View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in
the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
in Washington, D. C.,

PRESENT:

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

on Tuesday, March 22, 1966, at 9:30 a.m.
Martin, Chairman,

Bopp
Brimmer
Clay
Daane
Hickman
Irons
Maisel
Mitchell
Robertson
Shepardson
Treiber, Alternate for Mr. Hayes

Messrs. Wayne, Scanlon, Francis, and Swan,
Alternate Members of the Federal Open Market
Committee
Mr. Patterson, President of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Sherman, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Kenyon, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Broida, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Molony, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Brill, Economist
Messrs. Eastburn, Green, Koch, Mann, Partee,
Solomon, Tow, and Young, Associate
Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market
Account
Mr. Coombs, Special Manager, System Open Market
Account
Mr. Williams, Adviser, Division of Research and
Statistics, Board of Governors
Mr. Hersey, Adviser, Division of International
Finance, Board of Governors
Mr. Axilrod, Associate Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Miss Eaton, General Assistant, Office of the
Secretary, Board of Governors

-2

3/22/66

Messrs. Latham and Strothman, First Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of Boston and Minneapolis, respectively
Messrs. Eisenmenger, Link, Ratchford, Taylor,
Jones, and Craven, Vice Presidents of the
Federal Reserve Banks of Boston, New York,
Richmond, Atlanta, St. Louis, and San
Francisco, respectively
Mr. Nelson, Director of Research, Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Mr. Geng, Manager, Securities Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Mr. Stiles, Senior Economist, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago
Chairman Martin noted that a new member was attending his
first meeting of the Open Market Committee today--Andrew F. Brimmer,
a member of the Board of Governors--and that Mr. Brimmer had executed
his oath of office as a member of the Committee prior to today's
meeting.

The Chairman also noted that since the preceding meeting

of the Committee Mr. Robertson had been appointed Vice Chairman of
the Board of Governors.
Upon motion duly made
and by unanimous vote, the
the meeting of the Federal
Committee held on March 1,
approved.

and seconded,
minutes of
Open Market
1966, were

Before this meeting there had been distributed to the members
of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of the System Open
Market Account on foreign exchange market conditions and on Open
Market Account and Treasury operations in foreign currencies for the
period March 1 through March 16, 1966, and a supplemental report for

-3

3/22/66
March 17 through 21, 1966.

Copies of these reports have been

placed in the files of the Committee.
In comments supplementing the written reports, Mr. Coombs
said the Treasury might soon have to transfer a sizable amount,
possibly $75 or $100 million, from the gold stock to the Stabili
zation Fund.

Otherwise, prospective orders between now and the

month end would pretty well clean out the Stabilization Fund.

The

Russians were still out of the market and, while it remained
possible that they might make some massive sales between now and
the month end, the probability decreased with each day that passed.
Meanwhile, however, the continuing prospect of Russian sales sooner
or later this spring was helping to dampen market speculation, while
heavy arrivals of gold from South Africa had also helped to relieve
pressure on the gold pool.

Earlier South Africa had been in the

process of rebuilding its gold stock and had withheld gold from
the market, but that situation now seemed to have turned, at least
temporarily.

So far this month, intervention by the London gold

pool had been minimal.
On the exchange markets, Mr. Coombs continued, sterling had
again been in the limelight, mainly owing to election uncertainties,
sizable swings in monthly trade figures, and widespread rumors of
possible discount rate increases in the U.S., in Britain, or on the
continent.

In trying to adjust to those pressures, the Bank of

-4

3/22/66

England allowed the sterling rate to slip from a level of $2.8032
on February 16 to a low point of $2.7930 on March 9.

That was a

fairly steep decline and created the risk that selling pressures on
sterling might cumulate on the way down.

The Bank of England was

very much aware of that risk and each day had consulted with the
New York Bank on the state of sentiment in the London and New
York markets.

On March 9, the New York Bank staff had advised the

Bank of England that in their view the risk of an adverse shift
in market sentiment had become serious, and with the concurrence of
the British the New York Bank had moved in to bid each bank in the
New York market for sterling.

That was more or less a repetition of

the tactic employed last September 10, except that this time the
rate was not pursued upward; the object was only to establish a
temporary floor.

In any event, the market reacted strongly upward

and sterling had subsequently fluctuated in a quiet market within
the range of $2.7945 to $2.7960.

The Bank of England was well

satisfied with the result of the operation, which provided another
illustration of how effective such a tactic could be in stabilizing
expectations.

Indeed, it was so powerful that it was important it

not be overused.

The recent operation was only the second of its

type, and he hoped that similar operations would not be required
too often in the future.

-5

3/22/66

Mr. Coombs said he understood that, in addition to dollars
expended for market intervention and settlement of forward contracts
during March, the Bank of England had reversed a $50 million swap
drawing with the Bank of Italy and had also paid off another $50
million of short-term debt to the Bank for International Settlements.
The British might again want to avoid showing a reserve decline at
the month end, and so might approach the Federal Reserve for some
type of credit facility.

He thought that it would be appropriate

to finance part of the reserve short-fall by a drawing on the swap
line, but he hoped that the British would obtain the bulk of the
funds they needed by drawing upon the $200 million of Treasury
funds made available in the September package.

He had already raised

that question with the Treasury and was hopeful that they would
agree.
At the last Basle meeting, Mr. Coombs continued, the Bank
of England reported that they had obtained a sympathetic response
from the International Monetary Fund to their request for a $500
million standby facility to provide a partial backstop for the
$1 billion central bank credit package now under negotiation.

The

BIS might also be prepared to take $250 million of medium-term
British bonds, equivalent to the U.S. "Roosa bonds," which would
enlarge the backstop facility to a total of $750 million.
his view that probably would be adequate.

In

If the Bank of England

3/22/66

-6

were to use the whole $1 billion credit package provided by the
central banks and then found that the market situation did not
reverse itself within a year's time, the Bank could legitimately
be expected to supplement the $750 million backstop now in sight
by drafts upon its own reserves in the amount of $250 million,
thus permitting full liquidation of the central bank credits.
That, in effect was what they had done to repay drawings on the
swap line with the System.

There were other ways also in which

the matter could be taken care of, and it would be a pity if the
whole package were to be unduly delayed by debates over the absence
of a backstop for the remaining $250 million of central bank credits.
Mr. Coombs concluded by noting that he had no recommendations
to set before the Committee today.
Mr. Mitchell commented that in his judgment the "rescue"
operations for sterling that Mr. Coombs had described were graphic
cases of massive intervention in foreign exchange markets that did
not reflect well on the System.

He was sure that Mr. Coombs meant

what he said about not using such tactics too often.

But the

Committee should be wary of yielding to the temptation to protect
the market in a way that perhaps was hostile to the nation's long
run interests.
Secondly, Mr. Mitchell continued, he was concerned about
the British use of its swap line with the System for window-dressing

3/22/66

purposes.

-7

That matter had been discussed by the Committee on

earlier occasions, and it had been agreed that the System's own
true position should be made known at all times.

If the System

had not met that goal perfectly, it had come close.

He questioned,

however, whether there was any substantial difference in principle
between window dressing by the System and the Committee's per
mitting other countries to use its facilities for that purpose.
Perhaps the latter could be justified at times, but not as a
continuing policy.
Mr. Coombs said he would comment separately on each of
Mr. Mitchell's two points.

On the first, he perhaps had not expressed

himself clearly in his earlier remarks.

The New York Bank had

intervened across the board in the sterling market on two occasionssuccessfully both times.

The operation last September 10 probably

was the one factor that had averted a possible serious breakdown of
the whole international payments system.

He hesitated to think of

what the consequences might have been if it had not been successful.
The operation had been used again on March 9, when the market was
unsettled by the British elections, and it had given the market a
lengthy breathing space.

His conclusion was that the tactic was so

powerful that the Committee would not want to dull its effectiveness
by using it too often.

But the Committee did have responsibility

for defending the dollar, directly and indirectly.

Given the

power to change market sentiment when that sentiment was based on

3/22/66

-8

exaggerated expectations and not on underlying realities, he thought
the System would be derelict if it did not use it.
As to Mr. Mitchell's remarks on window dressing, Mr. Coombs
said, he supposed it could be argued that to some extent the System
was disguising the true position of the U.S. every time it drew on
its swap lines and used the proceeds to buy dollars from foreign
central banks, thereby avoiding gold losses.

The System's swap

operations were reported fully every six months, and he thought it
was a reasonable procedure to make such reports after the market
had had a chance to readjust.

British drawings on the swap lines

came to more or less the same thing; they strengthened the U.K.
reserve position and forestalled reserve losses.

The Bank of England

reported any use of its swap lines each month, although they did with
hold information on the amount of the drawings for several months.
In one respect the British might be said to provide a fuller
accounting than the U.S. did, since they reported drawings within
a month whereas the System did so only at six-month intervals.
Mr. Mitchell expressed the view that the Committee should
give a clear and accurate accounting of its operations.

As to the

British, in his judgment their failure to disclose the amount of
their swap drawings was tantamount to no accounting at all.

He

then asked whether the System's swap drawings were reflected in its
weekly statement.

3/22/66
Mr. Coombs replied in the negative.

He remarked that such

a suggestion would raise a major policy issue, and Mr. Mitchell
agreed.
Mr. Daane commented that immediate disclosure of operations
of the type being discussed clearly would have a market impact and
in his opinion would be undesirable.

The System did disclose such

operations after an appropriate interval, and thus reduced the
possibility of adverse effects.
Mr. Mitchell expressed concern that the Committee might be
drifting into the position of saying that the market was not entitled
to know the true situation.

He thought that would be a dangerous

position, and one that risked reactions that could lead to a
worsening of the underlying situation.
Chairman Martin thought it was important that the Committee
bear in mind the points Mr. Mitchell had made.

At the same time, he

did not think the Committee would want to go to the extreme of
reporting all of its foreign exchange operations immediately, just
as it would not want to announce its domestic policy decision
following each meeting.
Mr. Mitchell agreed that the latter procedure would be
undesirable.

He added, however, that the information in the System's

published statements gave knowledgeable people some idea of the
nature of the Committee's decisions on domestic policy.

3/22/66

-10
Chairman Martin commented that the situation with respect

to the System's foreign exchange operations was affected by the
fact that they were experimental and that the System had not yet
accumulated a great deal of experience with them.

It also was

important to note that the existing foreign exchange markets had
developed relatively recently; there were only fragmentary markets
after World War II, until the major currencies became convertible
in 1958.

He shared Mr. Coombs' view that the two recent operations

in sterling had been quite successful but if repeated too often
such operations would lose their effectiveness.

And he agreed with

Mr. Mitchell that the Committee certainly did not want to engage in
window dressing or to obscure the realities of the situation in
other ways.
A discussion then ensued of the technical differences between
the "across the board" operations in sterling of September and March
and the more common transactions the New York Bank undertook for its
own account or that of others.
Thereupon, upon motion duly made
and seconded, and by unanimous vote, the
System open market transactions in
foreign currencies during the period
March 1 through March 21, 1966, were
approved, ratified, and confirmed.
Chairman Martin then invited Mr. Daane to comment on the
meetings he had recently attended in Paris and Basle.

-11

3/22/66

Mr. Daane noted that Mr. Coombs had referred briefly to the
part of the meeting in Basle that was concerned with the British
credit package.

There also had been an extended discussion in

Basle following the report by the Chairman of the Group of Ten on
developments at the meeting of the Deputies in Paris during the
previous week.
The Deputies met on March 7, 8, and 9, Mr. Daane said.

The

meeting took place against the background of reports in the French
press during the preceding weekend that General de Gaulle had
instructed the French delegation to take the position that there was
no need for any new plan for reserve creation, even on the basis of
contingency planning.

The French made an extended statement of

their position early in the proceedings at Paris and again at Basle.
From both statements it appeared that the French position was about
as follows:

First, they did not believe there now was a need for

any new reserve plan or for additions to liquidity.

They stressed

that their own suggestion for monetary reform, advanced in September
1963, had been based on the assumption that the U.S. and the U.K.
would have restored equilibrium in their respective balances of
payments, but that both countries still suffered from "massive
disequilibrium."
Secondly, Mr, Daane continued, the French pointed out that
in their earlier proposal for monetary reform they had suggested a

3/22/66

-12

new asset closely linked to gold and created for a limited group
of countries.

They now found that in their discussions the

Deputies had moved a long way from this French concept, and were
considering a reserve asset not linked to gold.

They also thought

that by considering proposals to include countries outside a limited
group in reserve creation, the Deputies were confusing the subject
of aid to underdeveloped countries with that of liquidity creation.
For those reasons the French felt that it was necessary for them to
take the position that now was not the time either to consider
actively or to put into effect a new reserve creation scheme.

In

their view the Deputies should confine themselves simply to "study
and reflection" on the subject.

They did say that the press stories

had overdramatized the French position by implying that France would
withdraw from the discussions.

They had no such intention; they

expected to participate in any discussions of reasonable proposals,
but on a "study and reflection" basis rather than looking toward
setting up a scheme for actual use in the foreseeable future.
The reaction of the representatives of the other nine
countries, Mr. Daane said, was that they should attempt to move ahead
with contingency planning.

They did not agree that the Deputies

should confine themselves to study and reflection, for several
reasons.

First, the mandate they had been given called for searching

out areas of agreement, and not simply for coming back with suggestions

-13

3/22/66
for further study.

Secondly, there was of necessity a long time

lag involved between the conception of a reserve asset scheme and
its activation.

That fact was emphasized by Mr. Deming of the U.S.

delegation, who pointed out that even if the Group agreed in
principle on some scheme, no new asset could come into being until
1968 or 1969 at the earliest.
Another point, stressed by Chairman Emminger and endorsed
by a number of the delegations, was that a call for further study by
the Group of Ten at this juncture would be extremely unsettling to
foreign exchange markets and might provoke speculation in gold, since
it would amount to saying to the world at large that the Ten were
unable to devise a method for making the future international payments
system viable.

Finally, the Deputies had been instructed to include

in their report suggestions for proceeding with the second phase of
the exercise, and if they were to move into that second phase with
widely divergent positions they would be exposed to consequences that
no one really wanted.

Thus, it seemed fair to say that the Deputies

reacted negatively to the French position.
The Deputies group then turned to a lengthy discussion of
the first of two papers put forth by the Belgian delegation, Mr. Daane
said.

That paper explained certain well-known Belgian proposals for

modifying and strengthening the facilities of the IMF--for example,
by making the gold tranche more automatic and changing its legal

3/22/66

-14

status so that it could qualify as a reserve asset of member
countries.

There also was a fairly full discussion of a paper the

Italians had submitted earlier, calling for the harmonization of
gold reserve ratios.

While that proposal seemed to elicit little

enthusiasm, there was fairly general recognition that the problem
had to be kept in mind in considering any reserve scheme.

In

effect, the Italian proposal was viewed simply as an element of any
over-all reserve asset plan.
Also, Mr. Daane continued, there was a discussion of a long
IMF document entitled "Need for Reserves," which took the position
that reserves should grow at a rate of 3 to 4 per cent, or $2 to $3
billion, a year.

The consensus at the meeting was that there was no

really good way of quantifying needed reserve growth.

That point

was emphasized by Chairman Emminger with the support of the Dutch
delegation, and also by Mr. Deming.

It was noted that the figures

used by the U.S. delegation at the previous meeting, and also those
in the Emminger proposals, had been purely illustrative.

At the

same time, it was recognized that the question of needed reserve
growth was not one for decision on an ad hoc basis each year.

No

delegation had specific suggestions on the subject, but there seemed
to be agreement that reserve needs should be calculated on a global
basis and in terms of longer-run trends.

3/22/66

-15
The Deputies then turned to a question-and-answer discussion,

along the lines of that held at the previous meeting, of another
Belgian paper that put forth a new proposal entirely centered in the
IMF and quite similar in some respects to one prong of the U.S.
proposal.

There was a proviso, however, that any country using the

new automatic drawing rights would have to put up an equal amount of
gold or make equal use of another ordinary IMF drawing right.

There

was little support for that aspect of the Belgian proposal.
Mr. Daane went on to say that Mr. Polak discussed a two-part
proposal put forward by the Managing Director of the IMF for the
creation of reserves through the IMF, so that the Fund now had a
proposal of its own on the table.

The first part involved quasi

automatic drawing rights similar to the special drawing rights of
the U.S. proposal, which could be implemented without amending the
Articles.

Both the credit lines and the Fund's regular assets would

stand behind the new drawing rights.

The second part involved a

reserve unit for all members of the Fund, to be created by an
affiliate of the Fund.

The reserve unit would be established by an

exchange of claims between all members and the Fund affiliate.
Allocation of units would not be made available to members with
outstanding credit tranche drawings until they had been repaid in
an amount equal to the allocation.

One important aspect of the Fund's

proposal was the sequence suggested; namely, to go forward initially

3/22/66

-16

with the first part, with the expectation that it would be gradually
superseded by the second part.

The latter was envisaged as likely

to prove the more flexible of the two.
With respect to the Deputies' future schedule, Mr. Daane
said, a four-day meeting would be held in Washington on April 19-22,
which hopefully would be the first report-drafting session.

Another

meeting would be held in Rome in mid-May to bring the report close
to completion, with the aim of putting it in final form by late
June or early July.

The Canadian delegation had been asked to

prepare a draft of the report's introduction before the April meeting,
and three delegations, including the U.S., were to prepare suggested
outlines.

The outlines would be considered by a working party on

the Monday preceding the Washington meeting, and then probably
would be discussed by the Deputies.

The objectives of the group

seemed to be to continue to move forward and complete the report
within the time schedule set; and to give it as positive a cast as
possible, by stressing the areas of agreement--while, of course,
noting the areas of disagreement.
At the subsequent Basle meeting, Mr. Daane remarked, Chairman
Emminger reviewed the proceedings at the Deputies' meeting, and
emphasized the need for a positive approach.

Much of the discussion

at Basle was a replay of that at Paris, but in some respects the
thinking was at variance with that in Paris.

There was a general

3/22/66

-17

feeling at Basle that there was no need for additional liquidity
now or in the foreseeable future, and there was little enthusiasm
for the U.S. proposal or for any of the other proposals.

The main

emphasis was on the need for the U.S. to bring its balance of
payments into equilibrium.

However, there also was recognition of

the problem noted in Paris--that it would be disadvantageous for
the System as a whole if the Group of Ten report simply called for
further study.
In concluding, Mr. Daane noted that Mr. Robert Solomon of
the Board's staff was a member of the U.S. delegation at the Paris
meeting and that Mr. Coombs had attended the Basle meeting.

He

thought they might have additional comments on the proceedings.
Mr. Coombs said he would note that the reaction he received
in private conversations at Basle was one of serious pessimism as
to the possible areas of agreement in the present negotiations.
that pessimism was justified it could have serious implications
for the gold and foreign exchange markets.
Chairman Martin commented that he had discussed the IMF
proposal, to which Mr. Daane had referred, at some length with
Managing Director Schweitzer of the Fund.

The proposal was an

important one, and he thought it would be desirable, if possible,
for copies of the full text to be made available to members of
the Committee.

If

3/22/66

-18Mr. Daane remarked that copies of the proposal did exist.

He noted, however, that the representative of the Fund at the
Group of Ten meeting had made some rather sharp comments regarding
leaks to the press of matters coming before the Deputies,
particularly in connection with the French position and with the
details of the Fund proposal.

He was not sure how the Fund would

react to a request for copies for use of the Committee.
Chairman Martin commented that he thought there was no
danger of press leaks through the Committee.

He asked whether

Messrs. Holland and Sherman would explore the possibility of
obtaining copies for the Committee, on the understanding that they
would be treated as extremely confidential.
In response to a question by Mr. Hickman, Mr. Daane said
that there seemed to be relatively greater support among the Deputies
for some type of reserve unit creation than for additional
drawing rights in the Fund.

The U.S. proposal had included provision

for drawing rights, and the Belgian proposal had involved only
such rights.

The British also supported such an approach, but with

the possible exception of the Italians it appeared that no other
delegation did.
Chairman Martin then invited Mr. Brill to comment on a
meeting that he had attended in Paris last week, of the Economic
Policy Committee of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development.

3/22/66

-19
Mr. Brill said that the meeting focused on the domestic

economic prospects and balance of payments outlook for a few key
countries and on the issue of the effect of capital controls in the
United States on European capital markets.
In commenting on U.S. economic prospects, Gardner Ackley,
head of the U.S. delegation to the meeting, reported on some recent
trends in sales and prices and indicated that, while the need for

further restraint was not clear at the moment, the Government was
prepared to adopt whatever measures should prove to be needed.
Mr. Trued, the Treasury member of the delegation, challenged the
pessimistic forecast that had been circulated in a Secretariat's
preparatory documentation, and indicated a number of areas in which
some improvement in the U.S. international position was possible.
He (Mr. Brill) reported to the meeting on recent developments in
U.S. money and credit markets.
There was considerable discussion, Mr. Brill continued,
of the impact of U.S. monetary restraints and the U.S. voluntary
foreign credit restraint program on European financial markets,
particularly with respect to the absorption of capital market funds
abroad through borrowing by large U.S. corporations.

Representatives

of the smaller industrial countries indicated the difficulties that
were facing them in obtaining funds in European capital markets.
The discussion went on to the subject of the need for improvement

-20-

3/22/66

in those markets and to the study currently underway under OECD
auspices to devise methods for facilitating the flow of investment
funds in Europe.

It was agreed that that would be the principal

topic at the next meeting of the EPC, scheduled for early July.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System
Open Market Account covering open market operations in U.S.
Government securities and bankers' acceptances for the period
March 1 through 16, 1966, and a supplemental report for March 17
through 21, 1966.

Copies of both reports have been placed in the

files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Holmes
commented as follows:
Since the last meeting of the Committee a new
element of uncertainty has crept into the financial
markets. Underlying market sentiment still anticipates
pressure on financial markets and on interest rates in
the months ahead, but expectations have become more mixed.
There has been at least a pause in the upward movement
of interest rates in long-term markets.
Underlying this new caution there appears to be a
growing conviction that current monetary policy and
interest rate levels are beginning to bite. Banks are
now apparently taking a harder look at credit applications
than for many years, and credit officers are learning to
say no with greater frequency. The rapid rise in interest
rates that has already occurred has now tended to make
some borrowers consider postponing new loans, or at
least not to rush into the market in anticipation of
needs, while investors are beginning to find current
rate levels increasingly attractive.
Of greater importance over the past week or so has
been the market's feeling that the Administration may be

3/22/66

-21-

changing its mind about the need for a tighter fiscal
policy. As a result, despite continuing evidence of
economic boom and pressure on prices, the financial
markets are beginning to wonder whether some change in
fiscal policy on top of current monetary policy might
not be enough to bring inflation under control. While

this questioning is still tentative, it has been
encouraged by the decline in stock market prices, and
represents a new market element that may require our
close attention in the weeks ahead.
Against this background, the System's move into new
high levels of net borrowed reserves had in itself little
impact on market rates, although Federal funds did rise
to an effective rate of 4-3/4 per cent on 3 days during
the period. While the rise in the prime rate from 5 to
5-1/2 per cent on March 10, just preceding the March tax
date, evoked increases in rates on CD's, commercial and
finance company paper, and bankers' acceptances, Treasury
bills have been in good demand. In yesterday's auction
average rates of 4.58 per cent and 4.78 per cent were
set on three and six-month bills, respectively, about
8 basis points below rates in the auction three weeks
ago, after a new high rate of 4.72 per cent had been set
on the 3-month bill a week ago. Government securities
dealers had come into the tax period in a strong
technical position. Bill inventories were only moderate
and dealers were under little pressure to absorb bill
sales from corporations who were paying taxes, partly
because of the large issue of March tax bills outstanding.
Money market pressures on the whole were surprisingly
light over the tax date, despite a record level of
borrowing from New York City banks. Banks seem to have
made careful advance preparation for the tax date,
including heavy borrowing from the Reserve Banks before
the weekend, and there is some evidence that the net
drain from maturing CD's was somewhat less than feared.
In fact, on the final day of the statement week ended
March 16 the funds market eased substantially and New
York City banks were left with a cumulated excess of
reserves of nearly $600 million which could not be
disposed of in the Federal funds market.
The volume of System operations in the open market
was relatively light during the interval. The System
supplied about $225 million reserves on balance, partially
offsetting reserve drains stemming from market factors

3/22/66

-22-

and permitting net borrowed reserves to deepen somewhat.
Reserves were released as the Treasury permitted its
balance at the Reserve Banks to run down to about $200
million as they passed through a seasonal low point in
their cash position. The effects of this development
in limiting the need for additional System action were
fortuitous indeed, as conditions of acute scarcities and
a rising level of demand in the Government securities
market made it quite difficult to purchase these issues
in large volume, either on an outright basis or under
repurchase agreements. In this situation, the authority
to operate in bankers' acceptances also proved to be
particularly valuable, as the System was able on several
occasions to meet part of the reserve need through
acquisitions of these obligations under repurchase
agreements.
During the period, the Government bond market had
its first sustained rally in many weeks with yields on
bonds in the 5-10 year area falling by almost 1/4 of a
per cent, and longer-term bonds by as much as 1/8 per
cent. At the close last night, no coupon issue was
yielding as much as 5 per cent. The prime rate change
had apparently been discounted in advance and reassuring
press comments helped allay any fears of an impending
rise in the discount rate. The strong technical position
of the market was a major factor in the price advance;
while there was moderate investment demand, there was
significant dealer covering of short positions in light
of the uncertainties noted earlier. By last Friday
dealers had moved into a long position of $47 million
Governments maturing in over 5 years compared with a
short position of $56 million about 3 weeks ago.
Developments in the markets for corporate and
municipal obligations roughly paralleled those in the
market for Treasury issues. Distribution of new and
recent offerings accelerated as investors displayed
current willingness to commit funds at current rate
levels, and yields declined from the high levels
prevailing at the start of the period. By the close of
the period there were no unsold balances in corporate
accounts and municipal bond dealers had reduced inven
tories to about $350 million, the lowest level in almost
four years. The markets derived additional stimulus
late last week, when the underwriting bid for $440
million New Jersey Turnpike Authority bonds was rejected
by the State.

3/22/66

-23-

It now appears that no further cash borrowing
by the Treasury will be necessary over the balance of
this fiscal year. The Commodity Credit Corporation
is planning to borrow $500 million late this month by
an auction of notes maturing in 4 months. Receipt of
these funds should be enough to see the Treasury through
its early April cash stringency, although there is still
a possibility that the Treasury might have to turn to
the Reserve Banks for accommodation for a few days.
Thereupon, upon motion duly
made and seconded, and by unanimous
vote, the open market transactions in
Government securities and bankers'
acceptances during the period
March 1 through March 21, 1966, were
approved, ratified, and confirmed.
Chairman Martin called at this point for the staff economic
and financial reports, supplementing the written reports that had
been distributed prior to the meeting, copies of which have been
placed in the files of the Committee.
Mr. Partee made the following statement on economic conditions:
The additional evidence which has come to light
since the last meeting of the Committee supports the
view that the economy is continuing to move strongly
upward and is pressing harder on available resources.
This is true even though we now expect a somewhat smaller
first-quarter rise in GNP than the very large $16 billion
gain of the previous quarter. Most of the slowing appears
to be in inventory accumulation, for which our present
estimates are highly tentative; final demands seem to
have increased more this quarter than last, with expendi
tures rising along a broad front and defense purchases
showing a particularly large increase.
The extent of the rise in consumption expenditures
this quarter has been in some doubt, due to the leveling
off in retail sales originally reported for January and
February. But we now understand that the January sales

3/22/66

-24-

figures are being revised substantially upward, with
February holding at the faster pace. The current sales
level thus is well above the fourth-quarter average,
indicating a substantial further rise in consumer out
lays this quarter, probably exceeding our green book 1 /
estimate of $7.3 billion. Personal incomes are
continuing to rise very rapidly, and now that the
initial impact of higher social security taxes has
been absorbed, I would expect even greater strength in
consumer demands. The new tax bill should have little
impact on consumption, since the amounts of additional
taxation involved are relatively small. And at mid-year
the introduction of Medicare will provide additional
stimulus to service outlays.
In the investment area, the new survey of plant and
equipment spending intentions provides confirmation of
our earlier expectations. The 16 per cent increase in
spending planned for 1966 is very close to the projection
included in the staff's chart presentation to the
Committee at the previous meeting, and the time pattern
of spending plans suggests a steady rise throughout the
year. It should be noted that, in each of the two
preceding years, actual expenditures considerably ex
ceeded those anticipated in March. But I would not
expect a similar result this year, mainly because
production rates, manpower shortages, and lengthening
backlogs in the equipment industries suggest that a much
larger rise would not be possible, at least in real
terms.
The whole economy, in fact, appears to be approaching
closer to capacity constraints. Thus, the capacity
utilization rate in manufacturing has edged up above
92 per cent and the recent further declines in the unemploy
ment rate have been centered in unemployment among women
and teenagers, suggesting that the pool of employable
On the
adult male workers is close to minimum levels.
face of it, certainly, it seems doubtful that recent
rates of real expansion can be long continued. The
industrial production index, in January and February,
increased at an annual rate of 11 per cent, well above

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

3/22/66

-25-

the 7 per cent addition to manufacturing capacity expected
this year. And nonfarm employment in the same period
increased by 250,000 monthly, a rate of gain which could
not long be supported by expected growth in the civilian
labor force.
The greater pressures on labor and plant resources
seem also to be showing up increasingly in current cost
and price developments. Hourly earnings in manufacturing
still are rising at a steady and moderate pace, but it
may be that larger wage increases are being offset
statistically by the addition of marginal workers receiving
less than average rates of pay. This notion is supported
by a recent narrowing in the year-to-year gain in output
per manhour in manufacturing, though that could also
reflect other factors, such as labor hoarding and
production bottlenecks, Whatever the reasons, unit labor
costs seem now to be moving up. The large increase in
January was mainly attributable to higher social security
taxes for employers, but new data indicate that a further
rise occurred in February.
New data also suggest some acceleration in the rate
of price advance. Wholesale industrial commodity prices
rose by one-half of one per cent in January and February
combined; this translates into an annual rate of around
3 per cent, which is considerably more rapid than the
1-1/2 per cent rate of increase prevailing during most
of 1965. A broad range of commodity groups showed
appreciable increases in these two months, including
many components of the key metals and machinery lines.
The February rise in the total wholesale index, which
received wide publicity, also reflected some sharp
further advances in agricultural products; but average
farm and food prices may now be at or close to their
peaks, since the cycle in per capita meat supplies is
expected to be reversed beginning in the spring.
In sum, the broad and pervasive advance in economic
activity shows every sign of continuing, spurred by
rising demands in every major sector of the economy
except housing and, perhaps, net exports. Recent rates
of gain appear unsustainable in a physical sense and,
accordingly, pressures on costs and prices seem to be
intensifying. Under these circumstances, continued
tautness in the cost and availability of credit, and
continuing substantial restraint on total credit flows,
are essential components of appropriate stabilization
policy.

3/22/66

-26-

This does not necessarily mean, however, that monetary
policy should be tightened markedly further at this time.
It seems to me that the Committee may wish to hold at
about the present degree of restraint for a time, while
the effects of earlier restraining actions--including
the increase in the prime rate--are being communicated
to the markets for goods and services. Given the lags
in transmission of monetary policy, it clearly is still
too early to gauge the extent of the impact on spending
decisions in such areas as housing, public construction,
business fixed investment, inventories, and consumer
durable goods. Passage of time also may clarify the
Administration's position on a tax increase, the outcome
of which will be a major determinant of the degree of
monetary restraint that will prove necessary to contain
the economy.
Playing the waiting game of course involves risksmainly the risk that the situation will get out of hand
and inflationary momentum really pick up speed. But the
risk seems to me fairly small, partly because of the
already substantial degree of monetary restraint and
partly because of the apparent continuing absence of a
major ballooning in speculative sentiment. Consumers
are spending freely, but not over-freely relative to
incomes; business spending on plant and equipment is
large, but not overly large in terms of present and
prospective pressures on capacity; inventory accumulation
is substantial, but perhaps not too substantial relative
to growing output and sales; investor expectations of
rising prices and profits are strong, but not so strong
as to have prevented a sizable stock market correction.
The developing economic pressures may appear substantial,
but at this point I am not yet persuaded that a more
drastic dose of financial medicine is required.
Mr. Hickman commented that if less efficient labor was now
being employed in production the part of the industrial production
index that was based on man-hour data might be rising faster than
the part based on physical quantity data.

He asked whether the

staff had made a comparative analysis of the two parts of the index,

and if so what the results were.

3/22/66

-27-

Mr. Partee replied that the staff made continuing comparisons
of the implied rate of productivity increase in the two components
of the index, and while he was not prepared to give a full report
on those studies it was his impression that the rate of productivity
gain had slowed in both.
Chairman Martin suggested that the staff might develop
information on the subject for the Committee's use, and Mr. Partee
indicated that that would be done.
Mr. Axilrod made the following statement concerning financial
developments:
Financial markets have recently caught their breathand a deep one as it turned out--after a rather exhausting
run since the beginning of the year, with interest rates
in recent weeks generally losing part of their earlier
increases. To market participants, the recent rally may
be a result of their reflections on the distance they have
come and on whether they have or have not out-paced such
events as credit demands, monetary policy restraint, and
the likely course of fiscal policy. For this Committee,
the change in market atmosphere--no matter how brief or
extended it turns out--provides an interlude for evaluating
the effects of monetary policy on financial market condi
tions and monetary aggregates and for attempting to separate
effects of policy actions from other market processes.
Since the beginning of the year there still has been
an over-all rise in interest rates of considerable magnitude
in long-term rates and most short-term rates, while there
has also been an apparently slower trend rate of growth in
bank credit expansion. The lessened bank credit growthwhich reflects both the reduced financial intermediary
role of commercial banks as well as open market and dis
count policy of the Federal Reserve--appears to be both an
effect and a cause of the rise in interest rates.
At first short- and then long-term rates rose as a
result of the December discount rate action and a consid
erable rise in demands on security markets in early 1966,

3/22/66

-28-

one consequence was a reduction in the financial
intermediary role of commercial banks, whose net
time and savings deposit inflows began to diminish
markedly. Despite the increase in time deposit
interest rates, corporations became less ready time
deposit customers. At the same time it is possible
that the higher interest rates that developed on U.S.
Government securities as well as on corporate and
municipal issues attracted some funds from individuals
that might otherwise have gone into time and savings
deposits.
Not only was the intermediary role of banks
reduced but a further squeeze on banks was generated
by the reduced availability of nonborrowed reserves
as winter progressed and by the continuing higher cost
of borrowed reserves. Most banks have made strenuous
efforts to maintain their market position and most
especially their customer relationships.
But the
resources to do so were not available and their efforts
therefore fed back on market interest rates and
contributed to the tightening of credit conditions.
Banks, especially large city banks, were forced to
liquidate U.S. Government securities, to reduce
acquisition of other securities, and to raise the
prime loan rate further.
The tightening of credit conditions has in turn
apparently begun to have some impact in restraining
the amount of over-all credit market borrowing. Since
early March a number of municipal issues have been
postponed, cancelled, or cut back, of which the most
important was the recent New Jersey Turnpike issue.
There have also been indications of some postponed
In mortgage and
private placements by corporations.
consumer credit markets, some greater selectivity in
lending appears to be developing. And banks have been
reportedly stiffening lending standards. But it is
certainly not clear exactly how to assess the effect
of such financial developments on the amount or timing
of spending.
While the recent pause in financial markets may be
partly attributable to early signs of borrower aversion
to high interest rates and greater lender selectivity,
there has also been a general assessment that both
equity and bond markets may have moved too far too
fast in a kind of herd instinct over-reaction to a

3/22/66

-29-

change in the economic and financial atmosphere. A
critical factor in extending this re-evaluation in
credit markets has been the recent discussion of a
more active use for fiscal policy--specifically tax
policy--as a restraining measure.

This has diminished

expectations of a further discount rate increase over
the near-term and generally resulted in some hedging
of bets as to the inevitability, timing, and extent
of future interest rate increases.
All of this does not mean that the months ahead
will be devoid of further upward interest rate pressures;
indeed, the recent decline in bond yields may itself be
something of an over-reaction. It does appear, however,
that credit markets may be completing their adjustment
to the December discount rate increase and the first
quarter burst in credit demands, at the same time as
the recent deepening of net borrowed reserves appears
to be taking effect.
In evaluating the degree of monetary restraint
associated with present levels of net borrowed reserves,
one is probably justified in concluding that more
restraint is being obtained per dollar of borrowings
than in earlier periods. For one reason, the discount
rate now is higher than in earlier periods of comparable
bank borrowings; for another, banks have heavy CD
maturities and are finding it difficult and expensive
to roll them over; and finally, member banks are
relatively more loaned up than earlier so that as they
find loan demand continuing and their intermediary role
reduced, lending terms tend to stiffen more. In the
current circumstances, larger banks are apparently
staying away from the discount window as long as possibleas testified by the margin of the Federal funds rate
over the discount rate--since their needs for funds
because of such developments as CD maturities cannot
be readily represented as temporary.
Under the existing degree of monetary restraint,
the money supply is showing an increase thus far in 1966
no more rapid than for 1965 as a whole, despite the
rapid economic expansion and even though time deposits
are increasing much more slowly than last year. However,
any pick-up in member banks' demand for credit at the
discount window could lead to some more rapid increase
in money and reserve growth from recent levels. Continua
tion of loan demand, difficulties in obtaining time deposits

3/22/66

-30-

and short-term borrowings elsewhere, and a cumulative
worsening of their liquidity positions are factors that
could erode the current degree of bank reluctance to
borrow from the Federal Reserve.
On balance, though, it appears as if the recent
trend rate of expansion in monetary aggregates might
just be continued with current levels of net reserve
availability, as indicated by net borrowed reserves
and the Federal funds rate. And it also appears as if
this complex of conditions is exerting a restraint on
borrowing that should begin to restrain marginal spending.
Thus, maintenance of the present degree of net reserve
availability may represent a fairly effective restraint
pending further clarification of the economic outlook
and resolution of the current fiscal policy debate.
But if this course were adopted, there is some risk, as
there always is when using a relatively fixed net reserve
availability target, that an erosion of banks' reluctance
to borrow at the discount window could generate a more
rapid expansion in nonborrowed reserves as open market
operations accommodated the increased demand--with the
result that monetary aggregates could rise more rapidly
and that upward interest rate pressure would tend to be
offset as the monetary aggregates were supported by
nonborrowed reserves.
Mr. Hersey presented the following statement on the balance
of payments:
I should like to start out with a few words about the
balance of payments since the turn of the year, and then
go on to talk about prospects for the rest of 1966 and
how they will be affected by policy decisions.
In the green book we used the word "significant" to
describe the improvement in the payments position in
January and February. "Significant" is a big word, and
I'd like to explain just what we meant. First, the im
provement was significant in the sense that it was more
than just seasonal. Secondly, the improvement was
significant in that the one explanation we can give for
it is a rational explanation, and one that carries some
encouragement for the future--namely, that the tightening
of bank lending policies after the turn of the year brought
a slowdown in the granting of new term loans to borrowers
abroad.

3/22/66

-31-

Having said this, I must add that we don't have
anything like full details of the January payments
picture, and we have very little to go on for February
except preliminary VFCR reports of further repayments
of bank credit. More to the point, I must remind you
that time and again the balance of payments has improved
for a while and then worsened once more. In fact, there
are very good reasons this time for thinking that a new
worsening is what lies ahead once again--or what may lie
ahead, if not prevented.
The major element of weakness in the U.S. balance
of payments structure under present conditions is the
acute strength of import demand. We have been seeing a
very considerable spillover of domestic demand into
demand for imported machinery, for imported finished
consumer goods, for imported materials. Balance of
payments analysts within the Government are now in
agreement that there is a great likelihood that in
1966 we will continue to have disproportionately large
increases in imports, as we did last year. Instead of
hoping for a 10 or 11 per cent year-over-year increase,
to a merchandise import total of less than $24 billion,
we must fear a 16 per cent increase, to $25 billion. The
rise within the year, from the very high fourth quarter
of last year to the fourth quarter of 1966, may be some
what less than 16 per cent, but it is not likely to come
down to the 7-to-9 per cent range of the prospective GNP
increase between the fourth quarters. Until the boom
quiets down, until pressures on plant capacity are eased,
and until protective inventory buying tapers off, we have
to expect a more than proportionate advance in imports.
With this revision in agreed views about the prospect
for imports, the outlook for the over-all balance is also
altered. Instead of a deficit of less than $1-1/2 billion
on the "liquidity" basis we have to fear a deficit of more
than $2-1/2 billion. The assumptions underlying this pro
jection include a somewhat larger rise in prices--and a
somewhat larger rise in current value of GNP--than the
staff projected for you at the last meeting. Also, this
balance of payments projection doesn't allow for quite
such a tightening of credit conditions and rise in interest
rates as was pictured in the chart show. For these reasons,
it may give too pessimistic a picture. But this new pro
jection must be regarded as lying within the range of

3/22/66

-32-

realistic possibilities if nothing is done to prevent
its realization.
The projection I have been describing does make
some allowance for effects of the change in U.S. credit
market conditions since December. However, if monetary
policy exerts intensified pressure on U.S. bank liquidity
and on non-bank corporate liquidity as the year goes on,
it may become possible to chop another half billion
dollars off the estimated capital outflow. Probably such
a change would be most evident in three types of flow.
First, the flow of bank credit could become an inflow,
with repayments exceeding new lending. Secondly, the
small inflow of corporate liquid assets we were still
having in the fourth quarter could continue, rather
than taper off. Thirdly, the net outflow to finance
direct investment might be reduced below the program
target if corporations felt so squeezed for liquidity
that they would step up their borrowings abroad even
more than now seems likely, or else might even cut back
their foreign plant and equipment expenditure plans in
order to reduce financing needs. As of December and
January, these plans for plant and equipment outlays
called for a whopping big increase of 24 per cent from
1965 to 1966, according to a special survey the Department
of Commerce conducted. No one really knows just how
flexible these investment plans might prove to be under
pressure.
With further fiscal and monetary policy action, the
current account of the balance of payments ought to do
The present view is that we have to fear
better also.
a deterioration from a goods and services surplus of
about $7 billion last year to one of only $6-1/2 billion
this year. This deterioration would be ascribable to
increased military expenditures abroad, but the failure
to get any improvement would reflect the steep rise in
imports. A moderation of the rise in U.S. prices and
incomes and a toning down of the intensity of demand
for plant and equipment and inventories surely would
make the import picture less bleak.
The conclusion to which this all leads is that the
U.S. balance of payments stands in need of all the help
What it needs
fiscal and monetary policy can give it.
from monetary policy is not higher interest rates, per
se, but rather a squeeze on the liquidity of banks and

3/22/66

-33-

business enterprises. So far as the external position
is concerned, help of that kind just can't be overdone.
At lease not until we have had a 12-month period with
the payments position averaging out near zero on the
"liquidity" basis--and that looks to be a long way off.
Chairman Martin then called for the go-around of comments
and views on economic conditions and monetary policy.

Mr. Treiber,

who began the go-around, made the following statement:
The most important event in monetary matters that
has occurred since the last meeting of the Committee
has been the increase in the bank prime rate from 5 per
cent to 5-1/2 per cent. The increase was an appropriate
response by the banks to recent economic and credit
market developments. It should encourage the deferment
of some credit demands, and should encourage business
concerns in need of long-term funds to seek those funds
in the long-term bond and equity markets.
Business activity is strong. The outlook is for
further substantial expansion. Capital spending plans
are strong. Unemployment has declined again. There has
been further pressures on prices and wages. There have
been a number of announcements of increases in prices.
Labor leaders have indicated that they will push for
wage increases without regard to the guidelines recom
mended by the Administration. There is more and more
concern over the prospect of inflation.
For the first quarter of 1966 our international
balance of payments appears likely to register a
seasonally adjusted deficit not much different, on an
annual basis, from the $1.3 billion deficit of 1965.
Banks apparently are continuing to make a favorable
contribution to the payments' situation, stimulated
of course by large loan demands at home.
The demand for credit upon all types of lenders
is strong. As banks have made loans in the face of a
reduced inflow of time deposits, their loan-deposit
ratios have risen further, and their holdings of U.S.
Government securities have been reduced to levels lower
than those of the tight money period of 1959-60.

3/22/66

-34-

Since the beginning of the year we have had several
personal discussions with the heads of the large banks
in New York City; and since the last meeting of the
Committee we have had further personal discussions with
practically all of them. Most of them report extraor
dinary loan demand. Most of them have reduced their
holdings of U.S. Government securities and tax-exempt
securities, and they are reluctant to make further
reductions. Many of them consider their present holdings
of U.S. Government securities as minimum holdings needed
to guard against emergencies. Further liquidation of
tax-exempt securities would generally bring substantial
losses. The immediate capital losses coupled with the
future loss of tax-free income could not be offset by
loan income. Despite the increase in rates on certificates
of deposit, the New York City banks as a group have not
substantially increased the total of such deposits.
In general, the banks have been reviewing their lines
of credit and have sought to trim them down as much as
practicable. But some types of customers are going to
need credit and are going to demand it. For example,
many insurance companies have notified their banks to
this effect. The banks feel they cannot say "no" to
If a creditworthy customer has kept
some customers.
good deposit balances for many years, "he has earned
credit," they say. If a bank were to refuse now to
make a loan to such a customer, the bank would lose the
customer for good and would lose his balances too. Thus,
highly valued customers are likely to get loans in some
amount, while other customers may not fare so well.
The banks recognize that they will not be able to
satisfy all customers with good credit standing, and
they have taken various steps to restrict lending to
essential loans. In varying degrees the banks have
encouraged customers to reduce the amounts of requested
loans, to postpone borrowing, and to go to the capital
markets rather than to the banks for credit. In some
cases the banks have established qualitative tests,
declining to make so-called non-productive loans such
as a loan to purchase an additional plant or company
where no over-all increase of production would result,
or loans for speculative investments or purchases. In
some cases banks have also established quantitative
limits on total loans by various departments.

3/22/66

-35-

The recent increase in the bank prime rate should
complement these other steps being taken by the banks,
and should help cut down the growth of bank credit.
Although our inquiry of banks in the Second District
outside New York City was much more limited, we are of
the impression that those banks are not likely to
experience as intense loan demand, and they are in a
better position to meet the demand.
Turning now to reserve credit, net borrowed reserves
have been over $200 million and member bank borrowings
have averaged above $550 million over the last two weeks.
These figures are somewhat higher than they have generally
been since the increase in the discount rate in early
December.
While net borrowed reserves and member bank borrowing
from the Reserve Banks are not nearly as high now as they
were in periods of restraint in the second half of the
1950s, the degree of restraint isn't correspondingly less.
In the 1950s the banks had more U.S. Government securities
which they could liquidate in order to make loans. In the
1950s, the negotiable certificate of deposit was not a
ready fund-raising instrument. Today banks are paying
high rates to obtain funds for a longer period either
through certificates of deposit or persistent use of the
Federal funds market; they prefer to do this rather than
to borrow for short periods at a lower rate from the
Reserve Banks. There is no doubt that the banks are now
under pressure from monetary policy.
Last week the Tax Adjustment Act of 1966 was enacted.
It should be helpful in providing some restraint on over
all demand, but many informed observers question whether
it will be adequate. In their view, a further increase
in taxes, some reduction in contemplated spending, or
both, are needed.
Despite the speed with which this recent tax legisla
tion was enacted, further fiscal action is likely to bring
more discussion and debate in the Congress, and the enactment
of effective legislation could take much longer. A proposal
for a tax increase is likely to produce debate not only on
the nature of the increase and on whom it falls, but also
on the question of what expenditures could properly be
reduced. The likely result would be a compromise measure
with some general increase in taxes and some cutback in
spending plans. The Joint Economic Committee of the
Congress has expressed its concern about inflation and

3/22/66

-36-

has urged fiscal action.

The majority stresses increased

taxes; the minority stresses reduced spending. In my
view, the Congress, through its appropriate legislative
committees, should be considering right now what further
fiscal policy steps would be appropriate.

Monetary policy is taking hold, but it is still
too soon to evaluate fully the implications with respect
to the rate of credit growth. It seems to me that we
should seek to maintain about the present degree of
reserve availability. Consistent with this objective
there might be net borrowed reserves fluctuating around
$200 million, member bank borrowing fluctuating around
$600 million, and Federal funds at 4-5/8 - 4-3/4 per cent
most of the time.
I see no reason to change the first paragraph of the
directive adopted at the last meeting, although I certainly
see no objection to the change in the first sentence of the
first paragraph of alternatives A and B prepared by the
staff.
Nor do I see any reason to change the last sentence
of the first paragraph even though there be no change in
policy. The goal is to moderate this year the growth in
the three specified items that took place over a long time
span that included last year. I doubt that we can be
precise enough to say that current growth rates are the
right rates that we should seek to maintain.
As for the second paragraph of the directive, I
question the advisability of tying the goal to net reserve
availability. I would prefer that open market operations
be conducted with a view to maintaining about the current
conditions in the money market. Net borrowed reserves
would, of course, be an important factor, perhaps the
most important, but not the sole factor.
Mr. Francis commented that, as suggested at the Committee's
last meeting, he had talked to bankers at most of the large Eighth
District banks about their demands for credit, actions they were
taking to balance supplies and demands for funds, and their expected

1/

Appended to these minutes as Attachment A.

-37

3/22/66

use of the discount facilities.

Most of those contacted stated

that the demands for credit were sizable and that they had had
to be more selective in granting loans, especially to contractors
and for real estate development.

Regular customers were virtually

all being accommodated to the normal extent, but much new business
and large increases in old lines were being rejected.
balances were receiving more consideration.

Compensating

Some bankers expected

further interest rate increases in the near future; others felt
that they had reached their peak.

A few bankers expressed concern

over the welfare of savings and loan associations in the current
situation.

Business loans had remained about constant since last

October at large District banks, compared with the 20 per cent
rate of increase at all weekly reporting banks in the nation.
In the discussions, Mr. Francis continued, none of the
bankers thought they would have necessity for large continuous
borrowing at the Federal Reserve.

There was no resentment expressed

concerning past treatment at the discount window.

Some asked questions

about the mechanics of submitting notes as collateral for their bor
rowings, and many believed that they might have need for more borrowing
for short-term adjustment purposes.

At the present time there were

no serious cases of continuous borrowing, although there were three
cases at the "watch closely" stage--but those were the repeaters.

3/22/66

-38

The total amount of borrowing from the St. Louis Federal Reserve
Bank had been higher in recent months, but the banks borrowing had
generally paid off after a brief period.

The discussions had

pointed up great concern by bankers over further inflation.

They

understood the Federal Reserve attitude toward excessive discounting
and he expected their cooperation with, at most, rare instances of
attempted abuse.
Economic activity had been expanding sharply, Mr. Francis
noted.

Both in the St. Louis District and in the nation, total

spending, employment, production, and incomes had been rising
markedly in recent months.
exceptionally optimistic.

Expectations for future activity were
Total demands had gone up faster than

output, and prices had increased.

He was inclined to believe that

the increases in the general wholesale price index should be taken
at near face value.

It was true that some agricultural and food

prices had risen exceptionally rapidly but, if supplies had been
normal in that field of inelastic demand, total demand would have
spread more into other areas and other prices would have gone up
more.
Both monetary

and fiscal actions had been expansive,

Mr. Francis remarked, and it appeared that fiscal actions would
continue to be stimulative.

The "high employment" budget, which

was at its lowest surplus level in many years during the last half

-39

3/22/66

of 1965, appeared to be in deficit in early 1966 and was expected
to be in even greater deficit later in the year.

Bank reserves,

bank credit, and money had risen at unusually rapid rates since
last summer.

Whether there had been any change in the rate of

increase of monetary magnitudes in recent months was a matter on
which there could reasonably be differences of opinion.

In his

view, bank reserves and the money supply had been following about
the same trend since the first of the year as in the last half of
1965,

It seemed to him that an illusion of a recently reduced

rate of increase had been given by the bulge at year-end consisting
of a great jump and subsequent partial loss of that increase.
With regard to policy, in view of the inflationary pressures,
the very stimulative fiscal situation, and exuberant expectations,
Mr. Francis suggested restriction in terms of slower rates of growth
in member bank reserves, credit, and the money supply.

Bank reserves

and money might appropriately increase at rates that were significantly
lower than the rate of growth of real product.
Several factors warned that restriction on the growth rate of
money should be moderate, Mr. Francis said.

The transactions demand

for money was presumably rising, some bankers were asking customers
for additional compensating balances, and there seemed to be few idle
balances to draw on.

Also with the rise in interest rates, the value

of many assets held by businesses and consumers had declined.

That

3/22/66

-40

downward pressure on the value of assets and a resulting reduction
in net worth might have some moderating effect on the propensities
for real investment and other spending.
A substantial slowing of monetary growth would probably
involve further firming of money market conditions and further
increase in interest rates, Mr. Francis observed.

There was some

firming in money market conditions in early March which might
induce some slowing of monetary growth.

Nonetheless, he felt that

in the absence of significant fiscal restraint some further
tightening in money market conditions and possibly further interest
rate increases might be necessary to obtain appropriate limitations
on demand for goods and services.

In many ways, he, of course,

did not like those high interest rates and the accompanying restric
tions on funds for real investment and economic growth.

But they

were, for the time being, imposed upon the Committee by the easy
fiscal policy of the past nine months and the prospective future.
In any case, the increasing interest rates had the benefit of making
the balance of payments situation less troublesome than it otherwise
would be.
Mr. Francis would not increase the discount rate at this
time, although a case could be made that it was low relative to
other money market rates.

He would prefer alternative B of the

draft directives, perhaps with some rephrasing as indicated by
Mr. Treiber to eliminate reference to net reserve availability.

-41

3/22/66

Mr. Patterson reported that a tighter labor market continued
to develop in the Sixth District.

Nonfarm employment had increased

further with especially strong gains in apparel and wood and furniture
products manufacturing.

Average weekly hours worked in District

manufacturing plants averaged 42.1 in January and probably had
increased since then.

The insured unemployment rate continued

below the national level.
When it came to the financial sector, Mr. Patterson said,
evidence of credit tightening was most evident in respect to rates.
Most of the larger District banks had announced higher prime rates,
but as yet no data were available to indicate how much of that had
been translated into higher rates on business loans.

The whole

rate structure for consumer instalment loans was expected to move
up very soon.

Bankers surveyed in Atlanta, Miami, Nashville, and

Birmingham reported that quoted rates had not changed but that
effective rates were higher since they were now making practically
no loans below quoted rates.

Major independent finance companies

in Atlanta had raised rates, and the captive finance companies
seemed to be on the verge of change.
would likely follow.

If that happened, the banks

A further increase in rates on floor plan

loans, already increased in January and February, was expected.
Auto sales in early March were very good in Atlanta, and preliminary

3/22/66

-42

data suggested a substantial rise in automobile instalment credit
extensions from January to February.
Total loan growth continued stronger this year, Mr. Patterson
remarked, while business loan expansion was slightly greater, chiefly
because of higher loans to trade concerns.

Nevertheless, pressures

for funds were limited to a relatively few banks, mostly the larger
banks.

Apparently, the banks as a group had not found it necessary

to liquidate investments to meet loan demands.

Only twenty-one banks

obtained funds through the discount window last week, and net
purchases of Federal funds were lower than last fall.
Mr. Patterson commented that the flow of funds into the
District resulting from the greater-than-national rate of economic
expansion might be responsible in part for the more comfortable
position of the District banks.

In part it might result from a

deliberate policy to limit lending, judging from the preliminary
reports received in the quarterly bank lending practices survey.
Although all reports showed the demand for commercial and industrial
loans as stronger, they also indicated firmer and more selective
lending.

None of the banks reporting were actively seeking loans.

Also, the more comfortable position might be explained by the
customary delay in transmitting changes in money market conditions
throughout the country.

Some effects of the recent tightening in

the money market were now beginning to show up in the District,

-43

3/22/66
however.

Atlanta bankers reported an increased loan demand from

customers who were shifting their borrowing from New York banks
and utilizing previously established lines of credit in Atlanta,
The relatively few District banks active in the CD market had
adjusted rates upward in line with rates in New York.
Mr. Patterson went on to say that the churning in the
Atlanta District illustrated very well that it took some time for
any policy action to permeate the various sectors of the economy.
Up to this time, the Committee had been able to observe only some
of the effects of the policy move of a gradual reduction in reserve
availability.

For that reason, he did not favor further tightening

at this time.

Neither did he favor raising the discount rate.

On the other hand, he believed the Committee should not dissipate
the tightening effects of its recent policy action by raising the
permissible ceilings on time deposits.

In the event of a liquidity

squeeze, he would prefer that, rather than raising the ceiling,
banks under pressure for funds should be forced to the discount
window.
In terms of free reserves, Mr. Patterson favored a net
borrowed reserve figure of around $200 million.

At the same time,

however, he believed the Committee should pay close attention to
the relation of the free reserve figure to the level of member
bank borrowing, bank credit, and the money supply.

Under conditions

of strong credit demands, free reserves might become increasingly

3/22/66

-44

unreliable as a measure of the effectiveness of policy.

He favored

alternative A of the draft directives with the amendment suggested
by Mr. Treiber.
Mr. Bopp commented that developments in recent weeks gave
some evidence that System policies of restraint were being felt in
financial markets.

The question now was whether still more

restrictive action was called for to meet future developments,
or whether to mark time for the present to observe further the
effects of policy actions already taken.

In looking to the future,

one could construct models that would call for either course.

A

case for further restriction could be based on factors such as the
following:

possibility of escalation of the Vietnam effort; delay

in raising taxes; further intensification of demands in the private
economy, with inventory building and capital spending cumulating in
anticipation of higher prices and shortages; growing tightness of
labor; and further crumbling of the wage-price guideposts.
Another model would give different emphasis to some of the
same factors, Mr. Bopp continued.

In the absence of new information

about the Vietnam effort, most current thinking was running along
the line that the impact of defense orders would moderate after
mid-year.

In the private sector, the latest information on inventories

provided some reassurance.

Inventory accumulation slowed in January,

and businessmen planned a slower rate of increase in the first and

3/22/66

-45

second quarters of this year than in the fourth quarter of last
year.

Capital expenditures, it was true, now were forecast to

increase about as fast as they did last year, and in this year's
economy such an increase imposed considerable strain.

There was

some reassurance in the fact, however, that spending was expected
to grow fastest in those industries that were hardest pressed for
capacity.

And it still seemed likely that new capacity would be

coming on stream at least as fast as production increases.
In short, Mr. Bopp said, although it would be hard to find
reasons why pressures on the economy might actually diminish, it
did seem possible that the rate at which pressures had been build
ing might slow down.

The relative stability of the weekly figures

on industrial prices recently offered some hope that that was the
case, but it would be important to see whether the weekly data
were borne out in the monthly index for March.
The difficulty of foreseeing the future, however, argued
even more forcefully than usual for moving gradually as the
situation unfolded, Mr. Bopp remarked.

He was inclined to feel

that policy actions already taken had been having considerable
effect, and it might well be that their impact would intensify in
coming weeks.

Flows of money and credit had been more moderate

recently, and rationing of credit, both by banks and the market,
seemed to be increasing.

If flows of money and credit were to

3/22/66

-46

continue at those more moderate rates as the economy continued to
expand, demands for funds might well increase sufficiently to
produce higher interest rates.
As to conversations with leading bankers, Mr. Bopp observed
that the Committee's discussion three weeks ago was too brief and
inconclusive to answer questions that bankers legitimately asked
during such conversations.

The questions were not internally

consistent, but they posed great difficulties on either horn of
the dilemma.

These were a few samples:

"In the present environment,

are you trying to tell me in a subtle way to ration credit rather
than increase rates, particularly the prime rate?"

It was agreed

that the answer should be no; but Mr. Bopp wondered if an increase
in the prime rate would have been attempted had the Committee
launched a crash campaign immediately after its last meeting.
"What criteria should I follow in rationing credit?"

The discussion

last time demonstrated only that there was no agreement as to what
constituted "productive" credit, but that was not very helpful to
a banker who was seeking help to cooperate in a general program.
"Is this merely a first step down the road to guidelines?"
Assurance that there was no intention to develop guidelines did
not always remove growing skepticism of intentions.
Mr. Bopp said he had not made a series of formal appoint
ments, one after the other, with the heads of the District's large

-47

3/22/66
banks.

He had, however, seized opportunities arising from other

contacts to discuss the problem.

Such contacts had arisen with

most of those who had not been on winter vacations.

He also

planned to discuss the problem in the field meetings which would
begin shortly and would cover the entire Third Federal Reserve
District.

He added that, on the basis of reactions he had been

receiving, he anticipated widespread and deeply-felt adverse
reactions to the latest revision in Regulation Q ceilings.

That

would not deter the Reserve Bank from meeting the issue head-on
as it had met other issues annually over the years.
Returning to the question of policy, Mr. Bopp said that
until the next meeting of the Committee he would be inclined to
hold money market conditions about where they had been in the past
week and observe closely the effect on financial markets and bank
credit.

If credit flows resumed their earlier rapid pace, further

restraint might be necessary.

He preferred alternative A of the

draft directives.
Mr. Hickman commented that reduced rates of growth of bank
reserves, bank credit, and the money supply in recent weeks indicated
that the Committee's policy objectives were being met.

Related

developments in the stock and bond markets, including postponements
of some municipal, turnpike, and utility financing, suggested also
that the tighter policy was having "real" as well as financial

3/22/66
effects.

-48
It was difficult for him to determine whether the

Committee's policy actions were evoking more realistic attitudes
towards fiscal policy, but eventually high interest rates were
bound to have some effect in that area as well.
Since the Committee appeared to have achieved quite a bit
in a short time, Mr. Hickman thought it should pause now to observe
the unfolding of what it had done.

Therefore he would vote for

alternative A of the draft directives, as submitted by the staff.
Translating that into a specific target for the Manager, he came
out with net borrowed reserves around $200 million, with borrowings
averaging about $600 million.

In his judgment it would be

particularly important in this critical period for the Manager to
be given leeway to deepen net borrowed reserves in the event of
another surge in the demand for bank credit.
Mr. Hickman said he could add little to what had been said
today and in the green book about the recent behavior of the
statistical indicators, and would comment instead on the latest
quarterly meeting of Fourth District business economists held at
the Cleveland Reserve Bank on March 14.

The overwhelming majority

of that group--which, incidentally, represented a number of
prominent national corporations in steel, autos, rubber, machinery,
and related industries--called for a reduction in Federal nondefense
spending and higher corporate and personal income taxes as the

3/22/66

-49

best ways

to cool off present inflationary pressures.

favored the use of monetary policy alone at this

No one

juncture, and

very few favored suspending the investment tax credit or imposing
selective credit controls.

Identical views were expressed at a

joint meeting of the boards of directors

of the Cleveland Reserve

Bank and its Cincinnati and Pittsburgh branches, held in Cleveland
on March 10.
Both groups--the economists and the directors--diagnosed
the present situation as one of

too rapid business expansion, with

mounting pressures on resources

and prices, Mr. Hickman said.

The

business economists' median forecasts for industrial production
showed gains in each quarter through the first quarter of 1967,
with the over-all percentage gain for
of 1965.

1966 expected to match that

For the second meeting in a row, not a single participant

expected production to decline in any quarter in the year aheada record unprecedented in the 20-year history of that group.
There was much less certainty in the forecasts of inventory
investment, Mr. Hickman commented, which was not surprising in view
of the lack of reliable information in that key area.

As was now

known, many in the System, and apparently some in the Administration
as well, completely missed the mark in predicting inventory behavior
in the fall of

1965, which was a factor in preventing the framing

of an appropriate public policy package to head off inflation.

As

-50

3/22/66

he had mentioned several months ago, something must be done about
the deficiency in knowledge of inventories.

He believed that the

Federal Reserve System should offer some of its resources to over
come this major obstacle to timely policy determination.
The Committee might be interested in one other item dis
cussed at the business economists' meeting, Mr. Hickman continued.
There was a fairly general view that current plans for plant and
equipment spending in 1966 could not be completely fulfilled because
of physical and financial limitations.

There was also a general

feeling that capital spending plans might be revised downward
because of higher construction and financing charges and uncertainties
associated with bottlenecks in the supply of labor and materials.
Following the discussion at the last Federal Open Market
Committee meeting, Mr. Hickman said, he talked with the chief
executive officers of several of the larger banks--five in Cleveland,
two in Pittsburgh, and three in Cincinnati.

He explained that the

System was now providing a reduced rate of reserve availability
and that member banks in turn would be expected to reduce the rate
of increase of bank credit, either through rationing or higher
interest rates.

The bankers were most receptive to the rate approach;

subsequently all of them raised their prime rates to 5-1/2 per cent.
Since then,several of the same bankers inquired about the
timing of the next increase in the discount rate, Mr. Hickman

3/22/66

-51

remarked.

He explained that rate relationships did not seem to

him, personally, to be out of line with the discount rate, and
that further discount rate actions would probably depend upon
market forces of supply and demand.

As a matter of fact, he

believed that most of his board of directors would push for a
higher discount rate if the 91-day bill rate moved much above
4.75 per cent.
Mr. Brimmer said he would not present a formal statement
on policy today or comment on the directive; he thought it would
be wise for him first to get his bearings and to learn something
about the machinery of Open Market Committee policy-making.

He

would, however, offer a few observations on the balance of payments
outlook.

Personally, he thought it most unlikely that an estimate

of the deficit for 1966 on the order of $2-1/2 billion would prove
to be a reasonable one.

Mr. Hersey had presented the results of

the appraisal of an Interagency Committee which was in the process
of revising its own forecasts.

The Interagency group would be able

to make a better appraisal after the fiscal policy situation was
clarified.
In his judgment, Mr. Brimmer continued, Mr. Hersey's
emphasis on imports as the most likely source of deterioration
was correctly placed.

A substantial deficit in travel and tourism

also would contribute to the deterioration, as would military

3/22/66

-52

outlays abroad and the foreign aid program. But the outlook for
the capital account for 1966 appeared to be for substantial
improvement relative to 1965.

Preliminary evidence from the

Commerce Department program suggested that corporations probably
would not use the full two-year quotas permitted under the targets
laid down.

He thought the information that would be made available

in a few days would show that corporations had got hold of the
situation in 1965, and that the actual capital outflow last year
was substantially less than anticipated.

Of course, that meant

that corporations had greater than expected leeway for 1966, and
the problem was to persuade them not to use their full quotas.

In

any case, he expected the focus to shift from the capital account
to travel and imports.

Those categories might be somewhat more

amenable to restraint by fiscal policy than others, and he saw no
reasonable means for restraining them other than fiscal action.
Mr. Maisel commented that as was made clear in the blue
book 1/one got a somewhat different picture of growth in reserves
and other credit factors depending upon which recent period one
considered in his calculations.

He had chosen, as one proper base,

the biweekly reserve period ending January 5.

By using the daily

averages during that period, the base became approximately January 1

1/ The report "Money Market and Reserve Relationships," prepared
for the Committee by the Board's staff.

3/22/66

-53

or the start of the year.

As his final period he had used the

daily averages for the current biweekly period ending March 16.
Thus far this year, the money supply showed no increase while
total reserves grew a little less than 4 per cent, the bank credit
proxy grew approximately 8 per cent, and business loans were up
21 per cent, all at annual rates.
For the last month, using as a base the biweekly period
ending February 16, Mr. Maisel found virtually no increase in bank
credit, an increase of two-tenths of one per cent in reserves, and
a 9 per cent increase in business loans; but a considerably higher
rise than previously in the money supply.
It seemed to Mr. Maisel that considering both periods
together the Committee was about on a proper target for the year.
Mr. Axilrod today and the blue book both indicated that, under the
present policy directive, reserves and bank credit would probably
continue to expand at a rate roughly consistent with that which
had prevailed so far this year.

Therefore, he would support the

present policies and alternative A of the draft directives.

He

assumed that the mix of variables should continue to expand at
about the rate prevailing since January 1, and at a somewhat faster
rate than had prevailed in the past month.

He would think it

proper for the Desk to react against large movements from the trend
in growth of reserves by allowing net borrowed reserves to move in

3/22/66

-54

the necessary direction.

He would not substitute a money market

goal for reserves in the directive since that might be construed
as reflecting a concern with rates.
Mr. Daane remarked that he would make only a brief comment
on policy today.

He found himself in general agreement with

Mr. Treiber, and was impressed that the Committee's policy was
biting.

Clearly, the problem facing the country--and it became

even more clear as time passed--was one of inflationary pressures
requiring some dampening down of aggregate demands, unless policy
makers were prepared to accept the prospect of domestic inflation
and of real deterioration in the balance of payments.

But he was

fearful that any appreciable tightening of System policy now would
have unduly constrictive--even disruptive--effects on money and
capital markets.

Accordingly, he would keep the degree of pressure

on the money markets that had been maintained recently.

He would

hope that at least an announcement of effective fiscal action in
the form of a tax increase would come early enough to help the
System avoid a difficult situation with respect to the discount
rate.

On that score, he personally was convinced that if such an

announcement had been made earlier the increase in the prime rate
would not have been necessary and probably would not have occurred.
As to the directive, Mr. Daane favored alternative A of
the staff drafts, except that he would change the last sentence of

3/22/66

-55

the first paragraph to conclude "...

by continuing to moderate

rates of growth in the reserve base, bank credit, and the money
supply."

He would accept Mr. Treiber's suggestion that the second

paragraph be written in terms of money market conditions.

That

suggestion was consistent with Mr. Axilrod's point that at this
juncture maintaining any fixed level of net reserve availability
might produce conditions that were either too easy or too tight.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that he could vote for either
alternative A or B for the directive, with or without the amend
ments proposed.

He had a slight preference for B as amended,

however, mainly because he thought the Committee should keep the
banking system under as much pressure as possible during the next
month or two without raising the discount rate.

He noted that

there were two strings to the bow of discount policy.
the rate itself, which was not changed often.

One was

The other was the

traditional reluctance to borrow on the part of banks which, he
thought, could be reinforced by the Reserve Bank Presidents in
discussions with borrowing banks, directed toward encouraging them
to cut down on their lending.

The banks already were under a good

deal of pressure as rates on CD's approached the ceiling, and
bankers were apprehensive about that situation because obtaining
funds through CD's was no longer a very profitable operation.
During March and April the System ought to do everything it could
to persuade banks to cut down on their credit extensions.

3/22/66

-56
Mr. Mitchell said he had to admit to some dismay when he

heard suggestions that the System should advise bankers on the
types of loans they should and should not make.

When bankers

were told they should not make loans for speculative inventory
investments their response often was that they could not distin
guish such investments from the non-speculative type.

Advice to

banks not to make loans for nonproductive purposes might well be
wrong;

such loans did not add to the demand for real resources in

the first instance, and in any case later uses of the funds were
uncontrolled.

The problem had to be resolved by the bankers,

since there was not much in the way of useful guidance the System
could offer.

Perhaps bank customers should be told to rely more

on the capital market and perhaps anticipatory borrowing should be
discouraged to the extent possible, but in his judgment those were
functions that should be performed by the commercial banks and not
the central bank.
Mr. Mitchell was somewhat surprised by the way in which
Mr. Axilrod assessed the implications of the withdrawal of planned
tax-exempt security issues.

He did not think that kind of action

was particularly helpful since it was not likely to have any effect
on spending.

He also was surprised to hear Mr. Daane imply that

he did not like the prime rate increase; he (Mr. Mitchell) thought
it was a helpful development.

What would disturb him would be

-57

3/22/66

another discount rate rise, and he did not think one was necessary
at present.

What was necessary was some further tightening with

respect to extensions of bank credit.
Mr. Daane observed that he had not meant to imply disapproval
of the prime rate increase; under the conditions prevailing he
thought it was appropriate and necessary.

His point was that the

circumstances bringing about the need for a higher prime ratewhich, in turn, foreshadowed a possible discount rate increasewould not have developed if there had been an announcement of some
form of tax increase.

That was a matter of judgment, but his

personal feeling was that such an announcement would have had a
calming effect.
Mr. Shepardson remarked that some of the information
becoming available suggested that the Committee's policy actions
were beginning to have a little effect.

But other information

seemed to indicate that there was still a good deal of inflationary
fever extant in the economy.

Since the Committee did not know

what other policy steps might be taken, it seemed to him that it
was faced with the need for doing its own job by keeping the
pressure on through monetary policy.
At the previous meeting, Mr. Shepardson said, he had
expressed the hope that the Committee would not be overly gradual
in applying pressure, but many of the comments made thus far today

3/22/66

-58

were to the effect that the move toward greater firmness, as gradual
as it had been, should now cease.

He favored maintaining the

pressure by some further gradual increase in firmness, as indicated
by alternative B of the draft directives.

That might result in

a deepening of net borrowed reserves, perhaps to a range between
$200-$250 million.

Although it was not clear to him how one would

word such an instruction in the directive, he thought it might be
appropriate to follow the course Mr. Robertson had suggested recentlythat of letting net borrowed reserves fluctuate, depending on the
strength of credit demands.

If, as some seemed to feel, the demand

for bank credit was slackening, net borrowed reserves would not
have to be deepened as much.

His own feeling, however, was that

there still was considerable pressure on the banking system.
Mr. Wayne reported that Fifth District business continued
to respond to strong expansionary forces.

In a special survey of

manufacturers, a substantial majority reported recent increases in
the prices they paid for raw materials, machinery, and supplies;
and a majority, though a smaller one, expected those prices to
rise further in the weeks immediately ahead.

Nearly one-fourth

of those manufacturers reported recent boosts in their own prices,
and nearly one-third were planning increases to become effective
in the near future.

Representatives of the construction business

-59

3/22/66

and the bituminous coal industry also reported price increases put
into effect in the past few weeks.

Half of the manufacturers

participating in the Richmond Reserve Bank's regular survey
indicated a further rise in new and unfilled orders, and a good
number reported increases in employment and hours.
In the policy area the indicators seemed to diverge a
little but, on balance, Mr. Wayne saw no reason to change the
Committee's posture of a gradual reduction of reserve availability.
As Mr. Axilrod had indicated, there were a few signs that the
policy of monetary restraint was making itself felt.

Stock prices

had dropped substantially and considerable amounts of new bond
offerings had been postponed or cancelled.

The money supply had

registered one small decline and rates of growth had been reduced
significantly for total reserves, bank credit, consumer credit,
time deposits, and retail sales.

The long rise in automobile

production and sales might at last be leveling off as car inventories
reached record levels.
But without doubt the economy as a whole was booming,
Mr. Wayne said, with several sectors moving up at rates which
could not be sustained for long.

A number of major industries were

operating at forced draft, beyond optimal capacity levels.

The

boom had attained so much momentum that the task of slowing it to
a sustainable pace without precipitating a recession was an

3/22/66

-60

extremely delicate operation.

Recent movements in interest rates

and the absence of any severe strain in the money market over the
tax and dividend dates suggested that the monetary pressure was
being applied smoothly and evenly.

Further, the recent behavior

of banking statistics might provide some evidence that the banks
were acting more responsibly and with more restraint.

In his

conversation with leading bankers he found reasons for cautious
optimism.
In the discussions Mr. Wayne had had with bankers in his
District since the last meeting of the Committee, he found a
profound concern with inflationary pressures which all thought
were a problem not for the future but for the present.

There was

a general feeling to the effect that the leading banks of the
country had lost control of their credit policies and were seeking
a crutch to lean on.

While the District banks said they were

becoming selective in their lending policies, to many that meant
that their primary concern was with the impact of their policy on
the relative position of their bank, with less recognition of the
implications for the national interest.

He found the actions and

policy decisions of leading banks varying from the extreme of one
large bank which had established a policy that probably would
result in reducing its relative position in the District by the
end of the year.

That bank was willing to follow such a policy

3/22/66

-61

because of its concern with the national interest.

At

the other

extreme were banks which felt strongly that unless some kind of
crutch was

provided nothing could be expected from the banks

themselves.
Mr. Wayne went on to say that banks

in his District

thought

the New York City banks had operated imprudently, and they were
sharply critical of the New York banks

for suggesting, when they

ran short of funds, that their customers draw on credit lines
outside of New York and thus relieve the pressure on them.

The

hope had been expressed to him that the System would not raise
Regulation Q ceilings again because banks

could not be relied on

to exercise prudence in setting time deposit rates.
Mr. Wayne said he joined Mr. Mitchell in hoping that no
voluntary credit restraint program would be needed.

He thought

it was naive to anticipate that, when the Reserve Bank Presidents
talked with bankers,
to provide

there would not be pressure for the System

some indications of the priorities to be followed in

bank lending policy.
resist such pressure.

He had done everything in his power to
It was clear, however, that the credit

officers of banks would use the very fact that there had been a
discussion with the Reserve Bank as a
dealing with their customers.

crutch on which to lean in

Their willingness to enforce "credit

restraint" simply meant that customers with substantial balances

-62

3/22/66

would get the credit they needed and other customers would find
it exceedingly difficult to do so.
Returning to his starting point, Mr. Wayne said he saw
no reason for changing policy.

It was important that monetary

pressures be maintained and slowly increased, but the Committee
should be alert for any evidence that pressure might be excessive.
The behavior of the stock market might be interpreted as such
evidence but he was inclined to doubt it.

Since he saw no convinc

ing evidence, he favored readoption of the existing directive
without change.

In his opinion the differences between that

directive and the two new alternatives proposed by the staff were
simply verbal.
Mr. Clay reported that since the last meeting of the
Committee he had had discussions with most of the large banks in
the Tenth District and several of the medium-sized banks.

All

reported unusually heavy loan demand from their regular customers,
from business customers who had had lines of credit or loan
commitments over a long period of time which they had never before
used, from national companies that had been regularly pursued by
those banks but never won, and from shoppers who were anticipating
difficulties with their present banking connection.

A number

indicated that the New York banks evidently were telling some of
their customers to "go west."

-63

3/22/66

The one common response to those increased demands and
limited availability, Mr. Clay went on, had been the increasing
of interest rates over several months and now.
little resistance to increases.

The banks reported

Several reported almost complete

lack of success in getting rid of customers by substantial rate
hikes intended to discourage without a direct turndown.

All had

taken some steps to slow or limit their loan expansion.

Those

steps covered the full range of possibilities and degree, and
involved selectivity with respect to type, size, area, and so
forth.

There was a general feeling that they must take care of

their regular customers, and--since they all anticipated
continuing demand and further tightening--they were working hard
to learn what demands they might expect from those regular customers
in the months ahead.

No banks had indicated that they would favor

institution of a program of voluntary credit restraint by the System.
To date, banks were reasonably conservative in reaching
for deposits, Mr. Clay said.

Most of them wanted only local CD's,

and were not trying to meet the New York market rates.

There were

exceptions to certain customers, but for most of them 4-1/2 per
cent for six-month CD's was the high.

They reported small growth

in time and savings deposits over the past few months.

Several

reported efforts to increase compensating balances by relating
rates more directly to balances.

3/22/66

-64
There seemed to be a general understanding that all their

potential demands could not be met indiscriminately at the discount
window, Mr. Clay said, and general acceptance of the fact that
there were and had to be limitations on the use of the discount
window.

However, there was great variance in the understanding

as to what those limitations were or should be.

He gathered that

most of them had been studying Regulation A in recent days.

Some

concern had been expressed that the System would change its dis
counting policy to tighten administration of the window.
Mr. Clay then remarked that analysis of the factors that
were pertinent to the formulation of monetary policy pointed
essentially to the same kind of domestic economic situation as
was apparent three weeks ago.

The aggregate picture continued to

be that of an economy in danger of trying to do too much too fast,
with unfortunate price consequences.

Accordingly, the monetary

policy objective also remained essentially the same as beforenamely, to facilitate credit expansion in keeping with the
economy's capacity for real output of goods and services.
Some progress had been made since the last meeting in
reducing the rate of growth in member bank reserves, Mr. Clay noted.
Moreover, the policy objective had been carried out without
disturbance in the money and capital markets, and along with the
development of a less tense atmosphere in those markets.

That

3/22/66

-65

situation might afford an opportunity to pursue the same policy
somewhat further.

On the other hand, it would be well to proceed

cautiously at this juncture in order to develop further evidence
of the financial response to the action already taken.

The net

borrowed reserve target might be set in the range of $200 to
$250 million for the period ahead.

In pursuing that policy, it

would be well to avoid placing such upward pressure on interest
rates as would precipitate a Federal Reserve discount rate
increase.

Alternative B of the draft directives appeared satis

factory.
Mr. Scanlon reported there had been no diminution of the
upward thrust of economic activity in the Seventh District.
Reports of labor shortages and slow or incomplete deliveries of
goods had become more frequent.

Many capital expenditure projects

were behind schedule because of delays in construction work or
lack of availability of equipment.

Automobile sales continued

strong with sales for 1966 projected at 9.3 or 9.4 million units,
about the same as last year.

Truck sales recently had been at an

annual rate of about 1.7 million units compared to 1.5 million
last year.

Here again, production would be even higher were it

not for shortages of some components such as axles and transmissions.
Perhaps the most significant development of recent weeks
in the District had been the step-up in demand for single family

3/22/66

-66

homes, Mr. Scanlon said.

Housing permits were up 10 per cent in

the Chicago area in 1965 and there was a rise of 12 per cent for
the four largest metropolitan areas of the District as a group,
compared with a decline of 3 per cent for the United States.

In

Detroit there were critical shortages of workers in the building
trades that prevented a larger volume of new construction.
Loan expansion at the big Chicago banks had been financed
largely by CD sales, Mr. Scanlon continued, with outstandings
rising by more than $250 million prior to the tax week.

Replace

ment of maturing certificates from now until after mid-April might
pose serious problems if rates on those instruments continued to
rise.

Chicago banks had acquired some additional bills, possibly

looking toward April 1 needs in connection with the local tax
date.

Their bill holdings were not much below the level they had

on hand prior to the tax assessment date last year when they
apparently were able to meet demands satisfactorily.

With reserve

positions fairly comfortable through mid-March, reserve city banks
had not borrowed heavily at the discount window but they indicated
that pressures could be expected to increase in the period
immediately ahead.

The number of banks using and inquiring about

using the discount facilities had been growing daily, as he gathered
was the case elsewhere in the country.
Mr. Scanlon reported that he had visited with the chief
executive officer of each of the major banks in Chicago individually,

3/22/66

-67

and also had had conversations with a number of bankers in other
reserve cities in the District, regarding the prudent rationing
of credit in a period of credit restraint.

Almost to a man, they

felt that monetary policy was beginning to bite, sharply and
rapidly; and they felt that bankers should prove they were bankers
and face up to their responsibilities in this area without benefit
of guidelines, written or otherwise.

Several medium-size banks

which felt they could not fully compete with money market banks
in the CD market thought that the Federal Reserve should re
examine its discount window policies.

They felt the System had

encouraged banks to be more competitive and, as a result, the
banks had gotten into longer-term investments.

In light of that,

they regarded the old criteria for judging steady borrowing as
obsolete.

In several instances, however, those were the views of

banks to whom the Reserve Bank had been talking about their use of
the window.

Absent fiscal action, all of the banks apparently

expected tighter monetary conditions given present credit demand.
Turning to policy, Mr. Scanlon said that because the full
impact of monetary actions was not evident immediately, and the
time effects of the recent reductions in capital values were still
unclear, it appeared desirable at this time to permit some addi
tional time for the economy to digest recent policy actions before
considering further policy changes.

-68

3/22/66

As to the choice of a directive, Mr. Scanlon was inclined
to agree that there was little difference among the existing
directive and the two alternatives proposed for this meeting.
However, since he favored no change on policy he leaned toward
alternative A.
Mr. Scanlon added that he agreed with Mr. Mitchell that
some resistance at the discount window was desirable at present.
He would caution, however, against any actions that might be
interpreted as an arbitrary change in the standards by which
appropriate use of the window was defined.

Officers of the

Reserve Banks had spent many years educating banks on that subject,
and if the standards were to be changed he would favor doing so as
a matter of general policy rather than in the course of informal
conversations with bankers.
Mr. Strothman said his report this morning would look at
the Ninth District economy from two aspects.

One would be the

Reserve Bank's view of District economic and financial developments
as revealed by the available statistics.

The second would be the

current and near-term banking scene as seen by the heads of major
banks.
It appeared that the District economy was still expanding
at about the rate of the fourth quarter of last year, Mr. Strothman
observed.

According to the latest statistics, production and

-69

3/22/66

employment gains were still substantially above what they were on
average in 1965.

Even the construction industry was getting on

better than expected and, on slender evidence, might even be said
to prosper.

Building permit and employment data suggested that

construction activity had recently been increasing much more
rapidly than it had on average in 1965.

The rate of increase of

consumer spending did not seem to have slowed at all from the
fourth quarter.

Preliminary trade employment data and the recent

behavior of consumer credit totals indicated that higher social
security taxes had had little or no immediate effect on consumer
spending in the District.

The seasonally adjusted District un

employment rate for January, the latest month for which figures
were available, was 3.1 per cent.
adjusted, was 41.7 hours.

The average workweek, seasonally

Those data suggested a very tight labor

market.
The banking statistics revealed a certain amount of the
"pressure," or "tightness," of which so much had recently been
heard in banking circles, Mr. Strothman remarked.

Loans by

District banks had continued to advance at a rapid pace, but with
the February and March increases somewhat more modest at country
than at reserve city banks.

Commercial and industrial loans had

dominated the increase for February, while loans to nonbank
financial institutions accounted for nearly all of the increase in

3/22/66

-70

the early March period.

Meanwhile, deposit outflow in February

was much heavier than usual but growth in the early March period
was above normal.

The average loan-deposit ratio for Ninth

District weekly reporting banks was higher now than it had been
for a long, long time--in fact, at 66 per cent it was at an all
time high for the series--and one suspected that the same might
be true for non-weekly reporting banks.

Their ratio, at 55 per

cent at the end of February, was but one point shy of an all-time
high on an unadjusted basis.
Borrowings by the reserve city banks had averaged about
40 per cent of required reserves, Mr. Strothman observed.

That

was a lot of borrowing, especially for so early in the year.

On

the other hand, such a scale of borrowing was not without precedent.
Also, it was to be noted that District banks--only a few of the
largest would be involved--suffered no real embarrassment as a
result of the early March maturation of a large portion of their
negotiable CD's.

Actually, reporting banks' CD's increased more

than seasonally in the three weeks preceding March 9.

In the

week ended March 16 there was a relatively modest loss.
Turning from those elements of the District financial
picture as seen by the Reserve Bank to the view as described by
bankers, Mr. Strothman noted seeming differences in perception.
The major bankers had characterized the situation with such

-71

3/22/66

expressions as "desperate" and "as tight as I have seen it."
Their banks had registered all-time loan highs in mid-March, and

the pressures continued.

They said they were confining lending

to regular customers and were trying to hold them to appropriate
purposes.

He would inject, however, that the Reserve Bank's

instalment loan survey indicated that, despite tight credit and
customer-selection policies, over-all consumer instalment credit
had increased and that the larger banks, at least, had not
endeavored to curtail the allotment of funds to their instalment
loan departments.

Actually, there was some information to the

effect that increased activity in that area was perhaps encour
aged by the banks' management.
As seriously as the District's larger banks viewed the
loan demand situation, it appeared to Mr. Strothman that they
were equally concerned about the extremely large volume of
negotiable CD's maturing in April.

One banker expressed the fear

that most of those could not be renewed at any price.

He asserted

that if there was to be a banking crisis it would come next month,
with the CD run-off coinciding with a further intensification of
the loan demand.
Mr. Swan reported that the expansion in business activity
had continued in the Twelfth District as elsewhere.

The Pacific

Coast States experienced a substantial employment increase in

3/22/66

-72

February which, combined with a much smaller increase in the labor
force, resulted in an unusually large drop in the unemployment rate
to 4.6 per cent, from 5.1 per cent in January and 5.4 per cent in
December.

Once more the aerospace companies added significantly

to their work force in February, and they accounted for almost one
half of the total increase in manufacturing employment in that
month.
Lumber markets had come under rather severe pressure in
March, Mr. Swan said, reportedly because of the combination of a
large volume of Government buying and some anticipatory private
buying against the possibility of a strike when the current labor
contracts expired on June 1.

That buying had pushed lumber prices

up rather sharply this month.
District banks were under some reserve pressure in late
February and early March, Mr. Swan continued, and had sold a rather
substantial volume of securities.

In the three weeks ending

March 9 the loan decline was about the same as a year ago, but
the decline in investments was much sharper.

However, the banks

apparently had over-allowed for expected loan demands in
connection with the March tax and dividend dates.

After being

net buyers of Federal funds through the first week ending in March
they were net sellers in the week ending March 9, and like the
New York banks they had ended the following week with funds they

-73

3/22/66
were unable to dispose of.

As of last Thursday they again expected

to be large net sellers of funds in the current week.

Their com

fortable reserve position also was reflected in the fact that
borrowings from the Reserve Bank dropped sharply in the week ending
March 16.
District banks were maintaining posted CD rates at levels
somewhat higher than earlier but still a little below those in
New York, Mr. Swan remarked.

They admitted freely, however, that

they would move their CD rates to the ceilings in individual cases
if necessary to retain substantial balances of national corporations.
Rates on savings certificates had edged up a little but also were
still below those in the east.

As of last week, the major banks

were maintaining a 4-3/4 per cent rate on savings certificates
and seemed to be a little nervous about going to 5 per cent.
There had been a good deal of concern about the flow of
funds to savings and loan associations.

In January, the latest

month for which figures were available, District savings and loan
share accounts rose slightly--by $112 million--to a total of just
under $26 billion.

That compared with a slight drop for the

country as a whole in January of this year and to an increase in
the District in January 1965 of $154 million.

Real estate loans

of District associations rose only $90 million in January, the
smallest monthly increase since April 1958.

Their borrowings from

3/22/66

-74

the Home Loan Bank and other sources were down about $100 million
in the month.

Such borrowings had declined in the country as a

whole, also, but associations in the Twelfth District accounted
for about 60 per cent of the national reduction.
In talking with the major San Francisco banks, Mr. Swan
said, he found that they were well aware of the loan demand
situation they faced.

They all reported strong demands and some

mentioned a spillover from national concerns that were not getting
all of the credit they needed from New York banks.

The District

banks indicated that they had adopted a somewhat firmer attitude
with respect to both rates and other loan terms.

They had raised

rates not only on prime loans but on other borrowings as well.
One interesting case was that of a major bank that had just
notified its branches that it was increasing the rates on auto
mobile loans, effective March 15, when the prime rate was raised.
The bank rescinded the notification, not because it did not want
to raise auto loan rates but because it wanted to increase them
more but preferred not to change them in two steps.
The banks also indicated that they were somewhat less
willing to make term loans and loans for real estate development,
Mr. Swan continued.

They apparently were eliminating a few of

their marginal borrowers and were pressing for larger compensating
balances, although he had some question about how successful they

3/22/66

-75

were in the latter respect.

They were less willing to accommodate

borrowers without established customer relationships, except for
particular borrowers that they had long wanted to accommodate.
The banks had sold a fair amount of real estate mortgages and some
were actively seeking to make further sales of such mortgages.
However, the fact remained that, at this point at least, Twelfth
District banks certainly were not in as tight a position as the
New York banks.
Mr. Swan went on to say that the major banks in the District
were unanimous on one point that came up fairly early in the
discussions--they hoped that the 4 per cent maximum rate on savings
deposits would not be raised, for two reasons.

First, higher rates

would add to their costs on the large volume of savings accounts
they had outstanding.

They had experienced some shift out of

savings accounts into savings certificates, but it had not been
great; and while there had been persistent small declines in their
total savings deposits, most recently that trend was reversed.
Secondly, they were concerned about the possible adverse effect
on savings and loan associations of an increase in rates on
savings accounts.

The rates currently offered on bank savings

certificates did not appear to be attracting funds in substantial
volume from local savings and loan associations, but a higher rate
on savings deposits might well do so.

-76-

3/22/66

In terms of policy, it seemed to Mr. Swan that recent
developments were just about what the Committee had expected when
it undertook its program of gradual redaction of reserve availability.
Like some others today, he did not have a strong preference between
the staff's two draft directives.

On balance, however, he thought

it probably would be better to maintain the present degree of
pressure and not to intensify it.

Perhaps there still was some

market reaction remaining to be assessed; and, while developments
associated with the March tax date had not posed any great problems,
it might be desirable not to take a further step until after the
April 15 tax date.

Accordingly, he leaned toward alternative A

for the directive, and he would be inclined to try to keep net
borrowed reserves around the $200 million level.

As to whether

the second paragraph of the directive should be written in terms
of money market conditions, as Mr. Treiber suggested, or in terms
of net reserve availability, as in the staff draft, he would
suggest a compromise:

to accept Mr. Treiber's proposed language,

but to add the words "including the present level of net reserve
availability".
Mr.

Swan did not think it was necessary to raise the

discount rate at this point.

The

System might not have to con

sider discount rate action until bill rates were substantially
higher than at present or there was a substantially larger volume
of member bank borrowing.

3/22/66

-77-

Mr. Swan supported Mr. Scanlon's remarks about the attitude
to be taken at the discount window, recognizing that the Reserve
Banks should take a firm position toward continuous borrowers and
borrowing for inappropriate purposes.

He noted, however, that

there could be a substantial increase in borrowing without a change
in policy.

In particular, certain large banks had not borrowed for

a considerable period; and if they should begin to do so--which
he was not necessarily predicting--it obviously would be difficult
to attempt to discourage them in view of their previous record.
Mr. Irons said that he had talked informally with the
presidents of perhaps a dozen banks in the Eleventh District
during the past three weeks, of which about half were large banks
and half small.

Like Mr. Wayne he had heard from a few banks some

rather sharp and severe criticisms of the New York banks--not only
for suggesting to customers that they "go west" for accommodations,
but also for working up the rates on CD's.

Rightly or wrongly,

some bankers in his District blamed the New York banks for the
present CD rate levels.

Also, some of the bankers contacted had

commented that they hoped there would be no further revisions in
Regulation Q.

Mr. Irons pointed out, however, that care should

be taken in generalizing from a few contacts.
Regarding the discount window, Mr. Irons said that

borrowings at the Dallas Reserve Bank had not been sizable, and

3/22/66

-78

he did not anticipate that they would become heavy, as long as
funds were available in the market from other sources.

He expected

the Bank to continue to administer the window as it had in the
past, in the manner prescribed by Regulation A.

While District

banks were borrowing relatively little, however, they were
substantial buyers of Federal funds.

Last Friday, for example,

borrowings at the Reserve Bank totaled only $8 million, but 5 or
6 major banks held over $250 million purchased in the Federal
funds market.

Obviously, banks were getting a large part of the

money they needed in the funds market, a source over which the
System had little control.
Mr. Irons noted that the bankers with whom he had talked
fully recognized the tightness of the credit situation and
expected it to become tighter.

They were seeing strong loan

demands and said they were being more restrictive in their lending
policies.

Perhaps banks could not distinguish precisely between

productive and nonproductive loans but the bankers contacted
thought, at least, that they were limiting their lending as far
as possible to productive as against speculative purposes.

One

of the large banks indicated recently that it was revising its
loan budget for the year downward by a significant amount.

There

was no lack of awareness of the need for credit restraint, and
banks were responsive to that need.

At the same time, banks had

-79

3/22/66

their own competitive positions to consider.

The result was likely

to be cooperation by banks with respect to their lending practices,
within the limits set by the competitive situation.
Turning to economic conditions in the Eleventh District,
Mr. Irons reported that they were very strong in all areas.

The

employment situation was tight and becoming more so, as the need
for skilled labor rose with the increase in production of defense
materiel.

Texas plants had received about one-half billion dollars

in defense orders in the last quarter of 1965 and those orders were
beginning to flow through the production process.

A large hel

icopter manufacturer recently had received an order for 2,000
machines; the firm had been producing helicopters at the rate of
60 per month, and it was attempting to find the skilled labor
necessary to step up production to 160 per month.

Defense orders,

which were likely to continue to come in at a substantial rate for
some time, were creating a labor problem.

District manufacturers

were scouring the country for skilled labor, looking particularly
to the areas of high unemployment.

One firm had instituted a

training program in cooperation with the Department of Labor.

In

short, the District economy was one of full employment and full
production, triggered by defense orders.

As to policy, Mr. Irons was rather pleased with the devel
opments over the past three weeks.

He also was pleased with the

3/22/66

-80

current discussions about the possibility of action in the area
of fiscal policy.

The comments being made on that subject were

rather contradictory and confusing, but the fact that the subject
was being talked about more was, in itself, a good sign and might
have some effects on expectations and on price developments.
There was no question in his mind but that the Committee's recent
policy was beginning to bite.

He noted also that there had not

been much distortion in financial markets.
For the coming period Mr. Irons favored maintaining the
policy that had been followed for the past three weeks.

He

would not suggest any absolute figure for net reserve availability,
but thought that net borrowed reserves might be somewhere in the
$200 million area, or perhaps $200 million plus.

With net

borrowed reserves at $200 or $250 million the Federal funds rate
might range around 4-5/8 to 4-3/4 per cent, and the rate on
3-month Treasury bills might move up to 4.70 per cent or slightly
higher.

He did not think there should be an attempt on the part

of the System to force interest rates upward, and he hoped that
market factors would bring about a satisfactory situation.
Mr. Irons favored alternative A of the draft directives
with Mr. Treiber's proposed amendment to the second paragraph.

He

thought it was better to call for maintaining current money market
conditions rather than, even if only by implication, for some
specific level of net borrowed reserves.

3/22/66

-81
Mr. Latham reported that all segments of the New England

economy continued to approximate the national expansive trends.
Unemployment had steadily declined.

Manufacturing production and

new orders were strong, and consumer spending continued unabated.
A preliminary tabulation, based on a 24 per cent employment
coverage, of New England manufacturers' capital expenditure plans
for 1966 had a decidedly bullish tinge.

The indicated planned

capital expenditures for 1966 were 32 per cent in excess of the
actual 1965 total, which in turn exceeded the 1964 total by 16 per
cent.

Those planned expenditures were about equally spread

between durable and non-durable goods producers.

There was,

however, a wide range among industries, from 85 per cent in trans
portation equipment to 4.3 per cent for the electrical machinery
industry.

Planned expenditures for plant were expected to increase

by 55 per cent and those for equipment by 26 per cent, with the
latter accounting for 76 per cent of the total dollar expenditures.
It was interesting to note that the Reserve Bank's 1965 spring
survey of capital expenditure plans closely approximated actual
expenditures for the year.
The short-term liquid asset ratio and the loan-deposit
ratio reflected the pressure on banks for credit accommodations
and the need for funds, Mr. Latham observed.

As of March 9, 1966,

the loan-deposit ratio of District member banks stood at 77 per cent

3/22/66

-82

and at Boston member banks it was 82.5 per cent.

The short-term

liquid asset ratio was only 1.5 at Boston banks and 5.2 for the
District.
In the past week Mr. Latham had talked individually with
the senior officials of the ten largest commercial banks in the
District for the purpose of discussing the need for credit
restraint.

Without exception, they stated that they not only were

under considerable pressure to meet the expanded needs of their
regular customers, but they also were being offered participations
in loans which were not previously available to them.

Mutual

savings banks, insurance companies, and other customers were
inquiring as to the continued availability of their little-used
lines.

Bankers contacted indicated that they were definitely

attempting to limit credit to productive uses, but admitted that
"productive use" was open to a wide range of interpretation.

With

only oneexception, no attempt had yet been made to limit consumer
credit other than by raising rates.

The one exception was a bank

reporting that its consumer credit portfolio had been fixed at the
balance outstanding at the end of February.

Bankers stated that

they were extending very little credit to new customers unless
good compensating balances were obtained.

Some said they were

setting up repayment schedules on long-outstanding collateral
loans and were trying to get accounts receivable loans taken over
by finance companies.

-83

3/22/66

Evidence was reported of customers reacting to the credit
squeeze in a twofold manner, Mr. Latham said.

Good customers were

increasing the amount of credit requested in anticipation of having
their requests cut, and other large firms, particularly utilities,
which had agreed to seek the public market for needed long-term
funds, were now shying away and again seeking bank credit.

Some

bankers indicated that they were being approached by marginal
concerns that they knew were being turned down by banks that had
previously met their credit needs.
The question was repeatedly asked as to what the Boston
Reserve Bank's policy would be with respect to the administration
of the discount window, Mr. Latham remarked.

All bankers expressed

the opinion that public demand would have to be curtailed and that
a firm fiscal policy was in order.

He added that it had been some

time since bankers were last put in a position where they were
required to say no to bankable credit requests, and they were
finding it difficult to do so.
Mr. Robertson then made the following statement:
There are one or two less strong readings among
the economic signals being reported to us this morning
(i.e.. less strong inventory growth in January, slower
rise in retail sales, and lower housing starts in
February), but the overwhelming bulk of the signals is
still continuing to come in strong. Expansion of
demand is building up real pressure on resources. The
rise in the wholesale price index for industrial
commodities picked up in February, and supplemental

3/22/66

-84-

information suggests that price increases are becoming
more pervasive.
In these circumstances, I believe that responsible
public policy calls for action to moderate the rate of
growth of demand.
As most of you know, I am one of those
who would like to see some excessive demands trimmed by
a further round of fiscal tightening. I suspect many of
us around the table are agreed on this, with the arguable
points being whether a tax increase is obtainable and
when and how much it might be. On these points, it seems
to me that the wisest attitude is not to be so skeptical
as to expect no further tax increase at all this year,
but, on the other hand, not to be so certain of its
likelihood and efficacy as to lay back on the monetary
oars and coast. To my mind, continued gradual tighten
ing of reserve pressure is the proper order for the day.
I think there is some reason for us to be gratified
with what has been accomplished with gradual reserve
tightening over the last six weeks. The rate of total
bank credit growth seems to have been slowed down, there
has been some lessening of bank loan availability, and
this has been accomplished without a major dislocation
of financial markets or interest rates. Any tendency
toward complacency in the light of these achievements,
however, should have been jarred by the upsurge in
business loans and money supply just before and over the
March tax date. Until and unless those increases prove
to be temporary, some partly offsetting firmness in
reserve posture ought to be sought.
This seems to me to be another situation in which
we could benefit by framing our directions to the
Manager in somewhat more flexible terms. To be explicit,
I would like to see net borrowed reserves averaging
around $200 million, but I would be prepared to see this
figure drop to $300 million should bank loan and money
supply expansion hold up strongly and expand required
reserves in the process. On the other hand, I would be
prepared to see net borrowed reserves move back to a
level closer to $100 million if bank loan and money
movements slacken and required reserves decline more
than seasonally. On the record, I believe this kind of

flexible instruction would have worked out rather well
over the past three weeks, and I think it could prove
equally apt in the uncertain weeks ahead.

3/22/66

-85

With this understanding of preferred operating
techniques, I would be prepared to vote in favor of a
renewal of the existing directive, or of Alternative B,
if we want change simply for the sake of change. I
would not want to expand this language to give any
special attention to money market rates. I think the
purposes of the Committee have been well served by our
recent greater emphasis on reserve availability, and
I think we should continue with this kind of policy.
In connection with Mr. Robertson's concluding remark,
Mr. Shepardson noted that several of the speakers around the table
had indicated that they favored no change in policy and then had
expressed a preference for alternative A for the directive.

He

would interpret no change in policy as calling for either readoption
of the existing directive or use of alternative B.
Chairman Martin indicated that he favored readopting the
existing directive; it seemed to him that little, if anything, was
added by the language changes made in either alternative A or B.
It was clear that the majority today favored keeping the pressure
on, but not applying it too stringently.

A number of people he

had talked with were generally agreed that the money market had
been handled quite well recently.

While there were no grounds for

complacency, he thought the Committee had come through the year
end period well, and it was evident that its policy now was biting.
In a recent conversation on the subject of credit rationing,
the Chairman continued, it had been suggested to him that "rationing"
was the wrong word; what was really needed was intelligent

3/22/66

-86

administration.

He hoped that the System would administer the

discount window intelligently and that bankers would be asked to

become bankers again.

Since there were twelve Reserve Banks with

discount windows to administer, completely uniform standards could

not be expected.

Basically, however, what the System was trying

to do was to restrain bank credit growth as much as reasonably
possible.

At the same time, it would be desirable in many cases

for banks to use the discount window in preference to other forms
of borrowing because the System could control the volume of dis
counting.

For a long time, he noted, many banks had not been

coming to the window at all.

Consequently, the window should not

be administered in too heavy-handed a manner; it was necessary to
weigh requests for accommodation in the light of general policy
objectives.

The go-around today had been quite helpful, he thought,

in pointing up the problem.
Returning to the subject of the directive, Chairman Martin
said that in his opinion Mr. Robertson had stated the matter
correctly--the modifications of language in the staff's two
alternatives seemed mainly to involve change for its own sake.
He suggested that the Committee vote on whether to readopt the
existing directive.
Mr. Hickman said that he agreed with Mr. Robertson as to
the type of policy that should be pursued, including centering

-87

3/22/66

the target for net borrowed reserves at the present level of
around $200 million.

He asked, however, whether readopting the

existing directive would not imply some further firming, rather
than maintaining the present degree of firmness.

He would not

want to see net borrowed reserves deepen to $300 million, for
example, unless the demand for bank credit strengthened.
Chairman Martin observed that it probably would be better
to have net borrowed reserves fluctuate, depending on the strength
of the pressures in the money market, rather than to have them
held at any specific level.

He did not believe it was possible,

however, to spell out that sort of instruction in the directive.
The problem was typical of those the Committee often faced in
composing its directive.

Perhaps Mr. Brimmer, as the newest

member, would like to try his hand at working out such problems.
Mr. Daane commented that he thought the objective sought
by Mr. Treiber's proposed amendment to the staff's draft directive
was simply to avoid the kinks in the money market that might
develop if there was too close allegiance to a target for net
borrowed reserves.

Perhaps that objective could be accomplished

within the framework of the existing directive.
Mr. Swan said that Mr. Hickman's point seemed to be a
valid one, since the existing directive called for further gradual
reduction in reserve availability.

3/22/66

-88
Mr. Robertson noted that the net borrowed reserve target

he had recommended in suggesting that the existing directive be
renewed was one fluctuating around $200 million--the present
level--and moving up or down from that level depending on the
strength of required reserves.
Chairman Martin said he doubted that monetary policy could
be formulated as a series of still pictures.

It was a moving

stream, constantly flowing in one direction or the other, and to
try to stop the stream could change the whole course of policy.
Mr. Hickman remarked that he had favored the recent firming
actions.

He did not want to overdo them, however, and did not

favor further firming until the Committee had more time to assess
developments.

He was prepared to vote for readopting the existing

directive if it was to be interpreted in the manner Mr. Robertson
suggested.
Chairman Martin said it was clear to him that the Committee
would not want to overdo firming action.
Mr. Treiber observed that the existing directive seemed
workable to him in the light of the discussion around the table.
Thereupon, upon motion duly made and
seconded, and by unanimous vote, the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York was authorized and
directed, until otherwise directed by the
Committee, to execute transactions in the
System Account in accordance with the fol
lowing current economic policy directive:

3/22/66

-89-

The economic and financial developments reviewed
at this meeting indicate that the domestic economy is
expanding vigorously, with prices continuing to creep
up and credit demands remaining strong. Our inter
national payments continue in deficit. In this
situation, it is the Federal Open Market Committee's
policy to resist inflationary pressures and to help
restore reasonable equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments, by moderating the growth in the
reserve base, bank credit, and the money supply.
To implement this policy, System open market
operations until the next meeting of the Committee
shall be conducted with a view to attaining some fur
ther gradual reduction in reserve availability.
It was agreed the next meeting of the Committee would be
held on Tuesday, April 12, 1966, at 9:30 a.m.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

ATTACHMENT A
CONFIDENTIAL

(FR)

Drafts of Current Economic Policy Directive for Consideration by the
Federal Open Market Committee at its Meeting on March 22, 1966
Alternative A (no further change)
The economic and financial developments reviewed at this
meeting indicate that the domestic economy is expanding vigorously,
with prices rising further and credit demands remaining strong.
Our international payments continue in deficit. In this situation,
it is the Federal Open Market Committee's policy to resist infla
tionary pressures and to help restore reasonable equilibrium in
the country's balance of payments, by maintaining moderate rates
of growth in the reserve base, bank credit, and the money supply.
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with
a view to maintaining about the present level of net reserve
availability.

Alternative B (further gradual firming)
The economic and financial developments reviewed at this
meeting indicate that the domestic economy is expanding vigorously,
with prices rising further and credit demands remaining strong,
Our international payments continue in deficit. In this situation,
it is the Federal Open Market Committee's policy to resist infla
tionary pressures and to help restore reasonable equilibrium in
the country's balance of payments, by moderating the growth in the
reserve base, bank credit, and the money supply.
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a
view to attaining some further gradual reduction in net reserve
availability.