View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Robert Vigfusson
June 14, 2011
Evaluating the Forecasting Performance of Commodity Futures Prices
Futures prices are frequently criticized as being uninformative for forecasting
purposes because (1) they seem to do no better than a random walk or an extrapolation of
recent trends and (2) futures prices for commodities often trace out a relatively flat
trajectory even though global demand is steadily increasing. In this note, we attempt to
shed light on these concerns by discussing the theoretical relationship between spot and
futures prices for commodities and by evaluating the empirical forecasting performance
of futures prices relative to some alternative benchmarks.
The key results of our analysis are:


When commodities are storable, spot prices reflect both current supply and
demand conditions as well as expectations for those conditions in the future
because market participants can arbitrage between the current spot price and the
futures price. Accordingly, relatively flat futures paths are neither surprising nor
an indication of dysfunction on the part of futures markets: For any given
expected price in the future, market participants will adjust their positions so that
the expected difference between the price now and the price in the future will
approximate market rates of return (adjusted for costs of storing or selling
commodities).



Futures prices have generally outperformed a random walk forecast, but not by a
large margin, while both futures and a random walk noticeably outperform a
simple extrapolation of recent trends (a random walk with drift). Importantly,
however, futures prices outperform a random walk by a considerable margin
when there is a sizeable difference between spot and futures prices.
These results suggest that futures prices remain a reasonable guide for forecasting

commodity prices. However, as we will discuss, futures prices may also, in principle,
contain a risk premium that creates a wedge between the observed futures price and the
spot price expected to prevail in the future. In the final section of this note, we attempt to
identify such a risk premium. Our results suggest that controlling for a risk premium in
real time does not materially improve the forecasting performance of futures prices.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

The Relationship Between Spot and Futures Prices for Commodities
Expectations of future commodity prices are a critical determinant of spot prices,
and this linkage depends on the capacity to store commodities in inventory.
Transactions in the spot market require the seller to accept that the price received is
adequate compensation for forgoing the opportunity to hold the commodity in inventory
to sell later. (For producers of commodities, a similar calculation applies to the decision
to produce an extra unit of the commodity today versus in the future.) Likewise, the
buyer must accept that the benefit of purchasing now outweighs the benefits of waiting to
buy later. Accordingly, the spot price embodies an expectation of what prices will be in
the future. As a corollary, changes in expectations of future supply and demand
conditions will show up as movements in both current spot and futures prices.
The relationship between spot and futures prices can be derived from conditions
that rule out profitable arbitrage opportunities, so that holders of commodities are
indifferent between selling them in the spot market or holding them in inventory to
deliver later at the contracted futures price. To illustrate, denote the current spot price as
S and the current value of the one-year ahead futures price as F, and consider the
following cases:


Case 1: Suppose that the spot price is above the futures price (S > F). Here the
arbitrage opportunity would be to sell out of inventory today at the spot price S,
put the money in an interest bearing instrument (earning interest R), and use a
futures contract to restock the inventory a year from now at the guaranteed price
of F. Such a strategy also has the benefit of reducing the storage costs that must
be paid to carry inventories (denoted C), which include both warehousing costs
and, for some commodities, product depreciation and/or spoilage. But keeping a
commodity in stock has its own additional value, which is often called the
convenience yield (denoted Y), which must be foregone under this strategy. Thus,
to rule out a profitable arbitrage opportunity, it must be that the benefits of the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

strategy, (1+R+C)S, are less than or equal to the costs, F+YS, or (1+R+CY)S ≤ F.1


Case 2: Suppose that the spot price is below the futures price (S < F). The
attempted arbitrage would be to borrow money (at interest rate R) to buy one unit
of the good at spot price S and then deliver it a year later at the already assured
price F. In holding the good, one pays the storage costs C but also receives the
associated convenience yield Y. Therefore, to prevent an arbitrage opportunity,
we require that the total costs of this strategy, (1+R+C)S, be greater than or equal
to the benefits, F+YS, that is, (1+R+C-Y)S ≥ F.
Combining these two conditions gives F=(1+R+C-Y)S or, equivalently,

F/S=(1+R+C-Y). As the storage costs (C) and the convenience yield (Y) tend towards
zero, the difference between the spot and futures prices converge to the rate of interest.
This convergence is equivalent to the familiar Hotelling’s rule that spot commodity prices
will rise at the discount rate, that is, F = (1+R)S. In this case, the futures-based forecast
is similar to a random walk forecast when interest rates are low. In contrast, the higher
the storage costs and convenience yield, the more the futures price can differ from the
spot price for any given interest rate.
The costs for storing a commodity should be a function of the level of inventories
and the physical properties of the commodity. When inventories are very high and
approaching storage capacity limits, the cost of additional storage (C) should also be
high. For example, in the fall of 2008, conventional oil storage facilities were near
capacity and, so, oil was stored in tanker ships, even though ship-based storage is much
more expensive than land-based storage. These high storage costs allowed the difference
between the spot price and the futures price to widen. In December of 2008, the spot

1

In this example, the storage cost C and convenience yield Y are assumed to be proportionate to the price
of the commodity S. Alternatively, we could have specified the cost in per physical unit terms, so (1+R)S
+ C-Y ≥ F.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

price for oil was around $40 barrel and the twelve-month ahead futures price was above
$55 per barrel.
In addition, storage costs also vary across commodities. For example, the storage
costs for fresh cut flowers can be thought of as approaching infinity, which would be
sufficient to break the link between the futures and spot prices. In such a market,
inventories cannot be used to smooth prices. In contrast, other commodities such as
metals have relatively low storage costs. For these commodities, inventory smoothing
limits the extent that future prices can differ from spot prices.
Whereas inventory accumulation becomes more costly as inventories near
capacity, the convenience yield (Y) of having an additional unit of stock is particularly
high when inventories are low. For example, one might require the good to keep a
production process running or avoid disappointing customers. As such, increases in the
convenience yield may at times drive the spot price well above the futures price.
How well do these theoretical results conform with the observed structure of
futures prices? Table 1 reports statistics on the distribution of the ratio of the one-year
ahead futures price to the spot price (F/S) for a selection of commodities from 1990
through 2010.2 The values in column iii show the percent of the time that the futures
price was within +/- 5 percent of the spot price (0.95 < F/S < 1.05). By this score, copper
ranks fairly high, with the futures price within 5 percent of the spot price 45 percent of
the time. Towards the other extreme is natural gas, for which the futures price was within
5 percent of the spot price only 24 percent of the time. Crude oil, at 29 percent, is in
between these extremes. The fraction of the time futures exceeded spot prices by more
2

Because not all futures markets have contracts for every month, defining the year-ahead futures price is
not straightforward. To maximize our sample, in this memo we use 12-month ahead futures for energy, 8month ahead futures for agricultural commodities, and 15-month ahead futures for metals.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

than 15 percent (F/S > 1.15, shown in column v) was essentially zero for many metals,
6 percent for oil, and 28 percent for natural gas.
These distributions accord well with reported storage costs. For example, storage
capacity for metals is virtually unlimited, as all that is required is a warehouse to protect
stocks from the elements, vandals, and thieves.3 Within the metals category, given that
storage costs per pound are similar for the various metals, the high average price of nickel
per pound—and correspondingly low storage costs per unit value—likely helps explain
why its futures price was within 5 percent of the spot 73 percent of the time, the greatest
percentage amongst the metals. Conversely, natural gas is notoriously difficult and
dangerous to store, requiring specialized equipment or suitable underground caverns.
And crude oil, which is typically stored in tanks, is between these extremes.
Additionally, agricultural commodities, which can spoil, tend to have a wider distribution
of F/S than more durable commodities such as metals.
Exhibit 1 plots the observed values of F/S for copper (on the vertical axis) against
the level of inventories (on the horizontal axis). Consistent with the previously described
results, when inventories of copper have reached unusually high levels, the futures price
has remained close to the spot price; storage costs for copper do not rise sharply with
inventory levels and the convenience yield of holding copper is depressed by ample
stocks. As inventories get very low (and the convenience yield of having copper on hand
rises), futures prices can lie well below spot prices. Historically, however, futures prices

3

For metals, the London Metals Exchange reports maximum daily warehouse storage rates of roughly
40 cents per ton, which at current commodity prices would amount to roughly 1.6 percent a year for copper,
0.7 percent a year for nickel, and 6.5 percent a year for zinc. (These rates vary somewhat by metal and by
location.) Warehouses can and do offer discounts to preferred customers. Additional charges are
associated with removing the metals from the warehouses, which can be a substantial source of revenue for
the warehouses.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

for copper have not tended to fall below 75 percent of the spot price.
Exhibit 2 shows a similar plot for crude oil. In contrast to copper, when oil
inventories get large, storage capacity constraints begin to bind and the marginal cost of
storage rises, resulting in futures prices lying well above spot prices. At low levels of
inventories, however, the pattern, as expected, is more similar to copper, with futures
prices lying well below spot prices.
To sum up, flat futures profiles for commodities are common when inventories
are within typical ranges. The reason for this is that arbitrage across the futures curve
ensures that spot prices incorporate information about future supply and demand
conditions. When inventories are particularly low or high, however, the costs associated
with arbitraging commodities over time are large, and futures prices can differ markedly
from spot prices.
Forecasting Performance of Futures Prices
In this section, we compare the forecasting performance of futures-based forecasts
with two alternatives: a random walk (where the forecasted value is the current spot
price) and a random walk with drift (where the forecasted value rises in line with recent
experience). We also present results showing that futures-based forecasts tend to
outperform random walk forecasts by the largest margin when the forecasts are most
divergent, that is, when futures prices differ the most from spot prices.
Our accuracy measure is the mean squared error (MSE) of the forecast. Futuresbased forecasts are compared to the alternatives by examining the relative MSE, that is,
the ratio of the MSE for the futures forecast to the MSE of the alternative. When the
relative MSE equals 1, the forecast performance of the two methods is equivalent. When

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

the relative MSE is less than one, futures dominate the alternative, and when it is greater
than one, the alternative dominates futures.
Table 2 reports the relative MSEs for futures versus the random walk for two
forecast horizons (3 months, and a year-ahead4) over two sample periods (1990 to 2010
and 2003 to 2010). As shown in the table, the relative MSEs are generally below 1 for
the full sample, indicating that futures-based forecasts have outperformed a random walk
over this period. For the 2003 to 2010 sample, however, the results are more mixed, with
neither futures nor the random walk clearly dominating.
To shed light on the changing forecasting performance of these methods over
time, Exhibit 3 shows the evolution of relative MSEs over 8-year moving windows for
copper, corn, and crude oil. As the figure makes clear, futures consistently outperformed
the random walk for all three commodities prior to the early 2000s and have continued to
do so for corn. During the latter half of the 2000s, in contrast, a random walk
outperformed futures for copper and oil. Most recently, however, futures and a random
walk look about the same for oil.
The second alternative to a futures-based forecast is a random walk with drift, in
which prices are projected to rise or fall at a rate comparable to that observed in the
recent past. Such an approach would be consistent with arguments that commodity prices
will continue to rise in line with global demand, thus extending recent trends. Table 3
reports relative MSEs for futures-based forecasts versus such a model where the drift
term is assumed to be the average growth rate over the past year. As can be seen in the
table, this model does very poorly when evaluated over the whole sample or just the
observations since 2003.
4

With the year-ahead as defined in Footnote 3.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Although futures do have a better record than a random walk over the entire
sample, the improvement does not appear to be substantial. This result should not be
terribly surprising in light of the discussion in the previous section. The storability of
commodities and the elimination of arbitrage opportunities implies that spot and futures
prices are linked. With modest storage costs and sufficient inventories to keep
convenience yields low, we should expect the futures-based forecasts and random walk
forecasts to be broadly similar.
That being said, there are times, as noted above, when futures prices can differ
markedly from spot prices. When the futures price and the spot price differ, the futures
price should in principle be more informative for forecasting prices relative to a random
walk. Prices will differ when there are temporary factors that result in sharp inventory
builds or declines. In these periods, the futures price should, in theory, look through
these developments and, thus, produce a better forecast.
Exhibit 4 examines this proposition for oil prices. The figure plots the ratio of the
one-year ahead futures price to the spot price. The blue dots denote the times when the
futures-based forecast outperformed the random walk, and the red dots show the times
when the random walk outperformed futures. It is evident that when the crude oil futures
price is materially above the spot price (the upper range of the graph), futures have done
a better job of forecasting prices in the vast majority of the cases.
When the futures price is below the spot price, the evidence is somewhat more
mixed. In the 1990s, the futures price generally did better. However, between 2003 and
2005, the futures price generally did worse as the market mistook the permanent shift in
oil prices for a temporary increase that would soon be reversed. Market participants did

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

not fully appreciate the persistence of the shocks hitting commodity prices and expected
commodity prices to moderate. Thus, in this period, the spot price proved to be a better
predictor than the futures prices.
More systematically, Table 4 reports the relative MSEs for futures versus a
random walk for a range of commodities as a function of the futures-spot relationship.
For crude oil, the relative MSE is close to 1 when futures are within 5 percent of the spot
price (column iii). But when futures are more than 5 percent above spot prices (columns
iv and v), the relative forecasting performance of futures prices rises markedly. Although
the results of this exercise vary considerably across commodities, the overall evidence
suggests that futures are more informative the greater their divergence from spot prices.
Risk Premiums
The previous results suggest that futures prices remain a reasonable guide for
forecasting commodity prices, at least relative to some basic alternatives. However,
futures prices, in principle, could also contain a risk premium that creates a wedge
between the observed futures price and the underlying expected future spot price. If such
a risk premium can be identified in commodity futures prices, then controlling for it when
making forecasts should improve accuracy.
To think about the risk premium, it is useful to consider three classes of futures
market participants. The first class is producers of commodities whose incomes depend
positively on commodity prices and who, therefore, would want to insure against price
declines by selling (i.e. go short) in the futures markets. The second class is users of
commodities whose incomes depend negatively on prices and who, therefore, would want
to insure against price increases by buying (i.e. go long) in the futures markets. The third

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

class is made up of market participants whose incomes neither increase nor decrease
appreciably with commodity prices. This group (who could be defined as speculators)
serves to balance the market by providing the net supply of insurance services to the
other participants; that is, they fill the gap between buyers and sellers in the futures
markets. The risk premium is the compensation given to the speculators to entice them to
participate in these markets.
To illustrate the roles of the first two kinds of market participants, Exhibit 5
reports the net long positions of producers/users as a fraction of open interest for eight
commodities traded on U.S. futures markets. (The available public data only reports this
aggregate category which includes both producers and users.) The following patterns are
clear. For almost all categories, the producers/users are net short. Thus, it seems that the
demand from producers to be insured against falling prices outweighs the demand from
users to be insured against higher prices. For energy commodities, the net long positions
of producers/users are relatively close to zero. Producers/users are almost always net
short for agricultural commodities, but there can be some fairly large swings in the
magnitude of these positions. Given these net short positions, speculators will have to go
net long to balance the market. As such, holding everything else equal, we should expect
the average risk premium to be positive and larger for agricultural commodities than for
oil. By a positive risk premium, we mean that we should expect the futures price to be
less than expected spot price, so that going net long -- that is, contracting to buy
commodities at the futures prices -- is a profitable activity for the speculators. However,

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

we should note that competition amongst speculators should serve to decrease the
profitability of providing insurance to producers.5
To test for risk premiums, we follow the literature in estimating forecast
efficiency regressions,6 which are defined as
St+k -St =  + *( Ft,t+k -St ) + vt
In these regressions, the dependent variable is the error from a random-walk forecast, and
the independent variable is the difference between the forecasted price from futures
markets and that from a random walk. There are four tests of interest: the three
individual tests of whether = 0,  = 0, and  = 1 and the joint test of and .
If and  then futures are an unbiased predictor of the spot price and there is no
identifiable risk premium. If the difference between the estimated constant and zero is
statistically significant, then there is evidence of a constant risk premium. If the
difference between the estimated slope coefficient  and 1 is statistically significant, then
the risk premium varies over time according to the tilt in the futures curve. Additionally,
if the slope coefficient  is significantly different from zero, then futures prices have
explanatory power for the forecast error from a random walk. Thus, this regression
provides an alternative method for comparing random walk and futures-based forecasts.
Table 5 reports the results of these hypothesis tests for the one-year ahead
forecasts over the 1990 to 2010 sample period. Column (i) reports the point estimates of
5

An additional constraint on the risk premium is that commodity producers and users have the alternative
of hedging by adjusting their inventory positions. If a user wants to guarantee his price, then he could buy
the product today and just hold it in inventory. Likewise, if a producer wants to insure the price received,
he could either sell out of existing inventory or else speed up extraction (which, in the near term, may be
more feasible for metals than for agricultural goods). Hence, the cost of using futures to hedge (the risk
premium) should not be much larger than the costs of hedging through physical holdings.
6
As discussed in Chernenko Sergey V., Krista B. Schwarz and Jonathan H. Wright (2004), “The
Information Content of Forward and Futures Prices: Market Expectations and the Price of Risk,”
International Finance Discussion Paper No. 808, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

the intercept term . As indicated by column (ii), for most commodities, we fail to reject
the null hypothesis that at the 95 percent critical value, meaning that there does not
appear to be a constant risk premium that is statistically significant. The point estimates
for the slope coefficient are reported in column (iii). For nearly half of the
commodities, we can reject the hypothesis that the slope coefficient equals 0, suggesting
that there is useful information in the futures. Although we fail to reject for most
commodities the hypothesis that the slope coefficient equals one (column v), the point
estimates can be quite different from one, suggesting that the risk premium varies with
the shape of the futures curve. As reported in the final column of the table, we get four
rejections (zinc, cotton, live cattle and wheat) for the joint hypothesis that and
 suggesting some bias and the presence of a risk premium.
Because the estimated coefficients for many commodities are less than one, it is
possible that forecasting performance could be improved by attenuating the slope of the
futures curve somewhat, which is equivalent to controlling for a variable risk premium.
However, making such corrections in real time is not so simple. We can only estimate
the values of  and  using the data that was available when the forecast would have been
made. In order to allow for structural breaks, the values of  and  were estimated over a
rolling sample of 30 monthly observations. As reported in Table 6, forecasts based on
these real-time estimates do not perform better than the simple, unadjusted futures-based
forecast over the 2003-2010 sample. The reason for this outcome is that the values of 
and  are not stable over time and hence using estimated values results in poor predictors
for subsequent periods. The only exception is a slight improvement for natural gas at the
three-month horizon.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 1 Distribution of the Slope of Futures Relative to Spot Prices (Percent)
F/S
<0.85
(0.85 to 0.95) (0.95 to 1.05)
(1.05 to 1.15)
>1.15
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
(v)
Energy
Crude Oil
16
31
29
19
6
Heating Oil
10
25
39
18
7
Natural Gas
12
16
24
20
28
Metals
Aluminum
0
2
38
58
1
Copper
5
17
45
27
6
Lead
9
18
50
22
0
Nickel
0
11
73
13
0
Tin
6
10
43
41
0
Zinc
12
22
46
20
0
Agricultural
Corn
3
7
23
26
41
Cotton
4
9
28
27
32
Coffee
10
7
30
30
25
Live Cattle
0
2
50
45
2
Soybeans
5
12
46
37
0
Wheat
5
19
19
20
36
Notes: For commodities in the energy category, statistics are calculated for 12-month ahead futures.
For metals, the statistics are for 15-month ahead forwards. For agricultural commodities, the
statistics are for 8-month ahead futures. Samples begin in 1985 or as available.

Page 13 of 23

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 2 : Relative Mean Squared Error of Futures Based Forecasts to Random Walk
Three Months Ahead
A Year Ahead †
Sample
1990-2010
2003-2010
1990-2010 e
2003-2010
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
Energy
Crude Oil
0.94
0.93
0.92
0.98
Heating Oil
0.96
1.01
0.92
1.03
Natural Gas
0.88*
0.92
0.86*
0.94
Metals
Aluminum
1.00
0.99
0.93
0.95
Copper
1.00
1.02
1.08
1.20
Lead
0.98
1.01
1.00
1.05
Nickel
1.00
1.01
1.00
1.05
Tin
1.00
1.00
1.05
1.04
Zinc
0.93
0.96
0.86
0.90
Agricultural
Corn
0.91
0.92
0.77
0.71
Cotton
0.96
1.04
0.97
0.93
Coffee
1.00
0.91
0.93
0.92
Live Cattle
0.75*
0.76*
1.59
1.63
Soybeans
0.88
0.84
0.84
0.81
Wheat
0.98
0.91
1.05
0.93
Notes: †The year ahead forecast is based on the appropriate and available futures contract. For
commodities in the energy category, statistics are calculated for 12-month ahead futures. For
metals, the statistics are for 15-month ahead forwards. For agricultural commodities, the statistics
are for 8-month ahead futures. Samples begin in 1990 or as available.
* Indicates a statistically significant difference based on a Diebold-Mariano test.

Page 14 of 23

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 3 : Relative Mean Squared Error of Futures Based Forecasts to Random Walk With Drift
Three Months Ahead
A Year Ahead†
Sample
1990-2010
2003-2010
1990-2010 e
2003-2010
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
Energy
Crude Oil
0.74*
0.64
0.36*
0.34*
Heating Oil
0.78*
0.72
0.38*
0.39*
Natural Gas
0.69*
0.68*
0.30*
0.35*
Metals
Aluminum
0.74
0.74
0.57
0.63
Copper
0.83
0.86
0.71
0.86
Lead
0.77
0.76
0.58
0.62
Nickel
0.80
0.83
0.43
0.46
Tin
0.85
0.88
0.56
0.55
Zinc
0.77
0.82
0.40
0.39
Agricultural
Corn
0.69*
0.71*
0.41*
0.43*
Cotton
0.78*
0.89
0.49*
0.55
Coffee
0.77*
0.70*
0.56*
0.57
Live Cattle
0.61*
0.63*
0.73
0.74
Soybeans
0.67*
0.63*
0.47*
0.45*
Wheat
0.76*
0.73*
0.63
0.57
Notes: † For commodities in the energy category, statistics are calculated for 12-month ahead
futures. For metals, the statistics are for 15-month ahead forwards. For agricultural commodities,
the statistics are for 8-month ahead futures. Samples begin in 1990 or as available.
* Indicates a statistically significant difference based on a Diebold-Mariano test.

Page 15 of 23

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 4 : Relative Mean Squared Error of Futures Based Forecasts, Conditional On Spread
Value of F/S
Full Sample
< 0.85 (0.85 to 0.95) (0.95 to 1.05) (1.05 to 1.15)
> 1.15
(v)
(vi)
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
Energy
Crude Oil
0.93
1.34
1.01
0.70
0.31
0.92
Heating Oil
0.44
1.37
1.00
0.75
0.51
0.92
Natural Gas
0.57
0.94
1.01
0.99
0.76
0.86
Metals
NA
Aluminum
2.73
1
0.91
0.02
0.93
NA
Copper
1.43
1.05
0.96
0.87
1.08
Lead
1.50
1.04
0.98
0.92
0.73
1
NA
Nickel
0.72
1.21
1.03
0.91
1
NA
Tin
0.03
1.19
1
1
1.05
NA
Zinc
0.42
0.81
0.98
0.76
0.86
Agricultural
Corn
0.10
0.85
0.98
1.16
0.67
0.77
Cotton
0.40
0.71
1.06
1.08
0.97
0.97
Coffee
0.47
0.80
1.02
1.50
0.60
0.93
Live Cattle
NA
0.23
1.10
1.55
5.24
1.59
Soybeans
0.32
1.42
0.94
0.81
NA
0.84
Wheat
0.45
0.87
1.06
1.16
1.29
1.05
Notes: For commodities in the energy category, statistics are calculated for 12-month ahead
futures. For metals, the statistics are for 15-month ahead forwards. For agricultural
commodities, the statistics are for 8-month ahead futures. Samples begin in 1990 or as
available.

Page 16 of 23

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 5: Forecast Efficiency Regressions, One Year Ahead
Slope, 
Intercept,
T-Test
T-Test
Point
Point
Estimate
Estimate
=0
 =0
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
Energy
Crude Oil
0.09
0.94
1.71
3.67
Heating Oil
0.07
1.33
0.93
2.66
Natural Gas
0.01
0.14
0.85
3.21
Metals
Aluminum
-0.02
-0.26
1.19
1.19
Copper
0.08
1.29
0.29
0.35
Lead
0.06
0.81
0.39
0.63
Nickel
0.08
0.88
0.79
1.22
Tin
0.09
1.44
-0.71
-0.66
Zinc
0
-0.02
2.07
3.91
Agricultural
Corn
-0.08
1.14
-2.03
4.49
Cotton
-0.07
0.8
-1.8
3.82
Coffee
0.02
0.24
0.69
2.74
Live Cattle
0.01
1.01
-0.06
-0.22
Soybeans
0.02
0.57
0.93
3.06
Wheat
0.01
0.21
0.39
2.51
Notes: Bold indicates significance at 10 percent level.

Page 17 of 23

T-Test
 =1
(v)

Joint Test
 =0
and  = 1
(vi)

-0.23
-0.19
-0.59

3.16
1.83
0.36

0.19
-0.83
-0.97
-0.33
-1.58
2.02

0.07
2.51
1.06
1.02
3.20
6.10

0.55
-0.95
-1.23
-3.69
-0.22
-3.91

4.16
7.23
1.61
23.77
0.36
16.2

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 6 : Relative Mean Squared Error of Futures Based Forecasts to Risk-Premium-Corrected
Forecasts
Three Months Ahead
A Year Ahead†
Full Sample
2003-2010 Sample
Full Sample
2003-2010 Sample
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
Energy
Crude Oil
0.80
0.80
0.62
0.76
Heating Oil
0.82
0.91
0.61
0.79
Natural Gas
0.78
1.02
0.82
0.90
Metals
Aluminum
0.82
0.80
0.60
0.59
Copper
0.83
0.80
0.49
0.52
Lead
0.84
0.87
0.62
0.70
Nickel
0.64
0.71
0.08
0.64
Tin
0.57
0.48
0.41
0.37
Zinc
0.59
0.65
0.30
0.27
Agricultural
Corn
0.80
0.84
0.81
0.74
Cotton
0.87
0.97
0.95
0.83
Coffee
0.75
0.57
0.54
0.54
Live Cattle
0.83
0.85
0.24
0.24
Soybeans
0.57
0.51
0.58
0.60
Wheat
0.83
0.70
0.84
0.80
Notes: †The year ahead forecast is based on the appropriate and available futures contract. For
commodities in the energy category, statistics are calculated for 12-month ahead futures. For
metals, the statistics are for 15-month ahead forwards. For agricultural commodities, the statistics
are for 8-month ahead futures. Samples begin in 1990 or as available.

Page 18 of 23

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 1

06-14-11

Relationship Between Future/Spot Prices and Inventories for Copper
Future/Spot

1.20
1.15
1.10
1.05
1.00
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.80
0.75

0

100000

200000

300000

400000

500000
600000
Inventory, tons

All data are from the London Metal Exchange. Sample period is 1990-2011.

700000

800000

900000

0.70

1000000

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 2

06-14-11

Relationship Between Future/Spot Prices and Inventories for Oil
Future/Spot

1.60
1.55
1.50
1.45
1.40
1.35
1.30
1.25
1.20
1.15
1.10
1.05
1.00
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.80
0.75

850

900

950

1000
Inventory, millions of barrels

1050

Prices are for WTI crude oil. Inventories are U.S. stocks of crude oil and petroleum products. Sample period is 1990-2011.

1100

0.70

1150

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 3

06-14-11

Relative MSE of Futures Versus Random Walk Forecasts Evaluated Over a Rolling Eight Year Window

1.4
1.3

Copper
1.2
1.1
1.0

Oil
0.9
0.8

Corn

0.7
0.6
0.5

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
End of Eight Year Evaluation Period

2008

2009

2010

For copper and oil, the evaluated forecasts are at the 12-month horizon. For corn, the evaluated forecasts are at the 8-month horizon.

2011

0.4

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 4

06-14-11

Relationship Between Future/Spot Prices and Forecasting Accuracy for Oil
Future/Spot
Ratio of Futures to Spot
Futures Has Smaller MSE than Spot
Futures Has Larger MSE than Spot

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

1.80
1.75
1.70
1.65
1.60
1.55
1.50
1.45
1.40
1.35
1.30
1.25
1.20
1.15
1.10
1.05
1.00
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.80
0.75
0.70
0.65
0.60

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 5

06-14-11

Net Long Futures Positions of Producers/Users
Copper

Corn
Fraction of Open Interest

Weekly

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Fraction of Open Interest
0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8

Natural Gas

2006

2007

2008

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8

2006

2007

2008

2010

2011

2008

2009

2010

2011

Fraction of Open Interest
0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8

Cotton

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8

Sugar
Fraction of Open Interest

2006

2009

0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8

Wheat (CBOT)
Fraction of Open Interest

2007

2011

Fraction of Open Interest

WTI Crude Oil

2006

2010

Soybeans
Fraction of Open Interest

2006

2009

0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Fraction of Open Interest
0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8

Source: Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Commitments of Traders.

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
-0.7
-0.8