View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS

Date:

March 9, 2009

To:

Federal Open Market Committee

From:

Eileen Mauskopf and David Reifschneider1

Subject: Economic Effects of Large-Scale Purchases of Long-term Treasury Securities
and Agency Debt and MBS

Summary
As has been discussed in several recent reports and presentations to the FOMC, largescale asset purchases (LSAP) of long-term Treasury securities and agency debt and MBS
provide a potential means of supplying additional monetary stimulus now that the federal
funds rate has effectively fallen to zero. This memo provides additional background
information on the economics underlying such LSAP programs; a forthcoming memo by
Gagnon, Lucca, McCarthy and Roush will provide information on other aspects of largescale asset purchases, including issues related to exit strategies.
Our main conclusions for the macroeconomic effects of a LSAP program are as follows:
•	 The efficacy of an LSAP program depends importantly on its ability to contribute to
an improvement in overall financial conditions, thereby boosting demand throughout
the economy. If the program were to lower interest rates and boost spending in only
one sector, the net effect on economic activity would be notably smaller.
•	 Model simulations suggest that a $1 trillion LSAP program could boost the level of
real GDP about 2 percent after several years, and appreciably more if the program
substantially lifted house prices. Model simulations also suggest that the amount of
economic stimulus provided by the program depends more on the overall volume of
asset purchases than on the specific asset market targeted.
•	 The current heightened level of economic uncertainty, coupled with unusually
restrictive credit conditions, make it difficult to gauge the likely stimulus of an LSAP
program.
•	 The ability of large-scale asset purchases on the order of $1 trillion to limit an
undesirable drift down in inflation is likely to be limited, because their impact on the
1

We thank Charlie Thomas, Joe Gagnon, Shane Sherlund, Andreas Lehnert, Bill English, Jim Clouse,
Chris Erceg, Steve Kamin, Michael Kiley, John Roberts, Laurie Pounder, Nellie Liang, Dave Stockton,
Dan Sichel, and Steve Oliner for comments and help with data.
Page 1 of 14

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 2 of 14

degree of economic slack likely would be modest. A larger program would, of
course, make a bigger dent in slack. At any order of magnitude, however, enactment
of such a program could bolster public confidence in the Federal Reserve’s
commitment to maintaining inflation near recent levels. In that case, more stable
inflation expectations might moderate the decline in inflation.
Economic effects of an LSAP program—general considerations
Although different money and capital markets show varying degrees of dysfunction, the
overall effect of the ongoing financial turmoil has been to raise the price and lower the
availability of credit in most sectors of the economy—a development that has had
extremely adverse consequences for real activity in general. To combat the weakness,
the FOMC has provided broad-based stimulus by cutting the federal funds rate
aggressively. But now that the federal funds rate is near the zero bound, the Committee
must consider other methods if it wishes to further stimulate overall spending and output.
Large-scale purchases of long-term Treasury and GSE securities are possible ways of
achieving this goal because such purchases, at least in principle, can lower borrowing
costs for a broad swath of the private sector, as well as noticeably boost household wealth
and reduce the foreign exchange value of the dollar.
The ability of an LSAP program to provide broad-based stimulus rests in large part on the
assumption that investors view long-term Treasury securities, agency securities, and
investment-grade corporate bonds as reasonably close substitutes. The historical
evidence suggests that Federal Reserve purchases of one of these assets, if carried out on
a sufficient scale, would materially lower the yield on the targeted asset. Whether such
purchases would also reduce yields on the other assets is less obvious. If Treasury
securities, agency MBS, and corporate bonds were perfect substitutes, arbitrage would
always ensure that a reduction in the yield on one asset would pass one-for-one into
reductions in yields on the other securities. However, these securities differ in important
ways—for example, in default risk and liquidity—and as a result their yields do not move
in lock step. Nonetheless, the historical correlations across assets of month-to-month
changes in yields have been quite high, and for this reason recent staff analyses have
assumed that a LSAP program would generate a coordinated decline in yields across
these three markets. The staff has also assumed that any induced reduction in MBS
yields would pass through fully into interest rates on conventional mortgages.2
In previous analyses presented to the Committee, the staff interpreted the historical
evidence as suggesting that a $500 billion purchase of long-term Treasury securities
would reduce Treasury yields by 50 basis points, and corporate yields and mortgage rates
by 30 basis points.3 The staff also assumed that a $500 billion purchase of agency MBS
2

In the weeks after the November 25 announcement of the plan for purchases of GSE debt and MBS, the 

rate on conventional mortgages did not drop by as much as did the MBS yield. But, in recent weeks, this

spread has returned most of the way to its level prior to the announcement. 

3
These assumptions were discussed in several of the notes distributed to the Committee on December 5, 

2009: “Purchases of Longer-Term Treasury Securities” (Cabana, Forster, Frost, Gagnon, Hilton,

Rodrigues, and Steinberg), “Purchases of Agency MBS and Debt” (Gagnon and Hilton), and “Quantitative

Analysis of Policy Alternatives Using the FRB/US Model” (Erceg, Kiley and Levin). 


Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 3 of 14

would reduce MBS yields and conventional home mortgage rates by 75 basis points,
corporate bond yields by 50 basis points, and Treasury yields by 30 basis points. The
assumption of larger own-yield effects for MBS purchases reflects, in part, the staff’s
view that directly intervening in this market might help to relieve some of the strains
afflicting housing finance to a degree that purchasing Treasuries (for which demand is
already extraordinarily strong) would not.
While we continue in this memo to use these same assumptions, it is worth emphasizing
that the actual magnitude of spillover effects across debt markets is highly uncertain.4 In
fact, there is a risk that such spillovers could be small in the current context. This risk
arises because the high historical correlation of yields on these assets may simply reflect
an important shared common influence on their prices—the expected future path of the
federal funds rate. The influence of an LSAP program on this expected path may be
small, given that the federal funds rate is already seen as likely to remain close to zero for
some time. Instead, the LSAP program may in the first instance work by reducing the
term and liquidity premiums embedded in the yield of the targeted asset; for example, the
primary effect of large-scale purchases of agency MBS might be to increase the liquidity
of mortgage-related securities. In this event, the decline in the own yield might be larger
than we have allowed because, in the absence of a diffusion to other asset markets, the
rate in the targeted market would bear the full brunt of the reduction in the supply of
long-term assets.
Assuming that large-scale asset purchases would indeed lower the overall level of longterm interest rates, the total stimulus provided by the LSAP program would also depend
on the extent of further spillovers into other financial markets. Such spillovers would be
consistent with standard arbitrage considerations, such as those embedded in the FRB/US
model. For example, the rate of return on corporate equity should fall as investors bid up
stock prices until their risk-adjusted rate has fallen in line with that on other financial
assets. And, to the extent that U.S. bonds and foreign bonds are substitutes, the decline in
rates of return on U.S. debt should lower the exchange value of the dollar, ceteris paribus.
If an LSAP program yielded a general improvement in financial conditions, as the staff
expects, it would stimulate aggregate spending and output through several channels.
Lower mortgage rates would increase the demand for housing and ultimately lead to
greater residential investment, while lower corporate financing costs in debt and equity
markets would raise business investment. Higher stock prices would increase household
net worth and thus consumption spending. And a lower dollar would increase net
exports.
Changes in household income flows and household resources, more broadly, would also
play a role in defining the response of spending. For example, a decline in interest rates
on government debt would reduce household income relative to what it would otherwise
be by reducing the return on gross new debt issuance. By contrast, a reduction in rates on
corporate debt would reduce household interest income but generally leave domestic
4

The forthcoming memo by Gagnon et al discusses the response of various interest rates to recent
announcements by both the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England concerning large-scale asset
purchases, and concludes that spillover effects have been substantial.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 4 of 14

households better off. Abstracting from the imperfect integration of corporate and
personal tax liabilities in the U.S. tax code, this offset occurs because lower interest
payments to households raise profits dollar for dollar (and households ultimately receive
the profit income). And, because foreigners own a smaller share of U.S. corporate equity
than they do of U.S. corporate bonds, U.S. households benefit from the decline in rates on
corporate debt at the expense of foreigners.5 However, these income changes are very
gradual because they affect only new debt issuance; that is, the change in the average
interest rate on long-term government and corporate debt varies with the share of the new
debt in the outstanding stock of debt.
Gauging the importance of financial spillovers using model simulations
FRB/US simulations support the claim that the efficacy of an LSAP program depends
importantly on its ability to influence a broad range of financial conditions. Table 1
summarizes model predictions for the response of real activity to enactment of a program
to purchase an additional $500 billion in agency MBS under different assumptions about
financial spill-over effects; table 2 does the same for a program of buying $500 billion in
long-term Treasury debt. For each table, all the simulation results incorporate the same
assumptions used in previous staff analyses and discussed above for the direct effect of
these purchases on own-yields; specifically, all the table 1 simulations assume that the
LSAP program would lower MBS yields (and mortgage rates) about 75 basis points,
while all the table 2 simulations assume that the LSAP program would lower long-term
Treasury yields 50 basis points. Controlling for these common effects, each table’s
simulations are then sequenced to allow for a progressively expanding range of financial
spillovers, first to other interest rates, then to the stock market, and finally to the real
exchange rate. In these sequenced simulations, the spillovers to other interest rates are
calibrated to match the staff estimates reported above, while the spillovers to corporate
equity and the dollar are derived using standard FRB/US asset valuation equations. The
full change in the prices of financial assets occurs in the second quarter of 2009 when the
program is first announced; these shifts persist through 2011 and then begin to fade in
2012 as the Federal Reserve’s positions in MBS and long-term Treasury debt are
assumed to be gradually unwound.6
As shown in the upper portion of table 1, purchasing agency MBS has only a small effect
on the overall economy in the absence of financial spillovers that extend beyond the
5

In the FRB/US model, the propensity to consume out of profits (whether in the form of dividends or
retained earnings) is the same as the propensity to consume out of interest income. So, this income transfer
from foreigners to U.S. residents means that there is, on net, a positive impact on consumption spending
from a decline in yields on corporate debt.
6
In the simulations, monetary policy is assumed to hold the federal funds rate close to zero through 2012
(consistent with the extended outlook presented in the January Greenbook) and to follow the prescriptions
of the Taylor rule thereafter. For computational convenience, private agents are assumed to have an
incomplete understanding of the effects of an LSAP program, in that they base their expectations for the
future on the forecasts of an estimated small-scale VAR model; other analysis (not shown) shows that
allowing agents to have model-consistent expectations, and thus a complete understanding of the program,
does not greatly change the results reported in tables 1 and 2. Under either expectational assumption, the
initial reduction in long-term interest rates erodes somewhat over time as investors, recognizing the
medium-run implications of the LSAP policy for real activity and inflation, price in the expectation of a
higher path of the federal funds rate beyond 2012.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 5 of 14

mortgage market. Under these conditions, the only noticeable stimulus to aggregate
demand in the simulation comes through residential investment, which has only a small
effect on overall activity because housing represents such a small share of nominal GDP
at present. The stimulus from the LSAP program is larger if the decline in MBS yields
leads to a fall in a broad range of long-term interest rates, because then the general
reduction in borrowing costs gives rise to a more appreciable increase in business capital
spending, residential investment, and household purchases of durable goods. As shown in
the bottom portion of the table, if the MBS purchases also boost stock market wealth and
cause the dollar to depreciate, thereby increasing the stimulus to household spending and
net exports, the total effect on the level of real GDP climbs to roughly double that of the
effect on interest rates alone.
This same general pattern characterizes results for large-scale purchases of long-term
Treasury debt. As shown in the upper portion of table 2, FRB/US predicts essentially no
stimulus from such purchases if there are no financial spillovers beyond the Treasury
market, because government yields do not factor directly in the spending and production
decisions of households and firms. At the other extreme, if declines in Treasury yields do
result in lower private borrowing costs, higher corporate equity valuations, and a lower
foreign exchange value of the dollar, then the overall stimulus from a Treasury LSAP
program would be appreciable. In fact, based on these FRB/US simulations, its real GDP
effects would be almost as large as those of a MBS purchase program. This result,
however, depends crucially on the exchange-rate effect; in the absence of spillovers to the
exchange rate, the stimulus from an MBS purchase program is almost twice as great after
three years as that provided by a Treasury purchase program.
The potential effects of house price appreciation and mortgage refinancing
The FRB/US simulations likely capture many important channels through which an
LSAP program would influence household and business spending. In particular, the
results reported in tables 1 and 2 take account of the stimulus from changes in the cost of
capital, wealth, and the exchange rate. But some potentially important links involving
house prices and mortgage refinancing are not included in the model’s structure.
In theory, the price of a house should be determined in the same manner as the price of
corporate equity or other assets—by capitalizing the expected flow of services or income
from the asset. FRB/US does not capture this expected capital gain on housing from a
change in interest rates but instead assumes that the relative price of a house is invariant
to interest rates. Based on calculations using an asset valuation model in tandem with
time series estimates of house prices and house rents, a $1 trillion LSAP program (evenly
divided between purchases of Treasury securities and agency MBS) would raise house
prices by about 15 percent, given the assumptions discussed above about the direct and
spillover effects of such a program on interest rates. (See the appendix for this
calculation.)
Ample reason exists to question the size of the interest-sensitivity that results from this
method. For one, households may purchase homes for reasons other than their expected
return, implying that the average house price may depend less on factors included in the
asset valuation model and more on other factors. Second, the estimate that derives from

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 6 of 14

the asset valuation model is very sensitive to the data applied to the model. In any event,
other empirical evidence indicates a much smaller influence of interest rates on house
prices. Indeed, reduced-form models of house prices suggest that a percentage point
decline in the 30-year mortgage rate—the effect implied by our assumptions for the direct
and indirect effects of purchasing $500 billion in Treasury securities and $500 billion in
agency MBS—would raise house prices by only 2½ percent, although the statistical
precision of this estimate is such that the true figure could be twice as large.
With total residential real estate in the range of $22 trillion in 2009Q1, a 2½ percent
increase in house prices would add roughly $550 billion to real estate wealth relative to
baseline. Assuming the same propensity to consume out of housing wealth as other
wealth, this increase would directly boost consumer spending by about $17 billion. By
contrast, if the decline in interest rates instead boosted house prices relative to baseline by
around 15 percent, as suggested by the asset-valuation calculation, residential real estate
values would increase by $3.3 trillion, and consumption would increase by about $105
billion. In addition to this direct wealth effect, such a large boost to house prices could
significantly improve bank balance sheets and thereby increase the availability of bank
credit. Also, by importantly checking the decline in home prices embedded in the
baseline outlook, the LSAP program might convince potential buyers that house prices
have hit bottom and that nothing is to be gained by postponing a house purchase. Such a
change in perceptions would accelerate the recovery of the housing market.
Mortgage refinancing and related income redistribution effects represent another omitted
channel that could help to stimulate real activity by more than shown in the model
simulations. Refinancing at a lower interest rate raises the disposable income of
borrowers but lowers the interest received by creditors, dollar for dollar. If borrowers
have a higher propensity to consume than creditors, this redistribution stimulates
consumption even with no change in the aggregate disposable resources of households.
Empirical evidence suggests that such differences in consumer behavior exist. The
stimulus to consumption will be even larger if foreigners finance some share of U.S.
mortgage debt, via their direct holdings of U.S. mortgages and mortgage securities or via
their ownership of U.S. banks or other U.S. institutions that may hold such debt. In this
instance, every dollar less in mortgage interest payments following a refinancing reduces
interest received by U.S. households and domestic banks and institutions by 80 cents,
based on an estimate that suggests the foreign ownership share of U.S. mortgage debt is
approximately 20 percent.7
The staff estimates that about $2.6 trillion in mortgage debt will be refinanced over the
remainder of this year and through the end of 2010, based on recent and projected
declines in mortgage rates, and taking into account the Administration’s plan that raises
the maximum loan-to-value permitted on GSE refinances. An LSAP program that
7

When a loan in an agency MBS is refinanced, that loan disappears from the MBS. The owner of the MBS
is repaid the principal on that loan and may choose to invest those funds anywhere. Thus, interest received
by the foreign owner of the MBS does not necessarily fall in proportion to the decline in MBS yields
because the investor may invest the repaid funds in something other than another MBS. However, as long
as foreign investors reinvest those funds in U.S. debt securities, the quantitative estimates suggested in the
text are in the ballpark.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 7 of 14

shaved a percentage point off mortgage rates would likely boost the volume of
refinancing to roughly $3.1 trillion, thereby lowering mortgage interest payments around
$27 billion by the end of this year and $36 billion next year.8 With the share of mortgage
debt owned by foreign entities at 20 percent, the interest received by domestic entities
would decline over $21 billion this year and almost $29 billion next year. If the
propensity to consume of borrowers is 1.0 and of creditors is 0.5, aggregate consumption
would be boosted almost $19 billion later this year and $22 billion by the end of 2010.
However, this estimate probably understates the effect an LSAP program would have on
consumer spending through this channel. First, the spending response of creditors
probably appreciably lags that of borrowers because the lower interest receipts mainly
show up in the returns to institutional holders of mortgage debt—financial institutions
and pension funds—rather than directly or immediately in household disposable income.
Second, some homeowners may take advantage of refinancing to extract equity from
their homes in order to finance an increase in consumption.
Table 3 illustrates that these potential effects from higher home prices and mortgage
refinancings could significantly boost the macroeconomic stimulus provided by an LSAP
program. The table reports simulation results for a $1 trillion program, with purchases
evenly divided between long-term Treasury securities and agency MBS. Consistent with
the assumptions discussed earlier, we assume that such a program would subtract 105
basis points from MBS yields and mortgage rates, and 80 basis points from yields on
Treasuries and investment-grade corporate bonds. Using the standard version of
FRB/US—that is, the version that excludes the direct spur to consumption from higher
home prices and mortgage refinancing just discussed—the program is estimated to boost
the level of real GDP about 2 percent over the next few years, lower the unemployment
rate ¾ percentage point, and provide a modest boost to inflation. Taking at face value the
calibrated impetus to consumption from higher household net worth and mortgage
refinancings described above, the boost to the level of real GDP could be as much as 5¼
percent relative to baseline, reducing the unemployment rate by 2 percentage points, and
raising the inflation rate ½ percentage point.
Caveats
There are many reasons to be cautious in using FRB/US and other models to gauge the
likely stimulus provided by large-scale asset purchases. For one, the ability of our
models to predict the macroeconomic effects of an unprecedented policy action is
necessarily quite limited, even under normal conditions. Moreover, conditions today are
far from normal. Given the heightened degree of uncertainty, and the unusually restricted
availability of credit, the average historical behavior embedded in FRB/US and other
models may be a poor predictor of how agents would respond to an LSAP program in
today’s environment.
8

Given the baseline assumptions for refinancing activity, the 100 basis point reduction in mortgage rates
generated by the LSAP program would reduce interest costs by $17 billion in 2009Q4 and $26 billion in
2010Q4 for homeowners who would have refinanced in the absence of the program. For homeowners who
only refinance because of the program, the interest savings would be about $10 billion by late 2009 (and
beyond), assuming that all the additional $500 billion in refinancing occurs this year, and that the average
interest rate on these refinanced mortgages falls from 6 percent to 4 percent.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 8 of 14

For example, business investment in the FRB/US model depends only on output and the
price of capital; credit constraints play no explicit role, even though they may account for
much of the current unexplained weakness in capital spending. The lack of a clear credit
channel suggests that the model may overstate the ability of many firms to finance
increased investment at present, even if the LSAP program stimulates demand to the
point that firms would like to increase capacity. The current heightened level of
uncertainty may also make many firms extremely reluctant to invest even if borrowing
conditions improve substantially.
Similar considerations may also limit the responsiveness of many consumers, who may
not be able to obtain the financing necessary to take advantage of lower interest rates, or
may be unwilling to spend because of fears about the future. On the other hand, it is
possible that credit-constrained households may prove to be unusually responsive at the
moment to any additional income or employment generated by the large-scale asset
purchases. Thus, it is difficult to say whether the model simulations presented above
over- or understate the consumption effect of an LSAP program.
Another area of uncertainty concerns the response of the dollar, which FRB/US models
using an “open-interest-parity” condition. Although this approach—which relates
movements in the foreign exchange value of the dollar to the spread between domestic
and foreign interest rates—is standard, its empirical track record is quite poor (although
no other approach does any better). Unpredictable movements in the premium investors
are willing to pay to hold dollar assets is one reason for this poor performance, and the
model simulations may understate the degree to which a LSAP program might lead
investors to look favorably on the prospects for the U.S. economy. To the extent that
sentiment shifts toward the dollar, the simulation may overstate the amount of exchange
rate depreciation that would be expected from the decline in U.S. interest rates.
The inflation effects of an LSAP program
The FRB/US model of inflation falls into the group of new Keynesian Phillips curve
models. In particular, current inflation depends on the gap between the actual and desired
price level, where the desired price level in turn depends on unit labor costs (a proxy for
marginal cost) and the desired markup of prices over marginal costs. Both factors vary
pro-cyclically. In addition, because prices are sticky, inflation also depends importantly
on expected inflation.
In the version of FRB/US used for these simulations, agents are assumed to form their
expectations under a form of limited-information rationality. In particular, agents form
expectations of future movements in output, inflation, and interest rates using a reducedform VAR model of the economy. In both this VAR model and the FRB/US model,
long-run inflation expectations are ultimately tied to the public’s perception of the
policymakers’ inflation target. The public updates its perception of the inflation target
based on the realization of inflation as well as on deviations of the federal funds rate from
historical norms. As seen in the tables, the stimulus to economic growth provided by the
LSAP program makes only a modest dent in economic slack. Moreover, because the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 9 of 14

public looks exclusively to the setting of the federal funds rate (relative to current
resource utilization and inflation) to draw inferences about the inflation target, the
announcement of an LSAP program does not by itself influence the perception of the
inflation target and expected rates of inflation. As a consequence, this program fails to
significantly slow the down-drift in inflation expectations that occurs in the baseline
projection, as illustrated by a comparison of the black and blue lines in figure 1.
In theory, the public’s expectation of the policymakers’ inflation target could be directly
influenced by the very announcement of a program like the LSAP program. The
announcement itself might impress the public with the authorities’ commitment to
keeping inflation on a stable path. Thus, rather than relying only on the federal funds rate
to infer policymakers’ desired inflation target, the public might instead look to large-scale
asset purchases. Of course, with no historical experience of large-scale asset purchases,
evidence on how much policymakers can directly influence inflation expectations is
essentially nonexistent. To give some idea of the possible benefits of such effects, we
make the assumption that, upon implementation of the LSAP program, long-run inflation
expectations become firmly anchored and independent of the evolution of the economy—
similar to the assumption in recent Greenbook alternative scenarios. As can be seen from
the red line in figure 1, under this assumption, inflation outcomes are considerably better.
But it bears repeating that these better-anchored inflation expectations are purely
illustrative because we have no empirical evidence to suggest that an LSAP program
would alter expectations in this way.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 10 of 14

Table 1 

Economic Effects of a Program to Purchase a Further $500 Billion of Agency MBS 

Under Different Assumptions for the Extent of Financial Spillover 

2009

2010

2011 2012

Financial spillovers limited to home mortgage rates
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.08
-.02

.15
-.05

.17
-.07

.14
-.06

Financial spillovers limited to home mortgage rates, bond yields,
and other long-term interest rates
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.12
-.03

.30
-.10

.48
-.16

.60
-.19

Financial spillovers limited to home mortgage rates, bond yields,
other loan rates, and corporate equity prices
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.16
-.04

.46
-.15

.74
-.25

.88
-.31

Full financial spillover (including the real exchange rate)
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.22
-.05

.65
-.22

1.06
-.37

1.26
-.46

Note: Results shown in the table are from FRB/US simulations using staff estimates for the interest rate
effects of large-scale asset purchases. Announcement of the program is assumed to subtract 75 basis points
from MBS yields and conventional home mortgage loan rates, 50 basis points from yields on corporate
bonds, and 30 basis points from long-term Treasury securities. These direct effects on the level of longterm interest rates are assumed to persist though the end of 2011 but fade away in 2012 as the Federal
Reserve’s position in MBS is gradually unwound. Accompanying spillover effects on corporate equity
prices and the real exchange are based on standard FRB/US asset-valuation equations. In all the
simulations, the federal funds rate follows the Taylor rule subject to the zero bound constraint (which in the
baseline binds through 2012).
1.
2.

Percent change from baseline in the Q4 level of real GDP.
Change from baseline in the Q4 level of the unemployment rate.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 11 of 14

Table 2 

Economic Effects of a Program to Purchase $500 Billion in Long-term Treasury Securities 

Under Different Assumptions for the Extent of Financial Spillover 

2009

2010

2011 2012

Financial spillovers limited to Treasury yields
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.00
.00

.00
.00

.01
.00

.01
.00

Financial spillovers limited to Treasury yields, corporate bond
yields, and mortgage and other long-term loan rates
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.05
-.01

.15
-.05

.25
-.08

.33
-.10

Financial spillovers limited to Treasury yields, corporate bond
yields, mortgage and other long-term loan rates, and corporate
equity prices
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.08
-.02

.24
-.08

.39
-.13

.50
-.17

Full financial spillover (including the real exchange rate)
Real GDP1
Unemployment rate2

.17
-.04

.52
-.17

.83
-.30

1.00
-.39

Note: Results shown in the table are from FRB/US simulations using staff estimates for the interest rate
effects of large-scale asset purchases. Announcement of the program is assumed to subtract 50 basis points
from yields on long-term Treasury securities and 30 basis points from yields on corporate bonds and
conventional home mortgage loan rates. These direct effects on the level of long-term interest rates are
assumed to persist though the end of 2011 but fade away in 2012 as the Federal Reserve’s position in longterm Treasury securities is gradually unwound. Accompanying spillover effects on corporate equity prices
and the real exchange are based on standard FRB/US asset-valuation equations. In all the simulations, the
federal funds rate follows the Taylor rule subject to the zero bound constraint (which in the baseline binds
through 2012).
1.
2.

Percent change from baseline in the Q4 level of real GDP.
Change from baseline in the Q4 level of the unemployment rate.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 12 of 14

Table 3 

Macroeconomic Effects of a $1 Trillion LSAP Program, 

Equally Divided Between Purchases of Treasury Securities and Agency MBS, 

Under Different Assumptions for House Prices and Mortgage Refinancing Effects

2009

2010

2011

2012

Real GDP
Without house price and mortgage refinancing effects
With refinancing effect and 2½% rise in house prices
With refinancing effect and 15% rise in house prices

.40
.59
.63

1.19
1.52
2.03

1.94
2.49
4.11

2.15
2.80
5.30

Unemployment rate2
Without house price and mortgage refinancing effects
With refinancing effect and 2½% rise in house prices
With refinancing effect and 15% rise in house prices

-.09
-.15
-.16

-.39
-.51
-.65

-.67
-.87
-1.39

-.80
-1.05
-1.95

Core PCE inflation3
Without house price and mortgage refinancing effects
With refinancing effect and 2½% rise in house prices
With refinancing effect and 15% rise in house prices

.12
.13
.13

.16
.20
.22

.29
.38
.47

.26
.35
.50

Federal funds rate2
Without house price and mortgage refinancing effects
With refinancing effect and 2½% rise in house prices
With refinancing effect and 15% rise in house prices

.00
.00
.00

.00
.00
.00

.00
.30
2.06

2.15
2.97
5.93

1

Note: Results shown in the table are from FRB/US simulations using staff estimates for the interest rate
effects of large-scale asset purchases. Announcement of the program is assumed to subtract 105 basis
points from MBS yields and conventional home mortgage loan rates and 80 basis points from yields on
corporate bonds and long-term Treasury securities. These direct effects on the level of long-term interest
rates are assumed to persist though the end of 2011 but fade away beginning in 2012 as the Federal
Reserve’s position in long-term Treasury securities and agency MBS is gradually unwound. In all the
simulations, the federal funds rate follows the Taylor rule subject to the zero bound constraint (which in the
baseline binds through 2012). See text for details about the size of the refinancing effect.
1.
2.
3.

Percent change from baseline in the Q4 level of real GDP.
Change from baseline in Q4 level.
Change from baseline in Q4-over-Q4 change in the PCE price index excluding food and energy.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 13 of 14

Figure 1

Inflation Consequences of a $1 Trillion LSAP Program

Under Different Assumptions for Long-Run Inflation Expectations

Core PCE Inflation (Q4 over Q4)

percent

2.4

2.4

2.0

2.0

1.6

1.6

1.2

1.2

0.8

0.8

0.4
08Q1

0.4
08Q3

09Q1

09Q3

10Q1

10Q3

11Q1

11Q3

12Q1

Long-Run Inflation Expectations

12Q3

percent

2.2

2.2

2.0

2.0

1.8

1.8

1.6

1.6

1.4

1.4

1.2

1.2

1.0
08Q1

1.0
08Q3

09Q1

09Q3

10Q1

10Q3

11Q1

11Q3

12Q1

12Q3

LSAP program, unanchored inflation expectations

LSAP program, anchored inflation expectations

baseline


Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015

Class II FOMC—Restricted (FR)

Page 14 of 14

Appendix

The Effect of Interest Rates on House Prices In an Asset Valuation Model 

Under a standard model of asset valuation, the price of a house, P, is expressed as
P = E / [(1-t)i - π + δ + ρ] ,
where E is the current period service flow (akin to what the house would rent for), t is the
marginal personal income tax rate, π is the expected rate of change in the price of housing
services, δ is the rate of depreciation on the house, and ρ is the “equity premium” on
housing. The nominal rate of interest, i, is a weighted average of the mortgage rate and
the opportunity cost of funds to the homeowner, where the weights represent the
homeowner’s debt and equity respectively relative to the value of the house. The
percentage change in the house price with respect to a percentage point change in the
interest rate is thus (1-t) / [(1-t)i - π + δ + ρ].
If we observed π and ρ directly, we could use this expression to calibrate the expected
sensitivity of house prices to interest rate changes from this expression. But, we do not
have direct observations on either. However, because this expression is equivalent to
(1-t) P/E, measures of house prices and imputed or actual rents can be used to estimate
the interest-sensitivity. Data on house prices and rents compiled by Davis, Lehnert and
Martin (“The Rent-Price Ratio for the Aggregate Stock of Owner-Occupied Housing,”
2008) suggest that the P/E ratio stood at just over 24 in the second quarter of 2008,
compared to an average of about 20 since 1960. Allowing for a 10 percent decline in
house prices since the middle of last year, the ratio would now be about 22.9
Assuming a marginal personal income tax rate of homeowners of 25 percent, a
percentage point decline in long-term interest rates would imply a 16½ percent increase
in house prices. Under an LSAP program of $500 billion in Treasury securities and $500
billion in agency MBS, the mortgage rate declines by 105 basis points and the yield on
Treasuries by 80 basis points (the sum of the direct and spillover effects we assume for
the separate LSAPs). Applying a weight of 55 percent to the decline in the mortgage rate
(based on a ratio of aggregate mortgage debt to aggregate house values) and a weight of
45 percent to the decline in the Treasury yield (where we assume that the Treasury yield
measures the opportunity cost of funds for homeowners), the change in the relevant
interest rate for this calculation is 93 basis points. Thus, house prices would rise a bit
more than 15 percent, given the staff assumptions for financial spillover effects discussed
above.

9

Time series for P and E were constructed from indexes of percent changes in prices and rents and
converted to dollar figures by estimating the levels of price and rent for a base-year. Note that the baseyear estimates permanently affect P/E; that is, an estimate of base-year rent that is 5 percent lower results in
a time series for P/E that is everywhere 5 percent higher. Accordingly, the sensitivity of house prices to
interest rates would be estimated to be 5 percent higher. This sensitivity of P/E to the estimates of base-year
price and rent should be kept in mind when using the constructed P/E ratio to gauge interest-sensitivity of
house prices.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/04/2015