View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

March 4, 2016
Probability of Recession Implied by Credit Market Sentiment
Giovanni Favara, Kurt Lewis, and Gustavo Suarez

As noted in the companion memo by Travis Berge, Nitish Sinha, and Michael
Smolyansky, corporate bond spreads and the slope of the Treasury yield curve (that is,
the term spread) are two financial indicators that appear to be especially informative
about the likelihood of an economic downturn over a year-ahead horizon. One reason for
this statistical result is that those yield spreads—like all financial asset prices—are
forward-looking variables, and thus they contain important information about the real
economy: the term spread, for example, may be a useful summary of the current stance of
monetary policy (relative to long-run expectations), while credit spreads may anticipate
future economic activity because they incorporate investors’ expectations of future
corporate defaults. 1
A number of recent papers have emphasized that credit spreads, in particular, may
help predict economic activity for reasons unrelated to default risk. 2 The purpose of this
memo is to evaluate the information content of a component of credit spreads that is not
directly attributable to expected default risk and thus to news about future cash flows.
Specifically, we use a measure of investor sentiment in the corporate bond market—the
so-called excess bond premium (EBP) introduced by Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012)—to
predict the likelihood of an NBER-dated recession occurring over the next 12 months.
We first document that over the past four decades, the predictive power of credit spreads
for economic downturns is due entirely to the EBP. According to this measure, credit
market sentiment has deteriorated noticeably since the summer of 2015, and as of the end
of February, our simple model predicts about a 45 percent chance that the U.S. economy

1
Indeed, considerable empirical evidence suggests that these yield spreads may be the clearest aggregators
of information on incipient recessions; see, for example, Estrella and Hardouvelis (1991); Estrella and
Mishkin (1998); Ang, Piazzesi, and Wei (2006); Stock and Watson (2003); Gilchrist, Yankov, and
Zakrajšek (2009); and Faust, Gilchrist, Wright and Zakrajšek (2013).
2
Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012); Greenwood and Hanson (2013); Krishnamurthy and Muir (2015); and
Lopez-Salido, Stein, and Zakrajšek (2016).

Page 1 of 8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

will enter a recession at some point over the next year, about 15 percentage points above
the unconditional probability of such an event occurring since 1973. We then briefly
discuss two economic mechanisms related to investor beliefs and the supply of credit that
may explain the relationship between the EBP and the real economy.
The excess bond premium as a measure of credit market sentiment
We begin by decomposing the Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012) credit spread (the
GZ credit spread)—which the companion memo has shown to have significant predictive
power for NBER-dated recessions—into two parts. The first is a component that captures
default risk of individual firms, and the second is a residual component, the EBP, that can
be thought of as capturing investor attitudes toward corporate credit risk—that is, credit
market sentiment. 3 In effect, the EBP tries to capture the variation in the average price of
bearing U.S. corporate credit risk—above and beyond the compensation that investors in
the corporate bond market require for expected defaults. Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012)
document that the EBP is significantly more informative—in both economic and
statistical terms—about future economic activity than a component of the GZ credit
spread that can be directly attributed to expected defaults. As shown in Figure 1, both the
GZ credit spread and the EBP have increased significantly prior to or during most of the
cyclical downturns since the early 1970s. Note also that during the past six months, the
EBP has climbed to levels last seen in the early summer of 2009, a period when the U.S.
economy was just beginning to emerge from the Great Recession.

Predicting NBER-dated recessions with the excess bond premium
To estimate the probability that the U.S. economy will enter a recession sometime
during the next 12 months, we use a simple probit regression and focus on the credit and
term spreads as the only two predictors. 4 Essentially, this regression looks at the
behavior of the credit and term spreads at times of past NBER-dated recessions and

3

The construction of both the GZ credit spread and the EBP are outlined in the appendix.
The companion memo estimates the probability of an NBER-dated recession at a specific forecast
horizon, that is, 3- 6-, or 12-months ahead. This memo, by contrast, estimates the probability that the U.S.
economy will enter a recession at any time between month t and month t+12, a modeling choice that is
economically more appealing given our focus on the 12-month forecast horizon.
4

Page 2 of 8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

estimates the probability that these two indicators are signaling the occurrence of an
economic downturn over the next year. 5
The first column in Table 1 complements the analysis of the companion memo by
reporting the marginal effects of the term spread and the GZ spread on the probability of
a recession over the 12-month horizon. The estimates imply that a decrease in the term
spread—a flattening of the yield curve—of 10 basis point in month t is associated with an
increase in the probability of a recession over subsequent 12 month of about 1.5
percentage points; the same-sized increase in the GZ credit spread in month t is estimated
to boost this probability by about one percentage point.
In column 2, we zoom in on the information content of the GZ credit spread by
allowing its two components to enter into the regression separately. These estimates
indicate that the predictive content of the GZ spread is due entirely to the EBP—the
marginal effect of the default-risk component of the GZ spread is statistically and
economically indistinguishable from zero. By contrast, a 10 basis point increase in the
EBP in month t is associated with a 3 percentage points increase in the probability of
recession over the subsequent 12 months. According to the (pseudo) R-squared reported
in column 3, the regression involving only the EBP has an in-sample goodness-of-fit that
is more than two-thirds of that implied by the model that conditions on both the term
spread and the GZ spread (column1).
To better isolate the role of credit market sentiment in U.S. business cycle
fluctuations, Figure 2 plots the in-sample fitted probability of a recession over the
subsequent 12 months, based on the specification reported in column 3. As shown by the
solid line, this probability has moved up significantly since the summer of last year, when
concerns about global growth prospects, centered on China, sparked an increase in
financial market volatility and a deterioration in investor sentiment in the United States
and abroad. This simple model implies about a 45 percent chance that the U.S. economy
will be in recession at some point between March 2016 and February 2017. 6 As a
benchmark, the unconditional probability of entering into a recession at any point over

5

The term spread is defined as the difference between the yield on the 10-year Treasury note and the 3month Treasury bill rate.
6
The model specified in column 2 implies a probability of recession over the same horizon of about 40
percent.

Page 3 of 8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

the subsequent 12 months, the dashed black line in Figure 2, is about 30 percent over our
sample period.
There are some important caveats worth spelling out. First, the EBP measures the
sentiment of investors transacting in the corporate bond market. While there is a certain
degree of arbitrage across financial markets, investors in other markets may have a
different assessment of current and prospective economic conditions. As a result,
fluctuations in the EBP may not be fully indicative of swings in broad credit market
sentiment. Second, the portion of credit spreads not accounted for by movements in
expected defaults may reflect other factors, such as time-varying liquidity premiums,
which may be unrelated to investor sentiment. Finally, our statistical analysis should be
taken with a grain of salt, as recessions occur rather infrequently and the time series
model is estimated over a sample period that includes only six NBER-dated recessions.
Additionally, as shown in Figure 2, the statistical model in column 3 produces
some—albeit only a few—false negative inferences (failing to predict recessions that did
occur) and false positive predictions (predicting recessions that did not happen) over the
past four decades. The most notable false positive prediction in our sample occurred in
2002, when credit spreads and the EBP increased sharply in response to a slew of
corporate accounting scandals that led to the bankruptcy of several large firms.
Possible economic mechanisms linking credit market sentiment and the real economy
While the results reported above suggest that the EBP provides a timely and
useful leading indicator of economic downturns, it is important to discuss the economic
mechanisms through which fluctuations in credit market sentiment may affect the real
economy. There are at least two potential mechanisms, which are not necessarily
mutually exclusive.
One possible mechanism linking investor sentiment and the real economy is
related to the way investors update their beliefs in light of incoming data. In particular,
investors may over-react to the most recent news and thus assign excessive weight to
future outcomes that have become more likely in view of recent data. For example, after
a few years of economic expansion, investors may become complacent about default risk,
an attitude leading to a compression in credit spreads, a loosening of other credit terms

Page 4 of 8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

and standards, and a surge of issuance of credit to very risky borrowers. In such an
environment, the sudden arrival of a string of unfavorable economic news may lead
investors to revise disproportionally their assessment of recession risk, thus amplifying
the widening in credit spreads. This reasoning implies that investor psychology can itself
be a cause of volatility in credit and investment, even in the absence of significant
changes in economic fundamentals. 7
Another possible mechanism linking fluctuations in credit market sentiment to
economic outcomes is related to changes in the supply of credit. Large unlevered
institutions such as mutual funds, insurance companies, and pension funds have become
in recent years the main investors in the corporate bond market. These institutions
effectively act as a marginal investor in a wide range of financial markets. 8 To the extent
that real and financial disturbances affect their willingness or ability to fund the provision
of new credit, the resulting tighter financial conditions may exert a significant drag on
future economic growth. 9

7

Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), Rabin and Vayanos (2010), and Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer
(2015) discuss psychological models of investor confidence, in which overly-extrapolative expectations
may lead to credit and business cycles, even without changes in economic fundamentals.
8
He and Krishnamurthy (2013) and Adrian, Etula, and Muir (2014) argue that the wealth of financial
intermediaries is an important factor for pricing various types of credit risk.
9
Lopez-Salido, Stein and Zakrajšek (2016) document the effects of credit market sentiment on economic
growth vis-à-vis changes in the supply of credit.

Page 5 of 8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Appendix
This appendix briefly explains the construction of the GZ credit spread and its
risk premium component, the excess bond premium (EBP). The GZ spread is built from
the bottom up, using secondary market prices of over 8,000 senior unsecured bonds
issued by more than 1,300 U.S. non-financial firms. To avoid duration mismatch issues,
spreads for each underlying bond issue are derived from a synthetic risk-free security that
exactly mimics the cash flows of that bond. The GZ spread in month t is a simple unweighted cross-sectional average of credit spreads in that month:
1

𝑆𝑆𝑡𝑡𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 = 𝑁𝑁 ∑𝑖𝑖 ∑𝑘𝑘 𝑆𝑆𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘],
𝑡𝑡

where 𝑁𝑁𝑡𝑡 is the number of bond observations in month t and 𝑆𝑆𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘] is the spread of bond
k (a security that is a liability of firm i) in month t. The EBP is extracted from the GZ
spread by first using a linear regression to remove expected default risk of individual
firms from the underlying credit spreads. Specifically, the log of the credit spread on
bond k is assumed to be linearly related to a firm-specific indicator of default 𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 and
a vector of bond-specific characteristics (𝑍𝑍𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘]), according to: 10

ln 𝑆𝑆𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘] = 𝛽𝛽𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝛾𝛾 ′ 𝑍𝑍𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘] + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘],

where 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘] is a credit spread “pricing error.” The predicted level of the spread for bond
k of firm i at time t is then given by:

𝑆𝑆̂𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 = exp �𝛽𝛽̂ 𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝛾𝛾� ′ 𝑍𝑍𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘] +

𝜎𝜎� 2
�.
2

The part of the GZ spread that is directly attributable to expected default risk is given by
the average of predicted spreads in month t:
1
𝑆𝑆̂𝑡𝑡𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 = 𝑁𝑁 ∑𝑖𝑖 ∑𝑘𝑘 𝑆𝑆̂𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 [𝑘𝑘],
𝑡𝑡

while the EBP is the component of the GZ spread net of expected defaults:
𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑡𝑡 = 𝑆𝑆𝑡𝑡𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 − 𝑆𝑆̂𝑡𝑡𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 .
10
Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2012) use the “distance-to-default,” a default-risk indicator based on the firm’s
equity valuations and leverage to capture the likelihood of default over the near-term horizon; in addition to
this market-based assessment of default risk, their credit spread pricing regression also includes bondspecific credit ratings, which capture the “through-the-cycle” information about the firm’s creditworthiness.
These credit risk factors account for about 70 percent of the variation in bond-level credit spreads over the
sample period.

Page 6 of 8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

References
Adrian, Tobias, Erkko Etula, and Tyler Muir. 2014. "Financial Intermediaries and the
Cross-Section of Asset Returns." Journal of Finance 69 (6): 2557-2596.
Ang, Andrew, Monika Piazzesi, and Min Wei. 2006. "What Does the Yield Curve Tell
Us About GDP Growth?" Journal of Econometrics 131 (1): 359-403.
Barberis, Nicholas, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1998. "A Model of Investor
Sentiment." Journal of Financial Economics 49: 307-343.
Bordalo, Pedro, Nicola Gennaioli, and Andrei Shleifer. 2015. "Diagnostic Expectations
and Credit Cycles." Working Paper.
http://scholar.harvard.edu/shleifer/publications/diagnostic-expectations-andcredit-cycles.
Estrella, Arturo, and Frederic S. Mishkin. 1998. "Predicting U.S. Recessions: Financial
Variables As Leading Indicators." The Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (1):
45-61.
Estrella, Arturo, and Gikas A. Hardouvelis. 1991. "The Term Structure as a Predictor of
Real Economic Activity." The Journal of Finance 46 (2): 555–576.
Faust, Jon, Simon Gilchrist, Jonathan H. Wright, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2013. "Credit
Spreads as Predictors of Real-Time Economic Activity: A Bayesian ModelAveraging Approach." The Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (5): 1501–
1519.
Gilchrist, Simon, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2012. "Credit Spreads and Business Cycle
Fluctuations." American Economic Review 102 (4): 1692-1720.
Gilchrist, Simon, Vladimir Yankov, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2009. "Credit Market Shocks
and Economic Fluctuations: Evidence From Corporate Bond and Stock Markets."
Journal of Monetary Economics 56: 471–493.
Greenwood, Robin, and Samuel G. Hanson. 2013. "Issuer Quality and Corporate Bond
Returns." Review of Financial Studies 26 (6): 1483–1525.
He, Zhiguo, and Arvind Krishnamurthy. 2013. "Intermediary Asset Pricing." American
Economic Review 103 (2): 732–770.
Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Tyler Muir. 2015. "Credit Spreads and the Severity of
Financial Crises." Working Paper.
https://www.gsb.stanford.edu/sites/default/files/documents/Krishnamurthy.pdf.
López-Salido, David, Jeremy C. Stein, and Egon Zakrajšek. 2016. "Credit-Market
Sentiment and the Business Cycle." NBER Working Paper 21879.
Rabin, Matthew, and Dimitri Vayanos. 2010. "The Gambler's and Hot-Hand Fallacies:
Theory and Applications." The Review of Economic Studies 77 (2): 730-778.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 2003. "Forecasting Output and Inflation: The
Role of Asset Prices." Journal of Economic Literature 41 (3): 788–829.

Page 7 of 8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022
GZ Credit Spread, Excess Bond Premium, and the Probability of NBER-Dated Recessions
Figure 1: GZ Credit Spread and the Excess Bond Premium
Basis Points
800
Monthly
EBP
GZ Credit Spread

600

400

Feb.
2016

200

0

-200
1973

1976

1979

1982

1985

1988

1991

1994

1997

2000

2003

2006

2009

2012

2015

Shaded regions correspond to the NBER-dated recessions.

Table 1: Marginal Effects on the Probability of Recession over the Next 12 Months
(1)

(2)

Term Spread

-0.138***
[0.023]

-0.113***
[0.022]

GZ Credit Spread

0.108***
[0.036]

Expected Default Component

(3)

-0.041
[0.051]

Excess Bond Premium
Pseudo R-squared

0.37

0.308***
[0.055]

0.329***
[0.075]

0.54

0.29

Note: Sample period is January 1973 to February 2016 (518 monthly observations). Standard errors are reported in brackets. The Pseudo
R-squared is the McKelvey and Zavoina (1975) measure.
*** denotes statistical significance at the 1-percent level.

Figure 2: Probability of Recession Implied by the Excess Bond Premium
Percent
100
Monthly
80

Feb.
2016

60

40

20

0
1973

1976

1979

1982

1985

1988

1991

1994

1997

2000

2003

2006

2009

2012

2015

Shaded regions correspond to the NBER-dated recessions. The dashed black line denotes the unconditional probability of entering into a recession at any point
over the subsequent 12 months.

Page 8 of 8