View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

BOARO OF GOVERNORS
OF THE

RESERVE SYSTEM
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20551

FEDERAL

March 11,

1975

CONFIDENTIAL (FR)
CLASS II-FOMC

To:

Federal Open Market Committee

From:

Arthur L.

Broida

Attached is a memorandum from Governor Holland transmitting a revised version of the first stage report of the
Subcommittee on the Directive.
We plan to list this report on the agenda for discussion at the meeting of the Committee to be held on March
1975,

on an "if

Attachment

time is

available" basis.

18,

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

TO:

Federal Open Market Committee

FROM:

Robert C. Holland, Chairman,
Subcommittee on the Directive

DATE:

March 10, 1975

Attached is a revised version of the first stage report
of the Subcommittee on the Directive that was originally distributed
on December 21, 1974.

The revision reflects the recalculation of

statistical tests of relationships between various reserve measures
and monetary aggregates that were necessitated by corrections of
the original reserve series that had been used.

The recalculations

are compared with the original results in the brief staff memo
(from Mr. Pierce) that is also attached.
The new results do not fundamentally change the recommendations of the Subcommittee, but they do alter the emphasis in some
degree.

Nonborrowed reserves continue to be recommended as the

principal reserve operating target of the FOMC, but somewhat more
emphasis is placed on following, on a current basis, the figures on
total reserves.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Confidential (FR)
Class II-FOMC

REVISED

To:

Date:

From:

Federal Open Market
Committee
Subcommittee on the
Directive

March 7, 1975

Subject: Improvements in the
Directive: Stage I

Introduction and Summary of Conclusions
At its July 1973 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee
established the Subcommittee on the Directive to undertake a thorough
reconsideration of the Committee's procedures for formulating and
implementing domestic policy directives.

To carry out its charge, the

Subcommittee divided its work into three stages and launched an extensive
System-wide research program for each stage.

This report sets forth

the Subcommittee's conclusions and recommendations reached in the first
stage of its inquiry.
The objective of the first stage has been limited to evaluating
alternative reserve measures that might serve, in place of RPD, as shortterm operating targets in an aggregate-oriented approach to policy.
Stage II of the Subcommittee's work will appraise the merits of these
operating targets against other possible short-run targets, such as the
Federal funds rate or other indicators of money market conditions.
Combinations of operating targets also will be considered.

In addition,

Stage II will evaluate whether pursuit of intermediate targets, such as
the monetary aggregates or interest rates, is helpful in formulating
monetary policy, and if so, which intermediate target (s) are "best."
In the third and final stage, the Subcommittee will attempt
to identify possible regulatory and institutional changes that

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 2 -

might produce a more effective execution of monetary policy in the
reasonably foreseeable future.
This report is limited to the conclusions and recommendations
reached in Stage I of the Subcommittee's work.

It is hoped that

Stage II will be completed by early next year.

Assuming that the FOMC

is agreeable, the Subcommittee plans to arrange for nonconfidential
portions of its work on Stages I and II to be reviewed and discussed
The final stage will be extended

by some leading academic economists.
over a longer period.
The Subcommittee recommends:

1) The FOMC should move toward replacing RPD with
nonborrowed reserves (NBR), a reserve target that is more
controllable to the Desk.

This step can and should be under-

taken without placing exclusive reliance on a reserve measure
as an operating target and while recognizing that none of the
various reserve measures promise precise control over the
monetary aggregates in the short run.
2)

The NBR target should be defined for the interval between

FOMC meetings (as illustrated in the appendix to this report)
rather than for the moving two-month horizon used for RPD.

The

target should be accompanied by estimates of the total reserves
that are expected to be consistent with it.
3)

Insofar as the FOMC directs the Manager to utilize

this reserve target, the Manager normally should not attempt
to "look through" NBR to the monetary aggregates, but rather

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 3 -

should attempt to maintain his operating reserve target
within a specified range of tolerance.

However, staff

materials and, in some degree, the record of FOMC actions
should include the principal assumptions that underlie
the projected multiplier relationships between NBR and
the monetary aggregates.

These assumptions would include,

among other things, projected member bank borrowing (with,
when significant, distinctions by type of borrowing--e.g.,
regular adjustment, seasonal, and emergency).
4)

There should be provision for the Manager to consult

with the Chairman to determine whether the NBR target should
be changed in the interval between meetings should this
target prove to be in conflict with other operating constraints,
such as the Federal funds rate.

Furthermore, the behavior of

total reserves may indicate that a sustained and unexpected shift
in member bank demand for borrowings is occurring and, as a
result, the NBR path may need to be adjusted in a compensating
direction.
5)

Until such time as the FOMC acts finally on the

proposals set forth herein, NBR should be added as a "shadow"
target to be included in the materials prepared for the FOMC.
This procedure will assist the FOMC in evaluating the
desirability of adopting the alternative operating target in
place of RPD and it will smooth the transition to NBR should
that be the Committee's final decision.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 4 -

Procedures for Evaluating Instruments
The Subcommittee on the Directive believes that the RPD
experiment begun in February 1972 has made an important contribution
to improving the FOMC's operating procedures.

The experiment has helped

the FOMC focus on the relationships between its reserve-supplying actions
and the behavior of the monetary aggregates, and has helped point up the
difficulties in achieving control over the monetary aggregates when Federal
funds rate movements are constrained.

The experiment has also aided

the Committee in clarifying the broader issues involved in the choice
of appropriate operating and intermediate targets.
However, several problems have been encountered in pursuing
the RPD experiment.
Desk to control.

First, RPD has proven to be very difficult for the

Second, the multiplier relationships between RPD and

the monetary aggregates are difficult to predict at times.

Thus, the

RPD concept has not always been a reliable guide for the FOMC in forming
its decisions concerning either longer-term or inter-meeting monetary
policy, nor in judging, after the fact, how well the Manager has complied
with FOMC instructions.

Finally, the RPD concept has proven deficient

in terms of enhancing public understanding of monetary policy.

As a

result, the FOMC now places little or no emphasis on RPD and the measure
has become virtually irrelevant to the Manager in his operations.
The Subcommittee took as its first order of business the search
for a more reliable substitute for RPD as the FOMC's aggregate-oriented

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 5 short-term operating target.

The following candidates were considered:

total member bank reserves, nonborrowed member bank reserves, RPD less
reserves required to support large certificates of deposits, and three
variants of the monetary base.

¹

The following criteria were employed

to evaluate each of these measures as a possible operating target.
1.

Controllability. An operating target should be one that the

Manager can control with reasonable precision over a weekly time period.
This implies that the target must respond quickly and predictably to
open market operations.

Information about the target should be available

to the Manager on a timely basis so that he can determine whether the
operating target is on track and react quickly with open market operations
should it deviate from path.
2.

Predictability. The relationships between the operating

target and the monetary aggregates whould be reasonably stable and
predictable.
3.

Interest rate implications. The operating target should be

evaluated in relation to its potential for introducing serious money market
disturbances.
4.

Public understanding. The operating target should enhance--

or at least not obscure--public understanding of monetary policy.

¹

The

The monetary base measures the net monetary liabilities of the Federal
Reserve and the Treasury to the private sector of the economy and consists
of member bank reserves plus currency outside member banks. It is the
base that underlies the stock of money balances held by the nonbank public.
The variants of the base that were used include the source base, the nonborrowed source base and the monetary base. The source base consists of
total reserves of member banks, vault cash held by nonmember banks, and
currency held by the public. The nonborrowed source base is simply the
source base less member bank borrowing. The monetary base is the source
base adjusted to reflect changes in reserve requirements and changes in
the size, type and distribution of deposits in the banking system. In
this report, the more familiar terms of nonborrowed reserves plus currency
and total reserves plus currency will be used for the nonborrowed source
base and the source base respectively.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 6 behavior of the operating target should not be conducive to the formation
of erroneous inferences concerning the intent of monetary policy by outside
observers.
In making these evaluations, the Subcommittee had the benefit
of a number of analytical papers prepared for it by members of the
staffs of the Board and several Reserve Banks.

Specific studies are

cited whenever their findings are particularly relevant.

A list of all

the papers is provided at the end of this report and copies of these
papers will be supplied by the Subcommittee on request.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-7 Evaluation of Alternative Operating Instruments
1.

Controllability.² Total member bank reserves, total

reserves plus currency, RPD, and RPD less reserves required to support
large certificates of deposit all suffer from the deficiency that they
are difficult, and at times impossible, to control in the short run.
Borrowed reserves are a component of all these measures.

Other things

equal, attempts to change any of these measures will be frustrated in

3/

the short run by an offsetting response of bank borrowing. 3/

An example should make the point: assume that total reserves
are used as the operating target and that they are growing more rapidly
than the FOMC desires.

Under these conditions, the Manager would reduce

the availability of nonborrowed reserves in an attempt to reduce the growth
of total reserves.

Because required reserves are fixed in the short

run, the banking system's first response to the reduced availability of
nonborrowed reserves necessarily would be to borrow more at the discount
4/
window. 4/Thus, total reserves would be little affected in the first
instance by Desk actions, but the mix between borrowed and nonborrowed
reserves would change.

The reduced availability of nonborrowed reserves,

2/ A detailed discussion of the controllability question is provided in
"Alternative Operating Targets for Monetary Policy," by Rudolph Thunberg
and in "On Controlling Monetary Aggregates via Base or Member Bank
Reserve Concepts," by Dennis Starleaf.
3/ In this context, the term "borrowing" will denote adjustment borrowing
by member banks.
4/ Lagged reserve accounting prevents the banking system from adjusting its
required reserves in any statement week. Even if there were contemporaneous
reserve accounting, the banking system would have only a small impact on
its required reserves in any week.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 8 and increased debt to the Federal Reserve, would trigger bank portfolio
adjustments, however, which would raise interest rates and set in
motion a reduction in the growth of deposits and hence in required reserves.
But this reaction takes time.

Over weekly (or at times even monthly)

intervals, the Manager would not be able to hit the target specified by
the FOMC.
Thus, over short time intervals--which is the appropriate
horizon for an operating target--the Desk would often be unable to carry
out a directive specified in terms of an operating target that includes
bank borrowing.

In fact, with lagged reserve accounting,it sometimes

would be impossible to reduce reserves sufficiently to hit the target.
In terms of the control criterion, the preferred alternatives
as the operating target are either nonborrowed reserves or nonborrowed
reserves plus currency (nonborrowed source base).

Except for as-of adjust-

ments, both measures are known with reasonable accuracy with a one-day lag.
Weekly control is subject to errors in projecting other factors affecting
reserves (principally float) and the availability of collateral for adding
reserves.

Relative to other candidates, both nonborrowed reserves and

nonborrowed reserves plus currency could be controlled quite closely,
even on a week-by-week basis.
The total of nonborrowed reserves and currency would be
slightly easier to control than nonborrowed reserves alone.

With a

nonborrowed reserves plus currency target, it usually would not be

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 9 -

necessary for the Desk to react to errors in currency projections.

If

currency unexpectedly rose or fell, nonborrowed reserves would move in
the opposite direction so that the total would tend to remain unchanged.
However, if the Desk were following a nonborrowed reserve target, an
unexpected movement in currency would cause nonborrowed reserves to
deviate from the desired path.

The Manager would learn about this

deviation in currency with a one-day lag, and would act to offset it
5/
in order to stay on the desired nonborrowed reserve path.
The problems of short-term control by the Desk associated
with each of the alternative reserve or monetary base measures except
nonborrowed reserves and nonborrowed reserves plus currency led the
Subcommittee to consider only these latter two as serious alternatives
to RPD as an operating target.
2.

Interest rate implications.

A nonborrowed reserve opera-

ting instrument appears preferable in terms of likely effects on interest rates.

If nonborrowed reserves were the operating target,

shifts in currency would be offset by open market operations and interest rates would not respond to currency movements.

If the target were

nonborrowed reserves plus currency, however, currency shifts would not
elicit an offsetting Desk response because nonborrowed reserves would
move in the opposite direction from currency.

Thus, these changes in

the availability of nonborrowed reserves would produce sharper interest
rate fluctuations than would be the case under a nonborrowed reserves
target.

Available empirical evidence suggests that the superiority of

5/ The concept of currency used in this context includes all currency outside the Treasury and Federal Reserve banks. The currency component of
the money stock includes currency in the hands of the nonbank public,
i.e., currency as defined above less currency in the vaults of all
commercial banks.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 10 nonborrowed reserves over nonborrowed reserves plus currency in terms
of interest rate fluctuations
Infrequently,

however,

is

usually apt to be small in

practice.

6/

unexpected currency movements appear to be large

enough to produce a considerable

impact on the Federal funds rate if

the Desk were instructed to achieve a target consisting of nonborrowed
reserves plus currency.
Pursuit of any reserve or monetary base operating target that
includes member bank borrowing would produce sharper interest rate fluctuations than those measures that exclude borrowing.

The larger money

market reactions would arise because the tendency for borrowing to
offset changes

in nonborrowed reserves would be resisted by the Desk.

Assume that the Desk were following a target that includes bank borrowing,
say total reserves.

If total reserves growth were stronger than desired,

the Desk would respond by reducing the growth in nonborrowed reserves
thereby tending to increase the Federal funds rate.

Banks would respond

to this reduced reserve availability and the increased Federal funds
rate in the first

instance by increasing their borrowing from the Fed,

so that total reserves would tend to return to their earlier value.
The Desk would react again by reducing nonborrowed reserves.

While

the Desk would probably be unsuccessful in achieving its total reserve
target in the short run, the attempt could produce large week-to-week
movements in interest rates.

6/

See "Reserve Aggregate Target Experiment," August 12,
to the Subcommittee by James L. Pierce.

1974 memorandum

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

3.

11 -

Public understanding.

It is reasonable to expect that

current values of broader measures such as total reserves or total
reserves plus currency (source base) on average will move more closely
with current values of the monetary aggregates than will nonborrowed
reserves or nonborrowed reserves plus currency.
broader measures would be preferable
of monetary policy.

In this sense, the

in enhancing public understanding

There are times, however, when the short-term

movements in these broader measures will not accurately reflect the
thrust of policy.

For example, if a decision is made to reduce the

growth in the aggregates, the growth of nonborrowed reserves will slow,
but total reserves will continue to rise for a while because of an
increase in borrowing in the short run.

Only later, after banks are

impelled to reduce deposit growth in order to repay their indebtedness
to the Federal Reserve, will total reserves show a slower growth.

In

those cases, nonborrowed reserve movements would more accurately reflect
the thrust of current policy.
However, the fact that occasionally banks have to be pushed
much further into or out of debt to the Federal Reserve in order to
impel a timely change in their deposit-creating behavior creates a
problem of public perception.

At times,

the Desk would have to be

told to strive for a change in a nonborrowed reserve

target which in

percentage terms would be much greater than the percentage change
desired in overall deposits.

To the unsophisticated reader of the

FOMC policy record, such percentage changes

in nonborrowed reserve

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-

12 -

targets would exaggerate the intended extent of monetary policy changes.
This effect could presumably be forestalled to some degree by stating
FOMC targets for nonborrowed reserves in terms of dollar levels or
dollar changes rather than annualized percentage rates of change.
The more global measures such as total reserves or total
reserves plus currency (the source base) will tend on average to
move more closely with the monetary aggregates.

Because the source

base includes currency--a relatively large and stable component of
M1 and M 2 --it should show percentage changes most closely paralleling
the monetary aggregates.

It is important to recall that while these

global measures usually create fewer interpretation problems for the public,
they create the greatest control problems for the Desk.

Table I

shows the growth in the various candidates for the operating target
along with the growth in the monetary aggregates.

The greater similar-

ity between the percentage changes in deposit aggregates and those in
the measures that include currency can be discerned readily from the
7/
table.
On the other hand, there may be some difficulty in persuading
the public that the use of an operating target that includes both
currency and reserve balances can improve control over the broader
deposit aggregates.

The a priori logic of such a relationship is

somewhat disconcerting, since currency in the hands of the non-bank
public does not support deposit growth.

Indeed, since currency in

effect carries a 100 per cent reserve requirement, and demand deposits
less than a 20 per cent reserve requirement, shifts in the public's
7/

The source base would have caused interpretation problems in the second
half of 1974 because of the rapid rise of currency relative to demand
deposits in the second half of the year.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-

13

-

money holdings from demand deposits to currency should absorb reserves
and greatly restrict deposit growth.

That the relationship between

offsetting movements in currency and reserve balances turns out
usually not to contract deposits (due to such factors as changes in
deposit composition) is an empirical fact in the real world, but it
may not be easy to explain to the public.
4.

Predictability.

It was expected that the broader reserve

or monetary base measures, such as total reserves, total reserves plus
currency or RPD would be more closely related to the monetary aggregates
than would the more narrowly defined nonborrowed reserve measures.
That is, it was expected that the multiplier relationship between the
more inclusive operating targets and the aggregates would be more
predictable. The staff's empirical results support this expectation; the
broader, more difficult to control reserve measures, such as RPD and
total reserves, give better predictions of the monetary aggregates than
do the narrower, more controllable measures, such as nonborrowed reserves
8/
and nonborrowed RPD.
The empirical evidence was examined in several different ways.
The most successful effort in terms of predicting M 1 and M 2 was one in

8/ A detailed discussion of the analysis is provided in the revised version
of "Reserve Measures as Operating Variables of Monetary Policy: an
Empirical Analysis" by Daniel Laufenberg and in "Money Stock Control:
an Aggregate Approach," by Albert Burger.
9/

The staff's empirical work was directed primarily toward establishing
a ranking of the various potential operating targets in terms of their
ability to predict the monetary aggregates. With additional work, the
staff, could, no doubt, increase the precision with which any one operating target predicts movements in the monetary aggregates. This further
research would be conducted if the FOMC selected one of the potential
candidates as its operating target.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 14 which both current and lagged changes in the operating target were
related directly to changes in M 1 and M 2 by regression analysis. 10/
As shown in Tables II and III, there is remarkably little
difference,within the sample period, among the error performances
11/
of the regressions for any of the operating target measures.
However,
the error statistics indicate that for predicting M 1 and M 2 even one
month into the future, sizable errors were made by using any of the
measures.
Tables IV and V show the errors in predicting M1 and M 2 made
by the regression equations for the twelve months oustide the sample
period.

These results probably give the best measure of the reliability

of the relationships because they are roughly the equivalent of forecasts.
Outside the sample period there are distinct differences among the
various operating targets in their ability to predict

M1 and M 2 .

RPD

and total reserves gave the closest predictions of the monetary aggregates during 1974.

Total reserves plus currency (the source base)

performed relatively poorly during the period because of the large shifts
into currency that occurred in 1974.

None of operating targets that

exclude member bank borrowing performed as well as total reserves on
RPD.

However, nonborrowed RPD and nonborrowed reserves did provide

fairly reliable predictions of M1 and M 2 .
The results for 1974 indicate that there is a trade off between

10/In these regressions all reserve measures were adjusted for changes in
legal reserve requirements. The monetary base measures were not adjusted
for changes in required reserves associated with changes in deposit mix.
ll/Only the errors for the last year of the 1969-73 sample are shown. The
performance of the regressions over the entire period was quite similar
to that of 1973.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 15 the controllability of the operating target on the one hand and the
stability of its relationship to the monetary aggregates on the other.
The controllability criterion favors nonborrowed reserves and nonborrowed
reserves plus currency.
total reserves.

The predictability criterion favors RPD or

The use of nonborrowed reserves appears to offer a

reasonable balance between the two conflicting criteria.

Nonborrowed

reserves are highly controllable by the Desk and the relationship of NBR
to the monetary aggregates is fairly close--although variations in
member bank borrowing do weaken the relationship.
The results in both the estimation period--1969 to 1973--and
the forecast period for 1974 indicate that the FOMC should clearly
distinguish between (a) nonborrowed reserves as an operating target for
the Desk, and (b) a broader reserve measure such as total reserves which,
because of its closer relationship to the monetary aggregates, can be
used to judge whether the goals with respect to the monetary aggregates
are being achieved.

Because of this distinction, it is important that

the projected behavior of member bank borrowing during the inter-meeting
period be made explicit so that the behavior of actual relative to
projected total reserves can be monitored.

The appendix table illustrates

the borrowing projections for three bluebook alternatives.
It is important to note, however, that monthly multiplier errors
for nonborrowed reserves tend to be offset from month to month, so control
12/

of the monetary aggregates should be fairly close over a calendar quarter. 12/
The errors for nonborrowed reserves over various time horizons are shown in

12/This offsetting behavior of successive errors also holds true for other
reserve and monetary base measures. For additional supporting evidence,
see Albert Burger, "Money Stock Control: An Aggregate Approach."

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-

Table VI.

16 -

This evidence suggests that if the growth in the aggregates is

stronger than expected in a particular month, given the growth in nonborrowed reserves, it is likely that the growth in the aggregates will be
weaker than expected in subsequent months.

This finding implies it

is preferable for the Desk to stay on the established reserve path since
short-run deviations in

the monetary aggregates from their expected values

tend to be self-correcting.
In evaluating these results, it is important to keep several
factors in mind.

First, the size of the errors highlights the fact that

adoption of any single reserve measure as an operating target probably
would not result in a marked improvement in the accuracy of control over
the aggregates in the short run.

The errors obtained by using the

regression technique are fairly close to those that have been experienced
recently in bluebook projections.

But, it is possible that the errors

indicated in the statistical results could be decreased by adjusting the
estimates to reflect judgmental factors in much the same way as is done
currently in preparing the bluebook.

However, it is important to realize

that control over the monetary aggregates will be worsened whenever the
range of tolerance for the Federal funds rate is too narrow to allow the
appropriate movements in the operating target.

The Subcommittee has not yet

carried out studies far enough to determine whether or not it should
recommend adjustments in the operating constraints on the Federal funds rate.
This determination

will come in phase II of the Subcommittee's work.

Finally, it should be noted that there are technical reasons for
suspecting that the statistical results may understate the errors in
13/
controlling the aggregates through a reserve operating target.
13/ For a more detailed discussion, see "Interim Staff Report to the Subcommittee on the Directive," June 12, 1974 memorandum by James L.
Pierce and John H. Kalchbrenner.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-

17 -

These results were obtained from data generated during a period in
which a reserve measure was not used exclusively as the operating
target.

The actual short-run implementation of monetary policy was

conducted in terms of operations on both RPD and the Federal funds
rate, and the intermediate targets themselves were given weight when
the multipliers appeared to be in error.
Under these circumstances, whenever the funds rate approached
the limits of its allowable range, the Manager would provide or withdraw
a sufficient volume of reserves to maintain the funds rate within the
range.

This process permitted the monetary aggregates to expand or

contract along with increases or decreases in the demand for money.
Thus, in part, reserves were reacting to the growth in the aggregates
rather than the aggregates responding to reserves.

The results indicate

the closeness of the relationships in the data, but do not prove the
direction of causation.

On these grounds, actual use of these measures

as operating targets could yield greater errors for the monetary aggregates than the empirical evidence indicates.
Summary of Evaluation Results
The evaluation of each of the alternative operating targets
suggests the following conclusions:
1.

Controllability:

nonborrowed reserves plus currency

or nonborrowed reserves are the preferred targets.
2.

Interest rate variability: an intermediate target that
excludes member bank borrowing is to be preferred.
Nonborrowed reserves is the best on this score, but
apparently only marginally so.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-

3.

18 -

Public understanding: a broad measure such as total
reserves or the monetary base is preferable.

4.

Predictability: the lowest errors in predicting

M

and M 2 were achieved using RPD or total reserves;
nonborrowed reserves performed quite well.

However,

all of the statistical results should be received with
considerable caution.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 19 Recommendations
The Subcommittee recommends that the FOMC move toward replacing
RPD with nonborrowed reserves (NBR) as its short-term quantitative
operating target.

The nonborrowed reserves measure was preferable on

two of the four evaluation criteria--controllability and interest rate
variability.

Nonborrowed reserves did not perform as well as RPD or

total reserves in terms of predicting the monetary aggregates but it did
a creditable job, particularly as the prediction errors tended to be
offsetting.

Because of the great importance that the Subcommittee

attaches to specifying a target for the Manager that he can control
between FOMC meetings without producing large disturbances in the money
market, we are willing to recommend NBR as the operating target even
though this measure does not produce the smallest monthly prediction errors
for the monetary aggregates.
Total reserves and RPD, which performed highest on the predictability criterion, suffer from the flaw that they are virtually
impossible to control month by month because of the offsetting reaction
of member bank borrowing in response to open market operations.

Moreover,

RPD, and to a lesser degree nonborrowed RPD, is particularly difficult to control
by the Desk because the future mix of deposits is highly uncertain.
To more nearly satisfy the criterion of public understanding,
where NBR does not score highly, the Subcommittee recommends that staff
materials, and in some degree the record of FOMC actions, include a statement of the principal assumptions and projections concerning borrowing,
excess reserves and deposit mix that underlie the multiplier relationship

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 20 -

between NBR and the monetary aggregates.

The availability of this informa-

tion would generally increase public understanding of current monetary
policy, and reduce the likelihood of misinterpretation when NBR moves in
a direction counter to the thrust of monetary policy.
The Subcommittee believes that a change from RPD to NBR is a
natural, understandable progression.

Furthermore, adoption of NBR as

the operating target does not preclude the addition of currency to the
target at a later date (i.e., a switch from nonborrowed reserves to the
nonborrowed source base) should experience indicate that this further
evolution is desirable.
The Subcommittee also recommends that the path for the NBR
target only be defined for the interval between FOMC meetings.

The

current procedure involves the specification of moving two-month paths
for both the intermediate targets M1 and M 2,and the operating target RPD.
This makes it difficult for the FOMC to appraise how well its objectives
are being achieved monthly by blurring the distinction between errors in
hitting the target and policy-directed changes in the target itself from
month to month.

Adoption of the interval between meetings as the target

period would allow this distinction to be observed.

Because the Manager

could hit a NBR target with reasonable accuracy, there is no reason to
use the moving two-month horizon for the operating target.

The NBR

target should be described as the dollar change from the previous intrameeting period in the level of the target to be attained on average over

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 21 -

the next four or five week interval.

In order to allow for inter-

ferences from a variety of factors, it is suggested that the instructions
14/

include a tolerable range of error of ± $50 million. 1 4 /

As shown in Table VI, evidence compiled by the staff suggests
that over time errors in the relationship between nonborrowed reserves
and the monetary aggregates tend to be offsetting.

Thus, it does not

appear that it would be productive to "look through" nonborrowed reserves
to the aggregates.

For this reason, the Subcommittee recommends that

the Manager be instructed not to make adjustments for apparent multiplier
errors in the interval between meetings but rather to adhere to the
assigned nonborrowed reserve path provided that the funds rate remains
within its range of tolerance.
However, the Manager should be instructed to consult with
the Chairman if it becomes apparent that the NBR target cannot be achieved
within the established Federal Funds rate constraint.

In addition, when

sizable, sustained and apparently explainable deviations in the assumed
multiplier relationships between NBR and the monetary aggregates develop
between meetings, there should be provision for the Manager to consult
with the Chairman concerning possible adjustment of the target.

For

example, when there is a sustained shift in bank attitudes toward adjustment borrowing, it would become necessary to modify the nonborrowed
reserve path.

Such a shift would be reflected in the behavior of total

14/ This figure, it should be noted, represents a tolerance range around
a 4 or 5 week average. Errors in projections of reserve factors may
be larger than $50 million in any given week, but these errors will tend
to be offsetting over a longer period. At the current level of nonborrowed reserves, a tolerance of ± $50 million represents an annual
rate of change in a range of a little over 3 per cent. For a more
extended discussion of these projection errors, see "Preliminary
Investigations into Nonborrowed Reserve Projection Errors," November
26, 1974 memorandum by Sheila Tschinkel.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

- 22 reserves.

Since total reserves bear a tighter relationship to the

monetary aggregates than do nonborrowed reserves, a sustained movement
in total reserves relative to expectations should be taken as an indication that some adjustment may be required in the NBR path.
A large volume of emergency borrowing would also require
adjustment in the NBR path.

In this case, the adjustments in the

multiplier and hence in NBR would depend upon reactions by the emergency
bank and other banks to the situation that develops, with the extent of
portfolio adjustments and shifts in banks' demands for free reserves
governing the size of adjustment needed in NBR.

In general, the adjust-

ment of the NBR path does not lend itself to a predetermined formula but
rather would have to be determined in light of prevailing circumstances.
The possibility of adopting an interest rate target or money
market condition as either the sole or supplementary operating target
has not been excluded by the Subcommittee.

The results of these

alternatives relative to the reserve measures will be evaluated in stage
II of the Subcommittee's investigation.
Until such time as the FOMC acts finally on the substantive
recommendations contained herein, the Subcommittee recommends NBR
be added as a "shadow" target to be included in
for FOMC use on a continuing basis.

the materials prepared

It is felt that the process of

tracking the proposed alternative target will assist the FOMC in
evaluating the desirability of adopting NBR in place of RPD; further,
it will smooth the transition from one instrument to the other if that
should be the Committee's final decision.

An example of the manner in

which these materials would be presented is included as an appendix
to this report.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

APPENDIX

Paragraph on Nonborrowed Reserve Target
(as it might have appeared in Blue
Book for November 19 meeting)
The expected levels and changes in nonborrowed reserves
(NBR) are shown in the table below for the three policy alternatives,
along with other related measures.

Under alternative B--which assumes

that money market conditions are about unchanged from those recently
prevailing--NBR is indicated to increase about $470 million, seasonally
adjusted and bank borrowing is expected toremain about $215 million
below the average of the past four weeks.
in NBR is targeted under alternative A.

A more substantial increase
Under alternative A, in view

of the expected slightly further easing in the Federal funds rate, and
assuming no change in the discount rate, member bank borrowing is expected
to drop over the next four weeks to $875 million on average.

This drop

in borrowing would offset about half of the expansion in nonborrowed
reserves under alternative A, and total reserves are expected to show
moderate growth over the period on average.

The monetary base, which

includes currency in circulation as well as total reserves, would
be expected to show a larger increase, reflecting the steady expansion
of currency.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Average Nonborrowed Reserves and Relate d Measures
($ million)

4 weeks ending
November 20
ALT. A

4 weeks ending
December 18
ALT
ALT. B
(Levels)

C

35,635

36, 290

36,105

35,935

1,215

875

1,000

1,125

Total reserves
(1+2)

36,850

37,165

37,105

37,060

Currency outside
banks ¹

69,330

69,765

69,765

69,765

6,180

106,930

106,870

106,825

Nonborrowed reserves

Member bank borrowings

Monetary base

(3+4)

ALT. A

ALT.

C

655

470

300

-340

-215

-90

Total reserves (1+2)

315

255

210

Currency outside
banks ¹

435

435

435

Monetary base (3+4)

750

690

645

Nonborrowed reserves
Member bank borrowing

¹

ALT. B
(Changes)

Currency outside member banks includes currency held in the vaults of
nonmember banks.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Papers Prepared for Improvements in the Directive: Stage I
Burger, Albert, "Money Stock Control: An Aggregate Approach,"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
Laufenberg, Daniel, "Reserve Measures as Operating Variables of
Monetary Policy: An Empirical Analysis," Board staff.
Revised version forthcoming.
___________,

"Report: Nonborrowed Reserves Adjusted," Board

staff.
Pierce, James L.,
___________,

"Reserve Aggregate Target Experiment," Board staff.
and Kalchbrenner, "Interim Staff Report to the

Subcommittee on the Directive," Board staff and Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago.
Starleaf, Dennis, "On Controlling Monetary Aggregates via Base or
Member Bank Reserve Concepts," Board staff and Iowa State University.
Thunberg, Rudolph, "Alternative Operating Targets for Monetary Policy,"
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
Table Ia
Actual One-Month Percentage Change
at Annual Rates

Total
Reserves

Nonborrowed
Reserves

Source
Base

Nonborrowed
Source Base

RPD

RPD Less
Reserves
Against Large CDs

Nonborrowed
RPD

Nonborrowed RPD
Less Reserves
Against Large CDs

1973
5.2
4.7
0.5
6.5
13.4
13.7
3.6
-0.5
-1.4
4.1
12.6
9.4

9.4
7.0
5.4
7.8
12.0
11.7
5.2
7.0
4.5
9.5
12.0
10.6

27.3
-18.7
10.3
12.5
6.0
1.1
27.0
-4.3
9.4
11.3
-3.6
28.0

23.9
-36.2
1.6
17.8
1.2
0.8
24.6
-12.5
21.8
25.9
-0.8
32.5

11.3
2.9
11.5
8.5
4.6
7.1
7.3
0.3
5.2
9.6
10.3
9.5

10.0
-2.5
8.8
10.0
3.1
7.2
6.2
-2.3
9.1
14.3
11.4
10.8

14.7
-0.7
8.1
10.5
8.1
16.8
16.6
11.4
14.0
1.8

Jan. -2.7
Feb.
9.7
Mar.
9.2
6.1
Apr.
4.3
May
10.4
June
2.1
July
0.9
Aug.
Sept. 1.7
4.7
Oct.
6.8
Nov.

6.9
11.1
9.7
8.0
4.5
11.2
5.2
5.0

32.6
-23.6
-4.7
31.1.
21.2
7.1
21.7
-4.3
7.1
-1.8
-1.6
16.0

42.6
-29.2
-9.2
17.2
-7.7
-7.1
13.1
49.6
17.6
34.3

8.9
6.6
5.9
13.5
6.5
6.7
4.2
3.4
8.2
8.4
16.1
11.8

11.9
5.0
4.1
9.6
-3.2
2.0
0.8
3.0
9.2
25.2
22.6

17.6

8.7

19.7

-7.7

-4.2

Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

8.9

12.4
-6.1
-18.7
16.3
4.2
13.7
24.4
16.2
3.6
5.7
5.9
14.3

10.5
19.1
-1.4
16.1
3.1
17.5
13.4
3.5
27.7
16.4
-0.3
12.9

5.9
2.9
8.2
19.1
21.5
15.7
8.6
10.8
7.8
-1.3
-3.0
6.4

-1.1
-4.0
6.7
10.5
1.8
3.4
3.1
4.1
2.7
3.2
6.9
9.3

15.4
2.3
3.9
4.0
-9.5
1.2
-1.7
10.6
10.6
53.3
17.2
25.4

-3.6

7.8
-26.4
-13.7
5.5
-1.8
14.3
21.4
7.6
18.2
23.1
9.9
19.2

1974

3.2

Dec.

2.1

8.5
9.7
2.5

1975
Jan.

-8.9

3.1

-5.9
9.7

0

-11.7

11.5

9.6

-10.2
1.7
-7.3
-35.3
-14.9
-9.9
3.0
5.5
70.4
31.5
31.7
1.4

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
Table Ib

Actual Two-Month Percentage Change
at Annual Rates
NonM
1

Nonborrowed
Base
Source

RPD Less
Reserves

Nonborrowed
RPD

Nonborrowed RPD
Less Reserves
Against Large CDs

M2

Total
borrowed Source
ReservesReserves
Base

11.0
8.2
6.2
6.6
9.9
11.9
8.5
6.1
5.8
7.0
10.8
11.3

22.2
4.3
4.2
11.4
9.3
3.6
14.1
11.4
2.6
10.4
3.9
12.2

12.2
-6.2
-17.3
9.7
9.5
1.0
12.7
6.1
4.7
23.9
12.6
15.9

10.2
7.1
7.2
10.0
6.6
5.9
7.2
3.8
2.7
7.4
10.0
9.9

6.8
3.7
3.2
9.5
6.6
5.1
6.7
2.0
3.4
11.8
12.9
11.1

13.2
7.0
3.7
9.3
9.3
12.5
16.7
14.0
12.7
7.9
-0.9
2.7

10.2
3.2
-12.4
-1.2
10.3
9.0
19.1
20.3
9.9
4.7
5.8
10.1

2.3
14.8
8.9
7.4
9.6
10.3
15.5
8.5
15.6
22.1
8.1
6.3

-20.0
4.1
1.9
6.3
17.9
14.5
12.9
20.7
16.5
14.6

8.8
9.0
10.4
8.9
6.3
7.9
8.2
5.1
4.1

37.6
6.7
-19.2
4.0
4.8
-7.4
3.0
3.6
1.9
29.7
33.6
26.0

9.2
7.7
6.2
9.7
10.1

9.1
6.1

30.3
4.5
14.2
13.2
26.2
14.2
14.4
8.7
1.4
2.7
-1.7
7.2

5.4
3.8
5.8
8.3
12.3
14.1

11.4
8.5
4.5
6.8
3.2
-0.6
1.4
1.9
6.1
17.3
24.1
20.3

7.5
4.4
5.6
13.7
20.3
18.6
12.2
9.7
9.3
3.3
-2.2
1.7

6.6
-2.6
1.4
8.6
6.2
2.6
3.2
3.6
3.4
3.0
5.1
8.1

14.2
8.9
3.1
4.0
-2.8
-4.2
-0.2
4.5
10.6
32.0
35.3
21.3

14.4
-0.3
-4.3
-2.8
-21.3
-25.1
-12.4
-3.5
4.3
38.0
51.0
31.6

2.8

12.4

27.0

2.0

6.7

3.2

-1.2

18.5

16.6

RPD

Against Target CDs

1973
Jan.
9.7
Feb.
5.0
Mar.
2.6
Apr.
3.5
May 10.0
June 13.6
July 8.7
Aug.
1.6
Sept.-1. 0
Oct.
1.4
Nov.
8.4
Dec. 11.0

-1.2
-9.3

1974
Jan. 3.4
Feb. 3.5
Mar. 9.5
Apr. 7.7
5.2
May
June 7.4
July 6.3
Aug. 1.5
Sept. 1.3
Oct.
3.2
Nov.
5.8
Dec.
4.5

5.9

6.6

1975
Jan.

-3.4

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Table II
First Differences Regression Procedure
(billions of dollars)
Errors in Estimating M
Within Final Year of Sample Period

Nonborrowed

Composite
Date

Total
Reserves

Source
Base

RPD less
CDs

Nonborrowed
Reserves

Nonborrowed
Source Base

Nonborrowed
RPD

Nonborrowed
RPD less CD

-0.502
-0.564
-0.760
0.717
0.814
1.295
-0.319
-1.173
-0.621
0.195
2.357
1.424

-0.457
-0.648
-0.560
1.015
1.005
1.548
-0.133
-0.851
-0.421
0.537
2.295
1.163

0.058
-0.319
-0.662
1.135
0.746
1.594
-0.011
-1.292
-0.765
0.121
1.550
1.211

-0.321
-0.090
-0.645
0.456
0.235
0.968
-0.370
-1.171
-0.854
-0.321
1.410
0.788

0.032
-0.468
-0.485
0.790
0.782
1.442
-0.205
-1.080
-0.559
-0.136
1.995
1.397

0.072
-0.469
-0.385
0.996
0.917
1.598
-0.080
-0.859
-0.414
0.100
1.991
1.192

.895

.886

RPD

1973
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June

July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

MAE

-0.382
-0. 710
-1.011
1.025
0.716
1.560
0.031
-1.193
-0.580
0.181
1.988
1.330

.892

-0.675
-0.573
-1.206
0.372
0.549
0.895
-0.319
-1.048
-0.572
0.045
1.947
0.847

.754

.789

.636

.781

.756

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Table III
First Differences Regression Procedure
(billions of dollars)
Errors in Estimating M
2
Within Final Year of Sample Period

Composite

Date

Total
Reserves

Source
Base

Nonborrowed

RPD

RPD less
CDs

Nonborrowed
Reserves

Nonborrowed
Source Base

Nonborrowed
RPD

Nonborrowed
RPD less CDs

1973
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

MAE

-0.501
-0.406
-0.887
1.305
1.217
1.111
-1.126
-0.462
-0.094
1.129
2.641
2.428

-0.835
-0.280
-0.908
0.007
0.473
-0.342
-1.250
-0.039
0.255
1.115
2.218
0.959

-0.848
-0.624
-0.429
1.636
1.320
0.175
-1.485
-0.695
-0.473
1.411
3.089
2.532

-0.184
-0.588
0.174
2.271
2.188
1.191
-0.593
0.498
0.582
2.505
3.325
1.944

1.337
0.965
0.379
1.780
1.163
1.190
-1.112
-0.415
-0.683
0.683
1.125
1.893

0.341
1.061
0.239
0.430
-0.039
-0.333
-1.325
-0.046
-0.562
0.281
0.955
0.669

0.850
0.360
0.405
2.009
1.365
0.553
-1.221
-0.391
-0.602
0.899
1.899
2.084

1.166
0.081
0.539
2.259
1.980
1.250
-0.426
0.460
0.482
1.664
2.417
1.798
1.210

1.109
1.109

1.337

1.060

1.052

1.226

.523

.723
.723

1.337

1.060

.523

1.052

1.210

1.226

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Table IV
First Differences Regression Procedure
(billions of dollars)
Errors In Estimating M
Outside Sample Period

Composite

Date

Total

Source

Reserves

Base

-1.696
-0.197
0.520
0.513
-2.046
0.574
-0.525
-1.251
-0.163
-0.465
0.210
-0.176

-2.416
-0.269
0.162
-0.988
-2.894
0.190
-0.727
-1.320
-0.541
-1.341
-0.550
-1.857

.695

1.104

Nonborrowed

RPD

RPD less
CDs

Nonborrowed
Reserves

Nonborrowed
Source Base

Nonborrowed
RPD

Nonborrowed
RPD less CDs

-2.451
-0.118
0.785
0.273
-1.512
1.624
0.125
-0.695
-0.283
-0.898
0.023
-0.425

-1.983
-0.580
0.508
0.988
-1.333
1.661
0.396
-0.859
-0.102
-0.678
-0.781
-1.594

-2.865
-0.755
0.306
-0.009
-1.941
-1.260
0.090
-0.976
-0.473
-0.294
-1.956
-3.287

-2.152
-0.270
0 762
0.515
-1.266
1.732
0.201
-0.856
-0.017
-1.192
-0.596
-0.683

-2.450
-0.337
0.835
0.747
-0.786
2.259
0.439
-0.667
-0.088
-1.474
-1.090
-0.952

.956

1.351

.854

1.010

1974
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July

Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

MAE

-2.003
-0.027
0.648
-0.140
-2.247
0.916
-0.133
-0.984
-0.120
-0.341
0.664
-0.087

.692

.768

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Table V
First Differences Regression Procedure
(billions of dollars)
Errors in Estimating M2
Outside Sample Period

Composite
Date

Total

Source

Reserves

Base

-0.208
1.310
1.421
0.210
-4.833
-1.181
-2.242
-1.693
-0.894
0.191
1.166
-1.359

-1.320
0.701
-0.043
-2.610
-6.048
-1.284
-1.732
-1.778
-1.779
-2.209
-1.442
-5.579

1.392

2.210

Nonborrowed
RPD less
CDs

Nonborrowed
Reserves

Nonborrowed
Source Base

Nonborrowed
RPD

Nonborrowed
RPD less CDs

0.271
1.448
0.779
-0.383
-4.320
-0.233
-1.125
-1.371
-0.963
0.084
1.277
-1.142

-1.176
0.980
1.038
0.651
-2.196
2.448
0.689
-0.071
-0.898
-0.858
-0.423
-2.792

-1.105
0.172
1.212
2.320
-1.369
2.906
0.850
-0.413
-0.713
-1.546
-3.268
-5.961

-2.374
-0.208
0.095
-0.335
-3.202
1.661
0.395
-0.771
-1.676
-4.397
-5.142
-9.319

-0.506
0.713
0.769
1.377
-1.420
2.865
0.946
-0.356
-0.759
-1.426
-2.262
-4.517

-1.079
0.606
0.981
1.556
-0.610
4.053
1.700
0.183
-0.563
-1.504
-2.636
-4.437

1.116

1.185

1.820

2.465

1.494

1.659

RPD

1974
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

MAE

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
Table VI
Average Errors in Predicting Change in M1 Using Nonborrowed Reserves
Regression Equation: Outside Sample Period

1974

Single
Month

2-month
Average

3-month
Average

4-month
Average

5-month
Average

6-month
Average

7-month
Average

January

-1.983

February

-0.580

-1.282

March

0.508

-0.036

-0.685

April

0.988

0.748

0.305

-0.267

May

-1.333

-0.172

0.054

-0.104

-0.480

June

1.661

0.164

0.439

0.456

0.249

-0.123

July

0.396

1.028

0.241

0.428

0.444

0.273

-0.049

August

-0.859

-0.232

0.399

-0.034

0.171

0.227

0.112

September

-0.102

-0.480

-0.188

0.274

-0.047

0.125

0.180

October

-0.678

-0.390

-0.546

-0.311

0.084

-0.152

0.010

November

-0.781

-0.730

0.520

-0.605

-0.405

-0.060

-0.242

December

-1.594

-1.188

-1.018

-0.789

-0.803

-0.603

-0.280

1974
August

8-month

9-month

10-month

11-month

12-month

Average

Average

Average

Average

Average

-0.150

September

0.085

-0.145

October

0.073

0.000

-0.198

November

-0.088

-0.022

-0.078

-0.251

December

-0.411

-0.256

-0.179

-0.216

-0.363

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
BOARD OF GOVERNORS
OF THE

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Office Correspondence
To

Subcommittee on the Directive

From James L. Pierce

Date
Subject:

March 7,1975

Revisions in

the empirical

results for "Improvements in the
Directive Stage I"

It has recently developed that errors were made in the
construction of the reserve series specially constructed for the purpose
of the empirical research for the first stage report of the Subcommittee
on the Directive.

These errors do not bring into question the reserve

series presented to the FOMC in the bluebook and other sources.
The errors in these special series have been corrected
and the empirical work redone.

The new results indicated that non-

borrowed reserves is not as dominant as we previously thought.
In order to provide the necessary basis for reviewing the
entire first stage report, all of the regressions were re-estimated using
data supplied by the Banking Section or taken directly from published
sources.

The period of study was extended to cover all of 1974.

First,

it was necessary to determine whether or not the first difference regression

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
- 2-

approach was superior to the naive multiplier or the moving average multiplier
approaches using the most recent correct data.

Re-estimation of the relation-

ships between money, narrowly and broadly defined, and each of the alternative
reserve measures used in the report indicated that the first difference
approach is the superior method as before.
Second, using the new first difference regression approach
results, it was necessary to see if there was a change in the rankings of
reserve measures by the degree to which they "explained" money using the
revised and corrected data.
The mean absolute errors in predicting changes in M1 are shown
below for the results in the current Subcommittee report and the revised
results.

The complete revised results are included as Table 1.1 in the

appendix.

Mean Absolute Errors in
Predicting Change in M1
(Last Year of the Sample Period-1973)

Original

Revised

Total
Source
Reserves Base RPD
.927
.759
.912

.892

.754

.895

RPD
less CD
.930

.886

Nonborrowed Nonborrowed Nonborrowed Nonborrowed
Reserves
Source Base
RPD
RPD less CD
.784
.811
.660
.793

.789

.636

.781

.756

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
-3-

From these results, it is apparent that the original expectation
that broader reserve measures would be more closely related to money than
narrower measures is not confirmed in either set of results.

Within the

sample period, the lowest errors for 1973 were achieved using the
nonborrowed source base and the source base.

RPD and Total Reserves rank

toward the bottom, with nonborrowed reserves ranking in the middle.
However, there were substantial changes in the rankings of the
mean absolute errors associated with the alternative reserve measures
outside the sample period.

In the current report, the data outside the

sample ended in August, 1974, while the entire year is included in the
revised analysis. This information is shown below, and the complete results
are included as Table 1.2 in the appendix.
Mean Absolute Errors in
Predicting Changes in Ml
(Outside of the Sample Period)
Total
Source
Reserves Base
RPD
Original
Revised

.903
.695

1.033
1.104

RPD
Nonborrowed Nonborrowed
less CDs Reserves
Source Base

.937 .964
.692 .768

.827
.956

.858
1.351

Nonborrowed
rrowed
RPD less Cds

Nonborrowed
RPD
.864
.854

.871
1.010

In the original report the results outside the sample period
favored the four nonborrowed measures.

Nonborrowed reserves and the non-

borrowed source base had the lowest errors.

In the revised results, the

broader measures dominate with the exception of the source base.

RPD and

total reserves have the lowest errors, and the two base measures rank at
the bottom.

Nonborrowed reserves, formerly with the smallest error, now

ranks fifth.

Furthermore, the difference between the smallest and the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
-4-

largest error is more pronounced in the revised results.
While not quite as large, there were similar changes between
the original and the revised results in terms of the accuracy of predicting
M2.

The mean absolute errors for the last year of the sample period (1973)

are shown below and the complete results are in Table 2.1 in the appendix.
Mean Absolute Errors in
Predicting Changes in M2
(Last Year of the Sample Period-1973)
Total
Source
Reserves Base
Original
Revised

1.135
1.109

.928
.723

RPD
1.226
1.226

Nonborrowed
RPD
less CDs Reserves
1.225
1.337

.951
1.060

Nonborrowed Nonborrowed Nonborrowed
Source Base
RPD
RPD less CDs
.600
.523

1.016
1.052

1.100
1.210

A comparison of the results for predicting M2 within the sample
period indicates that there were only minor changes in ranking of the
various reserve measures between the original and revised estimates.

In the

original estimates, the two monetary base measures yielded the best prediction
results.

This pattern is sustained in the revised estimates, and the

errors are reduced substantially.

As in the original results, RPD measures

ranked lowest.

The comparable figures for M2 prediction outside the sample period
are shown below, and in complete form as Table 2.2 of the appendix.

As in

the case of Ml, the revised results include all of 1974 while the original
data were through August only.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
-5-

Mean Absolute Errors in
Predicting Changes in M2
(Outside of the Sample Period)
Total
Source
Reserves Base
Original
Revised

1.796
1.392

1.495
2.210

RPD
2.001
1.116

RPD
Nonborrowed Nonborrowed Nonborrowed Nonborrowed
less CDs Reserves
Source Base
RPD
RPD less CDs
1.326
1.820

1.485
1.185

Outside the sample

1.078
2.465

1.277
1.494

1.319
1.659

period, the two base measures ranked lowest

in the revised estimates,two of the RPD measures had the smallest errors,
and the rank of total reserves changed from 7 to 3.

The dispersion of the

errors increasedacross the eight measures for the revised estimates and a
longer period outside the sample.

In the original estimates, the nonborrowed

source base ranked first and RPD last.

In the revised estimates this order

is reversed.
Summary
For the prediction of Ml, within the sample period, the nonborrowed
source base had the lowest mean absolute error in the revised (and original)
estimates.

Outside the sample period, the revised estimates indicate that

RPD (followed closely by total reserves) had the lowest errors.
For the prediction of M2, the revised estimates indicate that the
nonborrowed source base had the lowest error within the sample period (as in
the original results).

But, in the period outside the sample, the lowest

error was again achieved using RPD.
As in the original analysis, the first difference regression
approach proved superior to either the naive multiplier or the moving average
multiplier approach.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021
-6-

In the existing Subcommittee report, it is noted that the
lowest errors in predicting M1 were achieved using nonborrowed reserves
and the lowest errors for predicting M2 were achieved using the nonborrowed
source base.

The revised results indicate that the preferred variable for

predicting Ml is RPD (or total reserves), and the preferred variable for
predicting M2 is also RPD.

In the existing report, the results indicated

that the most easily controlled reserve measures were also the best
predictors of Ml and M2.

In the revised results, the more easily controlled

reserve measures rank fairly low in predictability, and the reserve
measures that are more difficult to control rank highest.

The choice of

the preferred reserve variable as an operating target thereby becomes more
difficult.