View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in
the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
in Washington, D. C., on Tuesday, June 24, 1969, at 9:30 a.m.
PRESENT:

Martin, Chairman
Bopp
Brimmer
Clay
Coldwell
Daane
Maisel
Mitchell
Robertson
Mr. Scanlon
Mr. Sherrill
Mr. Treiber, Alternate for Mr. Hayes

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Messrs. Francis, Heflin, Hickman, and Swan,
Alternate Members of the Federal Open
Market Committee
Messrs. Morris, Kimbrel, and Galusha,
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of Boston, Atlanta, and Minneapolis,
respectively
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Broida, Deputy Secretary
Messrs. Kenyon and Molony, Assistant
Secretaries
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Partee, Economist
Messrs. Axilrod, Baughman, Eastburn, Gramley,
Green, Hersey, Reynolds, Solomon, and
Tow, Associate Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market Account
Mr. Sherman, Consultant, Board of Governors
Mr. Cardon, Assistant to the Board of Governors
Messrs. Coyne and Nichols, Special Assistants
to the Board of Governors
Mr. Williams, Adviser, Division of Research
and Statistics, Board of Governors

6/24/69
Mr. Wernick, Associate Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Mr. Keir, Assistant Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Mr. Bernard, Special Assistant, Office of
the Secretary, Board of Governors
Miss Eaton, Open Market Secretariat
Assistant, Office of the Secretary,
Board of Governors
Messrs. Taylor and Jones, Senior Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of Atlanta and St. Louis, respectively
Messrs. Eisenmenger and Hocter, Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of Boston and Cleveland, respectively
Messrs. Garvy and Kareken, Economic Advisers,
Federal Reserve Banks of New York and
Minneapolis, respectively
Messrs. Bodner and Wallace, Assistant Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of New York and Richmond, respectively
Mr. Cooper, Manager, Securities and
Acceptance Departments, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York
Mr. Lynn, Director of Research, Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco
By unanimous vote, the minutes of
actions taken at the meeting of the Federal
Open Market Committee held on May 27, 1969,
were approved.
With respect to the memorandum of discussion for the meeting
held on May 27, 1969, the Secretary reported that one revision on
page 3 of the preliminary draft, which was indicated in the memo
randum of proposed changes, had inadvertently not been made in the
revised draft distributed before this meeting.

He noted that

corrected copies of the affected page would be distributed following
the meeting.

6/24/69
The memorandum of discussion
for the meeting of the Federal Open
Market Committee held on May 27,
1969, was accepted.
Chairman Martin reported briefly on the Sixteenth Monetary
Conference of the American Bankers Association, held in Copenhagen
on June 15 to 20, which he had attended along with Governors Daane
and Mitchell and Presidents Hayes, Scanlon, and Francis.

Although

not much of substance might have been accomplished, he said, there
had been some interesting discussions to which he had sought to
contribute in speaking at the closing meeting.
The Chairman noted that the Monetary Conferences had been
initiated as the outgrowth of discussions when he was Assistant
Secretary of the Treasury.

It had been his opinion that the useful

ness of the ABA's annual convention was limited by the extremely
large attendance, running into the thousands, and that it would
be helpful to supplement the convention with a small conference
of perhaps 50 or 60 top officials of U.S. banks, at which monetary
problems could be considered in greater depth.

Unfortunately, the

size of the Conferences had grown over the years--more than 300
people had attended one of the sessions at Copenhagen--and they
were now distracted by the spotlight of publicity attendant upon
them.

He hoped it might be possible to restore something of the

original flavor of the Conferences, although admittedly that
involved problems for the ABA, and he suggested that those in the
Federal Reserve might use their offices to counsel in that direction.

6/24/69
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of the
System Open Market Account on foreign exchange market conditions
and on Open Market Account and Treasury operations in foreign
currencies for the period May 27 through June 18, 1969, and a
supplemental report covering the period June 19 through 23, 1969.
Copies of these reports have been placed in the files of the
Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Bodner
said that the Treasury's gold stock remained unchanged, as it had
for a year.

The Stabilization Fund's gold holdings now stood at

$794 million, about unchanged since the previous meeting of the
Committee.
Mr. Bodner commented that the principal feature of inter
national financial activity during the past month had, of course,
been the Euro-dollar market.

The intense pressures in that market

had resulted in major flows of funds that had dominated developments
in both the gold and exchange markets.

As the Committee was well

aware, interest rates in the Euro-dollar market had been moving
up steadily through the spring months, and in mid-May had reached
levels over 9-1/2 per cent.

Shortly after the previous meeting

there had been a jump to 10-1/2 per cent, and during the course
of early June there had been a further escalation as U.S. banks
drew steadily increasing amounts from the market.

Rates hit a peak

6/24/69

-5

of about 13 per cent per annum on June 10 following the prime rate
increase of the preceding day.

Although there had been some

easing since then, rates currently were about 11 per cent for
maturities of one to six months, and the available evidence indi
cated no slackening in the demands being made on the market by
U.S. banks.

Indeed, after having risen by just over $1 billion in

each of the first two weeks of June, those borrowings advanced by
over $1.25 billion in the week ended last Wednesday (June 18).
With the mid-year window-dressing period on the continent now
coming up, most market observers were looking for a renewed in
crease in rates before the month-end.
So far, Mr. Bodner said, the Euro-dollar market had
proved remarkably resilient in the face of those unprecedented
demands.

Indeed, he doubted that the most optimistic observers

would have thought that such a period of extraordinarily high
interest rates could be experienced without any really serious
dislocations in the market.

One major reason seemed clearly

to be that the market had been heavily supplied from this country,
if the recent U.S. balance of payments figures were any guide.
Nevertheless, he thought it would be dangerous to be too sanguine
about the prospects for the immediate future.

There would be

sizable withdrawals of funds by several continental countries at
the month-end, and with the flow into the market from Germany

-6

6/24/69

virtually at a halt until today, continued heavy pressure from
U.S. banks could yet result in some serious difficulties in the
market.
Any such pressures were likely to be felt not only in the
Euro-dollar market itself, Mr. Bodner continued, but, of course,
also in the exchange markets.

Few major currencies had escaped

the impact of the Euro-dollar pressures and if those should
intensify, a further round of the kinds of defensive measures that
had already been taken in a number of countries probably could be
expected.

Indeed, the Dutch had indicated at the last Basle

meeting that they were actively considering measures to restrict
the access of their banks to the Euro-dollar market.

That was in

response to a heavy drain on Dutch reserves during the past month
as the Netherlands Bank was forced to spend some $100 million in
supporting the guilder at the floor.

As the Committee was aware,

the Dutch had reactivated their swap line for a total of $82
million to date.
Mr. Bodner noted that similar pressures had been felt
among the Scandinavian countries, with Sweden in particular having
lost nearly $60 million in the past month and the Danes becoming
increasingly concerned about their ability to maintain the present
parity.

The Belgian franc also had been driven to the floor, but

the Belgian reserve position had not deteriorated quite so much
because the Belgians had already instituted requirements for their

-7

6/24/69
banks to repatriate funds.

Nevertheless, the National Bank of

Belgium had had to make some further use of the swap line; their
drawings presently stood at $130.5 million.
was under pressure again this morning.

The Belgian franc

It was, of course, the

smaller countries that had been the most vulnerable to the Euro
dollar pressures and that had been most anxious to see something
done on the U.S. side to reduce those pressures.
Mr. Bodner remarked that among the major countries the
picture had been somewhat, but not entirely, different.

For most

of the period, Germany was the major European supplier of funds
to the Euro-dollar market and the heavy demands served a useful
function by encouraging the reflux of speculative funds from Germany.
The German Federal Bank had assisted in that reflow by maintaining
relatively attractive swap rates as well as by supporting the spot
rate just below par.

Consequently, by June 11, the German

Federal Bank had sold on a spot or swap basis about $3.5 billion
of the nearly $5 billion that had come in during April and May.
By then, however, short-term interest rates in Germany had begun
accelerating rapidly and, with large tax payments due at the end
of June, the Germans had become concerned about the level of
domestic liquidity.

They consequently had adjusted both their

spot and forward intervention rates and those measures, along with
the natural adjustments taking place in the market, had resulted

6/24/69

-8

in a complete halt in the outflow from German reserves.

However,

the outflow had resumed today.
The situation in France had of course been different,
Mr. Bodner said, although there too the high Euro-dollar rates
had brought additional pressure, within the limits imposed by
exchange control.

Bank of France losses during the period had

been heavy and continuous, and from the beginning of June
through last Friday had reached a total of over $400 million.
The French trade situation continued to look weak and the forth
coming wage negotiations posed a further threat to the position
of the franc.

Meanwhile, to cover losses this month the French

had had to draw further on the credit lines established last
November.

Moreover, at the end of May, the French had obtained

$250 million from the Germans as a recycling credit.

The French

had repaid that credit this month, but to do so they had had to
draw a substantial amount of the remaining leeway under the
November arrangement.

There probably was less than $150 million

still available under those lines, allowing for the fact that some
of the participating countries did not have funds to advance.
Although the franc had strengthened following the announcement
of the new French cabinet, its longer-run prospects looked no
better than they had for some time.
In Italy, Mr. Bodner observed, the central bank had taken
some defensive measures in March to require Italian banks to

-9

6/24/69

repatriate substantial funds by the end of June.

Those measures

had tended to protect Italian reserves over the past few monthsalthough the lira had frequently been at or close to the floor
as the bank note outflow from Italy had continued at a very high
level.

During the past weekend the Bank of Italy had moved again,

raising the discount rate to 5 per cent from 3-1/2 per cent for
those banks that had made heavy use of their rediscount privileges
Mr. Bodner remarked that the only countries that might be
said to have escaped the pressures to some extent were the United
Kingdom and Switzerland.

Throughout the past month, the British

had continued to take in small amounts of dollars and, following
the publication of good trade figures for May, they had picked
up a fairly substantial amount.

The absence of more obvious

pressures on sterling would seem to be accounted for by the very
great tightening of credit in Britain and by the fact that the
sterling balances of the non-sterling area already had been run
down to such a very low level.

Clearly, a major risk in the U.K.

situation was the political difficulty of maintaining the credit
squeeze over a long period.

Moreover, although the market

seemed to have taken it fairly well, the inability of the govern
ment to push through the union legislation did not augur well for
the future; and with sterling now coming into a seasonally more
adverse period the outlook was rather bleak.

-10

6/24/69

As the Committee was aware, Mr. Bodner continued, Britain
would be drawing approximately $500 million from the International
Monetary Fund at the end of June under the new $1 billion standby
facility.

On present intentions, some $200 million would be used

to repay short-term credits from the Bank for International Settle
ments that had been made in anticipation of the drawing.

In view of

the small rise in British reserves so far this month, some part
of the remaining $300 million probably would be needed to finance
the mandatory repayments under the second sterling balances
arrangement.

Consequently, it now seemed likely that there would

be somewhat less money left over for repayment of drawings on the
System swap line than originally had been anticipated--perhaps
no more than $100 million.
The one major currency which he had not yet mentioned,
Mr. Bodner said, was the Swiss franc.

There too, the pressures

in the Euro-dollar market were exerting an influence that was
disturbing the usual June pattern.

Because of the high rates

available on dollars, Swiss banks had been reluctant to begin
repatriating funds for the month-end.

At the same time the Swiss

National Bank, concerned about the over-all shortage of liquidity
in the Swiss market, had advised the banks that it would make
short-term swaps available for the month-end only to a total of
$250 million, with each bank assigned a specific quota.

The bulk

of those swaps had already been done and the money returned to the

6/24/69

-11

Euro-dollar market.

The National Bank expected the rest of the

liquidity needs--thought to be on the order of $500 million--to
be met through rediscounting of paper with the National Bank or
spot sales of dollars to that Bank.

So far, however, the Swiss

franc had remained below the ceiling and some of the Swiss banks
reportedly believed that they would be able to get through the
end of the month simply by rediscounting paper, without having
to sell dollars.
Finally, Mr. Bodner remarked, he might say a word about
the gold market, which also had been affected by the high cost of
dollars.

After a rather long period during which the price had

been very stable at $43.50--with the South Africans feeding out
just enough gold to keep the price from rising and not enough to
bring it down--the market had begun to break at the end of May
when Euro-dollar rates jumped to levels over 10 per cent and
when South Africa began making substantial transfers out of its
published gold stock.

Those transfers were seen in the market

as indicating sizable current South African sales and that, coupled
with the rising cost of holding gold, encouraged a fairly sizable
liquidation of private positions which brought the price down to
below $41.00.

There was, in fact, no indication that those trans

fers did represent large current South African sales; it seemed
more likely that they were simply a rebuilding of the fund that
South Africa had set aside to disguise market sales.

During the

-12

6/24/69

last couple of weeks, the market had quieted down and the price
tended to center on about $41.40.

This morning the price had de

clined to $41.20 and the indications were that it would be
somewhat lower in the afternoon.
By unanimous vote, the System
open market transactions in foreign
currencies during the period May 27
through June 23, 1969, were approved,
ratified, and confirmed.
Mr. Bodner said he had only one recommendation for a
formal action by the Committee today, relating to Belgian use of
the swap line.

A small drawing--in the amount of $3 million--by

the National Bank of Belgium would reach the end of its first three
month term on July 16.

If the drawing were renewed for another

three months and remained outstanding for its full term the
Belgian line would have been in continuous use for more than one
year.

Accordingly, under the language of paragraph 1D of the

foreign currency authorization, renewal for a three-month period
would require specific authorization from the Committee.
Mr. Bodner noted that the Belgians anticipated taking in
dollars during the course of the summer.

In a conversation yesterday

they had indicated that they had every expectation of repaying,
before the one-year period elapsed, the drawing in question and
also two other small drawings--of $2.5 million and $4 million,
maturing on July 2 and 3, respectively--for which Mr. Coombs had
recommended renewal at the previous meeting of the Committee.

6/24/69

-13

Therefore, he (Mr. Bodner) recommended renewal of the $3 million
drawing if requested by the National Bank of Belgium.

He should

add, however, that at the next meeting the Committee probably
would have to consider the renewal of several larger Belgian
drawings that would again raise the question of maturities ex
tending beyond the one-year limit.
Mr.

Maisel said it

had been his understanding that the

Committee interpreted the one-year limit as applying not to
individual drawings but to the swap line as a whole.

Specifically,

he thought the rule was that, in the absence of special authoriza
tion, outstandings should be zero at some point within any twelve
month period.
Mr. Bodner remarked that that was his understanding also.
In the case under discussion, the latest date on which the National
Bank of Belgium had had no drawings outstanding was just before a
drawing on September 30, 1968, so that the one-year period would
be exceeded if they did not repay their outstandings in full by
September 30, 1969.

Technically, renewal for three-month periods

of the three small drawings in question would permit them to
remain outstanding until October 1969, but as he had indicated
the Belgians expected to liquidate those drawings before maturity.
The course he recommended was one the Committee had followed in
the past--for example,

in

connection with British drawings--of

-14

6/24/69

authorizing renewals of drawings on the understanding that they
would actually be repaid before the one-year limit was exceeded.
In response to a question by Mr. Hickman, Mr. Bodner said
that that understanding would apply to the three small drawings
maturing through July 16.

As he had mentioned earlier, there

were other drawings by the National Bank of Belgium maturing soon
that would again raise the question of the one-year limit.
By unanimous vote, renewal
for further periods of three months,
if requested, of the swap drawings
by the National Bank of Belgium
maturing in the period July 2-16,
1969, was authorized.
Mr. Bodner then noted that a memorandum from the Special
Manager 1/ had been distributed to the Committee last week which
outlined the current situation with respect to the warehousing
arrangement between the System and the Stabilization Fund and
transmitted a request from the Treasury that the Committee con
sider a temporary expansion of that facility.

As the memorandum

indicated, under the current interpretation of the $1 billion
warehousing authority, only $350 million was available for
financing the general operations of the Stabilization Fund and
$195 million of that authority was presently in use.

The members

would recall that the warehousing arrangement went back to

1/ A copy of this memorandum, dated June 18, 1969, and
entitled "Request for a more liberal interpretation of the $1
billion warehousing facility for the Stabilization Fund," has
been placed in the Committee's files.

6/24/69

-15

November 1963 when the Committee had authorized warehousing of
up to $100 million of currencies in which the Treasury had out
standing indebtedness.

At that time the lira was weak and there

was an opportunity to acquire lire to cover Treasury securities
denominated in that currency, but the Stabilization Fund did
not have sufficient resources for the purpose.

Subsequently,

in April 1966, the authority was increased to $200 million.
Then, in November 1967, as noted in Mr. Coombs' memorandum, the
authority was increased to $350 million in connection with the
credit package to the United Kingdom that was then being negotiated.
At that time it was specifically spelled out in the Committee's
discussion that the $150 million additional authority was to be
used for warehousing guaranteed sterling.

In 1968 the authority

was increased to its present level of $1 billion in connection
with the Treasury participation in the Second Group Arrangement
for financing sterling balances.

The memorandum of discussion clearly

indicated that the additional $650 million was to be used solely for
that purpose, although there was nothing in the language of the
foreign currency authorization to that effect.

To sum up,

although the language of the authority was general, the staff
believed that the clear intention of the Committee to date had
been that not more than $350 million of warehousing should be
made available to the Stabilization Fund for general purposes

-16

6/24/69

and, of that $350 million, not more than $200 million might be
in currencies other than guaranteed sterling.
As things stood at the moment, Mr. Bodner continued,
it was likely that the $155 million available for further ware
housing under that interpretation would not prove adequate in
the next few months.

There was every possibility that the

French would be in to sell a substantial amount of gold in
the near future in view of the large drawings on their swap
lines they had made this month.
calls on Treasury resources.

In addition, there might be other

The only readily available source

of funds other than the System would be monetization of some of
the Stabilization Fund's large gold holdings.

A decision on what

to do with the Stabilization Fund gold was currently under
discussion at the Treasury, but the Treasury clearly preferred
not to have to make and execute that decision immediately.

One

course under consideration, for example, was using the gold to
repay the $800 million owed to the IMF.

If the Treasury decided

to go in that direction, however, it might well want to wait
to make the move in connection with other negotiations in the
Fund.
Mr. Bodner observed that the question at issue was simply
whether the System believed it was both desirable and necessary
to force the immediate, or early, monetization of some of the
Stabilization Fund's gold holdings, or, alternatively, whether

6/24/69

-17

it was prepared to give the Treasury some leeway in timing the
execution of that decision.

The monetary effects were the

same in either case--that is, purchase of the foreign exchange
from the Stabilization Fund added to the money supply in exactly
the same way as did monetization of the gold.

In any case, it

was clearly the Treasury's intention to make use of the gold
holdings and, consequently, the need for additional warehousing
should prove to be a temporary one.

He was, therefore, suggesting

simply a temporary liberalization of the understandings governing
the use of the warehousing arrangement.

Since the language of

the authority was not restrictive no formal action by the Com
mittee appeared to be necessary.
Mr. Coldwell asked whether adoption of the course Mr. Bodner
recommended might not create problems later, if a need arose for
use of the warehousing authority for the original purposes but
it was found that the necessary leeway was already employed.
Mr. Bodner replied that circumstances were conceivable
under which the present over-all authority to warehouse $1 billion
for the Treasury might prove inadequate, as Mr. Coombs had pointed
out in his memorandum.

The Treasury's commitment under the second

sterling balances arrangement remained in force, and it was
possible that the British would make drawings on the BIS of
sufficient size to require the BIS to activate its standby facili
ties with the U.S. Treasury and other participants in the

-18

6/24/69
arrangement.

If that should happen at a time when the Treasury

had already warehoused a substantial volume of foreign cur
rencies with the System it might prove necessary to increase
the over-all limit on amounts warehoused.
However, Mr. Bodner continued, he thought such a
combination of events was highly unlikely.

At the moment the

British were authorized to have drawings of only $35 million
under the second arrangement, and they were in the process
of repaying earlier drawings.

The resources of the BIS currently

seemed adequate to finance any likely British drawings.

The

latter could become substantial only if there were a sharp
reduction in sterling holdings of the overseas sterling area,
and there were no indications that such an event was in the
offing.

Thus, the chances that the BIS would activate its

standby facility with the Treasury seemed small; and even if
it did so, there would still be the option of asking the Treasury
to raise the necessary funds by means other than warehousing
currencies with the System.
Mr. Mitchell noted that Mr. Bodner had suggested a
"temporary" liberalization of the understandings on use of the
warehousing authority.

He asked whether that could be interpreted

as meaning liberalization only for the remainder of 1969.
Mr. Bodner replied that a Treasury decision regarding
Stabilization Fund gold holdings was likely to be made during

6/24/69

-19

the next month but the question of the date of execution
remained open.

As he understood it, the matter might be re

solved well before the end of the year, and the year-end was
likely to be the outside limit.
In reply to questions by Mr. Brimmer, Mr. Bodner said
the Treasury might want to utilize a substantial part of the
$650 million of the warehousing authority that originally
had been earmarked for use in connection with the second sterling
balances arrangement.

However, he did not think they planned

to use the full amount.

Moreover, any use would be temporary,

since the Treasury definitely was going to make some decision
soon about the gold holdings of the Stabilization Fund.

From

the System's point of view it was immaterial whether the
decision was to monetize the gold or use it to repay debt to
the IMF; under either procedure the Stabilization Fund would
have the resources to repay the System.
Mr. Maisel commented that the question of whether or
not the Stabilization Fund's gold holdings should be monetized
had been a major one in the 1930's, and was still significant
today.

He would be willing to support Mr. Bodner's recommendation

since it called for only a temporary arrangement.

However, he

thought the System should not permit its resources to be used
to enable the Treasury to avoid monetization at the Treasury's

-20

6/24/69

discretion unless there was a thorough exploration of the under
lying issues.

Those were not detailed in the memorandum under

discussion.
Mr. Daane said he agreed with the principle Mr. Maisel had
expressed but did not think it applied to the Treasury's current
situation.

As he understood it, the Treasury wanted to provide

against the contingency that the IMF would activate its $800
million claim on U.S. gold, and was prepared to monetize the
Stabilization Fund's gold holdings if the IMF did not do so.
Mr. Maisel observed that the issue seemed to him to be
one of a not very good or elegant form of window dressing.

The

claim of the IMF on the Treasury was not new; it had been out
standing for many years.
Mr. Daane agreed that the claim was of long standing
but noted that the question of whether it should be exercised
had recently been raised in some quarters.

Accordingly, he

thought it was desirable to give the Treasury the kind of flexi
bility it sought.
Mr. Robertson noted that Mr. Bodner had indicated that
under certain circumstances it could prove necessary to raise
the present $1 billion limit for warehousing, and asked how high
a limit might prove necessary.
Mr. Bodner replied that under the most extreme circumstances
an increase in the limit to $1.650 billion would be required.

-21

6/24/69

Those circumstances would arise if the Treasury should utilize
the full $1 billion authority now existing for present purposes
and then be faced with a request by the BIS for activation of
the entire $650 million Treasury standby under the second bal
ances arrangement.

As he had indicated earlier, however, he did

not expect any increase to be required, and he had raised the
point only because some possibility existed.
Chairman Martin asked whether there would be any objec
tion to temporarily liberalizing the understandings regarding
use of the warehousing authority on the basis discussed today.
It was agreed unanimously that
the informal understandings governing
use of the existing authority to ware
house up to $1 billion of foreign
currencies for the Stabilization Fund
should be temporarily liberalized to
permit use of the full facility for
the general purposes of the Stabili
zation Fund without limitation as to
currency.
The Chairman then invited Mr. Mitchell to comment on
the recent meeting in Basle that the latter had attended.
Mr. Mitchell said that the discussion covered four main
topics.

The first concerned the progress being made by the

United States in its fight against inflation.

He had reported

that the System was exerting steady and continuous pressure, and
that the results of its monetary policy were beginning to show
up in financial markets and in a reduction in the rate of real

-22

6/24/69
economic growth.
position.

The second topic had to do with the British

Governor O'Brien of the Bank of England appeared to

be quite apprehensive about the consequences of another possible
wave of speculation in marks.

He had not expressed much confidence

in the government's program and was frankly pessimistic about
the possibility of Britain's going further into debt.

British

officials at the Monetary Conference in Copenhagen had taken the
position that the results of recent government measures were in
train and should lead to an improvement in Britain's position
in late 1969 or in 1970.

Perhaps Governor O'Brien's attitude

at Basle reflected fatigue from fighting the battle for so long.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that the third topic discussed at
Basle--and the one that got the most attention--was Germany's
decision not to revalue the mark.

There was not much Dr. Blessing

could say except that Germany was trying to neutralize the effects
of speculative flows into the mark through recycling and other
measures.

But his comments did not forestall questions as to

why Germany had not revalued or taken other actions.
The fourth topic, Mr. Mitchell continued, related to
U.S. participation in the Euro-dollar market.

That subject

was discussed at some length, but he should note that the Basle
meeting was held the day before the meeting of experts and, of
course, before Euro-dollar borrowings of U.S. banks had reached

6/24/69

-23

their present level.

The views expressed generally followed

the pattern Mr. Bodner had described today.

Representatives

from Germany, Italy, and Switzerland did not express any
concern about developments in the Euro-dollar market.

In fact,

President Stopper of the Swiss National Bank had said that the
Swiss authorities were grateful for the resulting upward pres
sure on their domestic market rates.

He (Mr. Mitchell) was not

sure how President Zijlstra of the Netherlands Bank felt.

The

British had larger headaches than the Euro-dollar market and
had not expressed concern.
comment.

The French had made no specific

On the other hand, the Belgians and the Swedes were

quite vocal on the subject.

On the whole, the discussion

had been friendly but inconclusive.
Mr. Mitchell said he might conclude by quoting two
statements that Dr. Zijlstra had made in the course of a speech
at the luncheon on June 9.

The first was as follows:

"I fully

recognize that there are limits on the ability of central banks
to resist the depreciation in the value of money.
must use their powers as fully as possible.

But they

This means that

in the operating model of central banks the money supply must
be taken as an independent variable; otherwise there would be
little reason to have central banks at all."

That statement

was in the tradition of Dutch monetary analysis, but it struck

-24

6/24/69

him as interesting considering the environment.
quotation was as follows:

The second

"In this situation, it is not

surprising that the dollar is affected by the troubles of
the system--seeing that it is the principal reserve currency
of the system and that the U.S. Treasury is still the supplier
of last resort of monetary gold.

While we may expect that

SDR's will be approved without long delay, they cannot be
expected to resolve the problem fully so long as gold is kept
as a valued reserve medium."
Chairman Martin then asked Mr. Solomon to report on the
three European meetings he had recently attended--the meetings
of Working Party 3 and the Group of Ten Deputies, and the meet
ing of experts at the BIS on the Euro-dollar situation.
Mr. Solomon remarked that he would resist the tempta
tion to begin his report by quarreling with the second of
Dr. Zijlstra's statements that Mr. Mitchell had quoted.

At

the Working Party 3 meeting, the British situation had been
given a very careful review as part of the process leading up
to the approval of use of the General Arrangements to Borrow
in connection with the standby agreement under which the British
had now drawn $500 million from the IMF.

The upshot of the

discussion was that there was still some skepticism about the
ability of the British to achieve their balance of payments

6/24/69

-25

objectives, which had been scaled down from earlier.

They

now expected to achieve a surplus of 300 million pounds during
the current fiscal year.

Their fiscal policy was pretty well

set--which sounded like a familiar statement--but they were
preparing to use monetary policy more fully.

They had already

begun to do so, and had set a limit on the expansion of monetary
aggregates.

They were employing a new concept of "domestic

credit expansion," defined as the increase in bank deposits
plus or minus the balance of payments deficit or surplus.

The

rationale for that concept was that excess domestic monetary
expansion could be disguised when part of it was absorbed by
a payments deficit.

A staff memorandum on the subject was avail

able to any Committee member who wanted to pursue the subject
further.
The Working Party looked rather closely at the U.S. situa
tion, Mr. Solomon said.

The state of the U.S. balance of payments

was an important consideration to be taken into account for activa
tion of SDR's, a subject also discussed at this meeting.

As one

might expect, there was some sentiment that U.S. policy might
usefully employ a little less gradualism and be more harsh in slowing
down the economy, but that view was far from unanimous.

There was

puzzlement about the way in which U.S. monetary policy worked and
particularly about its impact on the Euro-dollar market.

The

U.S. representatives were asked specifically why the United States

6/24/69

-26

had not acted as many European countries had, to place direct
restrictions on banks' domestic lending.
The Euro-dollar market itself was discussed at both
the WP-3 meeting and the experts' meeting in Basle, Mr. Solomon
continued.

He had little to add to Mr. Mitchell's comments.

Considerable concern was expressed by some participants, and
two types of problems were noted.

Some countries were worried

about the impact of high Euro-dollar rates on their own interest
rates and on their reserves.

But the Germans welcomed the rise

in Euro-dollar rates because it gave them leeway to raise their
domestic interest rates without attracting foreign money.

The

second concern was about the effect on the viability and stability
of the Euro-dollar market itself of the current very high levels
of interest rates.

There was a danger, some felt, of failures of

some borrowers and irrational acts of withdrawal on the part of
some depositors.
Finally, Mr. Solomon said, WP-3 and then the Group of Ten
Deputies discussed the creation of SDR's.

He could sum up the dis

cussion in WP-3 by saying that some concern was expressed that early
activation of SDR's might hinder balance of payments adjustment,
in that it would provide financing to some deficit countries
who might then take less vigorous action on their own; but there
also was a realization that failure to create new reserves could

6/24/69

-27

frustrate the adjustment process.

Under Secretary Volcker had

made an excellent statement on the subject, in which he said that
if other countries followed their past behavior, the major con
sequence of not creating reserves would be to force balance of
payments deficits back on the United States.

In the end, no one

felt that SDR's should not be created in the near future.
The question for the Group of Ten Deputies, Mr. Solomon
remarked, was not whether SDR's should be created, but how muchbut that group did not attempt at this meeting to reach a specific
conclusion on the question.

The range of discussion was from $2

billion a year up to $4 billion or more, and his guess was that
the outcome would fall within that range.

Whether the first

decision to allocate SDR's would be for a full five years also
was in question.

The main concern in that connection was about

the U.S. balance of payments deficit and whether it would constitute
a large source of reserves for the rest of the world.
Mr. Solomon said that an increase in IMF quotas next year
also came up for brief discussion.

The question was whether to

have a general increase, selective country increases, or both.
He thought there was agreement that that issue would not be allowed
to interfere with the activation of SDR's.

The French representative

said he understood that some members wished to give priority to SDR
activation and that he had no objection to such a course; but that
the French themselves would like to have a special quota increase.

-28-

6/24/69

Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System
Open Market Account covering domestic open market operations for
the period May 27 through June 18, 1969, and a supplemental
report covering June 19 through 23, 1969.

Copies of both reports

have been placed in the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Holmes
commented as follows:
Most interest rates reached new historical high
levels over the four weeks since the Committee last
met, a period dominated by a growing feeling of
pressure within the banking and financial community.
The increase in the prime rate to 8-1/2 per cent on
June 9 highlighted the interest rate developments
and touched off a rapid upsurge in short-term interest
rates which is amply described in the written reports
to the Committee. In yesterday's regular Treasury
bill auction average rates of 6.52 and 6.87 per cent
were established respectively for 3- and 6-month
bills, up 40 and 65 basis points from the levels
established in the auction just preceding the last
meeting of the Committee.
Despite all the frenzy, which reached a peak
just prior to the June 16 tax date, the money and
credit markets were able to turn in a creditable
performance. The ability of the major banks to
pull in funds from the Euro-dollar market--while
causing its own set of problems--alleviated the need
to dispose of Government and municipal securities
in the domestic markets. In the absence of selling
pressure, yields on long-term Government securities
actually declined over the period, despite competition
from record high yields on corporate securities. In

6/24/69

-29-

the corporate market, a large volume of new issues
generally moved well at rising interest rates. The
tax-exempt market, in contrast, continued to show
a heavy tone even though a number of new issues were
postponed, either because of market conditions or
because of interest rate ceilings.
Generally speaking, the markets appear to have
learned to live--albeit not too comfortably--with
the unsettled conditions that have prevailed recently.
Carrying costs are, of course, extremely high.
While dealer firms have had to take substantial
losses on inventory and continue to be apprehensive
about the future, there does not appear to be evidence
of any extreme financial problems in the dealer com
munity. In fact, the passage of the tax date without
disaster appears to have led to some relaxation of
market tensions, and the weak performance of the
stock market has begun to convince some market
observers that there may be some hope for the bond
market after all.
While there appears to be a growing conviction
that anti-inflationary policies will take hold, it
would appear likely that the money and credit markets
will continue to be vulnerable and sensitive to day
by-day developments in the domestic economy and on
the international scene. The mid-year interest
crediting and Euro-dollar window-dressing period is
likely to provide the next test for the markets,
and there will be constant pressure from Government
agency financing and the return of the Treasury to
the market in July to contend with. The municipal
market still appears to be the greatest problem
area. Banks have recently been forced to take on
more short-term tax-exempt notes than they want,
and this supply, together with the pent-up demand
from States and localities, is still overhanging
the market. Thus, I would agree with the blue book's 1/
conclusion that substantial upward pressures on both

1/ The report, "Money Market and Reserve Relationships,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

6/24/69

-30-

long- and short-term interest rates are likely to
continue, but that a shift away from inflationary
expectations could become a major factor in long
term markets.
Open market operations over the period since
the Committee last met had to be flexibly adapted
to take account of the pressures in the central money
market exerted by bank apprehensions about tax-date
problems and to handle a large volume of foreign
sales of Treasury bills. Banks generally tended to
be very cautious in managing their reserve positions,
and with the major money market banks running heavy
basic reserve deficits there was a tendency for
money market conditions to be very taut before the
weekend and to ease thereafter. Accordingly, open
market operations were used to inject reserves
early in the statement week, while matched-sale
purchase agreements again proved invaluable as an
instrument for absorbing temporary reserve excesses
late in the statement week. Over the period foreign
official accounts were heavy net sellers of Treasury
bills, with the total reaching $1.7 billion--mainly
reflecting the diversion of funds to the Euro-dollar
market by Germany. As the written reports indicate,
the System bought approximately $1.2 billion of
Treasury bills net from foreign accounts, including
some purchases that were designed solely to keep
bills out of a very unreceptive market. In general,
it proved possible to offset any unwanted reserve
impact from these purchases, although a rather
schizophrenic set of operations was required on
several occasions.
As far as monetary aggregates are concerned,
both the bank credit proxy and the money supply
appear to be turning in a weaker performance in June
than anticipated at the last meeting. The credit
proxy--after adjustment for the large increase in
Euro-dollars--is currently projected at a 2 to 4 per
cent rate of decline for the month, and a further
decline is tentatively projected for July. The

6/24/69

-31

statistics are not easy to interpret, however, and
there has not been time to analyze completely the
results of the new statistical information collected
on the growth of nondeposit liabilities at the banks.
It appears, however, that banks were able to offset
at least part of the decline in deposits by the use
of various new instruments, so that a further rough
adjustment of the proxy would bring it to about a
zero growth rate. And there is continuing evidence
of still further expansion of credit outside of the
commercial banking system.
As far as the period ahead is concerned, I have
nothing to add to the discussion of money market
conditions contained in the blue book, although I
would stress that there are major uncertainties, and
not all of them statistical, that lie ahead. Open
market operations will have to be adapted flexibly
to meet shifts in sentiment that may arise as the
markets and the banking system continue to live
with, and adapt to, cumulative conditions of mone
tary restraint.
Mr. Mitchell asked if the dimensions of mid-year demands
for Euro-dollars by European banks for window-dressing purposes
could be estimated.
Mr. Holmes replied that prevailing uncertainties made
it difficult to predict the volume of funds that European banks
might choose to repatriate.

It was his impression, however,

that high interest rates were tending to keep more funds invested
in the Euro-dollar market than had been anticipated.
Mr. Mitchell inquired whether there was any specific
information available concerning outflows of funds from the
United States to the Euro-dollar market.

-32

6/24/69

Mr. Bodner indicated that the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York had conducted a survey among its contacts in New
York banks at the request of the Board staff.

While no system

atic evidence was uncovered, the general impression was that
funds were being drawn out of the country into the Euro-dollar
market.

Foreigners were reported to be making net sales of

equity securities and considerable interest was being shown
by individuals and small corporations concerning methods of
transferring funds to the Euro-dollar market.

In general,

banks appeared to be observing the foreign credit restraint
guidelines and were not undertaking to transfer funds for cus
tomers, but it appeared that funds were flowing out of the
country nevertheless.

The balance of payments statistics also

suggested that substantial movements of funds were occurring,
but none of the market specialists contacted in New York
could report that significant transfers of funds were being
reflected on their books.
By unanimous vote, the open
market transactions in Government
securities, agency obligations,
and bankers' acceptances during
the period May 27 through June 23,
1969, were approved, ratified,
and confirmed.
The Chairman then called for the staff economic and
financial reports, supplementing the written reports that had

-33-

6/24/69

been distributed prior to the meeting, copies of which have been
placed in the files of the Committee.

At this meeting the staff

reports were in the form of a visual-auditory presentation and
copies of the charts have been placed in the files of the
Committee.
Mr. Partee made the following introductory statement:
Monetary policy in the year ahead is likely
to be faced with one of its more difficult tests
of the postwar period, if the forecasting judgments
we are presenting today prove to be roughly on tar
get. For while the economy is now in the middle of
intense inflationary pressures and a severe squeeze
in the credit markets, we think that the odds favor
ing a marked cooling off over the next year are quite
high.
Today's projection assumes that fiscal policy
will stay on the restrictive course recommended by
the Administration. A tight ceiling on budget outlays
of $192.9 billion is implied, and we are told that the
Administration puts a high priority on keeping within
that total. Also, we assume that the surcharge will
be extended at 10 per cent till year-end and 5 per
cent thereafter, and that the investment tax credit
will be eliminated. Both of these measures seem now
to stand a good chance of getting through Congress,
though perhaps with some delay.
For monetary policy, we are assuming continuation
of the current policy stance over the months immediately
ahead, and then a gradual move towards less restraint
in the fall, when we expect the incoming information to
signal more clearly the projected economic slowdown.
The timing and extent of this move towards reduced
restraint are critical. Too early or too large a shift
in policy could seriously injure hopes of getting
inflation under control; too late or too small a move
might contribute to a deeper and more prolonged setback
in the economy than would be socially or politically
tolerable.

6/24/69

-34Mr. Wernick reviewed nonfinancial developments as

follows:
Considerable momentum is still evident in
important sectors of the economy, despite the
slowing in real growth over the past year. As a
result, current statistics present a mixed picture
of economic developments. Industrial production
has been rising rapidly, and may show a 6 per cent
annual rate of increase in the current quarter.
Prices, too, have been moving up rapidly. Since
early this year, consumer prices have risen almost
twice as fast as a year ago, and widespread increases
have also been registered in wholesale prices.
At the same time, retail sales have been
sluggish since last fall, and the dollar volume is
now running only about 3 to 4 per cent above a year
ago. With prices higher, real takings have actually
fallen below year-ago levels. And employers are
adopting more cautious hiring policies; production
worker employment in manufacturing declined slightly
in April and May, following a sharp run-up earlier.
Despite these conflicting indicators, we believe
real growth in the economy will slow further. The
sluggish pace of Federal purchases and consumer
buying since last summer, together with the unusually
high costs and limited availability of borrowed funds,
appear to be affecting business decisions in important
ways.
Thus, the most recent Commerce-SEC survey points
to a marked slowing in plant and equipment spending
during the last half of this year, and this seems to
be confirmed by the trend of new orders. With the
investment tax credit assumed to be eliminated, and
the imbalance between output and available capacity
worsening, we expect the slowdown to turn into an
actual decline early next year.
We are projecting business fixed investment to
be falling at an annual rate of 8 per cent by the
second quarter of 1970. This would be a bit steeper
than the decline in early 1967, but it is not as
severe a drop as in the 1957 recession.
A slower pace of business fixed investment
would increase the prospects for an inventory
correction. For durable goods manufacturers,
inventory-to-sales ratios have been hovering at

6/24/69

-35-

about the level they reached at the end of 1966--prior
to the inventory adjustment of early 1967. Recent
stock-sales ratios, however, have been moderately
below those reached at the upper turning points of
the 1957 and 1960 cycles. But if final sales weaken,
these ratios could rise rapidly, as they did in earlier
periods of slowing demands, inducing businesses to cut
back production and orders.
We are not, however, projecting a decline in
inventory investment until after the fourth quarter
of 1969. Inventory investment in the third quarter
of this year is expected to stay at about the first
half rate, and then to rise a little in the fourth
quarter as final sales slow materially. In the first
half of 1970, inventory investment should drop substan
tially as businessmen attempt to trim excess stocks.
This pattern of change would resemble the 1957
experience, when the rate of inventory investment
remained fairly steady until the cycle peak, and then
dropped sharply.
The large jump in inventory investment late in
1966 and the steep decline thereafter is not a typical
cyclical pattern. Such large changes in the rate of
inventory investment seem unlikely to be repeated.
As Mr. Partee noted, we assume that the fiscal
restraint program proposed by the Administration will
be adopted. The tight budget ceiling implies that
Federal expenditures on the national income accounts
basis will show only a slow rise following the Federal
pay increase in the third quarter. In fact, a slight
decline in defense expenditures is anticipated after
the third quarter--a pattern that seems consistent with
recent order trends and announced troop deployment in
Vietnam.
Federal receipts are projected to show little
further growth this year, reflecting completion of
retroactive tax payments, and then to decline somewhat
in the first half of next year, because of slower income
growth and the assumed reduction in the surcharge to
5 per cent on January 1.
The budget surplus should therefore decline a little
after midyear, and a small deficit is projected for the
first two quarters of 1970. However, much of this swing
to deficit reflects the slowdown in economic expansion.
On a full employment basis, using the third quarter of
1969 as a base, the budget would still be showing a
moderate surplus in the first half of 1970.

6/24/69

-36-

Turning to the consumer sector, it is now quite clear
that higher taxes since mid-1968 have tempered growth in
consumer expenditures, as well as in disposable income,
even though consumers have reduced their savings rate
appreciably.
Over the next year gains in consumer expenditures
are projected to be moderate, with the average quarterly
increase below the first quarter of this year. The
dampening effect on disposable income of reduced over
time work and declining employment is the most important
factor limiting growth in consumer outlays. While the
Government pay raise just ahead and the reduction in the
surcharge on January 1 will make important additions to
income, the impact on spending should not outweigh the
effects of slower growth in wages and salaries.
On balance, there appear to be few remaining sources
of strength in the economy, and there is, therefore, a
strong possibility of a considerable slowdown in GNP
growth over the next year. The weakness should become
evident later this summer, after the Federal pay raise
has given a temporary fillip to retail sales in the third
quarter, and growth in GNP should fade to about $11
billion in the fourth quarter. Next year, the reduction
in the surcharge may help to sustain consumer buying,
and residential construction could pick up as competing
uses of funds moderate. Nonetheless, these factors seem
far too weak to offset dampened business spending and
the multiplier effects on income and consumption. We
expect that gains in GNP will drop to a $6-7 billion
range by mid-1970.
Translated into real terms, GNP growth would recede
to about a 1 per cent annual rate in the fourth quarter
of this year, and then come to a standstill in the first
half of 1970.
If growth in the economy follows the projected path,
resource requirements could be expected to ease appreciably.
Capacity utilization is projected to fall significantly by
mid-1970, reflecting both a decline in industrial output
and continued additions to capacity. Businessmen should
find it increasingly difficult to pass on cost increases
to higher prices as available capacity becomes excessive.
Demands for manpower have already begun to moderate
somewhat--employment gains have slowed and unemployment
has started to move up slightly in recent months. In the
year ahead, our GNP projections imply rising layoffs and
a labor force growth that is close to a normal pace.
Consequently, unemployment is projected to increase to 4
per cent by the end of this year and to slightly over
4-1/2 per cent by the middle of next year.

6/24/69

-37-

Even with some easing in labor market pressures,
wage increases are likely to remain large as workers
bargain hard to hold down erosion in real earnings.
Consequently, we are not expecting much slowing in the
rate of increase in hourly earnings in manufacturing
before early 1970. Negotiations are expected to be
extremely difficult next year when many major labor
contracts are reopened.
However, past experience does suggest that the
rate of wage increases will diminish if the slowing in
aggregate demand is maintained over a period of time.
Thus, in 1956 and early 1957, wage increases slowed
and then fell off substantially in the four quarters
after the downturn. By contrast, during the short
lived inventory adjustment after the fourth quarter of
1966, wages continued to advance fairly rapidly and
then began to accelerate.
Because productivity growth typically slows in a
recession, unit labor costs continue to rise long after
the cycle peak--they reached a high in early 1958 and
again in early 1961, at the bottom of the recession.
After a prolonged period of stability from 1961 to the
end of 1965, unit labor costs began to move up sharply,
and the rise did not slow after the 1967 inventory
adjustment.
Over the long pull, unit labor costs and industrial
commodity prices move together, but industrial prices
respond more quickly to changing economic demands.
In
each of the recent periods of economic slowdown industrial
prices leveled off, although unit labor costs kept rising.
We expect this pattern to be repeated in the year aheadwith unit labor costs continuing to increase sharply for
a while, but some slackening developing in the industrial
price rise.
The GNP deflator is much less responsive to changes
in the rate of real GNP growth, because food and services
weigh heavily in that index. Nevertheless, with varying
lags, over-all prices also have responded to easing in
economic activity. Thus, in the 1960-61 recession, the
rate of increase in the price deflator did not taper off
appreciably till the recession was nearly over.
In early
1967, by contrast, the deflator responded fairly quickly
and sharply to the drop in GNP growth.
In the current period, gains in real GNP have
already moderated significantly, and are expected to
decline substantially further over the next year. While
the rate of increase in the deflator should moderate, as

-38-

6/24/69

it did in late 1957 and 1958, it may be some time before
significant progress is seen in cooling inflation.
Mr. Gramley presented the following analysis of
financial developments:
Private nonfinancial borrowers have raised
enormous sums in the credit markets since mid-1968;
their borrowing during this past year has amounted
to over 11 per cent of private GNP expenditures. But
monetary restraint this year has changed credit costs
and availability substantially, and we expect a sig
nificant decline in private borrowing in the second
half of 1969.
With GNP growth projected to moderate over the
projection period, private borrowing should remain
relatively low in the first half of 1970--assuming,
as we do, that a massive rush for liquidity such as
occurred in 1967 will not happen again.
Total Federal borrowing, including the borrowing
of quasi-governmental agencies, should turn up again
soon, as loan programs continue and the NIA budget
shifts to a small deficit in early 1970. But the
total of funds raised is projected to remain well
below recent peaks, when both Federal and private
demands were larger than we are projecting for the
year ahead.
In the economic climate envisaged, market forces
would be expected to exert downward pressures on in
terest rates--and perhaps rather strong pressures,
since currently high rate levels reflect inflationary
expectations. Once it becomes clear that excess
aggregate demand will not continue, investor willing
ness to acquire fixed-income securities could increase
markedly.
At many times in the past, interest rates have
seemed to us the most appropriate guides for monetary
policy, and the best available indicators of financial
conditions. But in the projected economic environment,
it is not clear how much rate decline would be needed
for consistency with our GNP projection, since borrowers,
too, will be reconsidering their calculations of invest
ment profitability as economic and inflationary
expectations change. With both borrower and lender
attitudes changing, how far or fast the interest rate
decline should go is difficult to quantify with precision.

6/24/69

-39-

Accordingly, although the level and structure
of interest rates must continue to be important
factors in assessing the course of policy, the
chances of serious error might be reduced if, over
the next year, relatively more emphasis were to be
placed on quantitative targets in setting a longer
run course for monetary policy.
The question of which quantitative target
should be selected, however, is not easy. Bank
credit, money supply, and reserves are three lead
ing candidates for selection as policy targets
over the longer run, and the choice among them is
not a matter of indifference.
Interpreting changes in bank credit growth
has become increasingly complex in recent years.
For example, during the first five months of
1969 the credit proxy adjusted for Euro-dollar
borrowing declined at more than a $2 billion
annual rate. The unadjusted credit proxy de
clined a good deal more. The arithmetic of adjusting
the proxy for Euro-dollar borrowing is simple, but
its analytic implications are not. An increase in
bank credit due to additional Euro-dollar borrow
ing does not add to the public's holdings of
deposits. Its effect on credit markets is not
the same as an increase in bank credit resulting
from open market purchases by the System, which do
generate additional deposits and increase liquidity.
And what should we make of the wide swings in
bank credit growth attributable to the volatility
of large-denomination CD's? We certainly cannot
ignore them; indeed, the effects of CD ceilings
on bank liquidity have played a major role in the
timing and sectoral distribution of the impact of
monetary restraint. But since CD's are so much
like market securities, and the demand for them
is so interest sensitive, variations in CD's do
not have the same meaning as changes in the growth
of other deposits. Of course, recent innovations
by banks to obtain funds through channels that are
not reflected in bank balance sheets have made
bank credit growth even more difficult to interpret.
The most recent innovations in banking probably
have had less effect on the interpretation of the
money supply than on bank credit as an indicator
of policy. But the money supply has important
drawbacks as a policy target during a period of slow
economic growth. A comparison of the relative

6/24/69

-40-

growth of reserves and money during the recession
of July 1957 to April 1958 illustrates the problem.
Reserves and the money stock sometimes follow
different paths in such periods, because the public
may choose to hold the additional deposits supported
by reserve growth in the form of time accounts.
In that recession, bank reserves grew a bit
more than 2 per cent, but the money stock did not
rise at all--probably reflecting the sluggishness
of transactions demand. Additions to reserves over
this period produced a substantial rise in commercial
bank time deposits, however. A similar disparity
between reserve provision and money growth occurred
in the recession of 1960-61. In the mini-recession
of 1966-67, on the other hand, movements in the two
series conformed rather closely.
It seems to us, on balance, that total reserves
might be the quantitative target least likely to mis
direct the over-all course of policy during the period
ahead. If monetary policy were guided over the
longer-run by a variable growth rate of total reserves,
there would seem to be little basis for being overly
concerned about the resulting distribution of deposit
growth between demand and time accounts.
How much reserve growth should be provided, given
our GNP projection, is a difficult question. There
are many links between reserve provision and private
spending decisions, and our knowledge of them is
imperfect. It does seem clear that the negative
growth rate of the first half of 1969 should not
continue for long. We believe that the posture of
monetary policy will need to move gradually towards
an expansion rate suitable for longer-run economic
needs; that is, to somewhere around a 4-1/2 per cent
annual rate by the first half of 1970. We assume,
also, that a resumption in reserve growth would be
needed before this year is over, and that this need
will be more clearly indicated by economic develop
ments as the year progresses.
Given the projected rates of reserve expansion
and GNP growth, interest rates should begin to drop
later this year, and fall further in the first half
of 1970. Though our estimates here are highly un
certain, it seems to us that bill rates might drop to
around 5-1/4 per cent by the second quarter of 1970.
If economic growth proved to be weaker than projected,
bill rates might decline further, and consideration

6/24/69

-41-

would then need to be given to liberalizing the reserve
targets just discussed.
The accompanying decline in long-term rates would
depend on expectations of both investors and borrowers.
Downward movements are likely to encourage an increased
volume of municipal security offerings, and yields on
high grade municipals might fall only moderately, to
a range around 5 per cent. We are expecting less supply
response in the corporate market, so that the Aaa new
issue rate might fall relatively further, perhaps to a
range around 6-1/2 per cent. Mortgage rates will prob
ably experience only a little easing over the year
ahead, given the underlying strength of demand for
housing.
In fact, in the immediate future, some further
tightening of mortgage money seems foreordained by the
outlook for nonbank savings accounts. Growth in these
accounts during the first half of 1969 amounted to
little more than would be accounted for by the credit
ing of interest to existing deposits. We expect
currently high market interest rates to produce a
sizable further erosion during the summer and early
fall, but with a recovery later in the year holding
the annual growth rate to about 4-1/2 per cent for
the second half as a whole. If rates on market
securities decline later this year and in 1970 as
projected, rates of savings inflow should show a
modest upturn to about the 1968 pace in the first
half of next year,
As noted earlier, we are uncertain about the
response of the money stock to the projected rate of
reserve injection, given the assumed pattern of GNP
growth. As a rough estimate, monetary growth might
remain at around a 3 per cent annual rate in the second
half of this year. In the first half of 1970, trans
actions demand for money should ease, in line with
slower GNP growth, but if interest rates decline as
projected, the increase in the money stock could rise
moderately to about a 3-1/2 per cent rate.
Time deposit growth is expected to rebound from
the negative growth rate thus far in 1969, which has
resulted from a sharp run-off of CD's and a diminished
rate of expansion in other time deposits. This pro
jection is also surrounded with uncertainty, however.
Much depends on bank adjustments in the CD market, in
the Euro-dollar market, and in the new markets opened
this year. Our best guess is that time deposit
expansion might return to a 6 per cent annual rate

-42-

6/24/69

in the second half of 1969, and then rise to an 11 to
12 per cent rate in the first
half of next year.
Basically, what we are projecting is a return to
growth rates of money and time deposits that seem con
sistent with the economy's longer-run requirements, as
best we can evaluate them. The banking system probably
would wind up supplying about one-third of total funds
raised--not a high figure by historical standards. Thus,
our projection does not imply a switch to high rates of
monetary expansion such as occurred in late 1966 and
early 1967.
Mr. Hersey presented the following analysis of the balance
of payments:
In rereading our chart shows of the past two years,
I found a persistent over-optimism about prospects for
the U.S. trade balance that appalled me. But I also
found a chart on unit labor costs with a chilly message.
We noted that unit labor costs in U.S. manufacturing in
the spring of 1968 were already 9 per cent above the
level maintained from 1959 to 1965, and the chart pro
jected a continuing rise--close to what has actually
happened. By now the rise is 13 per cent. In Germany,
by way of acute contrast, unit labor costs in industry
were no higher at the end of 1967 than in late 1965,
and since then they have been virtually stableas productivity has kept pace with accelerating wage
advances. This divergence makes last May's non-event
of a mark revaluation seem a very desirable future
event. Whatever the United States may hope for in the
way of measures of adjustment by other countries, our
own due contribution to international equilibrium and
stability cannot be made if U.S. costs and prices
continue rising at their post-1965 pace.
In reassessing near-term prospects, we first take
note of the state of demand abroad. Since early 1966
(just before the start of a recession in Germany),
German industrial production has risen, net, by one-fifth.
In Germany and in many other countries, margins of unused
resources of labor and capital by now have become quite
small. The boom abroad was given a push by the spillover
of U.S. demand, but by now it has become self-generating.
In Britain, however, the growth of activity has been

6/24/69

-43-

slowed by measures to restrain domestic demand in the
interests of a better external balance.
In the United States, ten years ago, the combina
tion of tight fiscal policy and a very tight monetary
policy, plus a long strike in the steel industry, were
putting an end to the wave of inflation that rose in
the mid-1950's. Abroad, after a pause in 1957 and 1958,
industrial activity was rising rapidly in 1959. The
next year, 1960, demand abroad continued very strong
while a mild recession set in here.
Now once again we are aiming for stabilization.
In the twelve months ahead, the continuing strength of
demand abroad, apart from the United Kingdom, may again
be expected to serve as a counter-weight to the cooling
off in the United States, diminishing the risks of a
worldwide recession and helping to maintain the rising
trend in U.S. exports.
After the U.S. trade surplus had practically dis
appeared in the spring of 1959, it widened again during
the mild U.S. recession of 1960 and early 1961, partly
as a result of rising exports and partly through a
sharp fall iii imports. In the period ahead, after we
get past the dock strike distortions, we do not expect
as much improvement in the trade balance as in 1960-61,
because imports are not expected to fall. Exports,
however, will probably rise more than imports.
In 1960-61, imports both of materials and of
finished goods fell off. Contributory factors were
the ending of the 1959 steel strike and the competition
the new compacts were giving foreign cars. More generally,
U.S. demand for many kinds of imports eased off. In the
period ahead, finished goods imports may continue to
rise. Foreign suppliers seem to be able to hold their
export prices down even while their own domestic price
levels rise, and advances in U.S. prices in recent
years have made imports more attractive than ever. The
relative importance of finished goods among U.S. imports
has risen markedly in the past decade, making it all the
more likely that total imports will rise further in the
coming period.
I hope we are not being too optimistic again in
looking for a small recovery in the balance on goods and
services to something like a $3-1/2 billion rate by
mid-1970. This would still be far short of the 1966
balance which was $5-1/2 billion, and way, way, below

6/24/69

-44-

the $8 billion peak reached in 1964. Our projection
assumes little change in the net balance on services.
The improvement will be mainly in the merchandise
trade balance.
The published liquidity balance and the adjusted
over-all balance have been heavily in deficit during
the first half of 1969. Partly this has reflected
unusually large unidentified outflows, presumably
into German marks and Euro-dollars. Looking ahead,
we assume that the abnormal outflows will not be large
on balance over a 12-month period. But the trade im
provement may be offset by shrinkage in some capital
inflows, and over-all deficits are likely. On the
official settlements basis, the large surplus in the
first quarter has been followed by a near-zero balance
in the second quarter, and substantial deficits could
emerge later on. The difference between the official
settlements and the adjusted over-all balance is the
inflow of interbank borrowings, including those from
the foreign branches of U.S. banks, and this inflow may
be reversed later on.
Among the capital inflows likely to be smaller
than before, a principal example is foreign buying of
U.S. stocks. After running for several months at an
average annual rate around $3 billion, these fell off
to a rate under $1 billion in March and April.
The current picture regarding U.S. corporate
outflows for direct investments in subsidiaries, short
term investments, and commercial credits is obscure;
the $5 billion annual rate estimate for the first half
of 1969 is a rough guess that allows for some sizable
movements into German marks and Euro-dollars. For
the following twelve months we project some liquida
tion of short-term holdings but a relatively large
direct investment flow, so that the net total outflow
may be almost as large as in 1968. However, the
use of foreign funds from U.S. companies' new
borrowings abroad may be much smaller than in 1968,
and the use of U.S. funds would therefore be larger.
For one thing, the pressures put on companies by
the control program are less severe than they were
in 1968. For another, European financial markets may
be less receptive.
As you well know, a marked shift in interest
rate relationships has taken place since 1966. In
Britain, as in the United States, long-term rates

6/24/69

-45-

started rising again in 1967, while German rates con
tinued to decline until March of this year and since
then have moved up a little. No one can predict where
German rates will be a year from now.
The shift in interest rate relationships has of
course reflected monetary policy decisions, in turn
greatly influenced abroad by balance of payments
considerations. German short-term rates, even after
increasing since a year ago, are still relatively lowespecially when judged in the light of signs of infla
tionary pressures in the German economy. Meanwhile,
Euro-dollar rates have reached astronomical heights.
The pressures on national money and capital markets,
as well as on official foreign exchange reserves,
that tightness for Euro-dollars generates,are a cause of
concern for some continental European central banks.
British money markets did not tighten further in June.
The buildup in liabilities of U.S. banks to
foreign branches and other foreign commercial banks
was $3 billion in the first quarter of 1969. Tempo
rarily there was a reverse flow when funds were
moving into German marks, but the net inflow in the
second quarter is apparently exceeding $3 billion--or
perhaps even $4 billion. Supplies of funds have been
attracted from at least three main kinds of sources.
Short-term investors have moved out of marks on a
large scale, protected by forward cover sold by the
German Federal Bank. Some borrowers of Euro-dollars,
other than U.S. banks, have refinanced elsewhere. And
indirect evidence suggests that since February dollar
investors have been moving from the United States into
Euro-dollars on an increasing scale.
Despite the adjusted over-all deficit totaling $10
billion in the two-year period since mid-1967, U.S.
liquid and near-liquid liabilities to foreign official
reserve holders have decreased on balance, as a result
of the sharp rise in the liabilities to banks abroad.
The growth of liabilities to official holders was held
down also by the large U.S. gold sales in 1967 and 1968.
On the other hand, the increase in Federal Reserve and
other U.S. official holdings of foreign currencies has
tended to enlarge the reserve liabilities. Looking
ahead, if the adjusted over-all deficit in the next
twelve months amounts to something like the $4 billion
we have projected, and if U.S. reserve assets decline
moderately, our liabilities to foreign official
reserve holders will increase sharply if there is no
further increase in the interbank liabilities, and

-46-

6/24/69

still more sharply if these decrease. To maintain
inter-central bank cooperation under such circumstances,
it will be important for the United States to show
progress toward stabilization.
Mr. Partee concluded the presentation with the following
comments:
Our GNP projection for the year ahead shows more
similarities to that of a year ago than we care to
remember. The mid-1968 projection, as the Committee
well recalls, under-estimated significantly the expan
sive forces in the private economy, and there is a
chance--though we think it is an outside one--that
this could be true again. A major breakthrough toward
peace in Vietnam, for example, could have bullish
short-run economic implications which we haven't assessed
here. And inflationary expectations might be so deeply
entrenched that the effects of traditional economic
stabilization measures would continue to be blunted
for a while. Nevertheless, we are impressed by the
fundamental changes taking place in the economic situa
tion over the past 12 months.
The most important difference relates to business
fixed investment. A year ago we were on the threshold
of a sharp surge in plant and equipment expenditures
that partly offset the restraining effects of the new
fiscal program. The upswing proved to be a major
source of continuing pressures on resources and
prices. Now we seem to be in for a significantly
slower growth rate over the last half of this year,
and--when the investment tax credit suspension really
begins to bite in early 1970--a decline seems fairly
probable. In part, this change in trend reflects the
delayed effects of last year's fiscal restraint program
finally carrying through to business spending plans.
But this is being reinforced by an extremely taut
monetary policy that has raised credit costs sharply
further, and has reduced fund availability substantially
in recent months.
In the housing area, the strength of underlying
demands that boosted starts to a 1.7 million annual
rate in the first quarter of this year is, if anything,
intensifying. But starts have already begun to fall,
and a further decline in the months ahead seems almost

6/24/69

-47-

certain, given the additional recent tightening in the
mortgage market. But we are still hoping that the
downturn in starts and expenditures will remain modest,
and the projection calls for renewed expansion by the
first half of 1970, predicated on some easing of money
and capital market pressures.
Given the mixed evidence on current economic
developments that Mr. Wernick presented earlier, it
would seem to me too risky to recommend a major shift
toward monetary ease now to cushion the economic weak
nesses projected for later this year and early 1970.
Industrial production is still rising at a 6 per cent
annual rate, and prices are still rocketing upward. I
am reasonably confident that our GNP projection is in
the right ballpark, but there is still relatively little
confirmation of it in the current indicators. Until
more solid evidence of impending weakness appears, the
severity of the inflationary problem dictates caution in
policy actions.
Our balance of payments position indicates the
need for caution also. We are enjoying a surplus on
the official settlements basis so far this year--but
only by virtue of a massive inflow of Euro-dollars. The
deficit on a liquidity basis was huge in both the first
and second quarters. There is some hope for an improve
ment over the next year, but even so the projected
rate of deficit would still be too large.
The achievement of fundamental improvement in our
payments position will be a slow, hard process.
Monetary policy may not be able to wait before moving
to see that such improvement has been set in train.
But the balance of payments situation does argue
strongly against changing policy more quickly or
aggressively than is clearly required by domestic
developments.
For the longer run, the policy strategy we are
postulating calls for a moderate shift towards an
easier posture of monetary policy some time this fall,
to permit growth in total reserves to resume at a 2-1/2
to 3 per cent annual rate during the second half. The
timing of such a move should be dictated by the incom
ing economic data, and we believe that it will be
warranted by early autumn. If the economy subsequently
shows the weaknesses that our projection envisages,
a step-up in reserve growth to about a 4-1/2 per cent
annual rate during the first half of 1970 would then
seem reasonable.

6/24/69

-48-

Such a switch in policy would be much less pro
nounced than what occurred during the 1966-67 mini
recession, when total
reserves increased by almost 10
per cent for the full
year 1967.
In fact, a 4-1/2 per
cent rate of reserve expansion may be no more than
what is needed over the longer run to sustain full
employment at relatively stable prices. The moderate
character of the suggested policy response reflects
our concern with the problems that would be posed by
continued inflation
and large balance of payments defi
cits,
and also the desire to get out of the pattern of
"stop and go" monetary policy of recent years. Of
course, if economic weaknesses develop along a
considerably wider front than we have projected,
greater monetary stimulation would be needed.
We would, moreover, suggest that consideration
be given to suspension of Regulation Q ceilings on
large-denomination CD's around the end of this year,
if interest rates on Treasury bills and other short
term market securities decline as projected. The
existence of this ceiling has at some times been
ineffective in limiting CD sales, and at other times
much too effective.
The result has been alternating
periods of massive liquidity accumulation and runoff
by the banks--fluctuations that do not seem to have
contributed to financial and economic stability.
Indeed, since there always has been a hope in bankers'
minds that the ceilings would be raised when the going
got rough, Regulation Q ceilings may even have delayed
adjustments in bank lending policies during periods
of monetary restraint, then followed by undesirably
sharp adjustments when the necessity of cutbacks finally
became clear. If we can assure banks that the CD
market will be viable over the longer run by suspend
ing the ceiling at the next opportunity, this may help
to moderate the rush of banks into CD's as market
interest rates decline, and might help dissuade banks
from developing further the wide variety of nondeposit
sources of funds that currently are posing regulatory
problems.
In the interim, consideration might be given to rais
ing ceilings rates on large-denomination CD's by, say, 50
to 75 basis points for maturities of 3 months and longer.
Under existing ceiling rates, and assuming short-term
market rates at about current levels over the next
several weeks, extreme pressures on liquidity positions

6/24/69

-49-

of many banks will continue and could intensify. And
it is worth noting that the CD drain we have seen this
year goes well beyond the largest money market banks in
New York and Chicago. Other weekly reporting member
banks have lost about 20 per cent of their CD's since
December, in contrast to 7 per cent in the 1966 squeeze.
The result has been a sharp decline in liquidity
ratios this year--that is, in the ratio of liquid assets
to total liabilities less capital accounts--at both New
York banks and other weekly reporting banks. These
ratios are now at or below their 1966 lows. While effec
tive constraints on bank lending are clearly necessary
to combat inflationary pressures, there may now be a
real danger of a precipitous change in credit availability,
with effects on particular markets that could be too
harsh and too abrupt. The modest interim adjustment
suggested for the Regulation Q ceiling would reduce attri
tion over the near-term, but probably would not eliminate
it completely. Thus, continued pressure on liquidity
would keep the banking system on a very tight rein.
For the near term, the problem is one of steering
a course of monetary policy that keeps enough pressure
on banks and the financial system to ensure that a
further slowdown in GNP growth does occur. Until that
is more certain, we believe that monetary policy should
stay close to the stance that has been achieved, while
permitting the intense financial pressures that built
up over the tax period to continue unwinding. This
would probably imply, for the weeks immediately ahead,
a Federal funds rate around 8-1/2 per cent, and a 3-month
bill
rate fluctuating widely in a 6-1/4 to 6-3/4 per cent
range, but probably averaging somewhat below recent peaks.
Consistent with these interest rates is a net borrowed
reserve figure that would remain a little deeper than
$1 billion.
Since short-term interest rates have risen sharply
further in recent weeks, discussion of another discount
rate increase has come to the fore. An increase would
be consistent with market developments, but there is
no evident need for an overt signal that monetary
And since the discount rate is
policy is tight.
already far out of line with most short-term interest
rates, without any obvious ill effects, the question
of whether or not it is raised again at this time seems
to me almost entirely a matter of public posture.
Perhaps a one-half point increase could be linked

6/24/69

-50

with a similar rise in large-denomination CD ceilings,
with the combined move suggesting on balance neither
further tightening nor ease. But in any event, I
urge strongly that there be no further appreciable
intensification of restraint at this critical juncture.
If our GNP projection is approximately correct, the
next major move that the Committee will be consider
ing lies in the direction of easing off somewhat from
the present monetary posture.
Chairman Martin said that, in order to permit everyone to
participate in the go-around on the same footing, he wanted to in
form the Committee about certain policy matters which the Board of
Governors had under consideration.

Three Reserve Banks had taken

action to increase the discount rate, with two Banks proposing an
increase of 1 percentage point and the third Bank an increase of
1/2 percentage point.

The Board had been discussing possible

regulatory amendments to restrain the use by banks of certain
nondeposit devices to raise funds--most particularly, Euro-dollar
borrowing, but also repurchase agreements against bank loans,
issues of securities by bank holding companies, and Federal funds
transactions involving nonbank customers.

An increase in Regula

tion Q ceilings on large-denomination CD's had also been suggested
for Board consideration.

Expressions of views on those matters in

the course of the discussion would be welcome.
The Chairman then called for the go-around of comments
and views on economic conditions and monetary policy, beginning
with Mr. Treiber, who commented as follows:

6/24/69

-51-

The price situation is bad, and inflationary
psychology remains strong. There are few signs
of an immediate further slowing in the pace of
economic expansion.
Yet there are some factors
pointing the way, such as sluggish retail sales,
a modest downward tilt in housing, a modest reduc
tion in expected capital expenditures, and probable
growing pressure on profit margins. Real growth
has been at a rate of about 3 per cent this year
compared with over 6 per cent a year ago.
The balance of payments situation continues
to be discouraging. The trade balance in 1969 is
likely to produce no more than a small surplus. The
course of inflation at home will have an important
influence on our trade balance. On the capital side,
purchases by foreigners in the U.S. stock market
have declined from last year and the prospects for
capital inflows through portfolio purchases are
cloudy. The bulk of the recent abnormal capital
outflow in expectation of a revaluation of the
German mark has not been reversed. The Euro-bond
market is no longer an attractive source of funds for
foreign subsidiaries of U.S. corporations.
It appears likely that the Federal budget will
show a modest surplus this fiscal year. It's good
to see even a modest surplus, but current economic
conditions call for a greater surplus. Nothing can
be done now about the current fiscal year, but some
thing can be done about the coming fiscal year. An
extension of the income tax surcharge is essential.
To let it lapse would be irresponsible. The favorable
report of the House Ways and Means Committee is
encouraging, but the surtax extension is not yet law.
The course ahead is still delicate. In my opinion,
we need more than a mere extension of the surtax.
Unless there are real reductions in expenditures, next
year's surplus is not likely to be large enough, par
ticularly in light of the expected expansion of extra
budgetary financing by Government agencies. The chances
are that fiscal policy will play a modest part in
fighting inflation, and that monetary policy will
continue to bear the major burden.
The rate of growth of bank credit and the money
supply has been moderate. Over all, bank liquidity has
declined significantly; it is very low for most money
market banks. The savings banks and savings and loan
associations are concerned about a curtailment in the

6/24/69

-52-

growth of deposits, but so far the situation seems to
be under control. The sale of a number of municipal
issues has been postponed or canceled and the cost of
municipal financing is very high. Corporate market
borrowing has continued at high rates.
The banks have increased their Euro-dollar takings
enormously over the last few weeks, and Euro-dollar
rates at one time exceeded 13 per cent. A number of
foreign countries have taken action of one kind or
another to defend themselves against the adverse
effects on their markets caused by such high Euro-dollar
rates and other rates. We cannot be unmindful of the
effect abroad of monetary restraint in the United States.
The recent increase in the prime rate from 7-1/2
per cent to 8-1/2 per cent is evidence of the increased
intensity with which banks are feeling the current
monetary restraint. It is clear, however, that merely
increasing the cost of money, taken by itself, will
not bring about an adequate reduction in the demand
for credit. Banks will still have to be much more
selective in making loans; the increase in the prime
rate is not a substitute for rationing credit.
The much-heralded "super crunch" failed to
materialize. The possibility of severe monetary
strains over the mid-month tax-payment date was talked
about and feared so much that people adjusted for it.
The absence of a crunch, as the tax date came and
went, attested to the care and attention with which
financial institutions and business corporations
planned their affairs over the period.
While we have passed the mid-June tax date satis
factorily, the end of June and the fourth of July
weekend customarily bring market pressures. Thus, we
can expect continuing uncertainty and caution.
The banks have sought with vigor and great
ingenuity to devise new ways to get funds to meet
loan demand. As new ways have been developed and
expanded, various statistical series have become less
meaningful. For example, the expansion of cash items
in process of collection in connection with Euro-dollar
transactions has reduced demand deposits by perhaps as
much as $3 billion. Correction of the loophole would
immediately bring a large increase in the statistical
measurement of the money supply, and of course an
increase in required reserves.
The strength of the economy and the prevailing
inflationary psychology, in my opinion, counsel a

6/24/69

-53-

continuation of about the same degree of monetary
pressure. In considering appropriate open market policy
to promote this result, we must bear in mind the various
techniques employed by commercial banks to raise funds
outside the scope of Regulations D and Q, and the possi
bility of System action to curtail such techniques.
Mindful of the need for cutting down on the
availability of credit, it seems to me that there is
merit in pursuing a series of measures directed toward
reducing or eliminating the use of these other sources
of funds. Caution in the timing of the measures will
be needed to avoid an undue concentration of the result
ant pressure.
The noncompetitive deposit rate ceilings under
Regulation Q have played a major role in the development
of many of these techniques. Elimination of the ceilings
or an increase in the ceilings, particularly the ceiling
on large-denomination CD's, presumably would lessen
the incentive to resort to such techniques. A number of
foreign central banks have urged such action as a means
of relieving the pressure on the Euro-dollar market. But
any liberalization of Q ceilings would at best dampen
the incentive to cultivate these newly developed sources
of funds. The incentive would not be eliminated in this
period of restrictive credit policy, particularly where
Regulation D can be avoided as well as Regulation Q.
I fear that an increase in the maximum permissible
rate on large-denomination CD's to, say, 7-1/2 per cent
or 8 per cent would likely result in the effective rate
on CD's rising to the new maximum. As banks obtained
more funds by this route and increased their intermedia
tion function, is it likely that they would be as
selective as they now must be in making loans, especially
business loans? My answer would be in the negative.
A relaxation of Regulation Q would probably be
interpreted by many, if not most, observers as a retreat
from the present degree of intensity of monetary
restraint. At the same time, I would expect that
market rates in general would rise considerably. A
substantial adverse effect on thrift institutions and
home mortgages could easily be envisaged. One cannot be
unmindful of the social and political implications of
such a development. I am not persuaded that there are
clear advantages to liberalizing Regulation Q now that
would outweigh the disadvantages that are so apparent.
Last September the Board of Governors announced a
proposal to bring under Regulations D and Q certain funds

6/24/69

-54-

obtained by banks from a transfer of assets under re
purchase agreement. This proposal could be made
effective on short notice. It would have a restraining
.effect, putting pressure on the banks to be more selective
in making loans.
The recently announced proposal of the Board to amend
Regulation D to plug the loophole with respect to cash
item deductions in connection with Euro-dollar transactions
could be made effective shortly after the mid-July date
that was specified as the deadline for the receipt of
comments.
High priority should be given to the Euro-dollar
market. It is a large source of funds to the major
banks; their takings have grown rapidly and serious
pressures have resulted on European financial centers.
I would favor action by the Board placing a meaningful
reserve requirement on that portion of the borrowings
by a United States bank from its foreign branch, or any
other foreign source, that exceeds the level of such
borrowings on a recent base date. Such action would
be well received abroad as recognition of the need, and
of our desire, to avoid undue effects of United States
monetary restraint on foreign financial markets. At home
such action should be interpreted as recognition of the
need to contain what seems to have become more of an
escape hatch than a safety valve for the big banks.
With respect to bank-related commercial paper, it
should be possible to include in the definition of
deposits under Regulations D and Q obligations issued by
a bank affiliate where the proceeds of the obligations
are used to purchase assets from the bank or are lent
to the bank. I would favor an announcement of such a
proposal by the Board in the not too distant future.
The details of the proposal would require careful work
within the System, and there should be ample opportunity
for those outside the System to comment.
Open market operations may be called upon to
cushion adjustment incident to these various actions
by the System, but open market operations shouldn't
offset the actions. Taken together, open market opera
tions and the actions should keep up the pressure of
monetary restraint.
The 6 per cent discount rate is out of line with
other rates. Yet, we have had no serious problems in the
administration of the discount window at the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York. Thus, we see no need for an
increase for administrative reasons. I think an increase
would be unwise while the course of the surtax extension
continues to be delicate. An increase could easily

6/24/69

-55-

exacerbate tensions in the Euro-dollar market over the
mid-year. Further time should be taken to assess the
present situation which is likely to continue in strain
over the remainder of the month. Having raised all these
caveats, I am, nevertheless, inclined to think that an
increase of perhaps 1 percentage point in July may be
appropriate. But, of course, any decision will have
to be made in the light of circumstances as they unfold.
Looking to open market operations in the forth
coming weeks, I think they should confirm a continuing
policy of restraint. Such confirmation might be
evidenced by member bank borrowings between $1 and
$1-1/2 billion; net borrowed reserves between $900
million and $1.3 billion; and a Federal funds rate in
a range of 8-1/2 to 9-1/2 per cent.
To summarize, I would favor continuation of our
present policy of monetary restraint, reinforced by
restrictions on various fund-raising devices developed
by the banks to avoid or reduce the direct impact of
monetary restraint. I would be inclined to favor an
increase of 1 percentage point in the discount rate in
the not too distant future. I would not favor any change
at this time in Regulation Q ceilings.
As for the directive,1/ the first paragraph of the
draft submitted by the staff is acceptable. I don't
see the need to make the suggested change in that part
of the second paragraph that precedes the proviso clause.
Indeed, I think there is some advantage in retaining
the word "pressure", which is used in the present direc
tive in the context of "maintaining the prevailing pressure
on money and short-term credit markets." The proposed
change in the proviso clause, to add a reference to un
usual liquidity pressures, is satisfactory.
Mr. Morris said that the events of the past two weeks sug
gested to him that the restrictive monetary policy of the past seven
months was beginning to produce results.

The most impressive piece of

evidence was the precipitous decline in common stock prices.

Since the

primary source of new expansionary force in the economy during the
last nine months had stemmed from the inflationary psychology of the

1/ The draft directive submitted by the staff for consideration
by the Committee is appended to this memorandum as Attachment A.

-56

6/24/69

businessman and the investor, a deflation of common stock prices was
the signal he had been looking for that attitudes were in the process
of changing.

That signal had been a long time in coming, but he

believed its appearance represented an important turning point.
He thought the probabilities were high that, when the data for
June became available, a general weakening would be evident in
the other leading indicators--following the pattern of slight
decline in those indicators in May.
Mr. Morris thought there was no basis in

the current economic

statistics for changing policy, but there were ample grounds for
thinking that the current policy was producing results.
those conditions,

Under

he thought the Committee should seek to maintain

approximately the current level of monetary restraint.

But that

was going to be difficult to accomplish, since the momentum of the
market would probably work to intensify the level of restraint.
Mr. Morris commented that after reading the blue book it
was clear that it would be very difficult for him to define pre
cisely what was meant by "maintaining the current level of restraint."
He would certainly accept the money market conditions and the
marginal reserve measures described in the blue book,1/ and he

1/ The passage in the blue book referred to read as follows:
"Given the shifting locus of market pressures, a generally un
changed set of money market conditions over the next three weeks
may include a Federal funds rate fluctuating around 8-1/2 per cent,
member bank borrowings in a $1 - $1-1/2 billion range, and net
borrowed reserves averaging a little over $1 billion. The 3-month
bill may fluctuate widely, perhaps in a range as wide as, or wider
than, 6-1/4 - 6-3/4 per cent."

6/24/69

-57

thought the liquidity proviso the staff had suggested for the
directive was well advised for the period ahead.

On the other hand,

he was concerned that the prescribed money market conditions were
expected to require the banks to pull in up to an additional $1
billion from the Euro-dollar market in order to avoid a further
contraction of bank assets.
In such a dynamic situation, Mr. Morris continued, it was
clear that the Committee would have to leave much to the discretion
of the Manager.

However, he thought the Committee should make clear

to the Manager whether it was seeking to maintain the current level
of tension in the market or whether it was willing to let the
momentum in the market generate increased tensions.
Mr. Morris noted that there had been a great deal of concern
in the System about what might be called the "leakages" from monetary
policy.

Apart from the equity considerations involved, he thought

the concern might have been exaggerated.

The access to the Euro

dollar market and the other devices which the banks had used to
soften the impact of policy had permitted the banking system to
adjust in an orderly way to a very restrictive policy.

As a conse

quence, over the past seven months there had been a leveling off of
bank credit rather than the absolute contraction that otherwise
would have occurred; but in his opinion that was the sort of result
which the Committee should have been aiming for at the outset.

In

6/24/69

-58

any case, events were moving so rapidly that by the time the legal
staff had gotten around to devising means for closing all the loop
holes the need might have passed.
Mr. Morris observed that pressure was being exerted to lift
Regulation Q ceilings for large deposits, both for international
and for domestic reasons.

Despite the fact that Regulation Q left

much to be desired as a policy tool, he thought that step should be
resisted.

It would have a most unfortunate impact on market psy

chology just at the very time when the System was determined to
produce a change in psychology.

He agreed with the staff, however,

that an adjustment in Q ceilings should be made once the current
period of tension was over.
Mr. Morris said he had made an informal survey of nonbank
opinion in the Boston area on the subject of Regulation Q ceilings.
The general view which he had encountered among nonbank investment
people and academicians was that any lifting of the ceilings would
be interpreted as "throwing in the towel just when we had the banks
on the ropes."

The System had framed its current policy around

the Regulation Q ceilings, and despite the inadequacies of that
approach he thought it now had to stick it out.
Mr. Morris indicated he found the staff directive acceptable
provided that it was interpreted to mean that the Committee was
seeking to maintain about the current level of tension in the
banking system and provided that the liquidity proviso meant that

-59

6/24/69

the primary securities markets would continue to function in a
reasonably adequate way.
Mr. Coldwell commented that in his opinion the develop
ments of the past month still left unresolved the basic question
of whether sufficient progress was being made toward economic
stabilization.

It seemed apparent that the rate of real economic

growth had slowed but that the economy as a whole was still
advancing and, in specific sectors, the rate of gain was clearly
unsustainable.

Moreover, prices and costs were moving up at an

unacceptably rapid pace.
The System's efforts to restrain the economy had been
blunted, Mr. Coldwell said, by the utilization of a large pool of
liquidity and the steadily more rapid turnover of funds.

Banks as

individual institutions had found ways to avoid credit rationing
while the banking system had been fed only a parsimonious quantity
of new reserves.

With great patience and forebearance the System

might wait out the forthcoming collision between strong credit
demands and limited new supplies.

However, after six months of

waiting while price increases accelerated and more of the general
public became convinced of the inevitability of further inflation,
he believed it was time to call a halt.
Mr. Coldwell thought that interest rate increases had gone
so far that the impact of further advances on the credit demands of
businessmen or consumers appeared negligible.

The only thing that

-60

6/24/69

an avid borrower understood was a firm "No, we have no funds for
new loans."

Thus, availability of credit and attitudes of bankers

were the keys to real restraint.
An additional increase in discount rates might have
advantages in bringing them into better alignment with market rates
and forcing a better relationship between the costs to banks of
alternative means of adjustment, Mr. Coldwell continued.

However,

if bankers were not serious about making adjustments and merely
wanted to sustain their overloaned positions, then a rate increase
would just add to the fire of higher costs and might be a destabilizing
influence.

Moreover, there were clear political and institutional

risks in such a move at this time.

The System should be certain

that there were clear advantages to a discount rate increase and
that it was not just following the commercial bank prime rate move.
If the yield differential was measured against the bill rate, the
discount rate was not as far out of line now as in past situations.
On balance, he did not favor a discount rate increase at the
present time.

Nor did he favor a change in Regulation Q ceilings.

Those ceilings had acted as the cutting edge of policy recently,
and he saw no reason for raising them now.
Mr. Coldwell's preference for handling the discount window
under present conditions was a tighter administration uniformly
applied throughout the nation.

If the System was serious about

containing inflation, he thought the banks that were still taking

6/24/69

-61

every opportunity to extend additional credit and were sustain
ing their positions by Federal funds purchases, Euro-dollar
borrowings, or sales of assets should be counseled with indi
vidually and placed in a special category.

Perhaps a Board

statement to that effect would be helpful, as would be Board
action to enlarge the penalty for reserve deficiencies.
As members of the Committee knew, Mr. Coldwell continued,
he had been asking for further restraint and especially for a
statement to the banks requesting special efforts to limit loan
accommodation, particularly to businesses.

He would reiterate

that request today, and hoped that such a broad appeal could
include the injunction to the very aggressive banks.
As for current monetary policy, Mr. Coldwell said he
favored further restraint through open market operations and a
directive that would instruct the Manager to keep conditions taut
at all times and to seek opportunities to tighten money and credit
relationships further.

Such a policy would have the effect of

offsetting to some extent the projected rundown of Treasury deposits
and would keep bill yields at a higher level.

Effective Federal

funds rates should, in his opinion, be kept above 9 per cent.
With regard to regulatory changes to limit individual bank
sales of loans, guarantees of commercial paper, issuance of paper
by a holding company or affiliate, or other devices to evade

-62

6/24/69

Regulations D and Q, Mr. Coldwell said he approached such changes
from a fundamental position that banks should operate within their
own resources.

With that premise and the basic assumption that such

devices were being used by only a limited number of banks, he would
favor some Board curtailment of those devices.

However, he was

more concerned with the over-all limitation of reserves.
On the Euro-dollar reserve proposal, Mr. Coldwell indicated
he was in favor of extending reserve requirements on all new borrow
ing as of a specific date but without retroactivity.

He was

concerned about the balance of payments impact of forcing retrench
ment in such borrowing, but he was more concerned about the
further build-up in the overhang of borrowings and its impact on
the world-wide interest rate competition now under way.
With respect to the draft directive, Mr. Coldwell suggested
deletion from the first paragraph of the statement that the nonbank
thrift industry "reportedly was preparing for sizable outflows
during the mid-year interest-crediting period."

He saw no reason

to include only one phase of the projection, especially one which
involved considerable uncertainties.

In his view the second para

graph of the draft directive was unacceptable.
be reworded to state that ".

.

. operations

.

He suggested that it
.

. shall be conducted

with a view to developing firmer conditions in money and short-term
credit markets

.

.

. "

-63

6/24/69

Mr. Swan said he thought monetary policy should remain
unchanged at present, with open market operations directed at
maintaining the current firm conditions in money and short-term
credit markets.

This certainly was not a time to ease or to give

any kind of signal that might be interpreted as easing.

But,

like Mr. Morris, he felt just as strongly that policy should not
be tightened further at this point.

Having come through the

period of peak pressures associated with the mid-June tax date,
it seemed to him that the Committee should maintain a steady
posture until it was in a better position to assess the degree
to which those pressures were unwound.

He thought it possible

that there would be some lessening of inflationary expectations
in the weeks ahead, although such a judgment admittedly was
difficult to support.
Mr. Swan remarked that he would not favor increasing the
discount rate at this point--even though it was well out of line
with market rates--because an increase would have an undesirable
announcement effect.

As he had indicated, he believed that any

policy action likely to be interpreted as an overt move toward
further tightening would be inappropriate now.

He would prefer

to watch interest rate developments for a time and to see whether
or not the surtax was extended before making a decision about
the discount rate.

-64-

6/24/69

Mr. Swan thought consideration should be given to measures
restricting marginal increases in Euro-dollar borrowings and bank
use of some of the other fund-raising devices that had been
mentioned.

He was concerned about one new device--the so-called

placement of depositors' funds in the Federal funds market.
Although the exact mechanics were not clear, the funds involved
evidently were moved out of the deposit category and the Federal
funds rate was paid on them.

The San Francisco Reserve Bank did

not have knowledge of any specific transactions of that type shown
on the books of a bank but rumors of its use were becoming in
creasingly widespread.

The device was of immediate concern because

of the implications for required reserves of the transfer of funds
from deposit to nondeposit categories.

It also seemed to have

serious longer-run implications, as a threat to the whole structure
of demand and time deposits and to the Regulation Q ceilings on
time deposits.

It was the kind of development that could spread

rapidly in response to competition, and in his judgment it
required the immediate attention of the System.
Mr. Swan observed that he would not favor an increase in
ceiling rates on large-denomination CD's at this point, although
he recognized that banks were resorting to new fund-raising
devices because of the restrictive effects of present ceiling
rates.

He shared the view that an increase in ceilings might

be interpreted as a backing-off from monetary restraint.

However,

6/24/69

-65

if an effective check on the escape valves could be developed
promptly, some change in Regulation Q ceilings might be possible
without any implications of easing.

But consideration should first

be given to closing the loopholes.
Mr. Swan said he could accept the directive as drafted
by the staff.

He thought the new language proposed for the second

paragraph was much to be preferred to the wording of the previous
directive.

He had no objection to the addition of a reference to

unusual liquidity pressures in the proviso clause, although it was
not clear to him why the reference was proposed now; he thought
a better case could have been made in connection with the previous
directive, when the pressures associated with the mid-June tax
date still lay ahead.
Mr. Galusha commented that the Board staff had given the
Committee what was, in a way, an encouraging economic outlook.

The

Committee had been told that the GNP deflator was going to continue
increasing, but--what was most important--at a decreasing rate.
For a while at least, it would simply be a case of past increases
in costs pushing prices higher.

Apparently, prospects were for

actual decreases in real GNP and, extending over the next few
quarters, what he regarded as rather a sharp increase in the
unemployment rate.

But, of course, while not speaking of it,

Committee members had known all along that such an increase was
almost inevitable.

-66-

6/24/69

If the Board staff's forecast turned out to be correct,
Mr. Galusha continued, by next summer there might be a few
unpleasant things said about the Federal Reserve.

With

interest rates having increased to record levels, and with the
various monetary aggregates having increased relatively little,
there was not a chance that the System would escape blame for
the minor recession which seemed to be in the offing.

But

that prospect should not dissuade the System from carrying on.
The staff outlook could be wrong, although he personally did
not think so.

It seemed to him the System was close to having

altered business expectations if, as Mr. Morris had indicated
and as he believed, the stock market was the best thermometer
for taking the temperature of inflationary psychology.

But in

order really to change expectations, he thought the System had
to carry on a bit longer.
Accordingly, this morning he was for no change in Com
mittee policy, Mr. Galusha continued.

He was not joyous about

prospects for further decreases in bank credit, but even modest
changes in monetary targets could easily be misinterpreted.
Nor did Mr. Galusha think that discount rates should
be increased.

They were out of line with market rates, but a

supposedly technical adjustment of any size would be mis
interpreted and he saw little, if any, advantage to be gained
by raising discount rates.

6/24/69

-67
At this nervous juncture, Mr. Galusha observed, there

was a risk that market participants would over-react, one way
or the other, to whatever the System might do; and that being
so, he would have it do nothing--other, that was, than to carry
on as it had been.

He would have the System leave discount rates

unchanged and, unless absolutely necessary, refrain for the
time being from issuing any new rules or regulations.

If, as

some had indicated, a move to control in some way the flow of
Euro-dollars not only might help alleviate the System's current
problem but might also mitigate some of its troubles when domestic
interest rates started to unwind, he would certainly favor the
exploration.

For, unless the Committee chose to ignore today's

extraordinarily good staff presentation as well as the lessons
of history, it could anticipate rate easing and some attendant
troubles next year.
In conclusion, Mr. Galusha said he could accept the
targets for money and short-term credit market conditions spelled
out in the blue book and the staff's draft of the directive.

He

particularly liked the proviso clause shown in the draft and
would urge that it be adopted.
Mr. Scanlon said that in the interest of time he would
summarize the statement he had prepared concerning developments
in the Seventh District and would submit the full text for inclu
sion in the record.

He then summarized the following statement:

6/24/69

-68-

We have no convincing evidence that pressures
on resources in the Seventh District have eased.
Price increases on manufactured goods announced
in the past few weeks have been far more numerous
than at any other time in recent years. The increases
have been relatively large, commonly 5 per cent or
more, and have covered a wide variety of goods.
District wage increases granted this year show no
tendency toward moderation. Newly negotiated contracts
commonly call for increases in compensation ranging up
to 10 per cent per year and more.
Advertising for workers has been stepped up in
recent months, possibly in an effort to acquire some
of the new crop of high school and college graduates.
Unemployment compensation claims in the District are
well below last year, except for Iowa.
Labor shortages are especially severe in the
Chicago-Gary steel producing area. Major plants would
like to hire large numbers of additional workers,
including many unskilled workers. Partly because of
extended vacations, steel firms will be hard put to
catch up on deferred maintenance and repair work this
summer while maintaining production at a high level.
There are many reports of labor absenteeism, especially
in the auto industry, that hamper production and, there
fore, productivity.
Output of consumer durables, other than automobiles,
appears to have leveled on balance in recent weeks, but
demand for certain items, including furniture, mobile
homes, refrigerators, air conditioners, and dehumidifiers,
is very strong.
Auto producers with whom we talk are sticking to
forecasts made earlier in the year that sales of passenger
cars, including imports, will be close to 9.5 million units
this year. Truck sales are generally expected to exceed
1.9 million units and perhaps to reach 2 million, for a
new record.
The greatest strength continues to center in pro
ducers' equipment, including trucks, trailers, railroad
equipment, industrial and commercial air conditioning,
and machine tools. Farm machinery sales, weak earlier
in the year, have improved recently. Orders for most
types of equipment surged in April with demands for
repeal of the tax credit. But the reaction in May and
June has not been as great as had been expected.
Many capital expenditure projects are behind schedule
because of delays in deliveries, labor shortages, or

-69-

6/24/69

strikes, but we know of very few "voluntary" cut-backs
on capital expenditure plans this year.
The national retail sales data are puzzling. They
may be understating actual results--particularly for
restaurants, service stations, furniture and appliances,
drug stores and, possibly, food. If estimates of total
sales and sales of the large chains and department
stores are correct, the small and specialty retailers
must be doing badly. We have seen or heard nothing
indicating that that is occurring on a broad scale.
Business loans at weekly reporting banks in the
District continue to increase despite the sales of
loans by some banks to their overseas branches. The
two largest Chicago banks are estimated to have sold
in excess of $300 million of loans. Treasury securi
ties continue to run off and there have been some sales
of municipals.
Chicago banks continue to operate in a deep basic
deficit position, borrowing heavily in the Federal
funds and Euro-dollar markets. Their deficit has been
close to its current level since March. Those banks
have made only moderate use of the discount window.
Mr. Scanlon then said that money supply and bank credit
appeared to be increasing less in June than had been projected.
In light of current and projected business developments, that had
been desirable.

With evidence of moderation of the pace of

inflation so slow in surfacing, it was perhaps surprising that
interest rates had not risen even more strongly.

Efforts to

hold down interest rates now would be likely to thwart the
Committee's major objective--namely, containing inflation.
It would appear, Mr. Scanlon continued, that more indica
tions of easing of pressure on resources should be evident, given
the slowing in real economic activity implied in the quarterly
estimates of GNP.

The fact that that was not the case raised

6/24/69

-70

a question as to whether a program of gradualism could overtake an
inflation that had gained substantial momentum.

Certainly, drastic

actions in the fiscal and monetary sectors were much to be preferred
to either further drift toward price and allocation controls or to
decided steps in that direction.

But it would be premature to

abandon the gradualistic approach at this time.
However, Mr. Scanlon observed, within that basic approach
he would favor some changes that would help to keep the markets
functioning.

First, in contrast to some others who had spoken today,

he thought the discount rate should be moved closer to relevant market
rates.

The discount window would then be more effective as a safety

valve since there would be less need to raise the spectre that the
window might be closed altogether or against certain groups of
borrowers.

He thought there was one ill effect from the lack of a

change in the discount rate.

The large subsidy the Reserve Banks

provided on member bank borrowings, which were now in excess of $1
billion, seemed quite inconsistent with the System's announced policy
of restraint.

He recognized that there was a problem of timing, but

to delay an obvious action because it might interfere with the passage
of tax legislation or because of announcement effects was an approach
that had not proven successful in the past.

If it was the right action

to take, he would take it.
Secondly, Mr. Scanlon continued, he saw merit in establishing
some reserve requirements against Euro-dollars and other fund-raising

6/24/69

-71

devices used by banks, although he was not certain how an effective
method of doing so could be found.

Perhaps there would be an oppor

tunity to tie in such a measure with a third action:
ceiling on rates paid by banks on savings.

raising the

The System's posture

in holding down such rates was becoming increasingly incongruous
in an inflationary setting and should be changed along the lines
the Board was considering.

Whether that could be done without

marked political repercussions he did not know.

But the evidence

that funds quickly found alternative channels was becoming more
and more impressive.
Mr. Scanlon thought an appropriate policy posture would be
to provide for slow growth in total reserves, assuming Regulation Q
ceilings were raised so as to end the run-off of CD's.

Such a

policy approach would be consistent with slow expansion in the money
supply and bank credit.

In terms of a money market directive, he

favored maintaining about the prevailing degree of firmness in money
and short-term credit markets.

The staff draft of the directive was

satisfactory.
Mr. Clay remarked that there was some evidence of moderation
in the pace of economic activity.

In view of the monetary and fiscal

restraint that had been applied, however, the continued degree of
expansion remained rather impressive.

An important part of the pro

jected further slowing reflected a marked reduction in the growth of
business spending for fixed capital.

-72-

6/24/69

Of chief concern, Mr. Clay noted, was the continuing strong
inflationary push of costs and prices.

There was no need to catalog

here the important reasons, in terms of both domestic and international
considerations, why that trend had to be checked.

The record to date

was not encouraging.
Increasing evidence of strains was apparent in financial
markets and institutions, Mr. Clay continued.

One indication was

the scramble for nondeposit sources of funds by commercial banks
operating under the limitations of the Regulation Q ceilings.

Much

had been said about that with respect to the largest money center
banks, and no doubt the greatest amount was to be found there.

How

ever, the data collection just initiated by the System had revealed
more such efforts among the largest Tenth District banks than
anticipated; each of the nondeposit sources specified was found to
be employed by one or more of those banks.

In addition, it was

evident that plans were being made for the expansion of such methods
of obtaining funds.
Mr. Clay said that in view of the lagged effects of public
economic restraint measures, including the forthcoming fiscal legis
lation, it was difficult to know how much restraint was needed and
how long any given degree of monetary restraint should be applied.
While every effort had to be made to observe whatever evidence became
available for making that judgment, it was going to be necessary to
take some risk of overdoing and overstaying.

-73-

6/24/69
For

the present, there appeared to Mr. Clay to be little

choice except to continue the firm policy that the Committee had
been pursuing.

Extension of the surtax, along with enactment of

the other fiscal restraint measures, was of the utmost importance.
Under the prevailing circumstances, Mr. Clay added, statis
tical guidelines for the Manager were difficult to formulate and
probably should be stated in rather broad ranges.

Given the uncer

tainties of the flows of funds and other factors, the guidelines
for money and short-term credit market conditions listed in the blue
book appeared to be reasonable approximations for the period ahead.
Since the Federal Reserve discount rate was seriously out
of line with other money market rates, it should be increased at an
early date, Mr. Clay said.

He realized that the timing of such an

increase was a problem and he was not at all certain what that timing
should be.
The staff draft of the policy directive appeared to Mr. Clay
to be satisfactory.
Mr. Heflin commented that economic activity in the Fifth
District apparently continued to expand, but the Richmond Bank's
survey of business conditions indicated declining optimism among
businessmen and bankers.

As a matter of fact, the responses were

the most pessimistic in many months.

The survey also showed a marked

turn away from the bullishness that had been experienced in the

6/24/69

-74

District in retail trade and automobile sales.

While total District

construction activity was continuing to advance, residential con
struction had continued to slow.

District lumbermen reported sharp

reductions in prices and. increased supplies, reflecting to some
degree the softness developing in residential building.
Mr. Heflin observed that credit markets appeared to have
adjusted reasonably well to the latest prime rate hike, although
it seemed to him that a high degree of uncertainty continued to
dominate market sentiment.

The unusually large takings of Euro

dollars at interest rates as high as 13 per cent reflected the
extent to which the banking system was feeling the policy pinch.
In that kind of climate he was somewhat concerned over the latest
blue book projections of the prospective behavior of the bank credit
proxy.

The adjusted projections would appear to imply a level of

Euro-dollar borrowings that could add significantly to the pressures
in foreign markets.

Moreover, he was not altogether comfortable

with the prospect that credit would continue to decline for another
month and perhaps longer.
Nevertheless, Mr. Heflin said, given the seriousness of
the inflation problem he would recommend against any relaxation of
the current degree of restraint.

He believed the System had achieved

about the right policy posture and, while he would not want to
overstay that posture, he was convinced that it had to be maintained

6/24/69

-75

for the present.

On the other hand, given the present degree of

stringency and the current expectational climate, he believed that
any overt move toward further restraint at this time would involve
unnecessary risks of financial disturbances both at home and abroad.
For that reason he would not recommend any discount rate action at
this time.

The directive was satisfactory as drafted.

Mr. Mitchell said he could find no fault with the analysis
the staff had presented today and he thought their conclusions
regarding policy were appropriate to the situation.

Like Mr. Scanlon,

he disliked the subsidy implications of the present level of the
discount rate, but he thought an increase now would have undesirable
announcement effects.

Hopefully, the System would find a better

opportunity later to bring the discount rate into closer alignment
with market rates.
Mr. Mitchell agreed that no change in policy was the best
course at present.

However one might measure the existing degree

of restraint, it was considerable; and, particularly in light of
the lags involved, he would not want to firm further at this time.
Indeed, in his judgment there was more danger that restraint might
be excessive or continue too long than that it might be insufficient.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that he disagreed with most of what
had been said thus far about curtailing bank use of nondeposit funds.
He thought it was appropriate to think of credit restraint as

-76

6/24/69

applying not to banks alone but to the whole economy.

It seemed

inconsistent to him to argue that it was desirable for banks to
sell assets in the form of securities but undesirable for them to
sell loan participations or commercial paper.

In his judgment

none of those transactions was undesirable since whatever banks
sold had to be absorbed by the economy.

For that reason he thought

it was unnecessary to try to close most of the "loopholes" that had

been mentioned.
However, Mr. Mitchell continued, he would make an exception
in the case of Euro-dollar borrowings because of their consequences
for foreign financial markets.

If the flows had been in the reverse

direction this country might well have expected other countries to
take measures that would provide relief, and it was reasonable for
them to expect the System to act now.

Thus, he thought some action

was required to reduce the inflow of Euro-dollars, although he was
uncertain at the moment as to the appropriate form of the action.
Also, Mr. Mitchell said, he thought the Board should act at
some point to raise the Regulation Q ceilings on large-denomination
CD's of longer-term.

His reservations about doing so at present

were based solely on considerations of timing; it would be extremely
unfortunate if such an action were taken now and interpreted as a
relaxation of monetary restraint.

Perhaps that risk could be

avoided by combining the change in Regulation Q with an increase
in reserve requirements.

6/24/69

-77Mr. Mitchell thought the staff's draft directive was

appropriate.

However, in light of the comments in the chart show

today about the use of reserves for target purposes, he wondered
why the staff had not proposed directive language involving reserves.
Mr. Daane said he had found the staff's analysis excellent
and persuasive.

Nevertheless, he still thought the Committee's

immediate problem was inflation and inflationary psychology, and he
was not convinced that the System had done all it could do in dealing
with that problem.

While he did not advocate any appreciable further

tightening, he would favor shading open market operations in that
direction.

To use an old System expression, he would "err on the

side of restraint" and perhaps go a bit further.
Mr. Daane remarked that he had mixed feelings on the question
of whether the Board should restrict the various fund-raising devices
banks had been using.

Once the Board embarked on that course it

would be faced immediately with the issue of Regulation Q ceilings
on large-denomination CD's, and he would be reluctant to increase
the ceilings at the moment for the reasons Mr. Treiber had mentioned.
If the Board were to raise the Q ceilings, however, he thought it
would be appropriate to accompany the action with an increase in the
discount rate.

While a discount rate increase at this point could be

described accurately as a technical adjustment, it would also serve
to remove any sense of easing that a change in Q ceilings alone
might convey.

-78-

6/24/69

As to the directive, Mr. Daane said he would be agreeable
to the language Mr. Coldwell had suggested for the second paragraph.
However, if that language were not acceptable to a majority he would
favor retaining the wording of the previous directive, calling for
maintenance of prevailing pressure on the market, rather than employ
ing the modified language proposed by the staff.
Mr. Maisel remarked that the Committee faced a series of
questions in attempting to judge what existing monetary policy was.
What would be the current and lagged impact of action already taken?
What measures should the Committee use of the degree of restraint
contained in current policy?
firmness?

What did it really mean by current

What advantages and risks appeared likely if it adopted

the proposed directive?
If the Committee looked back at the past quarter, Mr. Maisel
said, it would note a steady escalation of firmness in money market
conditions as well as a steady fall in the monetary aggregates.

That

tightening had occurred even though the directives adopted at the
past two meetings had called for no change in policy.

Now was the

time to end that movement.
In the words of the Manager, Mr. Maisel continued, most
interest rates had reached historical highs in the past four weeks.
The average Federal funds rate in June would be more than 100 basis
points higher than that of April and the peaks reached would be even
greater.

The three-month bill rate would be 40 basis points higher.

6/24/69

-79

Borrowings and net borrowed reserves would have gone up.

At the

same time, the rate of growth in the bank credit proxy had decreased
sharply, and even the narrowly defined money supply had been expand
ing considerably less rapidly.
Under the proposed directive, Mr. Maisel said, the Committee
ran two types of risks.

The first--and the one most within the

Committee's control--was the likelihood that as liquidity continued
to disappear from financial markets, the probability would increase
that its rate of disappearance would accelerate and that that would
lead to excess strains in particular financial sectors,

The second

and less likely possibility was that similar distortions would occur
in output and production.
It seemed to Mr. Maisel that both of those possibilities had
a high enough probability so that even if the Committee gave a low
probability to the staff's projection--which he would not necessarily
do--it ought to define current tightness in terms of the concepts it
had considered advisable in January and February as to what a
logical long-run monetary policy should be.

It had agreed then to

adopt a restraining, anti-inflationary policy, but one with moderate
growth rates in the monetary and credit aggregates.

Recent policy

seemed to be driving the Committee beyond that point.
The problem was being escalated steadily, Mr. Maisel remarked.
How could the Committee move most sensibly to a proper posture and

-80

6/24/69
path?

How could it avoid a sharp stop-go shift?

The longer it

waited in getting back to a sustainable path, the more difficult
the transition and the greater the likelihood that the transition
would cause a major shift in expectations and credibility.
It appeared to Mr. Maisel that the Committee was at a point
at which it should start to approach a maintainable policy.
not think the present policy stance met that criterion.
likely to lead to a cumulative contraction of credit.

He did

It was too
The money

market conditions that had been allowed to develop had led to con
tractions in the monetary aggregates even with extremely heavy
demand for credit in the economy; any decrease in demand with
current policy should mean that the contraction in credit would
accelerate.

The projections for July were for very heavy run-offs

in both bank credit and total reserves.
In order to bring about the proper transition to a maintainable
level, Mr. Maisel suggested that the second paragraph of the proposed
directive be amended to call for operations to be conducted with a
view to "maintaining the firm conditions prevailing during this
quarter in money and short-term credit markets."

That would mean

net borrowed reserves slightly under $1 billion, the Federal funds
rate below 8-1/2 per cent, and the three-month bill rate between 6
and 6-1/2 per cent.

That would maintain recent average relationships

while avoiding cumulative pressures arising as liquidity disappeared.

6/24/69

-81
Another method of achieving the same goal would be through

the use of the proviso clause, Mr. Maisel said.

The Committee

could adopt the proposed directive if it agreed that the proviso
would go into effect and stay in effect if projections showed a
negative number for the credit proxy including Euro-dollars.
Mr. Maisel believed that the directive proposed was really
one for a further tightening of policy, as had resulted from the
past two directives.

As he had indicated, money market rates were

higher and aggregate flows lower.

He would not want to support a

directive that projected a two-month--June and July--annual rate
of decrease in the credit proxy of minus 10 to 12 per cent and an
even sharper decrease in total reserves.
Mr. Brimmer commented that he saw no reason to change policy

at this time.

He found the staff's draft directive satisfactory,

except that he agreed that the reference to the thrift industry's
expectations of sizable mid-year outflows should be deleted from
the first paragraph.

That was a most unusual statement for the

directive and was not needed.
Mr. Brimmer said he definitely would favor taking some steps
to restrict fund-raising by banks outside the scope of Regulations D
and Q.

He favored dealing with Euro-dollar borrowings in the manner

the staff recently had suggested to the Board.
Mr. Brimmer hoped the Board would be extremely cautious in
approaching the question of a possible increase in Regulation Q

6/24/69

-82

ceilings.

Apart from the fact that the ceilings had served as the

cutting edge of policy recently, it was necessary to anticipate
that banks would respond very quickly to any leeway allowed them
by an increase in ceilings.

That had been the experience following

the ceiling increases in 1966 and 1968; on both occasions banks
had recouped 90 per cent of their previous run-offs of CD's within
two or three months of the Board's action.

Recently banks had

cut back substantially their new commitments for term loans but
were continuing to make commitments on other loans at a rapid rate.
If they were able to attract a substantial volume of time deposits
as a result of an increase in the ceilings he would expect them
promptly to increase the rate at which they were making commitments.
He favored no change in the Q ceilings at this time.
Mr. Brimmer remarked that he was intrigued by the staff's
suggestion that the Committee should now begin to give greater
weight to aggregative targets, particularly reserves.

He recalled

that on various occasions the Manager had indicated that he would
find it somewhat more difficult to operate under targets formulated
in terms of aggregates than he did with money market targets.

Before

the Committee agreed to downgrade money market conditions for target
purposes it would be desirable to have a statement from the Manager
on the implications of such a change for his operations.
Mr. Brimmer observed that he had found the staff's balance
of payments projections interesting, but he noted that not much

6/24/69

-83

had been said regarding the near-term outlook.

He thought the

Committee should be aware of the fact that no plans were being
formulated within the Government to cope with the payments situation.
Indeed, efforts were being made to obtain some further relaxation
of the control programs, particularly the foreign credit restraint
program.

He saw no reason for any optimism in that area.
In concluding, Mr. Brimmer said he thought today's chart

show merited the favorable comments that had been made.

In addition,

explicit note should be taken of the hard work done by the staffs of
both the Board and the New York Reserve Bank in connection with pos
sible regulatory action to close the Regulation D and Q loopholes.
Mr. Sherrill said he approved the staff's draft directive
as written except that he also would favor deleting the reference
to possible mid-year outflows at thrift institutions.

He thought

that the current firm stance of monetary policy was correct, and that
it should be maintained at present without any suggestion of easing.
He firmly believed that the Board should not raise Regulation Q
ceilings at this stage because such an action would be interpreted
as a significant lessening of the degree of monetary restraint.

He

did not think an increase in the discount rate was necessary now in
light of the fairly stable situation at the discount windows, but
he would want to consider such action later, perhaps in July.
Mr. Sherrill remarked that Euro-dollar borrowings by U.S.
banks had become so large as to involve considerable risks, both

6/24/69

-84

domestically and abroad.
to restrict the inflow.

Accordingly, he would favor Board action
He thought the System also should move

promptly to stop Federal funds transactions of the type Mr. Swan
had mentioned, if his understanding was correct that those transac
tions were a device for paying the Federal funds rate on depositors'
funds.
As to other nondeposit sources of bank funds, Mr. Sherrill
favored preparing now to take action later to the extent that might
be considered necessary, but not acting at this time.

Bank access

to funds from such sources would be useful as a safety valve for
the time being, particularly if action were taken in the Euro-dollar
area.
Mr. Hickman observed that the economic situation had not
changed substantially since the Committee's last meeting.

The real

rate of economic growth remained below the potential rate at which
the economy was capable of expanding.

As the Board's staff had

indicated in the green book,1/ the rate of gain in real GNP probably
again fell below a 3 per cent seasonally adjusted annual rate this
quarter, with further softening expected in the third and fourth
quarters.

Nevertheless, it was clear that neither price pressures

nor expectations of continued inflation had yet been brought under
control.

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions."
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

6/24/69

-85
The recent sharp increase in interest rates in all sectors

was a matter of deep concern in the Fourth District, Mr. Hickman
said.

The immediate cause of the latest surge in interest rates

was the increase in the prime rate, but the stage had been set by
extreme pressures in financial markets, which were reminiscent of
the credit crunch of 1966.

With the passing of the tax and dividend

period, market pressures seemed to have eased a bit.

The question

now was whether the slightly improved tone would be allowed to con
tinue, or whether market pressures would build up again to the
levels of early June.
Mr. Hickman thought a restrictive monetary policy was
appropriate under present conditions.

There was, however, some

question as to how restrictive policy should be.

The System's

staying power might ultimately prove to have been weakened by the
extreme pressures that had been allowed to develop since the
Committee's last meeting.

What was needed, in his opinion, was a

moderately restrictive policy that could be maintained over a period
long enough to eliminate inflationary expectations.

If monetary

policy swung too far toward restraint--as he thought it might already
have done--it might induce an actual decline in real output before
inflationary expectations were brought under control.

If that

occurred, the question would then be whether the Committee would
be willing to maintain an appropriately restrictive policy, or

-86

6/24/69

whether it would swing to the side of ease, as it had in 1967 and
again in the last half of 1968.

In his opinion, the Committee

should adjust its sights to reasonable targets that could be main
tained over an indefinite period.

After five or six months of

virtually no growth, or outright declines, in the reserve aggre
gates and the bank credit proxy, it was time for a modest first
step toward the establishment of monetary conditions that would
accommodate moderate long-run credit growth.

He thought that

continuation of the current severely restrictive monetary policy
would be dangerous, and, therefore, he would not favor the staff's
draft directive.

He would, however, find acceptable a directive

of the kind suggested by Mr. Maisel.
For political, economic, and psychological reasons,
Mr. Hickman said, he would prefer to leave the discount rate where
it was, at least until the passage of the surtax was assured.

He

would, however, recommend to the Cleveland Bank directors that they
move with the System in the event the Board of Governors thought a
change was appropriate.

If that occurred, he would recommend that

the increase be coupled with a modest upward change in the ceilings
on large-denomination CD's.

He was afraid it might be a little late

in the cycle to do very much about reserves on Euro-dollars, although
he thought something should have been done earlier in that area.
Mr. Bopp commented that for some time the money and credit
aggregates and money market conditions had been registering clearly

6/24/69

-87

the restrictive monetary policy instituted at the beginning of this
year.

Most recently, revisions in the money and credit aggregates

for May and projections for June indicated that, if anything, policy
might have been a bit more restrictive than the Committee had
intended.
In a recent survey of large Philadelphia banks, Mr. Bopp said,
it was found that their experiences over the quarterly tax-payment
date were about what they had expected.

Last minute bulges in loan

demand and deposit declines did occur but were met with a minimum
of discomfort largely because they were well within the ranges pro
jected and prepared for by the banks.

However, all of the reporting

banks were feeling the bite of the pressure accumulating since the
beginning of the year.

As a result, within the past few weeks several

of the banks had initiated even more strict credit rationing.
In spite of the impact of policy on financial variables,
Mr. Bopp remarked, the response of the real sector of the economy
was still disappointingly little.

The spurt in the index of indus

trial production during May was particularly disappointing since its
behavior in the past few months had been one of the few indicators of
developing moderation.

In view of the upward revision in plant and

equipment expenditures for the second quarter and the economy's
general posture of strength, the $16 billion increase in GNP recorded
in the first quarter now seemed likely to be approximated in the
current quarter.

The impact of policy on prices seemed to be even

further down the road.

-88-

6/24/69

Locally, Mr. Bopp continued, the Philadelphia Reserve
Bank's May survey of the business outlook indicated that the
number of manufacturers expecting increased business six months
hence had dropped sharply for the first time since the end of
last year.

While the June survey confirmed that shift in expec

tations, no further declines had occurred.

Businessmen still

expected prices to continue to rise.
The tax-payment date and the problems it posed for policy
were now past, Mr. Bopp observed.

Nevertheless, the policy choice

this morning was as difficult for him as four weeks ago.

On the

one hand, the requisite degree of moderation in the economy was not
yet in sight.

On the other hand, still confronting the Committee

were the questions of how much more resilience the financial system
could possess and whether it would be possible to avoid a credit
crunch.

On balance, he concluded that the costs of faltering in

the effort to gain control of aggregate demand were so high that
there should be no relaxation of the restraint that had prevailed
thus far this year.
Mr. Bopp reported that at its last meeting the Philadelphia
Reserve Bank board of directors had debated at some length whether
to raise the discount rate.

Although they went along with his

recommendation of no change, they had strong feelings that monetary

6/24/69

-89

policy should be tighter than it was.

Several directors had indi

cated that they would like to see increases in reserve requirements
and imposition of reserve requirements against Euro-dollar deposits,
as well as regulation of other sources of bank funds.
In his judgment, Mr. Bopp said, the Committee should not
tighten the money and short-term capital markets further.
discount rate, of course, was far out of line.

The

There had been no

administrative difficulties for the discount window in the Third
District and its share of total national borrowings had been small.
He would, however, be willing to go along with some discount rate
adjustment if other Districts had had administrative problems that
might be mitigated by an increase.

He had some difficulty in

deciding when such an increase would best be made.
Mr. Bopp thought the staff's draft of the directive was
appropriate except that he would favor deletion in the first para
graph of the reference to expected outflows around mid-year at
nonbank thrift institutions.
Mr. Kimbrel said that, judging by the performance of Sixth
District banks, System policy was not achieving the desired reduc
tion in loan growth.

District banks continued to mount a greater

loan expansion than nationally.

During May, in contrast to April,

most of the loan growth had occurred at banks in the under-$100
million deposit group.

However, at the large banks business loans

continued to expand in early June.

6/24/69

-90One reason for the more expansive District-than-national

loan performance, Mr. Kimbrel continued, might be the better-than
national deposit trends.

Total deposits at all District banks

combined had generally trended upward since the first of the year,
largely because of time deposits other than savings at country banks.
Moreover, the District's large reserve city banks as a group had not
experienced the kind of attrition in deposits shown by the national
figures.
Nevertheless, Mr. Kimbrel remarked, liquidity pressures
were increasing and, at a few of the large banks in reserve cities,
they had become intense.

The reaction of such banks, however, had

rarely consisted of cutting back on loans.

Instead, there had been

slight reductions in investments by some banks, greater use of
Federal funds, limited use of the Euro-dollar market, increased use
of nondeposit sources of funds, and borrowing from the Federal
Reserve Bank.
District banks had deepened their basic reserve deficit
rather considerably in recent weeks, Mr. Kimbrel reported.

Federal

funds purchases had averaged $600 million daily, compared with $500
million in early May, with the big banks in one of the reserve
cities accounting for one-third of the total.

Federal funds sales

had shown a tendency to decline.
The banks that had been making intensive use of Federal funds,
Mr. Kimbrel said, were apparently the ones that had exerted efforts

-91

6/24/69

to secure funds from nondeposit sources.

The recent survey made at

the request of the Board of Governors showed that nondeposit sources
of funds at the thirty-two weekly reporting banks amounted to only
seven-tenths of 1 per cent of total deposits for all of the banks
reporting.

However, at one of the banks nondeposit sources con

stituted 9.5 per cent of total deposits.

Two of the District banks

showed outstanding balances in Euro-dollars.

One of the same banks

accounted for most of the $35 million of commercial paper issued by
a bank holding company reported by District banks.

Again, one of

those reserve city banks accounted for most of the consumer instal
ment loans sold.

Those banks also had high loans-to-deposits

ratios.
A careful bank-by-bank review suggested to Mr. Kimbrel that
in the Atlanta District a relatively limited number of aggressive
banks accounted for the major part of the loan growth.

Those were

also the banks whose efforts to maintain liquidity contributed to
bidding up Federal funds and related rates.

Although he was not

familiar with the details of what was happening in other Districts,
he gathered that somewhat the same situation prevailed elsewhere.
If that was the case, it seemed to Mr. Kimbrel that raising
the discount rate even by a full point would have very little
additional restrictive effect that was not already being exerted by
the high cost of Federal funds, Euro-dollars, and any other sources
those banks might be able to tap.

Even those aggressive banks were

-92

6/24/69

apparently beginning to realize that they could not continue indefi
nitely to maintain their reserve positions with high-cost borrowed
money.
That bankers were finally realizing they were going to have
to do something about bringing their operations within their resources
was evidenced by the visits to the Atlanta Bank last week of repre
sentatives of several of the District's large banks, Mr. Kimbrel
remarked.

It was interesting to him that, with one exception, the

bankers' visits were at their own volition and not at the Bank's
invitation.

Moreover, most of them had emphasized that they were

not coming to prepare the way for future borrowing.

What they

apparently were looking for was a receptive ear for a recital of
their difficulties.

Undoubtedly, they hoped they would learn that

the Federal Reserve was going to take some action to rescue them.
At least three of them suggested that some kind of controls would
be appropriate.

They did not like the idea of controls but apparently

were looking for a crutch that would reinforce the actions they knew
they had to take in reducing their loan expansion.
If the System could continue to limit general reserve
availability and keep a firm administration at the discount window,
Mr. Kimbrel observed, it should not be too long before it could
expect to see even the aggressive banks exert a little more restraint
in their lending.

-93

6/24/69

Mr. Kimbrel said he personally believed there was con
siderable merit in closing the loopholes which had distorted the
impact of monetary policy in its move to restraint.

Nevertheless,

with the delicate handling necessary to avoid contributing further
He

to the nervousness at home and abroad, timing was important.
would not urge any change in Regulation Q ceilings on large
denomination CD's at this time, although such a move might be

appropriate in the not too distant future if associated with an
increase in reserve requirements.
Under those circumstances, Mr. Kimbrel remarked, he would
like to have the System maintain about its present posture.
was, therefore, not in favor of a more restrictive policy.

He
He was

inclined to believe that raising the discount rate at this time
would serve no useful purpose.

On the other hand, raising the

rate now would have several disadvantages, including giving the
impression that the System was shifting toward a more restrictive
policy and unsettling the money and capital markets further.
Under those conditions, Mr. Kimbrel indicated his preference
would be to accept the directive as drafted by the staff after
eliminating the reference to expected outflows at thrift institu
tions from the first paragraph.
Mr. Francis commented that recent monetary actions seemed
to have been about right.

Since the Committee had adopted a more

-94

6/24/69

restrictive policy in December, money had risen at a 3 per cent
annual rate, or about half its average pace of the two previous
years.

The demand deposit component had increased even more

slowly since December.

Effects of those actions on total spend

ing should be evident in the near future.

Meanwhile, the System

should not be swayed into adoption of credit controls in the hope
that inflation could be slowed more quickly in that way.
Although monetary developments had been less expansionary
since December, Mr. Francis said, they did not appear too tight,
and the Committee should make certain that it did not relax either
intentionally or unintentionally.

Rather, it might be desirable

to reduce the rate of growth of relevant monetary aggregates some
what more, holding the growth of money to, say, a 2 per cent
annual rate.

Money had not grown at all for nine months from the

spring of 1966 to early 1967, and the moderation in spending in
early 1967, although pronounced, did not appear to him to have
been excessive.
Mr. Francis noted that growth in some other monetary
aggregates, such as money plus time deposits and total bank credit,
had slowed more than money since last December.

The studies of

the St. Louis Reserve Bank and its interpretation of the Board's
flow of funds information indicated, however, that those measures
were likely to be misleading at this time since they reflected a

-95

6/24/69

switching of funds out of banks and into other markets rather than
a net decline in total credit flows.
the well-known impact of Regulation Q.

That was due, of course, to
Markets would be more

efficient, small savers and small borrowers would be benefited,
and bank credit and M2 would be better measures of monetary develop
ments if Regulation Q ceilings were raised or eliminated.

If that

was impossible, at least the Committee should not be misled into
believing that the low rates of growth in those aggregates indicated
that the System was being overly restrictive.

It seemed to him

that a relaxation of Regulation Q ceilings, at least on large
denomination CD's, would eliminate the need to consider further
restrictive measures--of the type suggested by Mr. Treiber and
others--to curb bank access to nondeposit funds.
Mr. Francis observed that the Committee had now had some
time to evaluate the effects of the lagged reserve requirements
which were implemented last fall.

The chief advantage of the

change that had been advanced was to make member banks more
efficient in the utilization of their reserves.

That advantage

seemed to him to be of minor value compared with the adverse
effects of the new arrangement.

The System could provide more

reserves at little or no social cost if the banks desired to hold
greater excess balances.

The System's ability to control monetary

aggregates had been reduced.

Since those effects were of importance

-96

6/24/69

to the System in its execution of policy, he suggested that
consideration be given to rescinding the lagged reserve feature.
As for the immediate future, Mr. Francis trusted that
the Committee would not relax the monetary conditions which had
been attained.

If anything, the growth rates of bank reserves,

the monetary base, and money should be reduced a little further.
In view of the high level of market rates relative to the discount
rate, he believed it would be desirable to raise the discount rate
by at least one percentage point.
Mr. Robertson said his statement today would be quite
brief.

For the first time in a long time, he thought System

policy was on exactly the right track and that all that was
needed was to hold steady.
Chairman Martin indicated that he concurred in Mr. Robertson's
statement.

As to the directive, a number of members had spoken

in favor of eliminating from the first paragraph of the staff's
draft the reference to expected outflows from nonbank thrift insti
tutions at mid-year.

The change in the second paragraph proposed

by Mr. Maisel had not received much support in the discussion.
Mr. Robertson recalled that Mr. Treiber had suggested
that the language in the second paragraph of the directive adopted
at the last meeting, relating to the maintenance of "prevailing
pressures," be retained in the new directive.

6/24/69

-97Mr. Daane said he thought Mr. Treiber's proposal would

have some support.
Chairman Martin expressed the view that the choice between
the second-paragraph language of the staff's draft and that pro
posed by Mr. Treiber was a matter of taste rather than of substance.
In any case, the majority of Committee members seemed to favor
the former.

Accordingly, he proposed that the Committee vote on

a directive consisting of the staff's draft with the reference he
had mentioned deleted from the first paragraph.
With Mr. Maisel dissenting, the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York was
authorized and directed, until other
wise directed by the Committee, to
execute transactions in the System
Account in accordance with the follow
ing current economic policy directive:
The information reviewed at this meeting suggests
that expansion in real economic activity is continuing
to moderate slightly, but that substantial upward pres
sures on prices and costs are persisting. Most market
interest rates have risen considerably on balance in
recent weeks, as credit demands continued strong against
the background of considerable restraint on the banking
system. Growth in bank credit and the money supply
thus far in 1969 has been limited, and both declined
somewhat on average in May. Large-denomination CD's have
continued to run off at a rapid pace recently, and net
inflows of consumer-type time and savings deposits have
remained small. At nonbank thrift institutions, savings
inflows slowed somewhat on average in April and May.
Very heavy Euro-dollar borrowing by U.S. banks through
their foreign branches produced a large surplus in the
balance of payments on the official settlements basis
after mid-May. On the other hand, high Euro-dollar
interest rates apparently also stimulated outflows of

6/24/69

-98-

funds from the United States that contributed to a large
deficit on the liquidity basis thus far in June. In
light of the foregoing developments, it is the policy of
the Federal Open Market Committee to foster financial
conditions conducive to the reduction of inflationary
pressures, with a view to encouraging a more sustainable
rate of economic growth and attaining reasonable equi
librium in the country's balance of payments.
To implement this policy, System open market opera
tions until the next meeting of the Committee shall be
conducted with a view to maintaining the firm conditions
currently prevailing in money and short-term credit
markets; provided, however, that operations shall be
modified if bank credit appears to be deviating signifi
cantly from current projections or if unusual liquidity
pressures should develop.
Chairman Martin then proposed that the Committee continue
its discussion of possible outright System transactions in Federal
agency issues.

He noted that in accordance with the discussion

at the preceding meeting the Manager had prepared two memoranda,
suggesting guidelines for experimental operations and listing
considerations against proceeding with outright operations at
this time.l/
The Treasury had not yet reached a firm position on the
question of System operations, the Chairman continued, although
it was his impression that they thought it might be wise to delay

1/ The first of these memoranda was entitled "Experimental
open market operations in Federal Agency issues" and dated
June 18, 1969; the second was entitled "Considerations against
Federal Reserve operations in Agency issues at this time" and
dated June 20, 1969. Copies of both memoranda have been placed
in the Committee's files.

6/24/69

-99

such operations until there had been more time to work toward
consolidation of agency issues.

If that course were followed,

however, it was likely that no System action would have been
taken by the time the Board was called upon to testify on the
extension of the legislation authorizing the operations in
question.
Mr. Robertson said he agreed that it would have been
better if the Treasury had been able to accomplish some consolida
tion of agency issues before the System began outright operations.
Nevertheless, it seemed to him that there was much to be gained
by moving now on outright operations, and a lot to be lost by
delaying.

In particular, if the Committee had not acted by the

time of the Congressional hearings to which the Chairman had
referred, the System was likely to get a directive from Congress
in the matter.

He thought the guidelines suggested by the Manager

in his memorandum of June 18 were excellent.

If those guidelines

were approved by the Committee and then made public through a
statement to the press, misunderstandings of the Committee's
intentions would be avoided, and in his judgment most of the
arguments listed in the second memorandum against acting now
would be obviated.
Mr. Daane said he thought both of the Manager's memoranda
were excellent and the case made in the second memorandum against

-100

6/24/69

proceeding with outright operations at this time was a persuasive
one.

While he recognized that judgments could differ, it was his

judgment that the considerations against moving now which Mr. Holmes
had listed would be valid even if the guidelines were published.
For example, he thought that by acting now the System would weaken
its ability to avoid supporting individual sectors of the market,
and he agreed with the Manager that once operations were launched
it would be extremely difficult for the System to draw back in
the event that the experiment proved unsuccessful.

In sum, he

believed it would be highly unwise for the Committee to undertake
outright operations in agency issues at present.
Mr. Treiber concurred in Mr. Daane's observations.
Mr. Brimmer said he agreed with Mr. Robertson that the
Committee should act affirmatively on the matter at this time and
also that a press release containing the guidelines should be
issued.

Those steps, he thought, would strengthen the Board's

position in the forthcoming Congressional hearings.

Beyond that,

publication of the guidelines should prove helpful to the Treasury
in its efforts to rationalize the market for agency issues.

He

personally had no fears about being stampeded into undesirable
operations so long as the System had the option to sell as well
as to buy agency issues.

The danger in not acting was that Congress

would give the System a directive under which its options would
be severely restricted.

6/24/69

-101
Mr. Brimmer added that in his judgment the present situation

was similar to that in 1966, when the Board had indicated to
Congress that it was agreeable to legislation providing flexible
authority to regulate maximum interest rates on time depositsand by so doing had avoided a Congressional directive on rate
ceilings.

As on that occassion, it would be wise now for the

System to take a modest and judicious step to avoid a more drastic
outcome.
Chairman Martin remarked that Mr. Brimmer's comment about
the 1966 experience posed the question clearly.

In his opinion

one could make a good case that the course the System had followed
in 1966 had proved to be quite unwise; that the resulting heavy
reliance on Regulation Q ceilings for monetary policy purposes
had been the source of much of the difficulty the System now faced.
He agree, however, that the two situations were similar in the
sense that the issues involved in both were primarily political
rather than economic.

One could argue that it would be better to

get a Congressional directive on System operations in agency issues,
on the grounds that that would lead to a demonstration of their
ineffectiveness in accomplishing the intended objectives, and thus
to cancellation of the directive.
To his mind, the Chairman continued, the question of the
appropriate course was an open one.

If by adopting the guidelines

6/24/69

-102

suggested by the Manager the Federal Reserve could avoid getting
too deeply into operations in agency issues, it might be best to
go ahead on that basis.

But even if the System undertook experi

mental operations under the proposed guidelines it might get a
directive from Congress on the matter.

In any case, he personally

was convinced that the System would find it difficult to sell
agency issues from its portfolio, so that its operations would
be limited mainly to purchases.
Mr. Coldwell remarked that if the Committee approved the
proposed guidelines the press release on the subject should indi
cate clearly that any purchases of agency issues would substitute
for purchases of Treasury securities, and would not constitute
net additions to the System's portfolio.
Mr. Francis observed that he would rather risk getting a
Congressional directive than undertake experimental operations.
If a directive were issued it would be apparent to everyone that
Congress was responsible for the operations.
Chairman Martin said he was somewhat influenced by the
fact that Treasury officials had not reached any firm conclusions
on the matter, so that Treasury views could not be cited when
Federal Reserve testimony was taken on extension of the legisla
tion in question.

At the same time, it was not clear to him that

the hearings would be held before the next meeting of the Committee.

6/24/69

-103
Mr. Mitchell commented that while he did not feel strongly

he thought it would be wise for the Committee to take some steps
which could be reported to Congress in the forthcoming hearings.
However, he would not necessarily favor actually launching opera
tions before that time.

The Manager's June 18 memorandum implied

that in any case some time would elapse before operations would
be undertaken.
Mr. Holmes remarked that, as his memorandum indicated,
before operations were actually started it would be desirable to
hold discussions with the Federal agencies affected and with
dealers to explain the principles embodied in the guidelines.
Mr. Daane asked whether it would be possible to hold such
discussions without committing the System to actual operations.
Mr. Holmes replied that it might be feasible to talk with
officials of the Federal agencies about the nature of possible
System operations, while indicating that no decision to undertake
those operations had been made.

He did not think it would be

wise to hold similar discussions with dealers in advance of a
Committee decision.
Mr. Brimmer remarked that in his judgment it would be
most unwise for the Manager to discuss the question with the
Federal agencies involved until after the Committee had taken
affirmative action and had made the guidelines public.

It was

unlikely that the substance of such conversations would remain

-104

6/24/69
confidential for long.

In any case, one of the advantages of

moving at this juncture was to improve the System's position in
the forthcoming hearings, and for that purpose it would be desir
able to announce the decision in advance of the hearings.
Chairman Martin said he found it quite difficult to judge
whether affirmative action on the matter would strengthen or
weaken the System's position.

Perhaps it would be helpful to

indicate that the System was willing to experiment with outright
operations; but perhaps, as he had suggested earlier, Congress
would issue a directive anyway.

But while he was unsure on that

point, he was sure that outright operations in agency issues, if
carried too far, would constitute a trap for the System, at least
if there was not a considerable degree of consolidation of such
issues.
The Chairman then suggested that the Committee vote on
the question of whether to amend the continuing authority direc
tive, in the manner suggested in Mr. Holmes' memorandum of June 18,
to authorize System operations in agency issues, subject to the
guidelines also suggested in that memorandum.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that he was not prepared to vote
favorably on a final action at this time.

He would have no

hesitancy about authorizing the Manager to discuss the proposed
guidelines with the agencies, but he would like to reserve a
final judgment on System operations.

6/24/69

-105
Chairman Martin said the fact that the Treasury had not

yet reached a firm position on the matter offered grounds for
postponing a final decision until the next meeting of the Committee.
For the System to act in the absence of knowledge of the Treasury's
position would be a questionable procedure, in his opinion.

On

the other hand, the probable imminence of Congressional hearings
on the underlying legislation argued against a delay.

He under

stood that Mr. Cardon thought it quite likely that those hearings
would be held before the Committee's next meeting, although that
was not certain.
All things considered, the Chairman said, he personally
would be prepared to take the risks involved in carrying the
matter over until the next meeting.
Mr. Daane remarked that if Chairman Martin were prepared
to take those risks he would support the Chairman's position.
Mr. Robertson said he thought it would be desirable for
the Committee to vote up or down the question the Chairman had
put earlier, and Mr. Brimmer agreed.
Mr. Sherrill suggested that the Committee might first be
polled on the proposal that a decision be postponed until the
next meeting, and the Chairman concurred.
The poll indicated that nine members favored that proposal
and three (Messrs. Brimmer, Maisel, and Robertson) did not.

6/24/69

-106

Accordingly, it was agreed that a decision with respect to
outright System operations in agency issues should be postponed
until the next meeting of the Committee.
It was agreed that the next meeting of the Committee
would be held on Tuesday, July 15, 1969, at 9:30 a.m.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

ATTACHMENT A
June 23, 1969

Draft of Current Economic Policy Directive for Consideration by the
Federal Open Market Committee at its Meeting on June 24, 1969

The information reviewed at this meeting suggests that
expansion in real economic activity is continuing to moderate
slightly, but that substantial upward pressures on prices and
costs are persisting. Most market interest rates have risen
considerably on balance in recent weeks, as credit demands con
tinued strong against the background of considerable restraint
on the banking system. Growth in bank credit and the money
supply thus far in 1969 has been limited, and both declined
somewhat on average in May. Large-denomination CD's have con
tinued to run off at a rapid pace recently, and net inflows of
consumer-type time and savings deposits have remained small. At
nonbank thrift institutions, savings inflows slowed somewhat on
average in April and May and the industry reportedly was preparing
for sizable outflows during the mid-year interest-crediting
period. Very heavy Euro-dollar borrowing by U.S. banks through
their foreign branches produced a large surplus in the balance
of payments on the official settlements basis after mid-May. On
the other hand, high Euro-dollar interest rates apparently also
stimulated outflows of funds from the United States that contributed
to a large deficit on the liquidity basis thus far in June. In
light of the foregoing developments, it is the policy of the Federal
Open Market Committee to foster financial conditions conducive to
the reduction of inflationary pressures, with a view to encourag
ing a more sustainable rate of economic growth and attaining
reasonable equilibrium in the country's balance of payments.
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with
a view to maintaining the firm conditions currently prevailing in
money and short-term credit markets; provided, however, that opera
tions shall be modified if bank credit appears to be deviating
significantly from current projections or if unusual liquidity
pressures should develop.