View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

David Bowman
Joseph Gruber
June 14, 2011
Revisions to Economic Forecasts and Commodity Prices
Futures prices should, in principle, embody all available information affecting
commodity prices, including developments specific to individual commodities as well as
those influencing the global economy more generally. However, as shown in Exhibit 1,
futures prices typically projected relatively flat prices going forward from 2003 to 2008
even as commodity prices increased steadily, resulting in a string of upward revisions to
the staff’s commodity price forecasts. This process temporarily halted in 2009 as the
financial crisis sharply restrained global economic activity and commodity demand, but
over the past year futures again indicated that commodity prices would remain flat even
as spot prices moved up sharply and world economic growth resumed.
The failure of futures to predict the steady rise in commodity prices over the last
decade has led some to question whether they incorporate available information into an
efficient forecast of future spot prices. The run-up in commodity prices over the last
decade is widely attributed to the acceleration in growth among the emerging market
economies, particularly China and the rest of emerging Asia. Some have argued that, to
the extent that the path of growth in the emerging-market economies (EMEs) was
predictable, one should have expected commodity prices to continue to rise over the last
decade, rather than remain flat. Importantly, however, market participants did not predict
the acceleration in emerging Asian growth. As shown in Exhibit 2, the investment banks
and private forecasters surveyed in the Consensus Forecasts were repeatedly surprised by

Page 1 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

the rate of growth in both China and other Emerging Asia over the period between 2003
and 2008. Mirroring the commodities futures, forecasts of Emerging Asian growth were
either flat or downward sloping over this period and were steadily revised upward.
Further, at the same time that market participants were underestimating potential
commodity demand from the EMEs, forecasts of future supply (Exhibit 3) were steadily
revised downward between 2005 and 2010, providing another potential source of upward
pressure on prices.
This note briefly examines whether these revisions to market participant’s
expectations can explain the run-up in commodity prices. In doing so, we make an
important distinction between expected and unexpected components of economic growth
and commodity supply. If market participant’s forecast revisions (the unexpected
components) drive commodity growth, then futures curves may represent reasonably
efficient predictions, and the staff may only need to consider amending these predictions
to the extent that our own forecasts of economic growth (or future supply) are markedly
different from the market’s forecasts.
We find that revisions to forecasts of economic activity are statistically significant
predictors of price growth for oil and copper, the two individual commodities that we
consider, and also of changes in the IMF index of nonfuel commodity prices. Including
both actual growth and growth forecast revisions in our analysis, we find that forecast
revisions appear to be the more important determinant of the observed changes in
commodity prices over the last decade. We also include changes in the broad nominal
dollar in our analysis, taking these changes as proxies for unexpected movements in
exchange rates (under the assumption that market participants view exchange rates as

Page 2 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

likely to follow a random walk). We find that a depreciation of the broad dollar is
associated with a roughly equal percentage increase in commodity prices, though this
effect is only sometimes statistically significant.
Based on these findings, we propose an alternative forecasting methodology for
commodity prices that adjusts the futures path to reflect the staff’s assessment of the
degree to which market participants will be surprised by future global economic growth
and exchange rate movements. We calculate such surprises as the divergence between
the Tealbook forecast and private forecasts.
We illustrate how this approach could be implemented based on Tealbook and
private forecasts for global growth and the dollar. On average, this alternative approach
does about as well as simply using futures curves over the period between 2003 and 2010
(the period for which we have the requisite data to conduct a comparison), a result that
underscores the point that both the staff and private forecasters were surprised by the rate
of acceleration in emerging market growth over this period. Even so, our alternative
approach may be preferred on the grounds that it generates a forecast of commodity
prices that is explicitly rooted in and internally consistent with the broader contours of the
staff forecast. In addition, as we discuss below, it provides a useful empirical framework
for thinking through how alternative assumptions regarding the evolution of global
activity and exchange rates might affect global commodity prices.

Empirical Results
We examine movements in the spot prices of WTI, copper, and the IMF index of
nonfuel commodity prices. As a proxy for the market’s expectation of economic growth,

Page 3 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

we use surveys of market expectations of GDP growth published by Consensus
Forecasts, which receives forecasts of expected growth in the current year and the
subsequent year for a number of emerging and advanced economies from investment
banks and private forecasters. We construct quarterly measures of expected world
growth using GDP-weighted forecasts for the United States, euro area, Japan, Canada,
United Kingdom, China, India, South Korea, Brazil, and Mexico, which are available
beginning in 2003. As noted in the introduction, we also include changes in the broad
nominal dollar, taking this as a proxy for the market surprise in exchange rates under the
assumption that market participants view exchange rates as a random walk.
Tables 1 - 3 show our initial results. In line with the results of Gruber (“Modeling
Commodity Prices”), the first column of each of these tables shows that there is a
positive, usually statistically significant, relation between commodity prices and world
GDP growth and a negative relation between commodity prices and changes in the broad
dollar over this period. However, as demonstrated in the second column of each table,
the coefficient on actual GDP growth becomes statistically insignificant, and in two cases
takes the wrong sign, once we include our measure of GDP-growth surprises; in contrast,
growth surprises have a positive and generally statistically significant relationship with
each commodity price. The inclusion of GDP surprises rather than actual GDP does not
affect our finding of a negative relationship between the broad dollar and commodity
prices. In most cases we cannot reject that the elasticity between exchange rates and
commodity prices is -1, a value that would be predicted by some theories and which is
consistent with both other empirical work that we have done.

Page 4 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Some recent research has identified a strong empirical relationship between
commodity prices and emerging-market industrial production. In Table 4, we compare
our measure of GDP growth surprises to similarly-constructed measures of IP growth. In
general, world GDP growth surprises appear to perform better than world IP surprises
(for oil and copper, world IP has the wrong sign when both variables are included), but
EME IP growth surprises appear to explain commodity prices better than either of these
world measures over this particular period.1 Given the importance of the emerging
market economies in recent years, and their relatively heavy share of global
manufacturing, this result seems intuitive, although the extent to which it can be
extrapolated to other periods is a legitimate question. For example, Gruber finds little
difference in the impacts of actual advanced and emerging-market activity in his longer
sample.
In Table 5, we include supply measures in our model for WTI prices in addition to
the EME IP surprise variable. We use the U.S. Energy Information Administration’s
forecasts of growth in crude oil production as a proxy for expected supply in our oil price
regressions.2 The results indicate that the supply variables do not seem to help explain
quarterly changes in oil prices. This is surprising, but may be partially explained by the
endogeneity of supply responses – an exogenous upward movement in supply should
cause prices to fall, but at the same time, a rise in prices may be associated with an
increase in supply if producers are able to react within the quarter.
1

In other regressions, not shown here for brevity, we confirm that EME IP surprises are significant even
when actual EME IP or EME GDP (or EME GDP surprises) are included. Moreover, these other variables
are not statistically significant when EME IP surprises are present in these regressions.
2
We are only able to include supply forecasts in our oil price regressions. Copper supply forecasts are only
available on a semiannual basis from 2005, which is not a long-enough sample to include in the
regressions, and since there is no ready aggregation of supply forecasts across commodities, there are no
supply forecasts for the IMF index.

Page 5 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Finally, as a partial check of these results, we have also examined the highfrequency impact of macro announcements relating to Chinese industrial production.
Using Bloomberg surveys of market expectations of Chinese IP and Manufacturing PMI
announcements, we examined the change in oil prices on the days that IP and PMI figures
were released. Examining responses of commodity prices immediately following a
macro release may help better isolate the underlying source of movement. We found
little relation between IP announcements and daily oil-price movements, but this may
reflect that the Chinese government typically releases several other macro indicators at
the same time as its IP release. PMI releases do not have this problem, and although the
sample is short, they corroborate the finding that commodity prices appear to respond to
market surprises (Table 6).
To summarize our results, we find a statistically significant relationship between
economic growth forecast revisions and commodity prices. Our results indicate that it is
not growth as such that moves commodity prices, but changes in growth that were
unexpected by market participants. These results suggest that demand shocks have likely
played an important role in explaining movements in commodity prices over the past
decade, and can help explain the behavior of futures prices during the run-up in
commodity prices between 2003 and 2008. We find less statistical significance for
exchange rate movements, but our results are generally consistent with a negative
relationship between dollar exchange rates and commodity prices. While these results
are suggestive, it should be cautioned that our sample is limited by data availability and
that the economic surprises we study are not able to explain the very rapid increase in oil
prices over the second half of 2007 and first half of 2008.

Page 6 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

An Alternative Forecast Methodology for Commodity Prices
Our empirical results suggest that one might adjust the path implied by futures
curves for expected market surprises regarding economic growth and the exchange rate.
This is consistent with the results reported in Gruber (“Modeling Commodity Prices”)
which found that economic growth and the exchange rate were the two most important
variables in helping to explain (ex-post) movements in commodity prices. While market
surprises are by their nature difficult to predict, we outline a potential alternative
methodology for forecasting commodity prices that would take the staff’s assessment of
likely market surprises into account. Our expectation of market surprises is formed by
comparing the staff’s Tealbook forecast to outside private forecasts, specifically, those
reported by Consensus Forecasts. If the Tealbook forecast for global growth is higher
than private forecasts, then we would expect the market to eventually be surprised to the
upside, and, similarly, if the Tealbook forecast is below private forecasts, we would
expect the market to eventually be surprised on the downside.
In constructing our measure of future market surprises to global growth, we
compare Tealbook and Consensus Forecasts projections for world GDP. This has a basis
in the results presented above, but also is a practical choice; the staff does not currently
produce foreign IP forecasts. However, based on our finding that EME IP growth
surprises may help explain commodity prices, we are also considering methods of
producing foreign IP forecasts for inclusion in the Tealbook and will continue to study
the usefulness of methodologies that incorporate measures of industrial production.

Page 7 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

In line with the analysis above, we include the Tealbook forecast for the broad
nominal dollar in our measure of future market surprises in addition to our projected
world GDP growth surprises under the assumption that market participants expect the
exchange rate to follow a random walk. Table 7 shows the precise estimates we use to
translate our measures of expected market surprises into adjustments to the futures curves
forecasts for WTI prices and the IMF nonfuel commodity index. According to these
parameters, a 1 percent upward surprise to world GDP is associated with a 14.6 percent
rise in the spot price of WTI and an 11.1 percent rise in the IMF nonfuel index.3 We
constrain the exchange rate coefficient to have a unit elasticity, with the implication that a
1 percent depreciation of the dollar should raise commodity prices by 1 percent. Several
of our regressions discussed earlier have exchange rate coefficients that are larger than -1,
but our imposition of a unit elasticity is in line with a large body of empirical research.
We use our forecasts of market surprises to adjust the path of commodity prices
implied by futures curves. If the Tealbook forecast is perfectly in line with the
Consensus Forecasts, then there are no predicted market surprises, and the commodity
price forecast would simply be the path implied by futures. However, to the extent that
the Tealbook forecast differs from the outside forecast, our commodity price forecast
would adjust the futures path to incorporate our expectation that market participants will
be surprised by economic activity or exchange rate movements. Exhibit 4 shows the
adjustment (the dashed line labeled “adjusted forecast”) that this alternative methodology
would make to the current projection for non-fuel commodity and oil prices in the June

3

These parameter values accord well with our views on short-run price elasticities of demand. For
example, we view the short-run price elasticity of demand for oil to be in the range of -0.05 to -0.1. With
unchanged supply, an upward shock to underlying oil demand of 1 percent would translate into 10 to 20
percent increase in price.

Page 8 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Tealbook. It also shows a range of price paths (the dotted lines) that might prevail under
different assumptions regarding how much market participants will be surprised by the
evolution of global activity and the dollar.
One of the primary benefits of this alternative approach is that it generates a
forecast of commodity prices that is explicitly rooted in and internally consistent with the
broader contours of the staff forecast. As such, it can provide a useful empirical
framework for thinking through how alternative assumptions regarding the evolution of
global activity and exchange rates might affect global commodity prices. Exercises such
as those shown in Exhibit 4 may allow the staff to better assess the risks to our forecast.
Exhibits 5 and 6 demonstrate how this methodology would have worked at
several different points over the last decade in forecasting WTI and the IMF nonfuel
commodity price index. During periods in 2010, the staff’s forecast for world GDP was
above the Consensus Forecast, which would have led us to revise our commodity price
forecast above the futures path. In early 2009, the staff predicted a much sharper
contraction in world growth than Consensus Forecasts, which would have led us to mark
down our commodity price forecast below the path implied by futures curves. In most
other periods, the revision to the futures curve would have been fairly modest. Table 8
presents standard forecast evaluation statistics for the futures-based Tealbook forecast
and an alternative forecast based on the adjusted futures methodology we have described
over the 61 Tealbook forecasts from August 2002 to the January 2010. On average, this
alternative approach does about as well as simply using futures curves, a result that

Page 9 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

highlights the point that both the staff and private forecasters were surprised by the rate
of acceleration in emerging market growth over this period.

Conclusion
We have provided evidence that commodity prices have reacted primarily to
unexpected revisions to the outlook for world growth over the last decade. These results
suggest the possibility of adjusting our commodity price forecast for our expectation of
market surprises, contingent on the Tealbook forecast of world growth and exchange
rates being correct. On average, this alternative approach would have had only modest
impacts on our commodity forecast in recent years, because both staff and outside
forecasters were surprised by the rate of acceleration in the emerging markets between
2003 and 2008. However, apart from any impact on forecast accuracy, one advantage of
the alternative approach we propose is that our commodity price forecast would be tied to
the staff outlooks for global activity and exchange rates rather than being based solely on
an exogenous, market-determined projection.

Page 10 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 1: Explaining Changes in Oil Prices
(1)

(2)

Constant
Broad Dollar
World GDP
World GDP Surprise

0.7
-2.4*
1.3

5.3
-2.4*
-0.2
14.3

R^2
AR 1-3 test:
ARCH 1-3 test:

0.25
1.08
1.63

(3)


-3.0***
7.4

0.26
0.98
1.39

0.94
1.18

Dependent variable: Quarterly percent change in the spot price of WTI. Estimation from 2003
Q1 – 2010 Q4. * Indicates statistical significance at the 10 % level, *** at the 1% level.

Table 2: Explaining Changes in the IMF Non-Fuel Commodity Price Index
(1)
Constant
Broad Dollar
World GDP
World GDP Surprise
R^2
AR 1-3 test:
ARCH 1-3 test:

(2)

-1.8
-0.4
1.7***

2.2

-0.4
0.4

12.1*

11.4***


0.57
1.65
1.10

0.18
0.43

0.52
1.06
0.73

(3)


-0.9**


Dependent variable: Quarterly percent change in the IMF nonfuel commodity price index.
Estimation from 2003 Q1 – 2010 Q4. * Indicates statistical significance at the 10 % level, ** at
the 5% level, *** at the 1% level.

Table 3: Explaining Changes in Copper Prices
(1)

(2)

Constant
Broad Dollar
World GDP
World GDP Surprise

0.4
-2.1*
2.2*

13.1**
-2.1**
-2.0
38.8***

R^2
AR 1-3 test:
ARCH 1-3 test:

0.38
0.73
0.80

0.49
0.78
0.52

(3)

-2.9***
16.6*

0.30
0.22

Dependent variable: Quarterly percent change in the COMEX spot price of copper. Estimation
from 2003 Q1 – 2010 Q4. * Indicates statistical significance at the 10 % level, ** at the 5% level,
*** at the 1% level.

Page 11 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 4. GDP Versus Industrial Production
IMF Nonfuel Index

WTI

Copper

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Constant
Broad Dollar
World GDP Surprise
World IP Surprise
EME IP Surprise

4.4
-2.4*
26.1
-5.1

0.9
-1.4
-20.6

3.5***
-0.4
10.6
1.7

2.4**
-0.2
6.7

7.5***
-1.9*
30.4
-2.0

5.7**
-1.3
8.0

R^2
AR 1-3 test:
ARCH 1-3 test:

0.27
0.94
1.39

20.7***
0.44
1.08
0.94

5.3**
0.57
2.4*
1.11

0.63
1.75
0.18

10.6*
0.47
0.75
0.73

0.52
0.48
0.63

Dependent variables: Quarterly percent change in spot price of WTI (columns 1 and 2), the IMF nonfuel commodity index (columns 3 and 4),
and the COMEX spot price of copper (columns 5 and 6).Estimation from 2003 Q1 – 2010 Q4. * Indicates statistical significance at the 10 %
level, ** at the 5% level, *** at the 1% level.

Table 5. Supply Versus Demand in Explaining WTI
(1)

Constant
Broad Dollar
EME IP Surprise
Crude Production
Crude Production Surprise
R^2
AR 1-3 test:
ARCH 1-3 test:

4.1
-1.4
13.6**
-5.0
2.3
0.43
0.27
0.27

Dependent variable: Quarterly percent change in the spot price
of WTI. Estimation from 2003 Q1 – 2010 Q4. ** Indicates
statistical significance at the 5% level.

Page 12 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017

Table 6: Response of WTI to Chinese PMI Announcements
(1)

Constant
PMI
PMI Surprise

-0.07
-0.05
0.92*

R^2
AR 1-2 test
ARCH 1-1 test

0.04
1.80
13.64**

Dependent variable: Daily percent change in the spot price of WTI on days when monthly
figures for Chinese PMI are announced. Estimation sample Sept 2009 to present.
* Indicates statistical significance at the 10 % level, ** at the 5% level

Table 7: Commodity Prices and World GDP Surprises Index
IMF Nonfuel
Index

WTI
World GDP Surprise
t-statistic

14.6
1.63

11.1***
3.56

Broad Dollar
t-statistic

-1.0
---

-1.0
---

AR 1-3 test
ARCH 1-3 test

0.16
0.61

0.28
0.66

Regression constrained so that coeficient on the broad dollar is -1. Dependent
variables: Quarterly percentage change in WTI and the IMF non-fuel commodity
index. Estimation from 2003 Q1 – 2010 Q4.
*** Indicates statistical significance at the 1 % level.

Page 13 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Table 8:  Comparison of Alternative Model to Futures‐based Forecast ‐ Four Quarter Percent Changes
Sample:  61 Tealbook forecasts from August 2002 to January 2010
Mean Error
IMF Non‐Fuel Index
1
Tealbook Forecast
12.6
2
Alternative Methodology
14.4

Root Mean Square Error
21.3
23.4

WTI Oil
3
4

Tealbook Forecast
Alternative Methodology

Page 14 of 19

20.2
22.8

40.3
42.7

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 1


WTI Futures Curves
	

Dollars per barrel

120
	

100


80


60


40


20


2004

Source: Bloomberg.


2006
	

2008

2010

2012

2014
	

Copper Futures Curves

2016
	

Dollars per pound

0

5
	

4


3


2


1


2004

Source: Bloomberg.

2006

2008

2010

Page 15 of 19

2012

2014
	

2016
	

0

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 2


Chinese Consensus IP Forecasts

2004

Source: Consensus Economics.

2006

Percent change over previous year

2008

2010

2012

EME Asia ex China IP Forecasts

2004

Source: Consensus Economics.

2006

2014

2016

Percent change over previous year

2008

2010

Page 16 of 19

2012

2014

2016

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 3


Department of Energy Forecasts of World Oil Production

2004

Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration.

2006

2008

Millions of barrels per day

2010

Copper Production Forecasts

2004

Source: International Copper Study Group.

2012

Percent change

2006

2008

Page 17 of 19

2010

2012

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 4
	

Forecasts of Prices of Non-Fuel Commodities
Index, 2005 = 100

Index, 2005 = 100

Forecasts of Oil Prices
Dollars per barrel

2010

2011

2012

Dollars per barrel

2010

Page 18 of 19

2011

2012

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 03/31/2017
Exhibit 5
	

IMF Non-Fuel Commodity Index

2002

Index, 2005=100

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012
	

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012
	

WTI Oil

2002

Page 19 of 19