening would be called for.
Judgment that the remaining slack was

quite limited, as in the staff

forecast, might suggest that the costs, in terms of building inflation
pressures and inflation expectations, of an unexpected surge in demand
were greater than the penalty for a shortfall.

In the context of

generous credit availability, strong aggregate demand might be a distinct possibility so long as real short-term rates were still quite
low, especially if the failure to raise those rates pulled down real
long-term rates as well.
In this case, the question would remain as to how much to
firm--whether to raise the federal funds rate 25 or 50 basis points.
An immediate 25 basis point increase is about what is built into markets at this time.

Other interest rates probably would not move much,

at least initially, if this more limited action were taken, though
decreases in long-term rates would still be quite likely over time.
The risk of an outsized reaction in markets is small, and, in fact,

behaving in a steady, predictable fashion may erode some of the expectations of a steep trajectory of Federal Reserve firming over coming
months.

This option might be especially favored if there were sig-

nificant uncertainty about the strength of demand going forward, the
level of long-term rates consistent with containing inflation, and
hence about the need for more decisive action in reserve markets.
However, a 25 basis point move would leave in place expectations of
another action in the near term and the uncertainty about its timing.
A full 50 basis point firming, as under alternative C, is a
higher-risk option, with the potential for greater rewards.

If the

Committee were convinced that a 50 basis point increase were needed,
and fairly soon, to contain inflation pressures or to reduce them
further if that were your objective, there might be little advantage
to doing it in two steps.

Because it would surprise markets, their

reaction is difficult to predict.
than down, at least initially.

Bond rates are more likely to go up

However, if it were perceived as the

last move for a while, simply bringing forward in time actions
expected fairly soon in any case, the more decisive action of this
option might have a calming influence, and it should damp any emerging
inflationary expectations.

Accompanying the action with words that

suggested the Federal Reserve had returned to a posture of "watchful
waiting" for a time might help to temper market reaction.

In that

regard, if the Committee favored something like alternative C, consideration might be given as to whether a 50 basis point increase
ought to be accomplished through Board approval of a discount rate
hike.

That would give a natural forum for explaining the Federal

Reserve's intentions and expectations, if the Committee wished to
avoid reinforcing the precedent of explaining changes in policy
brought about through open market operations.

There is some risk of a

further sharp market response to alternative C if unanticipated action
were read as indicating that the Federal Reserve was even more concerned about inflation and prepared to continue tightening faster than
previously expected.
Suggesting that short-term rates might not need to change for
a while after implementing alternative C would be easier if you could

have some confidence that they were then close to their "neutral" or
natural level--consistent with the economy growing at its potential.

Surely they are below that level now, but how close another 25 or 50
basis points would bring them is hard to say.

The neutral level of

short-term rates is very much a moving target, depending on the other
forces acting on the economy, including the level of intermediate- and

long-term rates.

Moreover, absent a good indication of inflation

expectations,it may be difficult to determine the level of real rates.
By almost any measure, inflation and inflation expectations have come

down over the last year, so that even before the February 4 action
real short-term rates probably were rising.

If I use as a first

approximation the lagging 12-month CPI, the real funds rate is around
3/4 percent right now, though under the staff forecast it would fall
as increasing energy prices pushed up overall inflation.

From 1954

(when the fed funds series begins) through 1993, the average was 1-3/4
percent, suggesting a neutral funds rate of 4-1/2 percent plus if
inflation and inflation expectations level out near 3 percent.

An

interesting subperiod is 1954 to 1965, which excludes the inflation of
the 1970s and fiscal expansion of the 1980s.

For this period, the

average real funds rate is a little over 1-1/4 percent.

A 50 basis

point increase in the federal funds rate would bring real short-term
rates close to their 1954 to 1965 average.

Of course, market struc-

tures and relationships have changed considerably since then, and

-8-

inflation expectations are probably in excess of the measured CPI rate
of the last 12 months.

But such measures suggest you may not have

that far to go beyond the next few tightenings, especially if inflation remains subdued.