View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

March 4, 2016
Probabilities of the U.S. Economy Entering a Recession in the Coming Year
Travis Berge, Nitish Sinha, and Michael Smolyansky
Executive Summary
The increase in financial market volatility and softening in some economic
indicators since the beginning of the year has led many market observers to question
whether the U.S. economy is at a heightened risk of entering a recession in the near
future. In recent weeks, Wall Street economists have circulated a number of statistical
estimates of recession probabilities. These estimates are based on a wide range of
indicators, both macroeconomic and financial. While many indicators are potentially
informative, evidently, different specific indicators and analysis can yield materially
different conclusions.
To better understand the empirical issue and highlight the uncertainties
surrounding forecasts of this nature, we employ a statistical technique, Bayesian Model
Averaging (BMA), able to incorporate information from a wide range of economic and
financial variables to produce estimates of the probability that the U.S. economy
transitions into a recession at some point over the next 12 months. BMA combines a
large number of potential forecasting models to produce a forecast that is a weighted
average of each individual model forecast. The weights given to each forecast model are
related to that model’s ability to explain previous recessions. In this way, economic
indicators that have not anticipated past NBER-dated recessions are downweighted, given
little or no weight in the final forecasting model.
A key advantage of this approach is that it allows for different sets of variables to
be informative about recession risks at different forecast horizons. In particular, our
analysis reveals that while certain indicators of real economic activity and some financial
variables have forecasting power for predicting recessions at the 3-month horizon, real
variables have considerably less information content at the 12-month horizon. In
contrast, forward-looking financial variables, primarily corporate bond credit spreads and
Page 1 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

the slope of the Treasury yield curve, maintain considerable predictive power about the
risk of recession 12 months hence.
We estimate that the current probabilities of the U.S. economy being in a
recession 3, 6, or 12 months from now are 13, 18 and 16 percent, respectively. At all
horizons, the estimated recession probabilities are about in line with the unconditional
probability of the economy being in recession, 15 percent since 1973. Notably, however,
the probability of recession at each horizon has increased since December 2015. This
increase in recession risk has been driven by a deterioration in financial indicators that
have predictive power within our model – in particular, a flattening of the Treasury yield
curve and a widening of corporate credit spreads. Similarly, the uncertainty surrounding
the estimated recession probabilities has also increased since December 2015; for
example, the 68-percent confidence interval around the 12-month ahead recession
probability has increased to a range of 0 to 50 percent.
In the final section of the memo, we evaluate the performance of the BMA
methodology by performing a pseudo out-of-sample forecasting exercise. Specifically,
we end the model estimation prior to the onset of both the 2001 and 2008 recessions to
determine what the model-implied recession probabilities were ahead of these recessions.
Six months prior to the 2001 (2008) recession the model assigned about a 30 (25) percent
probability that the economy would be in recession in 6 months—not remarkably strong
signals, but noticeably higher than the current 6-month-ahead reading.

Modeling recession probabilities
Our objective is to predict a binary outcome: will the economy be expanding or
contracting at a particular date in the future, given our knowledge of the world today?
Clearly, there is no single indicator, or even fixed set of indicators, that contains
comprehensive information about the state of the economy 3, 6, or 12 months from now.
The economic outlook is usually mixed, with different indicators pointing in different
directions. Further, there is no reason to expect any set of indicators to be equally
predictive about the macroeconomic state prevailing at different forecast horizons.

Page 2 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

For these reasons, we consider a fairly large number of possible recession
indicators. Specifically, we consider a set of 17 monthly variables chosen to describe
different aspects of the economy: broadly speaking, labor market indicators, measures of
real economic activity, and forward-looking financial variables such as equity returns,
credit spreads, the Treasury yield curve and indicators of financial market stress.1 Our
dataset begins in January 1973 and continues through February 2016.2
With these 17 indicators in hand, the econometric problem becomes choosing
between a very large number of potential forecasting models. We use BMA to elicit the
best model at each forecast horizon.3 To be specific, the model is a weighted average of
a suite of static probit regressions that use NBER recession dates as the dependent
variable. In each probit regression, the dependent variable Yt denotes the binary state of
the economy: Yt = 1 if the NBER has declared that month t falls in a recession, and Yt = 0
if the NBER has declared that month t falls in an expansion instead. Accordingly, each
model estimates the probability that month t will be declared a recession by the NBER
with following equation:
Pr

1|

(1)

where Φ is the cumulative standard normal probability distribution.
In our setup, we have many regressions that take the form of equation (1), one
model for every possible combination of the 17 indicators. BMA estimates the
probability that the NBER will declare a month to be a recession from each regression,
and then calculates a weighted average of these estimates. For each model, let ̂ denote

1

See the appendix for a complete list of indicators included in our data set.
Many macroeconomic indicators lack February values at the time of writing, March 4, 2016 (though we
were able to incorporate today’s labor market data). For these indicators, we replace February values with
Board staff estimates thereof.
3
Leamer (1978) introduced Bayesian Model Averaging to the economics literature. More recently, many
other applications have appeared in the economics literature. For example, Wright (2009) uses BMA to
forecast future inflation; Piger and Morley (2008) use it to model trends and cycles in U.S. output; Faust,
Gilchrist, Wright & Zakrajsek (2013) employ BMA using a large number of financial indicators to forecast
real-time measures of economic activity. This memo draws heavily on the analysis of BMA forecasts for
recession probabilities in Berge (2015).
2

Page 3 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

the predicted probability of recession from model i, where i = 1, …, 2k.4 The Bayesian
model average forecast is the weighted sum:
̂

∑
̂

|

(2)

where ̂ denotes each individual forecast. The weights, Pr(Mi | Dt-h), denote the
Bayesian posterior probability of model i given the data at time t-h. Combinations of
variables that produce recession probabilities that match the actual NBER dates at each
forecast horizon receive larger weight in the average of the model forecasts, while models
that cannot anticipate recessions receive little or zero weight in the averaged forecast.

Model fit
Figure 1 plots the fit of the BMA model for forecast horizons of 3 and 12 months.
The estimated recession probabilities generally rise during NBER-defined recessions, the
shaded areas.5 However, the model produces several false positives—periods where the
estimated probability rises, but no recession occurs. For example, although the 3-month
ahead recession probability (left panel) spikes immediately following the 1987 stock
market crash, the economy continued to expand. The 12-month ahead recession
probability (right panel) similarly rises somewhat in the late 1990s, well before the 2001
recession.
In addition, the final values in the plots of Figure 1 indicate that the estimated
probability of recession has risen notably in the past few months. The forecast that
February 2017 will be declared a recession by the NBER currently stands at just above 16
percent, essentially equal to the unconditional recession probability over this sample
period (dashed blue line).

4

We use the method of Raftery (1995) to perform BMA, which approximates the posterior likelihood of
each model with a maximum likelihood estimate of its Bayesian Information Criterion.
5
We evaluate the fit of each model more formally in the appendix.

Page 4 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Figure 1. Estimated probabilities from the BMA model,
three- and twelve-month ahead forecasts.

Note: Figures show Pr( |
), so that the date on the x-axis is the forecast that
month t was declared recession given information t-h months prior. NBER recession
dates shaded.
Table 1 gives the estimated regression coefficients produced by averaging across
all models at each forecast horizon. The table shows variables for which the slope
coefficient β, weighted across all models, is non-zero at the 90-percent confidence level,
according to the posterior inclusion probability.6 At the 3-month horizon, both real and
financial variables are included as informative indicators of recession. The 3-month
change in nonfarm payroll employment, real personal consumption expenditures, as well
as the return on the S&P 500 index and the slope of the yield enter the model
significantly with nonzero weight. However, as the forecast horizon lengthens, variables
describing real economic activity drop out of the model, and financial indictors gain
prominence. Indeed, the model that forecasts recession 12 months from now depends
heavily on only two variables: the slope of the yield curve and the GZ credit spread
index, a measure of credit market conditions that is described in detail in the companion
memo by Favara, Lewis, and Suarez.

6

The posterior inclusion probability can be thought of as the probability, given the data, that the “true”
model includes a particular variable.

Page 5 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Table 1: BMA relies on different indicators at each forecast horizon.
Panel A:

Change in payroll employment
Slope of yield curve
S&P 500 (3‐month return)
Real PCE
Panel B:

Slope of yield curve
Change in payroll employment
S&P 500 (3‐month return)

Panel C:

Slope of yield curve
GZ Index

3-month horizon
Posterior inclusion
probability (%)
Coef.
100
‐2.9
100
‐0.9
100
‐0.1
95
‐1.0

std. err.
0.60
0.19
0.03
0.39

6-month horizon
Posterior inclusion
probability (%)
Coef.
100
‐1.1
100
‐1.6
100
‐0.1

std. err.
0.15
0.38
0.03

12-month horizon
Posterior inclusion
probability (%)
Coef.
100
‐1.4
95
0.7

std. error
0.16
0.24

Note: Table shows only indicators with posterior inclusion probability greater than 90
percent.
Current recession risks
As indicated by the black line in the right panel of Figure 2, we currently estimate
the probability of the U.S. economy being in recession 3, 6, or 12 months from now at 13,
18, and 16 percent, respectively. However, the recession probabilities produced by our
model have moved higher since December, and the uncertainty around this forecast has
widened considerably, as can be seen by comparing the current forecast to the left-side
panel, which displays the forecast using data through December 2015.

Page 6 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Figure 2. Recession risks have increased since December 2015
but remain relatively subdued.

What accounts for the recent changes to the forecast? Consider first the 3-month
horizon. In December, the 3-month ahead recession probability forecast stood at 1
percent, whereas by February it had risen to 13 percent. This increase was driven by the
two financial indicators that are important predictors at this horizon (as detailed in Panel
A of Table 1). Specifically, from December to February, the slope of the yield curve
flattened from 2.2 percentage points to 1.5 percentage points, while the S&P 500 index
also moved lower. And although the 3 month ahead forecast also depends on the growth
in nonfarm payroll employment and real PCE, neither of these changed appreciably in
recent months.
Turning to the 12-month ahead model, Panel C of Table 1 shows that the
forecasted recession probability depends primarily on two variables, the GZ credit spread
index and the slope of the yield curve. Incoming data in January and February have
increased the model’s view of the probability of recession 12 months hence from 5
percent to 16 percent. The increase has been driven by both a flattening of the yield
curve and a widening of credit spreads, with the GZ index having increased from 2.5
percent to 2.9 percent. In sum, the model views the recent deterioration in financial
indicators as signaling greater downside risk to the economy.

Page 7 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Finally, as forecasts of recession probabilities have increased since December
2015, the confidence intervals around these estimates have widened correspondingly.
The blue shaded area in Figure 3 displays the 68 percent confidence intervals around the
current BMA forecast. The current 68-percent confidence interval around the 12-month
ahead forecast now ranges from 0 percent to 50 percent, whereas in December the range
was 0 percent to 40 percent.7 It is noteworthy that, despite the flexibility of the BMA
approach, these confidence intervals span a very large range, emphasizing the limited
ability of simple statistical models to forecast downturns.

An important caveat: Forecasting accuracy out-of-sample
While the BMA models were designed to fit the historical pattern of U.S.
recessions, an additional issue is how they will likely perform out-of-sample. A natural
question to ask, therefore, is how strong a signal might the BMA methodology have sent
ahead of the 2001 and 2008 recessions? To shed light on this issue, we perform a pseudo
out-of-sample forecasting exercise by, for example, using data only through the fall of
2000 to produce forecasts over the next 12 months to measure the extent to which the
model could have anticipated the subsequent downturn.8
As shown in Table 2, six months prior to the 2001 recession, the model forecast a
35 percent probability that the U.S. economy would be in recession 12 months from that
point in time, well above the unconditional average. The results indicate that by
December, three months ahead of the NBER-dated recession, the model would have sent
a fairly strong signal of the pending downturn.

7

Note that this widening of uncertainty is in a sense mechanical—uncertainty in the probit model is
. However, because the transformation
reflected in the linear combination from equation (1),
from this combination to a probability is nonlinear, small movements in the covariates can produce large
changes in their associated probability and confidence interval.
8
Importantly, owing to data constraints, we use current-vintage data for this exercise. Any judgement on
the model’s success based on forecasts using revised data should be viewed as an upper-bound on the
model capability.

Page 8 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Table 2: Recession probabilities prior to 2001 recession
Forecast made using data through:
Sept‐2000
Dec‐2000
Current‐month
6
4
Three‐months hence
28
67
Six months hence
32
57
Twelve months hence
35
39
Note: NBER peak dated March, 2001; NBER trough is November,
2001.

Similarly, with data six months prior to the December 2007 peak in economic
activity, June 2007, the model forecast a 25 percent probability that the U.S. economy
would be in recession 12 months from that point in time. Three months later, with data
through September 2007 in hand, the model forecast of a recession 12 months had risen
to 40 percent. Most models do not send very strong signals of recession very far ahead of
time.9
Table 3: Recession probabilities prior to 2007 recession
Forecast made using data through:
June‐2007
Sept‐2007
Current‐month
15
22
Three‐months hence
26
22
Six months hence
26
41
Twelve months hence
25
41
Note: NBER peak dated December, 2007; NBER trough is June, 2009.

9

See, for example, Chauvet and Potter (2008), Hamilton (2011), and Berge (2015) for discussions of the
real-time performance of several different classes of recession models.

Page 9 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Appendix
Here we present a more formal evaluation of the model’s in-sample fit. Figure
A1 plots so-called Receiver Operating Characteristic (ROC) curve. The figure depicts the
tradeoff associated with achieving a particular true positive rate—that is, the likelihood
the model correctly forecasts recessions that actually occur—against the model’s
corresponding false positive rate—the likelihood it predicts high recession odds when the
economy actually continues to expand.10
Figure A1. Tradeoff between true positive and false positive
in-sample predictions in the BMA model

Focusing first on the left-side panel, at the 3-month horizon, to obtain a true
positive rate of 85 percent—that is, the fraction of times the model signals recession and
a recession is actually realized—one has to bear a false positive rate—periods when the
model signals recession but an expansion occurs instead—of just 5 percent. According to
the right panel, the 12-month ahead forecast is able to classify NBER-defined recessions
quite well in sample: to obtain the same true positive rate of 85 percent, the
corresponding false positive rate is only 15 percent, quite an impressive performance.

10

See Berge and Jorda (2011) for a formal introduction to ROC curves and their use in evaluating forecasts
of NBER recession dates.

Page 10 of 12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

An additional statistic that emerges from the ROC curves is the area underneath
the curve, or AUC. Values of the AUC vary between 0.5, indicating predictive
performance akin to a coin-toss, and 1, perfect classification ability. The AUC’s of the
BMA models at the 3 and 12 month horizons are 97 and 91 percent, respectively. Of
course, out-of-sample, the model’s performance would deteriorate. Berge (2015)
provides evidence from a pseudo out-of-sample forecasting exercise that the AUCs of
very similar models that forecast three and twelve months hence obtain AUC statistics of
90 and 85 percent, respectively.

Appendix Table 1: Variables included in forecasting models
Variable
Financial Variables
Slope of yield curve
Curvature of yield curve
GZ index
TED spread
BBB corporate spread
S&P 500, 1-month return
S&P 500, 3-month return
Trade-weighted dollar
VIX
Macroeconomic Indicators
Real personal consumption
expend.
Real disposable personal
income
Industrial production
Housing permits
Nonfarm payroll employment
Initial claims
Weekly hours, manufacturing
Purchasing managers index

Definition/notes

Transformation

10-year Treasury less 3-month yield
2 x 2-year minus 3-month and 10-year
Gilchrist and Zakrajsek (AER, 2012)
3-month ED less 3-month Treasury yield
BBB less 10-year Treasury yield
1-month log diff.
3-month log diff.
3-month log diff.
CBOE and extended following Bloom

3-month log diff.

4-week moving average

Note: Treasury yields from Gurkaynak, Swanson and Wright (2007).

Page 11 of 12

3-month log diff.
3-month log diff.
3-month log diff.
3-month log diff.
3-month log diff.
3-month log diff.
3-month log diff.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

References
Berge, T.J. and O. Jorda (2011) “Evaluating the Classification of Economic Activity into
Recessions and Expansions,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3(2), 246277, April.
Berge, T.J. (2015) “Predicting Recessions with Leading Indicators: Model Averaging and
Selection over the Business Cycle,” Journal of Forecasting 34(6): 455-471.
Chauvet, M. and J. Piger (2008) “A comparison of the real-time performance of business
cycle dating methods,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 26: 42–49.
Faust, J., S. Gilchrist, J.H. Wright, and E. Zakrajšek (2013), “Credit Spreads as Predictors
of Real-Time Economic Activity: A Bayesian Model-Averaging Approach,” Review of
Economics and Statistics 95(5): 1501–1519.
Gilchrist, S., and E. Zakrajšek (2012), “Credit Spreads and the Business Cycle
Fluctuations,” American Economic Review 102(4): 1692-1720.
Gurkaynak, R., B. Sack and J.H. Wright (2006) “The U.S. Treasury Yield Curve: 1961 to
the Present,” FEDS Working Paper Series 2006-28.
Hamilton J.D. (2011) “Calling recessions in real time,” International Journal of
Forecasting 27(4): 1006–1026.
Leamer, E.E. (1978), Specification Searches: Ad Hoc Inference with Nonexperimental
Data (New York: Wiley).
Piger, J., and J.C. Morely (2008) “Trend-Cycle Decomposition of Regime-Switching
Processes,” Journal of Econometrics 146: 220-226.
Raftery, A.E. (1995) “Bayesian Model Selection in Social Research,” Sociological
Methodology 25: 111-163.
Wright, J.H. (2009) “Forecasting U.S. Inflation by Bayesian Model Averaging”, Journal
of Forecasting, 28: 131-144.

Page 12 of 12