View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in
the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
in Washington, D.C., on Tuesday, June 18, 1968, at 9:30 a.m.

PRESENT:

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Martin, Chairman
Brimmer
Daane
Galusha
Hickman
Kimbrel
Maisel
Mitchell
Robertson
Sherrill
Bopp, Alternate for Mr. Ellis
Treiber, Alternate for Mr. Hayes

Messrs. Clay, Coldwell, and Scanlon, Alternate
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Heflin, Francis, and Swan, Presidents
of the Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond,
St. Louis, and San Francisco, respectively
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Sherman, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Broida, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Molony, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Brill, Economist
Messrs. Axilrod, Hersey, Kareken, Link,
Mann, Partee, Reynolds, Solomon, and
Taylor, Associate Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market
Account
Mr. Coombs, Special Manager, System Open
Market Account
Mr. Williams, Adviser, Division of Research
and Statistics, Board of Governors
Mr. Wernick, Associate Adviser, Division
of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors

-2

6/18/68

Mr. Keir, Assistant Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Miss Eaton, General Assistant, Office of
the Secretary, Board of Governors
Mr. Latham, First Vice President, Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston
Messrs. Eisenmenger, Eastburn, Parthemos,
Baughman, Andersen, Tow, Green, and
Craven, Vice Presidents of the Federal

Reserve Banks of Boston, Philadelphia,
Richmond, Chicago, St. Louis, Kansas
City, Dallas, and San Francisco,
respectively
Mr. Geng, Assistant Vice President, Federal
Reserve Bank of New York
By unanimous vote, the minutes of
actions taken at the meeting of the

Federal Open Market Committee held on
May 28, 1968, were approved.
The memorandum of discussion for
the meeting of the Federal Open Market
Committee held on May 28, 1968, was
accepted.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of the
System Open Market Account on foreign exchange market conditions
and on Open Market Account and Treasury operations in foreign
currencies for the period May 28 through June 12, 1968, and a
supplemental report covering the period June 13 through 17, 1968.

Copies of these reports have been placed in the files of the
Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Coombs said
that the Treasury gold stock would remain unchanged this week.

6/18/68

-3

For value today, the Bank of France was selling $220 million of
gold to the Stabilization Fund, while simultaneously selling a
total of $180 million to Germany, Italy, and Switzerland.

The

Treasury had initially taken the position that it would be
prepared to pay $35 flat for French gold delivered in New York or
London.

For gold delivered in Paris, however, where much of the

French gold stock was concentrated, the Treasury had specified a
price of $35 minus shipping costs to New York, or a net of roughly
$34.93.

Since the German Federal Bank and other European central

banks would clearly have been prepared to pay the full price for
gold delivered in Paris, that approach threatened to deprive the
United States of an opportunity to get back some of the gold it
had sold to France.

Subsequently, however, arrangements had been

made to swap gold located in Paris for gold located in New York
without charge to the United States, thus enabling the United
States to quote the full $35 price to the Bank of France for a
very sizable amount of gold.

Also, the Netherlands Bank was

selling $30 million of gold to this country tomorrow.

As a

result, for the first time since the spring of 1961 the Stabiliza
tion Fund would have a substantial amount of gold on hand.

For a

time, at least, that should enable the United States to stave off
the threat of a decline in the Treasury gold stock below the
critical $10 billion level.

-4

6/18/68

Mr. Coombs went on to say that the price of gold on the
London market had fluctuated between $40 and a figure somewhat
above $42. South Africa was still receiving large-scale capital
inflows and consequently was under no pressure to resume sales of
gold in the free market.

At the recent meeting of the Bank for

International Settlements, he and Mr. Hayes were visited by
Governor de Jongh of the South African Reserve Bank, and he
(Mr. Coombs) got the distinct impression that the Governor's main
concern at the moment was the threatened buildup of inflationary
pressure as a result of the heavy influx of foreign capital.

The

South African Reserve Bank was currently financing gold production
at an annual rate of $1 billion, a large figure for a country of
that size.

Obviously, if that situation were to continue for long,

major fiscal and monetary problems would arise.

At the same time,

the South African Government and Reserve Bank were clearly being
pressed hard by the gold mining companies to come to some sort of a
satisfactory arrangement regarding the marketing of gold, so as to
give the gold-producing companies some basis for future investment
planning.

So far as he knew, Governor de Jongh's conversations

with the European central bankers had not resulted in any promises
of special deals.

It seemed clear, however, that the European

central bankers had been growing increasingly restive over their
undertaking not to deal directly with South Africa.

Now that a

6/18/68

-5

number of them were receiving large amounts of gold from France-

and also from the International Monetary Fund, in connection with
the British drawing--their restiveness might be lessened, and it
might be possible to maintain the arrangement not to buy gold from
South Africa for some time to come.
Both the gold and foreign exchange markets continued to be
characterized by pervasive uncertainty, Mr. Coombs observed.

There

were welcome indications, however, that the dollar had improved
its relative standing--mainly owing, he thought, to political
unsettlement in Europe.

Such unsettlement, particularly in France,

could represent a watershed in the exchange markets.

One of the

most striking aspects of the developments in those markets during
the past few months had been the relatively small influx of dollars
into the European central banks--despite the fact that during that
period the United States had been running a heavy deficit, as had
the British and, more recently, the French.

The only important

drawing the System had had to make under its swap lines had been
one of $75 million on the Swiss National Bank. That suggested that
the bulk of the dollars being poured out by the United States,
Britain, and France had ended up in private hands, for placement
either in the Euro-dollar market at unusually attractive rates, in
overseas issues of convertible debentures by U.S. firms, or in the
New York stock market.

If the Congressional vote on the fiscal

-6

6/18/68

package scheduled for Thursday, June 20, was affirmative, he would
hope that the favorable trends for the dollar would gain further
momentum.
Nevertheless, Mr. Coombs remarked, the international
financial structure remained extremely fragile.

Two days after

the last Committee meeting--that is, on Memorial Day--a moment of
extreme danger had been passed.

On the preceding day General

de Gaulle had disappeared from Paris, and there were widespread
reports that he had decided to resign.

Those rumors were given

further credence on Thursday when, with the New York market closed
for the holiday, the .Bank of France suspended intervention through
the BIS and allowed the franc to slip below the floor.

Heavy

selling of sterling immediately followed and nearly $100 million
flowed into Switzerland.

At that point, he thought, the fate of

the entire international financial system had hung in balance.
Later that day, however, General de Gaulle succeeded in rallying his
forces, and since then the threat to the international financial
system posed by the French crisis had been gradually subsiding.
Despite the improvement in the atmosphere, Mr. Coombs
continued, the franc had been subject to continuing heavy pressure.
The Bank of France had suffered reserves losses over the past month
that now amounted to $1.1 billion; during the past week alone, it
had lost $500 million.

To meet those losses, the Bank of France

6/18/68

-7

had had on hand $700 or $800 million when the trouble had started
and it subsequently had drawn $885 million from the International
Monetary Fund as well as the $100 million available under its swap
line with the System.

The French Government apparently intended

to meet further pressures by gold sales, which had so far amounted
to $492 million.

At the latest BIS meeting in Basle, Bank of

France officials had been unusually pessimistic about the outlook.
The fact that they were taking care to stay well supplied with
dollars reflected their concern over the risk of sudden large
outflows.
With respect to credits under the System's swap network,
Mr. Coombs said that recent developments--including the large
British and French drawings on the Fund--were having substantial
effects on both sides of the ledger.

As of June 4, the System's

outstanding drawings totaled $903 million--a large figure but only
half the peak of $1.8 billion reached last December.

He thought

that as a result of acquisitions of currencies in transactions
connected with the British and French Fund drawings, it would be
possible to pay down the System's swap debts within a few days to
a total of about $265 million.

Discussions currently were under

way with the Swiss and Italian authorities about means for funding
the remaining System drawings on the central banks of those
countries, and he hoped it would be possible to clear them up
completely by early July.

-8

6/18/68

On the other side of the ledger, Mr. Coombs continued,
foreign central bank debt to the Federal Reserve had risen to
$1.6 billion.

The Bank of England's share of that total, which

was $1.2 billion, would be completely paid off tomorrow by use of
$800 million of the proceeds of Britain's drawing on the Fund,
supplemented by $400 million acquired through the sale of
guaranteed sterling to the System and the U.S. Treasury.

The Bank

of England was planning to apply about $340 million of the $1.4
billion Fund drawing to pay down debts to European central banks,
retaining the remaining $260 million for current requirements.
Governor Rasminsky of the Bank of Canada recently had advised
that he was hopeful of repaying $100 million of the $250 million
Canadian drawing shortly, and of clearing up the balance before
the July 31 maturity.

One unusual feature of the recent period, Mr. Coombs
observed, was the fact that three European central banks had

drawn on their swap lines with the Federal Reserve for the first
time.

Of these, the first was the Bank of France, which on June 5

drew the full $100 million available.

The French had been in a

difficult position at the time of their drawing owing to the strike
at the Bank of France and uncertainty as to the value date of the
French drawing on the Fund.

Secondly, on June 6 the National Bank

of Denmark had drawn $25 million to replenish an already low cash

6/18/68

-9

position that had been reduced further by the need to provide
dollars in connection with the conversion of the Danish krone
portion of France's drawing on the Fund.

Finally, the Netherlands

Bank had drawn about $25 million on June 7, to deal with a situation
similar to that of the Danes.

Yesterday the Netherlands Bank drew

a further $30 million and--significantly--chose to accompany the
drawing with the sale of gold to the United States that he had
mentioned earlier.
Mr. Daane asked whether any thought had been given to an
increase in the System's swap line with the Bank of France.
Mr. Coombs said that in his judgment such an increase would
be useful.

While the French gold sales had been helpful to the

United States, in the long run it would be more helpful to have
the Bank of France as a full-fledged partner in the swap network.
No doubt the French position would move into surplus again at some
point in the future, and it would be far better if any associated
pressures on the dollar then could be accommodated by swap drawings
rather than by U.S. gold sales.
Mr. Robertson asked whether it would not be better if the
initiative with respect to a possible increase in the swap line
were taken by the Bank of France rather than the Federal Reserve.
Mr. Coombs replied that if the experience in connection
with increases in other System swap lines was a guide neither side

6/18/68

-10

was likely to take a clear-cut initiative in the matter.

Typically,

the possibility of an increase in a particular swap line was first
broached informally, and often in discussions with third parties,
to avoid the risk that a direct proposal might be rebuffed.

He

had no specific indication as yet that the French were interested
in increasing their line with the System, but officials of the
central banks of other Common Market countries might be encouraging
the French in that regard and some had suggested to him that an
increase might well be useful at some point in the future.

In his

judgment, in conversations with third parties it was better to
leave the door open rather than to refuse to discuss the matter
while awaiting a direct proposal.
Mr. Mitchell questioned the relevance of past practice to
the present situation.

In light of the sensitive state of relations

with the French, he thought it would be desirable for the Special
Manager, in effect, to shrug his shoulders in response to any
approaches by third parties regarding an increase in the swap line
with the Bank of France.

The Committee could, of course, authorize

the Special Manager to enter into discussions, but he (Mr. Mitchell)
personally would prefer to let some time elapse before an increase
in the French swap line was considered.

In recent years the French

had attempted to undermine the whole framework of international
financial cooperation, and he was dubious about the possibilities

-11

6/18/68

for good-faith negotiations with them until there was evidence of
a change in their attitude.
Mr. Coombs replied that some time would undoubtedly elapse
in any case.

He added that the System's position all along had

been that it would welcome increases in the swap line with the
Bank of France, paralleling those made in other lines; the
resistance to such increases had been entirely on the French side.
At this point, a refusal to discuss the matter at all pending a
formal proposal from the Bank of France undoubtedly would be
interpreted as implying that the System's position had changed.
It was highly important, he thought, not to appear to be taking
advantage of France's current difficulties, but rather to make it
clear that the door remained open to them.

The System had main

tained its swap line with the Bank of France for a long period
during which it had been completely inactive, in the belief that
it represented a possible bridge to a future time in which France
would adopt a more cooperative attitude.
Mr. Daane agreed with Mr. Mitchell that it would be
undesirable for the System to take an immediate initiative in
the matter.

At the same time, it was important to recognize that

the Bank of France had been sympathetic all along with the Federal
Reserve's objectives in developing the swap network.

If at some

point they were to suggest an interest in increasing the swap line
he would not want to have the System adopt a negative attitude.

-12

6/18/68

Mr. Coombs remarked that the initial soundings on the
matter might be made through France's partners in the Common
Market rather than directly, and he would not recommend that they
be rebuffed.
Mr. Robertson said that he and, he thought, Mr. Mitchell
were not proposing a rebuff when they suggested that the initiative
should be taken by the French.

He suspected that there was not a

great deal of difference between their view and that of Mr. Coombs.
Mr. Hickman commented that in his judgment there was a
significant difference between responding to soundings by third
parties with a shrug of the shoulders, on the one hand, and
offering indications of possible System interest on the other.
He would favor the latter course.
Chairman Martin asked whether the members would agree that
the System should be sympathetic but not aggressive in the matter
of a possible increase in the swap line with the Bank of France.
No disagreement was expressed with the Chairman's statement.
By unanimous vote, the System
open market transactions in foreign
currencies during the period May 28
through June 17, 1968, were approved,
ratified, and confirmed.
Chairman Martin then suggested that Mr. Coombs present
his recommendations.
Mr. Coombs said he would begin by reviewing recent
developments in connection with sterling.

Earlier selling pressure

6/18/68

-13

stimulated by the French crisis had given way to moderate short
covering on the basis of news reports that progress had been made
at the June BIS meeting towards a new credit package designed to
deal with the sterling balances.

The announcement expected

tomorrow that the Bank of England's $2 billion swap line with the
Federal Reserve had been fully cleared should have a useful effect.
Unfortunately, however, the British trade figures for May released
this morning were as poor as those for April, and the balance of
payments figures for the first quarter to be released later today
would make very bad reading.

Furthermore, the new strike threats

in strategic areas of the British economy that were again appear
ing, and the generally increasing restiveness of the trade unions,
were likely to have adverse effects on the exchange market.
At the preceding Committee meeting, Mr. Coombs recalled,
there had been some discussion regarding the tenability of the
present $2.40 parity for sterling.

Having indicated in his

memorandum to the Committee of May 20, 1968, that he was beginning
to have increasing doubts on that score, he would like to explain
some of the things he had in mind.

First of all, it was reasonably

clear that so far as exports were concerned the present parity
should be more tenable than it was last November for the obvious
reason that British exporters had received a competitive edge,
after allowance for increased import costs, of roughly 7 per cent
as a result of the November devaluation.

British exports had

6/18/68

-14

responded well and should prove buoyant as the year progressed.
There was no argument on that score.
In Mr. Coombs' judgment the first main area of doubt
regarding the tenability of the present parity lay on the import
side, where devaluation had not succeeded in restraining imports.
In that area, everything depended on the Government's ability to
hold the wage line and to resist pressures for premature reflation.
Last year, they had caved in under such pressures and, against the
background of heavy Labor party losses in municipal and by-elec
tions, the market's judgment was that there was a major risk that
the Government would again fail to hold the line.

Obviously, that

was a value judgment, but it was one which he shared, together
with a number of European central bank officials.
Continuing, Mr. Coombs said the second major threat to the
tenability of the present parity lay in the capital position of the
United Kingdom.

Before devaluation, a number of people around

this table had feared that devaluation would do more damage on
the capital side than could be overcome by improvement on the
trade side, and so far that apprehension had proved more than
justified.

To help clarify just where the British stood on

capital account, he would like to give the Committee a few
figures:
1. As a result of its recent $1.4 billion drawing,
Britain's debt to the Fund now amounted to $3.0 billion.

-15

6/18/68
2.

Although the Bank of England was clearing up its swap

line with the System, it still owed $550 million in swap debt to
the U.S. Treasury.

Adding the $387 million of guaranteed sterling

held on Treasury account and the $292 million of such sterling
held on Federal Reserve account, total British debt to U.S.
monetary authorities was over $1.2 billion.

He thought there

was relatively little hope that that debt would be paid as a
result of a reversal of the flow of funds.
3.

Under the so-called sterling balance credit package

negotiated in June 1966, British debt to the BIS and various
European central banks amounted to $600 million.

The British

were proposing to refund that debt into a new obligation repayable
over several years' time.
4.

As he had mentioned earlier, the Bank of England was

devoting only $340 million of the recent drawing on the Fund to
repayment of its short-term debt to various European and other
central banks.

That would leave an outstanding balance of $700

million with a scheduled maturity date of September 1968.

In

addition, the British were indebted to the BIS on short-term gold
swaps in the amount of $350 million, for a total of $1,050 million.
5.

The Bank of England had roughly $1 billion still

outstanding in market forward contracts maturing between now and
next October.

-16

6/18/68
6.

British Government debt to Swiss commercial banks in

the amount of $130 million would mature next November.
7.

British Government borrowings of $250 million from the

U.S. Treasury and various European central banks in November 1967
to finance a repayment to the International Monetary Fund would
be amortized over a twelve-month period beginning this month.
8.

The British Government currently owed $4.4 billion to

the U.S. and Canadian Governments under the loan agreements of
1946.
The sum total of such debt amounted to $11.6 billion,
Mr. Coombs noted.

If the $4 billion of sterling balances held by

central banks of the overseas sterling area, which were now in
process of liquidation, were included, the total would be $15.6
billion.

He had left out of account the window-dressing credits

received over the end of each month by the Bank of England from
the U.S. Treasury, the latest of which was for $750 million, as
well as further overnight credits from other sources.
To him, Mr. Coombs said, those figures implied that the
British Government was now in a hopelessly bankrupt position;
they had virtually no prospect of ever being able to repay all
of their accumulated debt.

The main question, rather, was whether

reasonably orderly procedures could be devised to deal with that
massive debt structure in a way that would do minimum damage to

6/18/68

-17

the functioning of the international monetary system.

There was,

for example, the question of what precedence should be given to

Britain's various creditors.

At present the Federal Reserve clearly

had secured a highly favorable position; of the entire $15.6 billion
debt, only about $300 million--in the form of Federal Reserve
holdings of guaranteed sterling--was to the System.
position was unlikely to last very long, however.

That favored

The British had

heavy debt payments falling due between now and year-end, and unless
their external accounts should suddenly shift into heavy surplus,
which was improbable, they were likely to draw on the swap line to
meet those payments.
debt repayment

According to his estimates, their scheduled

between now and year-end, together with further

runoffs of sterling balances and of forward contracts, would total
roughly $2.4 billion. That estimated figure was comprised of the
following:

(1) short-term debt to central banks and the BIS,

$1,050 million; (2) debt to Swiss commercial banks, $130 million;
(3) scheduled repayments to the Fund, $200 million; (4) amortization
of the November 1967 credits to finance a Fund repayment, $125
million; (5) year-end debt payments to U.S. and Canada, $220
million; (6) estimated attrition on forward contracts, $350 million;
and (7) estimated attrition of sterling balances, $350 million.
It thus seemed to Mr. Coombs that there was a considerable
prospect of massive British drawings on the swap line between now

6/18/68

-18

and year-end for the purpose of repaying other creditors, quite
aside from financing whatever balance of payments deficits the
U.K. might suffer.

If the full $2 billion available were to be

drawn, total Federal Reserve and Treasury credits to the Bank of
England would rise to over $3 billion, about $500 million more
than the British Government had received during the entire four
years of the Marshall Plan.
Mr. Coombs said he understood the views of the Committee
with respect to the automaticity of the swap line.

It seemed to

him, however, that the Committee was now confronted with a much
broader situation in which certain joint understandings should be
reached by the United Kingdom and its major creditors in the
interest of an equitable settlement.

He would suggest that an

approach be made to both the British Government and the Bank of
England along the following lines:
1.

Extension to 1969 of Britain's short-term debts to

European central banks and the BIS would be a useful and equitable
counterpart to the $1.2 billion of more or less frozen debt owed
to the U.S. Treasury and Federal Reserve, and anything the Bank
of England or the British Government could do to obtain such an
extension would be helpful.
2.

The British Government should be strongly encouraged

to make some really meaningful concessions, in the form of a dollar

-19

6/18/68

guarantee, to official holders of sterling.

At the May meeting

of the BIS in Amsterdam the British had refused to consider such
concessions but there were subsequent indications that they were
becoming more flexible.

At the June meeting in Basle, the Bank of

England had put forward a proposal under which the main burden of
financing further liquidation of the sterling balances would be
thrust upon the U.S. Government and foreign central banks in the
form of a $2 billion, seven-year credit package.

Contrary to the

press reports, that British proposal had received an unfavorable
reception from the central bankers at Basle.

The latter urged the

Bank of England instead to offer a broad guarantee to official
holders of sterling balances in return for an undertaking by the
sterling area countries to limit their conversions of sterling to
actual balance of payments needs.

The British had promised to

come up with a new proposal in time for the July BIS meeting.

If

agreement, at least in principle, could not be reached at that
time, there was a risk that liquidation of the sterling balances
would accelerate.
3.

The Bank of England was continuing to allow sizable

discounts on forward sterling to develop, thus frustrating any
inflow of funds from the Euro-dollar market into London and
encouraging a runoff of maturing forward contracts.

By refusing

to intervene in the forward market the British in effect were

-20

6/18/68

discarding a major source of short-term financing from the market
which other countries, notably the United States, Canada, and
Italy, had not hesitated to draw upon.

To some extent the British

reluctance to try to pull in short-term money from the Euro-dollar
market might reflect a judgment that the competitive pull of U.S.
bank bids for Euro-dollar deposits had been so strong as to leave
little room for British takings.

But if passage next Thursday of

the tax bill were to bring about a major change in U.S. credit
conditions and a much reduced recourse by U.S. banks to the
Euro-dollar market, useful opportunities might open up for the
British to attract Euro-dollar money into London.

In any event,

a return by the Bank of England to the forward market would help
considerably to disprove current market judgments that the Bank
of England itself did not have sufficient faith in the tenability
of the $2.40 parity to operate in the forward market on a large
scale.
In conclusion, Mr. Coombs said that if all three of those
steps were taken--deferment wherever possible of British debt
maturing between now and the year-end, development of a guarantee
scheme for the sterling area countries, and resumption of strong
Bank of England intervention in the forward market--there might
be some hope that the British could, somehow or other, squeeze
through the rest of the year.

If the steps were not taken, the

prospect was bleak indeed--and not only for the British.

6/18/68

-21
Chairman Martin suggested that the Committee plan on

holding a full discussion of the sterling situation at its next
meeting, by which time the July meeting of the BIS would have been
held.

In the interim the members would have the opportunity to

give careful thought to the comments Mr. Coombs had made today.
The Chairman then noted that Mr. Maisel had just returned
from a European trip and invited him to comment.
Mr. Maisel observed that he had spent a good deal of time
in London discussing the sterling situation.

While he had been

exposed to substantially the same set of facts as Mr. Coombs, his
interpretation of those facts was somewhat different from the
latter's.
There was general agreement among the ten or fifteen
experts from banks, the government, and the universities with
whom he had talked, Mr. Maisel said, that the outlook for Britain's
current account would depend primarily on the course of imports,
as Mr. Coombs had suggested.

The majority, however, were more

optimistic than Mr. Coombs; they were of the view that the recent
high level of imports was a temporary phenomenon.

Exports would

now grow faster than imports and as a result the current account
would be moving into balance and then into surplus in coming
months.

If that judgment was correct the critical area for

Britain was that of their capital accounts and particularly that
of the overseas sterling balances.

-22

6/18/68

Secondly, Mr. Maisel continued, the view appeared to be
widely held in London that the government would fall if any change
was made in the present $2.40 parity for sterling.

Thus, while

there might be some question of the government's ability to hold
the rate, there was little question that it would take all measures
in its power in the effort to do so.
Mr. Maisel agreed that the three steps Mr. Coombs had
suggested that the British should be encouraged to take were
critical, although he (Mr. Maisel) would have placed the stress
somewhat differently.

From his conversations with European central

bankers he gathered that they would be willing, if not particularly
happy, to help underwrite the over-hang of sterling balances if
Britain took some measures (particularly by granting exchange value
guarantees) to deal with them.

It was their view, on the basis of

the experience when sterling was devalued last November, that the
dangers that would be posed for the whole international monetary
system if there were another sterling crisis outweighed the risks
to them of sharing some of Britain's current illiquidity.

While

they would not be happy to risk holding frozen sterling, they felt
it necessary to take such a risk in order to attempt to avoid the
danger of sterling's collapsing and pulling with it the entire
international monetary structure.
As to possible forward operations by the Bank of England,
Mr. Maisel continued, both in London and Brussels he had encountered

-23

6/18/68

the view that the pressure on sterling through the Euro-dollar
market was as much one of availability of funds as of price.
Great emphasis was placed on the willingness of U.S. banks to
acquire Euro-dollars even at considerable price differentials.
As a result granting cover would not solve the problem.

In any

case, Bank of England officials thought that renewed intervention
in the forward market would be interpreted by traders as a sign
of weakness and thus might damage confidence and do more harm than
good.
Mr. Coombs then said he had one further recommendation,
relating to a System drawing of $175 million on the Bank of Italy
that would mature on July 26, 1968.

The System had had drawings

outstanding on that swap line since September 19, 1967, so that if
the drawing in question was renewed for a further period of three
months and not repaid before maturity the line would be in active
use for more than one year.
if necessary.

He recommended renewal of the drawing

However, he hoped it would not be necessary; as he

had indicated earlier, discussions were now under way regarding
funding arrangements that should permit clearing up the Italian
swap line by early July.
By unanimous vote, renewal
for a further period of three months
of the System drawing on Bank of
Italy, maturing July 26, 1968, was

authorized.

-24

6/18/68

Chairman Martin then asked Mr. Solomon to report on the
recent meetings of the Group of Ten Deputies and Working Party 3
that he had attended.
Mr. Solomon said he would limit his report on the two
meetings--both of which had been held in The Hague because of the
uncertainty of the situation in Paris--to the developments of
particular interest to the Committee.

Of the three items, on the

G-10 agenda, the first related to improvements in the procedure
for use of the General Arrangements to Borrow for financing gold
tranche drawings on the Fund.

As the Committee knew, the gold

tranche position was regarded as a reserve asset automatically
available for use of the member countries.

However, if a large

drawing was made at a time when the Fund's holdings of currencies
were low, the Fund itself had to borrow currencies from the G-10
countries.

Existing procedures had involved consultations and

were rather cumbersome, and there was a need to reconcile the
formal automaticity of gold tranche drawings with the actual
availability of funds.

It was agreed that the IMF should

prefinance gold tranche drawings--assuming it had the currencies
needed--and subsequently come to the G-10 countries to replenish
its currency stocks, on the understanding that those countries
would give sympathetic consideration to the use of the GAB for
such ex post settlement.

That in fact was the procedure followed

-25

6/18/68
in the recent French drawing.

In his judgment the agreement was

an important development in the use of the GAB, and it strengthened
the Fund itself.
Other actions at the meeting, Mr. Solomon continued, were
approval of the use of the GAB for France's drawing on the Fund and
a redistribution, to eliminate France's share, of the contributions
under the GAB in connection with tomorrow's drawing by Britain.
Finally, Mr. Solomon said, he might mention one other
development at the meeting.

In connection with an earlier British

drawing on the Fund, France had lent the Fund $140 million through
the GAB, and it now wanted to use that claim as a reserve asset.
It was agreed that the French claim would be transferred to other
European countries--namely, Germany, Italy, Belgium, and the
Netherlands.

That transfer, which was the first of its kind,

confirmed that such claims could now be viewed as another type
of reserve asset, similar to the gold tranche.
Mr. Solomon then turned to the WP-3 meeting, noting that
it had focused mainly on prospects for the U.S. balance of payments
on the assumption that Congress would promptly enact the pending
fiscal restraint measures.
made for the discussion.

Rather careful preparation had been
In particular, the Chairman and the

Chief Economist of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development, after visiting the United States several weeks ago,

-26

6/18/68

had developed a fairly satisfactory statement on U.S. balance of
payments prospects.

The OECD Secretariat projected a distinct

slowdown in the rate of expansion of the U.S. economy over the
next year, more or less in line with the projections now being
made in Washington.

Their analysis led to the expectation that

there would be a deceleration of the wage-price spiral and a sharp
improvement in the U.S. trade balance, with a resulting strength
ening of confidence in the dollar and in present international
monetary arrangements.

The general picture of improvement over

the next year in the U.S. trade balance and over-all payments
balance was accepted by the WP-3.

Even the representatives of

countries that were likely to be most affected by a slowdown in
the U.S. economy, such as Britain and Japan, accepted the need
for it.
With respect to monetary policy, Mr. Solomon continued, in
his own presentation at the meeting he had stressed the need for
maintaining flexibility in the period ahead, given the uncertainty
as to how hard the contemplated fiscal package would bite.

He had

also emphasized the lag in the workings of monetary policy.

The

consensus at the meeting was to caution against too prompt and too
substantial an easing of U.S. monetary policy.

At the same time,

it was suggested that selective measures be used as far as possible
to shield the housing industry against the effects of tight money

6/18/68

-27

and high interest rates.

The members of WP-3 thought that both

domestic and balance of payments considerations justified the
caution against undue monetary easing.

That view was based not on

detailed projections of GNP and its components over the year, but
rather on the experience of WP-3 with other countries undertaking
stabilization programs, where the tendencies had been toward
underkill rather than overkill.

It also reflected a concern that

undue monetary ease might result in a deterioration in the capital
account that would offset the improvement expected in the trade
balance.

The only other recommendation WP-3 had for the United

States was that an incomes policy should be reinstituted once
fiscal restraint began to take hold.
Mr. Solomon noted that the French representatives made no
contribution at all to the discussion of the U.S. situation.

With

respect to developments in France itself, some reports were made
but it was clear that the situation was still too unsettled for any
definitive analysis.

The immediate problem was one of confidence;

current capital outflows from France involved funds of nonresidents
not affected by the new exchange controls and an adverse movement
of "leads and lags."

For the longer run, assuming that political

stability was restored and that effective government continued,
one major question was how large the increases in French wages and
other costs would be.

Other questions concerned the extent to

6/18/68

-28

which the higher costs would be passed through in the form of
higher prices, and the effect that price advances would have on
France's international competitive position.

Meanwhile, aggregate

demands certainly would be increased in France as a result of the
recent developments.

There was some spare capacity in the French

economy which should permit absorption of some of the demand
increases, but there no doubt would be income as well as price
effects on French imports.

The term "total transformation" had

been used by one of the French representatives to describe the
current situation.

In any case, there was a great deal of uncer

tainty, and some concern by France's neighbors that recent
developments there might spread across the French borders and
possibly across the English channel.
The British situation was the final item on the WP-3
agenda, Mr. Solomon said.

Everyone was still waiting for the

effects of the devaluation, particularly on imports, to appear.
As Mr. Coombs had indicated, exports had been doing reasonably
well and the prospects were favorable.

While there was some

anxiety about the absence to date of any significant decline in
imports, the general expectation of WP-3 and the OECD Secretariat
was that imports would fall off--although no one could pinpoint
the timing.

No specific policy proposals were made to the British

at the meeting.

6/18/68

-29
Mr. Solomon said he might mention two other matters,

although they were not formally discussed at the meetings.

On

the sterling balance prospects, it was his impression from talking
informally with various people in attendance at the meetings that
the British were prepared to go ahead with a scheme that would offer
maintenance of value guarantees of official holders of sterling in
exchange for commitments by the latter that they would run down
their sterling balances only to meet balance of payments needs,
and not for such purposes as diversifying their reserve assets.
The British hoped to combine such a scheme with the $2 billion
credit package mentioned by Mr. Coombs to finance unavoidable
reductions in sterling balances.

It was his understanding that

a letter to that effect would be sent toward the end of this week
or early next week to the central banks that were expected to
provide the "umbrella" of credits, and that the British hoped to
move ahead on both prongs at the July Basle meeting.
Finally, Mr. Solomon remarked, he shared Mr. Coombs'
favorable view as to the situation at the moment in the gold
market and the prospect for maintaining the arrangement under
which European central banks would not purchase South African
gold.

However, a new complication had arisen in the form of an

application by South Africa to sell some gold to the Fund under
the Articles of Agreement, at a price of $35 per ounce.

The Fund

-30

6/18/68

would be considering the matter next week.

The legal question

of whether the Fund was obligated to buy gold from a member
country was a complicated one; and if that question was decided
in the negative there would remain a policy question regarding
the proposed transaction.

The U.S. position on the matter had

not been worked out as yet and he suspected the same was true

for other countries.

The fact that South Africa had made the

application was not publicly known.
Chairman Martin noted that on June 3, 1968, a staff
memorandum entitled "Treasury views concerning backstopping
facilities for Federal Reserve swap arrangements" had been
distributed to the Committee, and that on June 7 a draft of
a possible letter from the Secretary of the Treasury to the

Federal Reserve had been sent to Under Secretary Deming for
review.1/ Since Mr. Deming had not yet had an opportunity to
respond, the Chairman suggested that the Committee postpone
consideration of the subject of backstopping facilities until
its next meeting.

Meanwhile, copies of the draft letter would

be distributed to the members.
There was no objection to the Chairman's suggestion.

1/ Copies of the memorandum and the communication to
Mr. Deming have been placed in the Committee's files.

6/18/68

-31Before this meeting there had been distributed to the

members of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System
Open Market Account covering domestic open market operations for
the period May 28 through June 12, 1968, and a supplemental report

covering June 13 through 17, 1968.

Copies of both reports have

been placed in the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Holmes
commented as follows:

During the period since the Committee last met, a
basic tone of optimism about the prospects for the tax
bill blossomed in the financial markets. And with this
better feeling, there was a corresponding waning of
concern that monetary policy might be tightened further.
In this atmosphere, interest rates moved substantially
lower, and there was a noticeable absence of the tension
that prevailed just a month ago. Favorable action on
fiscal policy by the House this Thursday would probably
result in a further consolidation of the gains made
recently, particularly in the longer end of the market;
unfavorable action would lead to financial market
conditions that no one really wants to contemplate.
Interest rate declines were most prevalent in the
Government securities market. Both the corporate and
municipal markets are laboring under a heavy calendar
of new issues, and investors were generally highly
selective in their approach to new issues that were
priced to yield less than the recent highs. Even in
these areas congestion seemed to be breaking up in the
past few days. In the Government securities market,
yields on longer bills were particularly affected, and
declined by 20-30 basis points over the period. Yields
on longer-term Treasury issues moved significantly
lower--generally by 1/8 to 1/4 per cent or more. In
yesterday's Treasury bill auction average rates of 5.58
and 5.63 per cent were set for 3- and 6-month bills,
down 12 and 24 basis points from the rates established
in the auction just before the Committee last met.

6/18/68

-32-

With market rates declining, the financial
institutions appear to be faring rather better than had
been anticipated earlier as they moved into the June tax
date and the mid-year interest crediting period. As the
blue book1/ notes, the decline in commercial bank CD's
now appears to be only little more than seasonal, partly
reflecting the willingness of dealers to build up their
portfolios of CD's, presumably in the hope of short-term
capital gains. The thrift institutions did not fare
badly in May, and with the recent decline in rates the
current outlook is better than had been anticipated
earlier. The more comfortable position of the banking
system appears to be reflected in the credit proxy,
which has moved to the plus side from the declines
anticipated three weeks ago.
Assuming favorable action on fiscal policy, interest
rates--particularly longer rates--should be subject to
further downward expectational pressure. This pressure
will be tempered--and could at times be offset--by
Treasury cash borrowing in July (with an announcement
probable late this month) and by corporate preparations
for retroactive tax payments. Unfavorable international
developments could also become a major factor influencing
domestic rates, particularly if they affect Euro-dollar
flows which have been so important in helping the
large banks face the current tax period with relative
equanimity.
Open market operations over the period supplied
about $211 million reserves on balance. Early in the
period a sizable amount of matched sale-purchase
agreements were made to counteract some temporary easing
in the money market. The June 5 statement week saw a
puzzling combination of very deep net borrowed reserves
and a generally comfortable money market. The net
borrowed reserve figure of $590 million originally
published for that week (subsequently revised back to
$542 million) was the deepest in nine years, but it
caused little or no concern to the market. In the
statement week ended last Wednesday, a substantial volume
of repurchase agreements was made in order to keep the
money market on an even keel, while awaiting the precise
timing of the British drawing on the International

1/ The report, "Money Market and Reserve Relationships,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

6/18/68

-33-

Monetary Fund. That drawing, now scheduled for tomorrow
as Mr. Coombs indicated, and the simultaneous pay off of
the British swap drawing from the Federal Reserve, will,
of course, have a major impact on bank reserves. The
swap repayment will in itself absorb $1-1/4 billion
reserves, although there will be a $400 million offset
from the System's purchase of guaranteed sterling and
from the System's warehousing of the Treasury purchase
of guaranteed sterling. In addition, there will be
substantial sales--perhaps $400 million or so--of
Treasury bills by foreign central banks who are asked
to convert the currencies drawn by the British into
dollars; we will, of course, have the opportunity to
take these bills into the System Account as a partial
offset to the reserve drain. Finally, there will be a
drain on the Treasury's balance stemming from the U.S.
share of the British drawing and from the redemption of
special Treasury certificates of indebtedness issued by
the Treasury to Belgium and Italy who will need the funds
in connection with the repayment of the System's swap
drawing on them.
In addition, the French transaction discussed by
Mr. Coombs will create some complications involving the
Treasury bill market and, depending on whether any portion
of the U.S. gold purchase from France is monetized, for
the Treasury's cash position.
Given the volume of activity on the international
side and the uncertainties about future developments, it
is difficult to be precise about the apparent need for the
System to supply reserves in the period ahead. On our
current estimates it would seem that we would have to
inject over $2 billion in reserves by the week of July 10
in order to keep net borrowed reserves within the recent
range of experience. While there may be a sizable
availability of Treasury bills from various foreign
central banks, it appears likely that we shall have to
do a substantial amount of outright buying in the market,
perhaps including some coupon issues. This should, of
course, exert some downward pressure on short-term rates.
As the blue book notes, the uncertainties on both
the domestic and international side make it particularly
difficult to predict the constellation of money market
conditions and reserve variables that will be compatible
with alternative policies over the period ahead. The
Committee has before it three alternative draft versions

6/18/68

-34-

of the directive1 / for its consideration. While the
interpretation to be given any of these directives
depends, as usual, on the outcome of the Committee's
discussion this morning, it might be useful to set out
the essential differences among them as I would presently
understand them from the blue book discussion.
Alternative A is essentially a no-change directive.
There would be room for a significant decline in bill
rates--if the Committee so desired--but only if
expectational and other market forces tended to bring
them about. If bill rates first declined, and then rose
under the impact of the Treasury's cash borrowing, the
Desk would not make any special effort to prevent this
from occurring, other than the normal sort of trade-offs
undertaken when the money market variables with which we
are concerned are moving in different directions.
Alternative B suggests that any early decline in
Treasury bill rates--if it occurs--should be accommodated
and confirmed by resisting any tendency for rates to rise
again. The resistance would take the form of providing
reserves to keep the Federal funds rate below 6 per cent
and by a reduction in pressure on banks' net reserve
positions. In essence this alternative suggests a change
in policy if the bill rate, after having declined, comes
under upward pressure during the period.
Alternative C is a straightforward easing of policy
designed to lead market rates of interest down. The
money market variables associated with this approach are
not far different from those associated with alternative
B, but they are to be attained even if the bill rate is
moving lower independently. A prompt move to the lower
levels of the Federal funds rate and net borrowed reserves
would probably be taken by the market as a confirmed shift
in Federal Reserve policy.
It should be noted that all three versions of the
directive contain language that would be useful in fending
off disorderly markets if anything went badly awry with
the tax bill. Given the strength of optimism about
passage of the bill, and the heavy discounting by the
market of that eventuality, I hope that these veiled
references to unfavorable Congressional action will remain
a matter of academic interest.
I should also note that under any of the directives
there would probably have to be wide swings in net borrowed

1/ Appended to this memorandum as Attachment A.

6/18/68

-35

reserves on a week-to-week basis to accommodate the
large fluctuations in country bank excess reserves that
typically take place in July--particularly between the
second and third weeks of the month. In the absence of
such swings in net borrowed reserves other money market
conditions could alternate between extreme tightness
and extreme ease.
Mr. Mitchell asked whether the Manager would expect any
significant change in the flows of funds to financial intermedi
aries--either disintermediation or a significant reduction from
the rate of inflows of a year ago--if the Committee adopted
alternative A of the draft directives.
Mr. Holmes replied that it was hard to say because it was
not clear how much downward pressure there would be on interest
rates.

He assumed there would be some; on the other hand, there

would also be upward pressures arising from retroactive corporate
tax payments and from the cash financing the Treasury would be
announcing in late June for payment probably around July 10 or 12.
The Treasury presumably would choose an instrument designed to
have a minimum impact on the market--most likely tax anticipation
bills--but the pattern of interest rate changes that would emerge
from the various conflicting pressures was uncertain.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that it was clear in any case that
adoption of alternative A for the directive would entail a greater
risk of disintermediation than would alternatives B or C.

He then

asked what Mr. Holmes anticipated with respect to pressures on the
Regulation Q ceilings.

-36

6/18/68

Mr. Holmes replied that the position of banks had been
helped considerably by the recent declines in secondary market
rates on CD's.

On the whole, the CD situation looked much better

now than had seemed possible a few weeks ago.
Mr. Daane said he gathered that despite various uncertainties
the Manager's best guess was that bill rates would decline following
fiscal action but subsequently would be subject to upward pressure.
He asked when that upward pressure was likely to occur, and whether
his understanding was correct that it would be resisted if the
Committee adopted alternative B but not if it adopted alternative
A.
Mr. Holmes replied that in his judgment upward pressures
were most likely late in the period before the tentative dateJuly 16--for the Committee's next meeting; perhaps in the second
week of July.

In general, he would interpret the directives as

Mr. Daane had suggested, although the Desk's specific response to
upward bill rate pressures under alternative B would depend on the
Committee's intentions.

For example, the bill rate might fall to

a relatively low level in the next few weeks--perhaps as low as
5-1/4 per cent.

If it then rose only part way back to current

levels--say, to 5-1/2 per cent--he would rely on the Committee's
instructions in deciding whether to resist the rise.
By unanimous vote, the open
market transactions in Government
securities, agency obligations,

6/18/68

-37
and bankers' acceptances during
the period May 28 through June 17,
1968, were approved, ratified, and
confirmed.
Chairman Martin then noted that a memorandum from the

Manager entitled "System Subscriptions in Treasury Cash Refundings"
had been distributed to the Committee on June 6, 1968, and a
memorandum from the General Counsel entitled "Legal considerations
regarding Federal Reserve participation in Treasury refunding
operations" had been distributed on June 12, 1968.1/

He asked

Mr. Holmes to comment.
Mr. Holmes noted that his memorandum dealt with a
complicated problem, and he would not attempt to review all of the
technical details orally today.

Briefly, the problem arose as a

result of new debt management techniques the Treasury had used in
both its February and May 1968 refundings, in which an exchange
offering for the maturing issues was combined with a cash offering.
In a straight cash offering with optional new issues, the System
traditionally had converted its entire holdings of the maturing
issue into the shorter of the new issues, in order to avoid market
uncertainty as to how much of the longer issue would have to be
taken up by the public.

For technical reasons, however, in the

combined cash-exchange offerings of February and May the System
1/ Copies of both memoranda have been placed in the files
of the Committee.

6/18/68

-38

had had to convert its entire holdings into the longer issue
offered in exchange, and none into the shorter issue sold for cash.
The result was that the nature of the System's subscriptions now
depended on the particular refunding technique the Treasury
employed.

It was desirable, in his judgment, to devise new

procedures that would give the System flexibility in deciding
which new issues to acquire in refundings, while preserving its
arms-length relationship with the Treasury.

The procedures

recommended in the memorandum would permit the Treasury to announce
simultaneously the specific amounts of the new issues offered to
the public and that additional amounts would be fully allotted to
the System and the Government Trust Accounts.

The memorandum also

suggested that the Treasury might want to discontinue the past
practice of making full allotments to other "bedfellows", such as
State and local governments, foreign central banks, and publicly
administered pension funds.

Finally, when--as in the February

refunding--the cash offering was later in time than the exchange
offering, it was proposed that the new issues offered for cash be
dated as of the maturity date of the maturing securities, so that
the System would not lose interest if it exchanged its holding of
maturing securities for the issues sold for cash.
In response to the Chairman's request for comment,
Mr. Hackley said he had found no legal objections to Mr. Holmes'

6/18/68

-39

proposals.

As noted in his memorandum, the only legal question

raised by the proposals was whether the new securities acquired
by the System would fall within the purview of Section 14(b) of
the Federal Reserve Act, which provided that direct and fully
guaranteed obligations of the United States may be bought and
sold either in the open market or directly from or to the United
States, and that the aggregate amount of such obligations acquired
directly from the United States that were held at any one time by
the Federal Reserve Banks shall not exceed $5 billion.

In his

judgment the securities would not fall within the purview of
Section 14(b).

He noted that for more than 30 years Committee

Counsel had consistently held that U.S. obligations acquired from
the Treasury in exchange for maturing securities acquired by the
System in the open market were not covered by the provisions of
Section 14(b).
In the course of the ensuing discussion Mr. Daane indicated
that he was not wholly persuaded of the desirability of all aspects
of Mr. Holmes' proposals.

At the end of the discussion it was

agreed that the Manager should be authorized to explore the matter
informally with the Treasury without undertaking commitments for
any change in present procedures, and that the Committee would plan
on pursuing the question at its next meeting.
Chairman Martin observed that the Committee had planned to
discuss today the memoranda before it on issues involved in setting

-40

6/18/68

interest rates on System repurchase agreements.

In the interest

of time, however, he suggested that general discussion be postponed
until the next meeting, with the members remaining free to make
any comments they chose regarding the current level of the RP rate
in the course of the go-around later in today's meeting.
No objection was raised to that suggestion.
The Chairman then noted that certain materials 1 / had been
distributed to the Committee on June 13, 1968, relating to the
so-called "Proxmire amendment" to S. 3133, the temporary interest
rate legislation.

The amendment, which had recently been approved

by the Senate Banking and Currency Committee, would authorize the
System to deal in agency issues in the open market and directly
with the issuing agency, and would express the sense of Congress
that the authority should be used "when alternative means cannot
effectively be employed to permit financial institutions to
continue to supply reasonable amounts of funds to the mortgage
market during periods of monetary stringency and rapidly rising
interest rates."

In his judgment enactment of that amendment would

create serious problems for the System.

Yesterday Mr. Robertson

and he had discussed the matter with Secretary Fowler and Chairman
Sparkman of the Senate Banking and Currency Committee, and a letter
to the Senator was now being prepared.

1/ Copies of these materials have been placed in the
Committee's files.

-41

6/18/68

In response to the Chairman's request for comment,
Mr. Robertson said that the amendment would be reconsidered by the
Senate Committee within a day or two.

It was the Board's hope that

it would be eliminated from the bill at that time on the grounds
that it represented an undesirable departure from traditional
central banking principles.

In effect, it would utilize the

Federal Reserve System to subsidize the housing industry.

It also

would create problems for the System and the Treasury, since any
System purchases of agency issues for purposes of the bill would
have to be offset by sales of an equivalent amount of direct
Treasury obligations, raising interest rates on the latter.
Mr. Robertson added that similar legislation was likely
to be introduced in the House next week.

Even if the Senate

should approve the amendment it was not a foregone conclusion
that the House would also do so.
Chairman Martin then called for the staff economic and
financial reports, supplementing the written reports that had been
distributed prior to the meeting, copies of which have been placed
in the files of the Committee.
Mr. Partee made the following statement on economic
conditions;
With the crucial vote on the fiscal restraint
package just two days away, we are faced with unusual
hazards today in projecting the short-run outlook. The

6/18/68

-42-

problem is greatest in the financial area, where
failure to vote the tax bill would be greeted with
deepest gloom, producing shock waves both domestically
and internationally. But the outcome for fiscal
restraint, of course, will also have a marked impact on
the outlook for the economy generally. We would expect
increased tax withholdings to have a.prompt and sizable
dampening effect on consumption, and for restraint on
Federal expenditures to have a gradual but progressively
larger impact as the fiscal year progresses. Taken
together, and including also the secondary effects on
other sources of spending, we believe that the prospect
would be for a sharp reduction in real growth in the
economy over the year ahead.
That pattern of events was presented to you in
some detail at the last meeting of the Committee, and
the outlook does not seem to me to have changed in any
important respect in the intervening three weeks. What
I would like to emphasize today is the high probability
of some slowing in economic expansion in the period
immediately ahead, even in the absence of enactment of
the fiscal restraint package. The configuration of
major strike threats, the apparent stabilization of the
size of the war effort in Vietnam, the cumulating lagged
effects of monetary restraint, the slowing in exogenous
injections of personal income resulting from Government
programs, and the continued conservatism of consumers
in their spending behavior--all point to a near-term
slowing in the growth of final sales. With less
frenetic expansion in markets, and with the existence
of ample production capacity, moreover, there seems to
me little prospect that business would greatly increase
its capital spending plans or engage in any extended
accumulation of inventories on a substantial scale.
The upsurge in final sales already appears to have
slowed substantially from the extraordinary 13 per cent
annual rate of the first quarter. Our current estimate,
as contained in the green book,1/ is for a rise of less
than $19 billion in the current quarter, down from $26
billion in the first quarter. But this estimate may
prove to be too high, unless there is a sizable further
gain in retail sales this month. Initial reports are

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

6/18/68

-43-

not promising. The sales rate for domestic new cars
dropped sharply in the first 10 days partly because of
the different timing of dealer sales contests, and
other retail sales were noticeably weaker in the first
week of the month, perhaps reflecting the Kennedy
assassination. Private nonresidential construction
also appears to have been running weaker than implied
by our business fixed investment projection, judging
from the April and May reports.
Looking ahead, the prospect is for a slowing in
the growth of personal incomes, even without the fiscal
package. The Federal pay raise at mid-year will provide
a significant addition, of course, but the effects of
other Federal programs--the increase in social security
benefits and in the minimum wage--are already largely
reflected in the second-quarter totals and will not add
appreciably to third-quarter flows. Moreover, a
temporary slowdown in income payments next quarter seems
likely in automobiles and steel, where inventories have
been accumulating sharply, and perhaps in related
industries. Assuming that consumers would continue
their high rate of saving in the absence of a tax
increase, which they appear to have been doing again
in the current quarter, slower growth in income would
be directly reflected in the consumption figures.
In other sectors too, there seems to me little
prospect of a marked near-term strengthening in spending.
The latest Commerce-SEC survey of business plant and
equipment investment intentions, though a shade higher
for the year than the previous survey, indicates little
increase in the pattern of expansion. The second half
is now projected to rise 3 per cent from the first half,
much of which probably reflects higher prices in the
heavy construction and capital goods fields. Residential
construction expenditures still seem likely to decline
in the months immediately ahead whether or not there is
a tax increase. Earlier declines in the flow of mortgage
commitments and the relatively bleak outlook for thrift
institutions point to at least a temporary interruption
in what otherwise appears to be an exceptionally strong
demand situation. Federal spending probably will be
limited also whether or not there is a tax increase,
reflecting earlier uncertainties in program planning
and restrictive appropriations policies. Finally, with
military force levels apparently stabilized in Vietnam,

-44-

6/18/68

at least for the time being, the sizable increases in
defense spending witnessed in the first half seem likely
now to taper off.
Given these prospects for moderation in the sources
of economic expansion, it might be questioned whether a
tax increase is really necessary. I continue to think
it is, for domestic as well as international reasons.
The self-generated moderation which I foresee could
prove largely temporary, and there is virtually no room
for error on the upside. Should consumer demand become
more ebullient and the saving rate decline from its
recent very high level, or should further acceleration
in the war effort suddenly prove necessary, we would be
right back in a situation of excessive over-all expansion
such as has prevailed in the early part of this year.
The most important domestic consideration arguing
for a firm posture of restraint in public economic
policy, however, is that the underlying inflationary
pressures in the economy continue unabated and are
likely to persist for some time to come. In order to
brake the pervasive tendencies toward excessive wage
increases, excessive price adjustments, and excessive
spending and investment anticipations based in part on
the psychology of inflation, it may well be necessary
to go through a period of reduced growth and less
receptive markets. These tendencies probably will
continue to be a major concern in the formulation of
monetary policy, as they have been for some time past.
Nevertheless, if the fiscal package is enacted, the
substantially more restrictive mix of economic policy
that results would appear to leave some room for an
easing off in monetary restraint. A policy that
deliberately courts a business recession seems to me
of dubious merit, either in terms of the immediate
objective of reestablishing more stable economic
conditions or as a viable solution to the longer-run
problem of bringing the inflationary uptrend to an end.
Mr. Brill made the following statement regarding financial
developments:
The Committee must by now be understandably weary
of the staff's repeated laments about the difficulty of
projecting constellations of market and monetary variables
for short periods ahead. This time we mean it. The
variety of possible events on the immediate horizon make

6/18/68

-45-

short-term forecasting, particularly of financial markets,
nigh impossible. The blue book distributed for this
meeting deserves an award for bravado, if not for clarity
or accuracy.
In recent meetings, the staff has addressed itself
to the problems of the longer-run strategy of monetary
policy in the event of failure, or alternatively, of
success in achieving fiscal restraint. I think the basic
themes of these analyses still hold: if the burden of
restraint remains on the shoulders of monetary policy,
financial conditions will have to be made somewhat
tighter. But the degree of additional monetary restraint
needed to achieve reasonably prompt and adequate economic
cooling-off is not very large, taking into account the
restraint already cranked into the system. Alternatively,
if the fiscal program is enacted, I still think we need
prompt but moderate easing of financial conditions, to
guard against too abrupt a slowing in activity next
winter, a slowing which would be much more severe, in
our judgment, than is suggested in the overly-optimistic
outlook of the OECD document to which Mr. Solomon
referred.
The question is, how do we get there from here, under
either fiscal alternative? The principal difficulty in
answering this question is the extent to which financial
markets, domestic and international, take the initiative
out of our hands. Consider, for example, the possibility
that the fiscal package fails of passage--a possibility
the staff found too horrible to contemplate and therefore
assumed away in the green and blue books. Recent
financial market developments suggest that the market is
betting, albeit somewhat nervously, against this
possibility. But looking back at recent periods when
market expectations were suddenly jolted--in March, at
the time of the gold crisis, and in mid-May, when the
tax hike was postponed--the result was some quick
unloading, particularly of longer-term issues in dealer
hands. A repetition on a larger scale might be expected
in the event of an adverse vote next Thursday.
The usual procedures for dealing with the emergence
of disorderly markets--clearing out dealer inventories
at progressively lower prices, until the market shows
signs of functioning on its own--would probably need to
be called into play, as would the procedures developed
in 1966 for emergency aid to other financial institutions.

6/18/68

-46-

Since we would want to come out of such a transition
period with more monetary restraint than at present,
the objective of interim action would not be that of
trying to forestall tightening of credit markets, but
rather that of keeping adjustments orderly and within
bounds, encouraging the market to find levels at which
borrowers and investors are willing to do business with
one another.
I am not too sanguine about the ease with which
these objectives could be achieved. My fears are based
not so much on domestic financial grounds as on the
possibility of major international financial repercus
sions. Perhaps we are trapped by our own efforts, which
have made the tax increase the sine qua non of fiscal
integrity. The international consequences of failure
to get fiscal restraint could swamp the purely domestic
impacts, and put us into a different ball-park for
monetary policy.
Let me now turn to the more probable and happier,
but not necessarily easier, set of problems for monetary
policy in the case of fiscal success. As the staff
indicated in the chart show at the last Committee
meeting, the longer-term monetary requirements in this
case involve establishing a financial environment in
which thrift institutions are encouraged to expand their
commitment activity promptly, in order to insure an
expansion in building activity next winter. Strength
in housing activity is essential, not only to insure a
reasonable amount of aggregate demand next year, but
also to meet the particular problem of a developing
housing shortage.
To achieve this will require maintenance of the
inflow of funds to thrift institutions, and removal of
the threat of massive outflows. Recent experience in
this regard has been surprisingly good. Net savings
inflows have been maintained at a much better pace than
might have been expected in light of the widening spread
in favor of rates on competitive market instruments.
Preliminary data for May, for example, indicate a rebound
in net inflows to mutual savings banks and savings and
loan associations comparable to that following the
year-end interest and dividend crediting period. But
the initial impact of the tax increase may well fall
heavily on such savings flows, particularly when higher
tax withholdings start.

6/18/68

-47-

Moreover, the rate relationships emerging subsequent
to passage of the fiscal restraint program may not
automatically provide the needed encouragement to thrift
institutions to stimulate a rise in commitments now in
the confidence that adequate savings inflows will be
available later. The market has to some extent already
discounted the tax increase. Given the Treasury's
near-term financing needs, and given investor attempts
to switch from short- to long-term investments, we may
experience a version of "Operation Twist" which would
tend to keep rates relatively high on those market
instruments most competitive with thrift institutions.
Thus, any further decline in short-term rates is
likely to be modest, and would likely be short-lived
if monetary actions are such as to maintain key money
market indicators--the funds rate and net borrowed
reserves--at or near recent levels, as would be the
case should the Committee adopt directive alternative
A.
The danger I see in this course is that we run the
risk of repeating the mistakes of early 1960, when a
sustained high discount rate induced banks to make
portfolio adjustments and pay off borrowings at the
Fed, rather than expanding credit for an economy
already beginning to slow up and head for a recession.
The staff has suggested another policy alternative,
one which still leaves the initiative to the market
but would avoid giving a misleading signal as to the
longer-run intent of policy. In this alternative--B--no
initiative would be taken by the System to push rates
down. But if short-term market rates did decline further
following enactment of the fiscal package, and then gave
signs of reversing trend--because of Treasury financing
demands, because of investor portfolio switches, or
because of apprehension about the intent of monetary
policy--then alternative B would require offsetting Desk
operations to reduce the funds rate. The precise level
of the funds rate needed to offset a reversing market
tendency is conjectural; a drop to the 5-3/4 - 5-7/8 per
cent range might do the trick, but the rate might have
to be even lower.
Another policy strategy is specified in alternative
C, which would have the System taking the initiative in
encouraging a downward movement in short-term rates, by
easing bank reserve positions sufficiently to get the
funds rate down below 6 per cent.

6/18/68

-48-

As the policy options are now cast in the draft
directives distributed to the Committee, alternative B
looks superficially attractive. It relieves us of any
obligation to make the first move, and it brings System
initiative into play only if market expectations and
market forces do not sustain a downward adjustment in
market interest rates. Yesterday's market developments
suggest that such an adjustment is under way. But once
the initial euphoria induced by improved prospects for
fiscal legislation is dissipated, the market will become
increasingly sensitive to indicators of the stance of
monetary policy. Maintenance of the funds rate at 6 per
cent or more, with a discount rate remaining at 5-1/2 per
cent, are not signals conducive to market expectations
for even a moderate easing in our policy posture, and a
snap-back in market rates would become more likely. I
don't see the point of letting misimpressions as to
policy becoming embedded in the market and then trying
to turn them around.
In view of the still high level of credit costs,
and the lag with which monetary actions have their
impact on the economy, it seems to me appropriate for the
System to take some modest initiative in moving interest
rates to levels more appropriate to the longer-run needs
of an economy operating under strong fiscal restraint.
Let me emphasize that I am not recommending offsetting
fiscal restraint by massive monetary easing. A bill
rate hovering below 5-1/2 per cent does not strike me
as cheap money, nor does bank credit expansion at a
6-8 per cent annual rate seem excessively generous,
particularly in a period of heavy Treasury borrowing
and unexpected corporate tax liabilities. But I do
think the market needs some signal that, with the
enactment of the tax and expenditure program, we are
going to step back a bit from the current degree of
monetary restraint. A deliberate but relatively small
step in open market operations may forestall the need
for a more overt signal to the market through discount
rate action, at least for a while.
Mr. Mitchell said he had thought that the major thrust of
the argument in favor of alternatives B or C for the directive was
the need to avoid any further deterioration in the flow of funds

-49

6/18/68
to thrift institutions.

But the evidence seemed to indicate that

those flows had been at a satisfactory level recently and that the
interest rate structure suggested they would continue to be
satisfactory throughout the dividend-crediting period.

Accordingly,

he was somewhat puzzled by Mr. Brill's policy recommendation.
Mr. Brill replied that he was perhaps less confident than
Mr. Mitchell that inflows to thrift institutions would be sustained
at recent levels even in the event of fiscal action.

One factor

that might operate to reduce such inflows was the reduction in the
saving rate that was likely to accompany the tax increase, as
consumers adjusted to the increase initially by reducing savings
in order to maintain their spending plans.

Moreover, to achieve

even the low 1-1/2 per cent rate of real growth the staff projected
for the first half of 1969, it would be necessary to have inflows
to thrift institutions of a size sufficient to induce those
institutions to expand their mortgage commitments--not simply
sustain them at recent levels.
Mr. Mitchell commented that consumers might react to the
tax increase by reducing either their spending or saving.

To the

extent they reduced spending the objectives of fiscal restraint
would be achieved and flows to thrift institutions would be
maintained.

But if the bulk of the tax increase was reflected

in lower saving, greater monetary restraint than otherwise would
seem to be required.

-50

6/18/68

Mr. Brill replied that the staff was projecting a decline
in the dollar flow of personal saving as a result not only of a
reduction in the saving rate but also because, as Mr. Partee had
indicated, growth in income was expected to slow as a result of
the fiscal package and other factors.

Accordingly, in the absence

of a change in monetary policy, inflows to thrift institutions
could weaken.
Mr. Mitchell then said he questioned the desirability of
making a monetary policy decision today on the basis of guesses as
to the probable course of events following enactment of the fiscal
package.

In his judgment it would be better for the Committee to

plan on holding another meeting after Congress had acted and there
had been an opportunity to observe the market reaction.
Mr. Reynolds then made the following statement on the
balance of payments and related matters:
This Committee meets today at a time when
substantial changes in the economic situation, both
at home and abroad, are either under way or about to
occur. We all have very much in mind the changes that
may follow Congressional action--either way--on the
fiscal program.
At the same time, at least two major changes seem
to be under way abroad. First, the convulsions in France
have thrown that country's balance of payments into
deficit and have forced France to draw from the IMF and
sell gold for the first time since 1958. Secondly, the
position of sterling has improved somewhat, or so it
seems to me. The massive U.K. reserve losses of May
have given way to modest reserve gains so far in June,
thanks mainly to reports of funding and guaranty

6/18/68

-51-

arrangements for the sterling balances; as already noted,
the U.K. foreign trade figures in May were unchanged from
April, but we would still expect improvement in the months
ahead in lagged response to last November's devaluation
and the March budget, which have already been reflected
in a sharp drop off in retail sales at home and in rising
export orders.
Two of these changes--enactment of the U.S. fiscal
restraint package and a turn of the tide for sterlinghad already been assumed in the balance of payments
projections given to the Committee at its last meeting.
It will be gratifying, of course, to see these favorable
developments actually occur--if they do occur--because
without them the prospects would be for a very uneasy
and crisis-ridden summer. But their occurrence may
still leave the United States with a payments deficit
that is large and only slowly diminishing. As Mr. Hersey
suggested last time, the official settlements deficit
could be of the order of $2-1/2 billion over the coming
fiscal year, assuming that the recent flood of liquid
funds from abroad will subside, as it must. Although
we would hope that some part of that deficit would have
its counterpart in a U.K. surplus and could be readily
financed by U.K. repayment of debt, the remainder would
be likely to involve renewed U.S. gold losses, IMF
drawings, and provision of exchange rate guarantees.
The third development that I have mentioned,
however--the set of changes that is resulting from recent
events in France--does represent a new element that can
be helpful to our balance of payments, and to the
adjustment process world-wide, provided that it goes
far enough in some directions and not too far in others.
For France alone, a modest swing toward more expansionary
domestic economic policies, a moderate once-for-all dose
of wage inflation (of the sort absorbed on occasion in
the past by the Netherlands and Italy), and even a
short-lived burst of capital flight, can be useful from
the point of view of international payments adjustment.
But I think we should hope that the French Government
can reestablish its authority very soon and that further
capital flight can be limited. French drawings on the

IMF and on swaps plus French gold sales already scheduled
total nearly $1-1/2 billion. That is a lot even for a
country that had $7 billion of reserves when the trouble
began. It would be no help at all to anyone for the

6/18/68

-52-

drain to persist to the point at which a new French
devaluation had to be considered. The present French
Government will certainly do everything in its power to
avoid that outcome. But the danger exists, nonetheless.
With French foreign trade totaling about $25 billion a
year, a mere shift of one month in average leads and
lags can cost more than $2 billion of French reserves.
Assuming that the capital flight can be stopped,
there will remain some more lasting adverse shift in the
basic French balance of payments. Much of this shift
will be reflected in larger surpluses for other Common
Market countries, and only a small part may show up as
an improvement for the United States and United Kingdom.
Against this background, it would be helpful if just a
little of the French malaise could spread to Italy and
Germany, It may well spread to Italy; also, the recent
elections there seem to open the way for more expansionary
fiscal policies, in line with promises made by the Moro
government on which delivery has yet to be made. But
whether inflation will spread to Germany seems much more
doubtful. Hence, unless the German Government takes a
strong lead in formulating more expansionary policies,
new strains may develop within the Common Market, and
also between that area as a whole and the rest of the
world. France will have a payments deficit, but Germany
and the EEC as a whole may continue to have a large
surplus. I might note, and of course one would not say
this publicly, that in that situation a German revalua
tion could provide a helpful way out--for France, for
Germany, and for the Common Market versus the rest of
the world. But it would be very difficult to sell this
idea to a German Government.
My tentative conclusion about the French disturbances
of recent weeks is that, provided their inflationary and
capital flight effects can be brought under control well
short of a French devaluation, they have bought the
United States and the United Kingdom a little more time.
They tilt the basic payments position a little in our
favor, compared with what it would otherwise have been.
And they have had a useful confidence effect, reminding
people that political and economic stability are not the
exclusive property of continental European countries.
It has been interesting to observe, as Mr. Coombs has
noted, that most of the capital fleeing from France
seems to have gone into dollar assets, rather than into
other European currencies.

6/18/68

-53-

On the other hand, whatever time we have been
granted was badly needed. The urgency of our making a
balance of payments adjustment is in no way diminished,
just because the odds that we can make it in time have
improved slightly.
Let me say a word now about the specific question
that is before the Committee today--the question of
how soon and how much to ease monetary policy if the
Congress adopts the fiscal restraint package. I think
there can be very little difference of view about the
course that we all want the domestic economy to take;
it is the same from both the domestic and international
points of view. We need a temporary but decisive
slowdown in the real growth rate in order to remove
excess demand pressures and slow down inflation. On the
other hand, we want to avoid--if it can be avoided--a
recession that would be likely to breed another too
rapid expansion.
The problem comes in specifying the monetary
conditions and actions that will lead to this desirable
result. Here I defer in large measure to my colleagues
on the domestic side. They have persuaded me that there
is some measure of over-kill in the combination of the
fiscal package plus the present degree of monetary
tightness, so that some degree of easing will be in
order when the fiscal legislation is enacted. On the
other hand, as a balance of payments specialist I hope
that any easing can initially be modest, so that we can
get at home a rather early disinflationary impact from
the tax action, and so that its confidence effects can
make themselves strongly felt in foreign exchange
markets for a time.
Mr. Galusha noted that there was a report in the New York
Times this morning about attempts by the French to secure protec
tionist relief from some of the Kennedy Round tariff reductions
that were scheduled to take effect July 1.

It would be unfortunate,

he thought, if such relief was granted and resulted in damage to
the foreign trade of the United States and Britain, both of which

-54

6/18/68

were counting heavily on the scheduled tariff reductions.

He asked

about the implications of the French effort and the prospects that
it would succeed.

Mr. Maisel remarked that a debate was under way at present
among the Common Market countries as to the extent to which cost
increases in France would have to be passed through to higher
prices.

The other members were arguing that French manufacturers

should be able to absorb the bulk of the cost increases, and
pointed to the recent experience in Italy and Holland by way of
example.

The French felt that the analogy did not apply since

their manufacturers had been operating with smaller profit margins
than those in Italy and Holland.

While France's request was being

resisted currently, the Common Market probably would accede to it
in the end.

In any case, the matter at issue was internal to the

Common Market, with no implications for external tariffs.
Chairman Martin then called for the go-around of comments
and views on economic conditions and monetary policy, beginning with
Mr. Treiber, who made the following statement:
There has been little change in the domestic
business situation. Available statistics show renewed
strength in May following hesitation in April when
civil disorder was widespread. The unemployment rate
remains at a low 3-1/2 per cent.
Consumer prices continue to rise at a rate of
about 4 per cent per annum, the highest rate for any
sustained period since the Korean war. The recent
slowdown in the rate of advance in wholesale prices

6/18/68

-55-

appears to be due to special factors. The underlying
pressures for price increases remain very strong.
Our balance of payments picture has improved
somewhat in recent weeks, due principally to continued
heavy long-term borrowing by American corporations in
the Euro-bond market through convertible debentures,
and to large purchases by foreigners of stocks of
American corporations. There is also some prospect for
improvement in the U.S. trade balance but this will depend
on our ability to restrain inflation at home.
Despite the improvement, the prospective underlying
deficit for 1968 is in the $3 - $4 billion range. The
hopes expressed at the beginning of 1968 for an improve
ment in our trade surplus in 1968 have foundered on the
rocks of inflation.
Interest rates have receded in recent weeks with
the improved prospects of a tax increase. If these
prospects are realized, it would appear that the thrift
institutions are not likely to experience large
withdrawals at the time of the mid-year interest and
dividend crediting period. The growth in bank credit
continues to be modest. In view of current rate levels
and the availability of funds in the Euro-dollar market,
the New York City banks do not appear to be overly
concerned about the possibility of a further runoff in
large-denomination certificates of deposit.
At long last it now appears that the House of
Representatives will vote this week on the tax bill
recommended by the Conference Committee. I trust that
there may be prompt enactment of this vital and long
overdue legislation. Even with the passage of the
bill--with its 10 per cent surcharge and its $6 billion
spending cuts--the over-all Federal budget is likely to
show a substantial deficit in the coming fiscal year.
Vietnam spending estimates have already been upped
substantially from last January's estimates. Some of
the other spending categories specifically exempted from
the cutback provisions are also likely to exceed earlier
estimates. At the same time, it is very doubtful that
the full cutback of $6 billion will be realized; later
relaxation of spending restraint is more likely than not.
The Treasury will have a heavy borrowing program in
the last six months of 1968. Indeed, it may be expected
to announce late this month an offering early in July of
perhaps $4 billion of new issues for cash.

6/18/68

-56-

In my opinion, Federal Reserve open market policy
should continue unchanged. Impending Congressional
action on the tax bill, the marginal competitive
position of the thrift institutions, and prospective
Treasury financing all counsel against a further
increase in Federal Reserve restraint at this time. On
the other hand, prompt enactment of the tax bill would
not, in my view, warrant an immediate easing of credit
policy. I have already mentioned the improbability of
a reduction in spending to the extent specified in the
tax bill. I think that we should await the enactment
of the legislation and seek to assess the effect of its
enactment before taking any steps to ease credit policy.
The inflationary pressures on our domestic economy
require more restraint than is now being provided by
monetary policy and our balance of payments remains
poor, necessitating the maintenance of relatively high
interest rates.
Money market conditions are, of course, measured
by a variety of factors which at times may move in
different directions. During the period immediately
ahead, these measures could be especially sensitive to
uncertainties, both domestic and foreign. With this
caveat, it would appear that a Federal funds rate
fluctuating around 6 - 6-1/4 per cent, net borrowed
reserves in a $350 - $450 million range, and member
bank borrowings in the $650 - $750 million range would
be appropriate. If enactment of the tax bill produces
a downward effect on Treasury bill rates and other
rates, it would not seem necessary to counter this
development by open market operations. I think the
System could afford to accommodate an expansion of bank
credit next month brought about by the cash borrowing
of the Treasury and corporate borrowing to meet stepped-up
tax payments.
If the tax bill is not enacted, there could, of
course, be serious repercussions in the domestic
financial markets and the foreign exchange markets.
Under such circumstances it may become necessary for
open market operations to focus on the maintenance of
orderly conditions, especially in view of the impending
large Treasury financing.
I have no suggestions with respect to the first
paragraph of the draft directive provided by the staff.
For the second paragraph, I favor alternative A.

-57

6/18/68

Mr. Latham reported that although there was some evidence
of a slowing down in the rate of advance, the New England economy
as a whole continued to show an upward trend which had now been
under way since mid-1967.

The New England labor market was tight

in practically all categories with demand continuing very strong.
Unemployment continued in the 3.8 to 3.9 per cent range which had
prevailed since last July.

Initial unemployment claims after the

communications strike influence were again running 5.2 per cent
below year ago levels.

Manufacturing output had had an erratic

course upward since the low of last July, with the gain in
nondurable goods.

Construction contract awards through April

still showed an upward trend since the low of late 1966, with the
level above the peak of 1966.

Residential contracts were sharply

upward for both single- and multi-unit housing, with single-unit
contracts exceeding the peak level of early 1966 in each of the
past three months.

Nonresidential building had shown little

change since last September.
After a first-quarter advance, Mr. Latham said, there
appeared to be some slackening in the second quarter in the rate
of inventory accumulation.
materials.

The exception seemed to be in raw

Prime defense contracts in the first quarter were

one-fourth above the corresponding period of a year ago.

Consumer

prices in the Boston area were up 1.6 per cent from January to

-58

6/18/68

April of this year, with the April index figure 4 per cent above
a year earlier.

That was the largest April-to-April advance since

the 1950-51 period.
Mutual savings banks outside of Boston were doing remarkably
well with respect to deposits, Mr. Latham continued.

Boston banks

were showing a growing decrease in net savings flows--deposits
less withdrawals--during the first five months of 1968.

Boston

mutual savings banks had been slow to join the rate race.
Mr. Latham noted that mortgage interest rates in the
District continued to rise in May, with 34 of 80 mutuals reporting
increases.

Seven per cent was the more common rate, but a number

of the country mutuals were still making mortgage loans at 6-1/2
and 6-3/4 per cent.

For the first time in recorded history the

average Boston rate was above the outside rate.
Mr. Latham commented that preliminary reports for May
indicated a tightening trend for life insurance companies.

Policy

loans continued to rise but as yet there was no evidence of any
decline in mortgage loan repayments.

Insurance companies were

exercising more caution in both loans and investments.

Large

commercial banks were evidencing concern over their heavy loan
positions; they anticipated increased demands with or without
fiscal action.

CD rates were at the ceilings.

Outstanding CD's

were declining but there were no present evidences of disintermedi
ation.

6/18/68

-59
While most bankers and businessmen reported business as

good to excellent, Mr. Latham said, there was growing evidence in
their comments that perhaps things had been too good for too long
and that what was needed was a further period of enforced belt
tightening, hopefully through fiscal action.
Mr. Coldwell reported that economic conditions in the
Eleventh District were still generally at a high level, with
further pressures developing on the employment market and
unemployment at minimal levels.

Some weakness had developed in

the construction area, but it was not clear how long it would
persist.

Retail trade remained very strong.

There were continuing

indications of speculative activities, including substantial
financing demands for mergers and takeovers.

Reports from banks

reflected unevenness in their positions and in the impact of
reserve pressures on them.

Bankers were expressing deep concern

over possible disintermediation and also over potentially strong
loan demands, especially in connection with the retroactive
corporate tax payments involved in the pending fiscal legislation.
They were also concerned about probable wage-cost increases in the
period ahead.
Mr. Coldwell observed that there had been little respite
from inflationary pressures nationally or from the problems in
the international financial arena.

He doubted that final sales

-60

6/18/68

would decline substantially as a result of the expected fiscal
legislation, since he suspected that consumers would be more
inclined to reduce saving than spending in response to a tax
increase.
Mr. Coldwell thought there were two broad policy questions
facing the Committee today.

First, was the Committee certain

enough of the future restraining effect of fiscal action to relax
monetary restraint?

Secondly, should monetary restraint be relaxed

at a time when near-term Treasury financing meant there would be
little chance for reversal if that should prove desirable?

His

own position was that the Committee could not afford to relax
monetary restraint until there was evidence that fiscal restraint
was having an impact on the current economic situation, and that
it could afford to wait until July before deciding whether there
was a need for relaxation.
Accordingly, Mr. Coldwell said, he would suggest maintaining
the status quo with respect to firmness, with a caveat on the need
to preserve orderly market conditions.

Alternative A of the

directive drafts was acceptable to him, although it might be.
worthwhile to add a reference to Congressional action on fiscal
legislation in view of the importance of such action.

He did not

favor alternatives B or C because both implied a precommitment to
easing.

However, he would give more than the usual degree of

-61

6/18/68

leeway to the Manager and have doubts resolved on the side of ease.
Certainly, interest rates should be permitted to move without
resistance.
Mr. Swan observed that economic conditions in general
continued good in the Twelfth District, although in May the
unemployment rate in Pacific Coast States rose by 0.2 of a
percentage point to 4.6 per cent.

The rise in unemployment was

accompanied by the fifth consecutive monthly decline in California
aerospace employment from the peak of December 1967.

Loan demand

was continuing to hold up well in the District and borrowings
from the Reserve Bank remained at high levels.

In fact, in the

three weeks ending June 12, District bank borrowings averaged
$140 million, about 20 per cent of the national total.

There

seemed to be less concern than earlier, however, about possible
disintermediation.

The latest available figures for share

holdings at California savings and loan associations--relating
to the experience through the first two weeks of June at five
associations which accounted for about 18 per cent of the State
total--showed some rise.

The associations considered the increase

quite satisfactory under existing circumstances.
As to policy, Mr. Swan said he shared what seemed to be
the general view that some definite slowing of the rate of economic
growth was needed.

In his judgment the Committee should not be

-62

6/18/68

He

too hasty in moving toward ease if the tax bill were passed.

recognized the possibility that some degree of overkill might be
involved in the combination of the proposed fiscal restraint and
the existing monetary restraint, and he also recognized that if
that should prove to be the case prompt action to ease monetary
But that did not necessarily argue for

policy would be required.

an immediate move toward easing.

In terms of market psychology

it would be better for the System not to appear to be attempting
to move immediately to offset the tightening effect of the tax
increase.

In other words, the danger of appearing to move too

far too fast in the direction of easing seemed to him to be
greater at the moment than the danger of overstaying a policy of
restraint.
Having said that, Mr. Swan continued, he had to admit that
he had hesitated between alternatives A and B for the directive
because he thought the System certainly should not offset any
decreases in short-term interest rates that might occur following
passage of the tax bill.

On balance, he favored alternative B,

despite the fact that the Manager had indicated he would interpret
A as not calling for efforts to resist such rate declines.

He

would, however, want to add a proviso regarding bank credit growth
to the staff's draft of B.

He was concerned about the possibility

that unduly rapid bank credit growth might result from the Desk's

-63

6/18/68

efforts to resist subsequent upward pressures on short-term rates,
as called for by B, and from other factors, such as Treasury
financing.

Accordingly, after the statement reading "provided,

however, that operations shall accommodate tendencies for
short-term interest rates to decline in connection with affirmative
Congressional action on fiscal legislation," he would add "so long
as bank credit expansion does not exceed current projections."

For

purposes of that proviso, he would specify the annual rate of bank
credit growth projected for both June and July as in the range of
3 to 6 per cent, the range given in the blue book for June.
Mr. Swan added that he would also suggest a change in the
final clause of the staff's draft of the first paragraph, which
read "while taking account of the potential impact on financial
markets of developments with respect to fiscal legislation."

He

would prefer to delete the words "financial markets," since the
Committee obviously was concerned with the effects of fiscal
legislation on the economy as a whole.
Mr. Galusha remarked, that System policy seemed to be
having an effect, at least in the construction industry.

He had

had reports, particularly from life insurance companies, that
inquiries from would-be borrowers had become much less numerous
than they had been.

No wonder, what with lenders getting interest

rates of 8 or 9 per cent or more on commercial construction loans,

-64

6/18/68

along with various kinds of "participations."

The word "participa

tions" should be in quotes for they had been of a nature that in
another era in his old home State of Montana would have aroused
the vigilantes.

Apparently many of those who had previously taken

options had been willing to pay very high rates--so as not to lose
their options.

But in reaction to such high rates, would-be

borrowers were not now taking further options.
Turning to Committee policy, Mr. Galusha expressed the view
that even if the House passed the tax bill tomorrow, the Committee
should not immediately make an overt change in policy.

It seemed

to him important not to give the rest of the world the impression
of having acted with indecent haste.

But he would not want to see

the Manager resisting further declines in interest rates unless,
of course, the House did not pass the tax bill.
He came out, then, for alternative B of the staff directive
drafts, Mr. Galusha said.

While it put something of a burden on

the Manager, it seemed nevertheless to be the best possible
directive in the present awkward circumstances.

It allowed for

an overt change in policy, if necessary, but sometime in the
future, and not immediately.

That, as he had said, seemed to him

important.
Mr. Scanlon reported that the economic picture in the
Seventh District had not changed appreciably in the past month.

6/18/68

-65

Price increases continued to outnumber decreases by a wide margin,
and labor markets remained very tight.

Price reductions continued

for products containing substantial amounts of copper, for certain
chemicals, and for some types of steel.

On the other hand, prices

of a wide variety of machinery and equipment, consumer hard goods,
and certain other chemicals had increased.

In agriculture, he

believed the prospect was for higher prices for pork, beef, and
poultry.
Mr. Scanlon noted that an informal survey of District
employers and reports from local Employment Service Offices
indicated continued shortages of readily usable workers, both
trained and inexperienced.

In fact, labor markets in some smaller

centers appeared to have tightened recently, and resembled the
larger centers more closely.

Steel ingot output was beginning to

drift lower following the earlier decline in orders.

But most

finishing mills in the area would continue to operate at practical
capacity through July.

Shipments also would be at a very high

rate in June and July, followed by an abrupt decline even if a
strike was averted.
Orders for equipment and equipment components had varied
greatly from product to product, Mr. Scanlon continued.

Over all,

there was little reason to anticipate more than a very gradual
uptrend for total equipment output in physical terms through the

-66

6/18/68
end of 1968.

Nevertheless, prices on the average were expected

to continue to rise at a 3 - 4 per cent annual rate.

District

residential construction continued at a high level, except in
Michigan where most building trades workers had been on strike
since early May.

Prices of existing homes offered for sale

appeared to be rising rapidly; the increase in the past year was
estimated at about 10 per cent.
Despite greater demands, the large District banks did not
appear to Mr. Scanlon to be unduly tight.

They had done very

little borrowing at the discount window and had reduced net
purchases of Federal funds, but Euro-dollar borrowings had risen
to new highs.

Negotiable CD's outstanding had declined about 15

per cent in the past three months but rates offered appeared
competitive in the current market.
Mr. Scanlon said he would like to see monetary policy
aimed in the direction of attainment of a modest growth in total
reserves.

However, he would be hesitant to change policy until

action had been taken with respect to the tax increase and
reduction in Government expenditures and the Committee had had
an opportunity to appraise the results.

For today, he favored

adoption of alternative A for the directive and he urged the
Committee to watch developments closely--either in the event of
fiscal action or in the event the bill failed to pass.

He believed

6/18/68

-67

it would be wrong for the record to show that the Committee had
tried to formulate monetary policy by speculating on the effects
of a bill whose passage was so uncertain.

If that required a

meeting in the interim before the next scheduled meeting, the
Committee should have one.
Mr. Clay remarked that the basic factors affecting the
economy domestically and internationally, and the problems with
which monetary policy was faced, remained essentially the same as
earlier.

The more immediate factor that might alter the role that

monetary policy would play in the weeks and months ahead was the
probable disposition of the Federal tax bill.

While that issue

was being decided--whether for part or all of the period until
the next meeting--the Committee should continue its restrictive
monetary policy, including the maintenance of firm monetary
conditions.

There now appeared to be a distinct possibility,

however, that the fate of the tax bill would be determined prior
to the next meeting of the Committee.

Thus, the System would

need to formulate monetary policy with the realization that the
fiscal measure probably would be either enacted or defeated in
that interval.
Assuming passage of the tax bill, Mr. Clay said, it could
be expected that interest rates in the money and capital markets
would respond by moving downward.

Considering that uncertainty

-68

6/18/68

concerning the tax bill had focused principally on the House of
Representatives, it might be that the reaction to the tax bill
passage would begin with a favorable vote in that chamber.

The

preferable approach on the part of the Committee would appear to
be that of awaiting developments in the money and capital markets
and of avoiding any overt move by the System to lead interest
rates downward.

However, an orderly decline in interest rates

should not be resisted.

That System policy stance would seem to

be appropriate until the next meeting of the Committee, at which
time a new assessment of the situation could be made.
There was, of course, the other possible contingency--namely,
defeat of the tax bill, Mr. Clay remarked.

That contingency might

be the more difficult one for which to formulate policy ahead of
time, granting the necessity of continuing a policy of strong
monetary restraint under those circumstances.

In fact, it might

become necessary to convene a special meeting of the Committee if
the tax bill was defeated.
Mr. Clay thought the targets of policy could be considered
to be within the general range of money market conditions specified
in the two paragraphs beginning on page 5 of the blue book.1/

1/

The paragraphs referred to read as follows:
"Current money market conditions would appear to encompass
a Federal funds rate generally in a 6 -- 6-1/4 per cent range,
net borrowed reserves in a $300 - $450 million range, and member
(Footnote continues at bottom of following page.)

-69-

6/18/68

However, special factors caused an abnormal degree of uncertainty
as to the variations that monetary variables might experience in
the period ahead.
Either alternative A or B of the directive drafts might
serve satisfactorily, Mr. Clay said.

However, alternative A

seemed to fit more closely the policy course he favored.
Mr. Heflin said that Fifth District business continued
to exhibit the same trends noted for the nation as a whole.
Manufacturers in the Richmond Bank's survey reported a strong

1/ (cont'd from previous page.)
bank borrowings averaging around $650 - $700 million. Pressures
in the aftermath of the mid-June tax date, any difficulties
banks might have in rolling over their very large Euro-dollar
holdings, and corporate need to pay $1 billion of additional
taxes within a short span of time after the tax bill is enacted
are all factors that would put pressure on the central money
market and hence may require net borrowed reserves more toward
the shallow end of the range if the Federal funds rate is not
to rise over the period ahead.
"Given this set of day-to-day financing costs and
pressure on bank reserve positions, the 3-month bill rate
can be expected to fluctuate within a 5-1/2 -- 5-7/8 per cent
range. The effect on investor and dealer expectations of a
favorable decision on taxes could accentuate any near-term
tendency for bill rates to decline and moderate any upward
pressure that might develop later. In the days immediately
ahead, the bill rate could move toward the lower end of the
range in reflection of reinvestment demand from holders of
maturing June tax bills not turned in for taxes; in addition,
the System is likely to be a sizable buyer for seasonal
reasons and also to offset the reserve impact of swap
repayments. But the odds suggest upward pressure on bill
rates later as the Treasury markets bills to meet its cash
need early in July, as businesses seek short-term funds to
make tax payments, and as investors tend to lengthen
portfolios."

-70

6/18/68

orders position and some step-up in inventory accumulation.
Further sizable increases in retail sales were also indicated,
with new automobile sales showing good gains throughout the
District.

Construction activity, however, appeared to be easing,

especially in the residential sector.
From the policy standpoint, Mr. Heflin was sure the
Committee was keenly aware that its problem over the near-term
future hinged heavily on Congressional action on the proposed
fiscal package.

While definitive action was expected within the

week, he believed the Committee should be prepared to cope with
the market impact of a further postponement of a vote.

In such

a case, it could be confronted with a significant backsliding in
the market, with rates moving once again into a range that might
induce considerable disintermediation and especially serious
problems for thrift institutions.

He would clearly favor resisting

any tendency for rates to move into that range.
He did not like to contemplate the question of the impact
on domestic and international financial markets if the conference
proposal failed of passage, Mr. Heflin remarked.

In such an

event, he believed the Desk could only be instructed to do
whatever it could to maintain orderly conditions in the market.
He was assuming, however--largely because it was a more attractive
assumption--that the conference proposal would pass, substantially

6/18/68

-71

in its present form.

In that case, it seemed to him that the

Committee had to face the question the Board staff had raised at
the last meeting--whether or not the Committee should move promptly
to relax credit policy.
Mr. Heflin said he could agree with the Board staff that
strict Administration implementation of the fiscal package, as
proposed, would represent a significant move in the direction of
fiscal restraint and that that, coupled with the current and
built-in credit restraint, might well turn the business advance
around in the course of the next four quarters.

But he was, in

the first place, rather skeptical as to the size of the cutbacks in
Government spending that would be realized.

The staff's estimates

of the magnitude of the turnaround in the high employment budget
could easily prove to be well over the mark.

Moreover, he would

be eager to avoid creating the impression abroad that the System
might be watering down the effects of the fiscal action through a
relaxation of credit that could prove premature.

At the moment,

the foreign problem remained sufficiently dangerous and the pay-off
of a premature easing sufficiently forbidding to warrant an error
on the side of too much restraint.

It was also reasonably clear

that, whatever the lags in monetary policy, an error on the
restrictive side could be redressed later on without unacceptably
great damage to the economy's performance in 1969.

For that

-72

6/18/68

reason, even assuming that the tax package became law, he would
prefer to hold off from any overt move toward less restraint.

He

would be prepared, however, to accept short-term rate declines
that might be associated with normal expectational reactions to
the fiscal move, even though that might produce 90-day bill rates
somewhat below the present discount rate.

He favored alternative

B of the draft directives.
Mr. Mitchell expressed the view that the Committee should
plan on meeting again two weeks from today to consider what
monetary policy was appropriate in light of the fiscal action he
assumed would have been taken by that time and in light of the
market's reaction.

If that was agreed he would favor alternative

A of the directive drafts.
However, Mr. Mitchell continued, if the Committee was not
prepared to schedule an interim meeting he would prefer alternative
B, with two amendments.

First, he thought the proviso clause in

the staff's draft would be clearer if the contingency involvedenactment of the proposed fiscal legislation--was stated explicitly.
For that purpose, he would insert after "provided, however" the
words "that if the proposed fiscal legislation is enacted..."

Secondly, he would favor adding the proviso relating to bank credit
that Mr. Swan had suggested.

However, alternative B was distinctly

his second choice; he would much prefer adopting alternative A
today and agreeing to hold an interim meeting.

-73

6/18/68

Mr. Daane said he had not attended the WP-3 meeting at
which Mr. Solomon had discussed U.S. monetary policy but from the
latter's report today he concluded that Mr. Solomon had struck
precisely the right note in emphasizing the need for flexibility.
The problem for monetary policy now was one of timing.

In light

of the various existing uncertainties, including those relating
to the fiscal package, he thought the Committee should not change
its policy today.

The System should not resist the market

reactions to enactment of the fiscal package; if, as he expected,
there were downward pressures on interest rates following fiscal
legislation, he would favor permitting rates to decline.

However,

he thought the System should not attempt to lead rates down.
Mr. Brill had referred to the risk of misleading the market
regarding the System's policy intentions if alternative C were
not adopted.

But he (Mr. Daane) thought adoption of that

alternative would risk misleading observers into believing that
the System was acting to offset fiscal restraint.

In his judgment

it would be better to await evidence of the effects of the fiscal
package, standing ready to move flexibly and quickly at the
appropriate time.

He thought the Committee could safely wait

until July 16--the tentative date for its next scheduled
meeting--before deciding whether monetary policy should be
changed, and that it was unlikely to have additional evidence,

-74

6/18/68

apart from the market's reaction to warrant a meeting at any date
much earlier than that.
In conclusion, Mr. Daane said he favored alternative A for
the directive.

As interpreted by the Manager, that directive

would be consistent with some fairly significant declines in rates
following fiscal legislation and then some fluctuations.
Mr. Maisel referred to Mr. Solomon's report regarding the
cautions offered at the recent WP-3 meeting against undue monetary

easing in the United States following fiscal action, and noted
that he had encountered a somewhat different view on his recent
European trip.

Several central bankers, while also suggesting

caution in monetary easing, had indicated that they would welcome
lower interest rates in the United States.

In their judgment

lower U.S. rates would reduce their internal problems of monetary
management and would lead to a better functioning international
monetary system.

It was also his impression that if the fiscal

package were adopted the Europeans would change their view of
what constituted "equilibrium" in the U.S. balance of payments,

because of the probable adverse effects on them of the type of
improvement in the U.S. trade accounts that would be needed to
reduce the over-all deficit below $2 or $3 billion.
Mr. Maisel said he would favor maintenance of current
monetary policy if action on the fiscal package was delayed.

If

-75

6/18/68

fiscal action was taken, however, he thought the Committee should
think in terms of the combined effects of fiscal and monetary
policies.

The degree of monetary restraint that had been effected

had been felt justified because needed fiscal restraint had not
been imposed.

If fiscal restraint was finally forthcoming, there

was no reason for the System to feel locked into the existing
degree of monetary restraint.

It was not proper, he thought, to

view monetary easing as "offsetting" fiscal tightening.

Rather,

it would represent a proper coordination of the two types of
policy.

The System had urged greater fiscal restraint to take

the place of monetary restraint.

It should now follow its own

advice by making certain that the current degree of monetary
restraint was not added to a package of fiscal restraint that

was greater than initially requested.
Finally, Mr. Maisel said, if the Committee concluded that
a reduction in U.S. interest rates would be appropriate once

fiscal action was taken, it should not permit such a reduction to
depend on the effects of market expectations, as called for by
alternative B of the draft directives.

In his judgment monetary

policy should not be dominated by expectations; if a rate decline

was desirable the System should take action itself to bring one
about.

Accordingly, he favored alternative C of the draft

directives, although he would add a bank credit proviso based on

6/18/68

-76

an expectation of an annual rate of expansion in bank credit in
the 3 to 6 per cent range in both June and July.
Mr. Brimmer said he thought it would be undesirable for
the Committee to decide on a change in policy today, two days
before the House was expected to vote on fiscal legislation.

He

was impressed by the apparent willingness of some members of the
Committee and staff to assume that the vote would be favorable.
While he also would like to be optimistic, the events of recent
months suggested that it was risky to count on enactment of the
measure.
Accordingly, Mr. Brimmer continued, he agreed with
Mr. Mitchell that the Committee should adopt alternative A for
the directive today and plan on holding an interim meeting in
two weeks.

If the consensus was against planning an interim

meeting, however, he would favor alternative B with the amendments
suggested by Messrs. Swan and Mitchell.
Mr. Brimmer thought an interim meeting would be desirable
whatever the outcome of the vote in Congress.

Failure of the bill

probably would result in financial market disturbances of a type
that could not be adequately dealt with simply by deciding today
to give the Manager more than the usual degree of leeway; an
interim meeting would be required to formulate specific instruc
tions for the Manager's guidance.

Such a meeting also would

-77

6/18/68

provide a useful forum for discussion of measures the Board might
take.

In his judgment there would be a need for emergency credit

facilities like those instituted in the summer of 1966 and perhaps
additional measures as well.
If the fiscal package was enacted, Mr. Brimmer said, the
Committee should meet in two weeks to decide on the appropriate
degree of monetary easing; in his view, such a decision should
not be put off until July 16.

It would be a mistake, he thought,

for the Committee to proceed on the assumption that the full $6
billion reduction in Government expenditures was not likely to be
made, as an earlier speaker had implied.

Rather, the Committee

should assume that the terms of the legislation would be carried
out in good faith by the Administration.

It would also be a

mistake to permit concern about "offsetting" the effect of fiscal
restraint to delay action.
was the wrong word.

Like Mr. Maisel, he thought "offsetting"

What would be involved was a change in the

fiscal-monetary policy mix, in which fiscal restraint substituted
for some degree of monetary restraint.

The System had acted

judiciously over the recent period in which it had applied
increasing monetary restraint, and it would be unfortunate if it
now followed a policy course that risked a recession.

In his

judgment, the combination of the proposed fiscal package and
existing monetary policy involved too much restraint as the

-78

6/18/68

economy moved through late 1968 and into 1969.

Rough estimates

by the staff suggested that such a combination of policies would
reduce the real growth of the economy in the first half of 1969
to a rate considerably below the 1.5 per cent projected to result
from a combination of fiscal restraint and moderate monetary
easing.

In his view the result would be a growth rate that was

too low.
Mr. Sherrill said he thought an interim meeting would be
desirable if the fiscal legislation failed to pass, but not
otherwise.

On close balance, he favored alternative A for the

directive, on the understanding that it would be interpreted as
the Manager had suggested.
Mr. Sherrill remarked that enactment of the fiscal package
would require a relaxation of monetary policy at some point, but
there was a difficult question of timing.

The long-range need

probably would remain that of restraining inflation.

In order to

achieve that objective it would be necessary to resolve the
underlying problems, one of which was a psychological problem
posed by the widespread view in the business community that
inflation was automatic.

The Committee should not encourage the

assumption that monetary restraint would be eased whenever fiscal
restraint was brought to bear.
In Mr. Sherrill's judgment the major argument in favor of
easing monetary policy at present was the need to sustain housing

6/18/68

-79

activity at acceptable levels, and there was some risk in that
connection in not moving toward ease.

He doubted, however, that

there would be a marked change in the willingness of thrift
institutions to supply mortgage funds so long as the pace of
inflows to such institutions continued about as at present.

The

prevailing high levels of mortgage interest rates in themselves
provided strong incentives to make mortgage loans, and the
prospect that those rates would decline some time after fiscal
action was taken would put the institutions under added pressure
to commit their funds to mortgages at present rates.
On the other hand, Mr. Sherrill said, if after some
initial decline bill rates started to rise as a result of Treasury
financing in July, a tendency for them to approach the upper end
of the 5-1/2 to 5-7/8 per cent range specified in the blue book
might create fears of disintermediation and lead thrift institu
tions to cut back on their mortgage commitments.

Accordingly,

while he favored alternative A for the directive, he would want
the Desk to resist increases in bill rates beyond the middle of
the range specified.
Mr. Hickman remarked that the step-up in inventory
investment and an expected improvement in net exports seemed to
assure that the second-quarter gain in GNP would be even larger
than that of the first quarter.

Looking ahead, with or without

-80

6/18/68

fiscal restraint a significant slowing of economic activity could
be expected in the second half, as temporary stimuli subsided and
as the lagged effects of monetary restraint took hold.

Near-term

moderation was suggested by the weakness of residential building
contracts and other leading business indicators.

Although the

labor market might ease somewhat, wage and cost pressures would
remain intense and profit margins would be squeezed.

The recent

slowdown in the rate of increase of industrial prices was probably
temporary, and upward pressures on consumer prices would
undoubtedly persist, reenforced by the resumption of the rise
in farm prices.
Mr. Hickman thought monetary policy recently had been
about right.

Until its next meeting, the Committee should try

to hold its ground and seek to maintain current money market
conditions as specified on page 5 of the blue book.

That would

include net borrowed reserves in a $300 to $450 million range,
borrowings averaging $650 - $700 million, a Federal funds rate in
a 6 to 6-1/4 per cent range, and the three-month bill rate within
a 5-1/2 to 5-7/8 per cent range.

As he understood it, that was

roughly the situation covered by the staff's alternative A.

He

would expect money market rates to move temporarily toward the
lower end of the indicated ranges, or even below them, in the
event of favorable fiscal legislation, and he would not resist

6/18/68

-81

such movements.

If Congress failed to enact a fiscal program in

the near future the market might become disorderly, and a special
meeting of the Committee probably would be necessary.

He would

also be willing to attend an interim meeting--say, on July 9--if
the fiscal program was enacted.

He doubted, however, that

significant new information on the real economy would be available
by that date, and accordingly he would prefer to have the next
meeting held on the scheduled date of July 16.
Mr. Bopp said that since the last meeting of the Committee
he had been reconsidering the question of the proper mix of
monetary and fiscal policy which the staff had raised in its
provocative chart presentation.

Assuming Congress passed a 10

per cent surcharge and a $6 billion cut in expenditures within
the next week or so, should monetary policy move promptly toward
less restraint?
The difficult question raised by the chart show, Mr. Bopp
continued, was the proper posture of monetary policy given the
outlook for the next few quarters and the lagged effects of both
monetary and fiscal action.

Insofar as current behavior of the

domestic economy was an indicator of the future, there was no case
for less restraint.
the U.S. economy.
tight.

Inflationary pressures continued to dominate
Demand was strong and rising and labor was

Conditions in the international economy certainly were

-82

6/18/68

not those which ordinarily called for less monetary restraint.
The balance of payments, and especially the balance of trade,
were still very unfavorable and the precarious state of sterling
and the French franc continued to threaten progress toward a more
viable international monetary system.
As he projected likely developments, Mr. Bopp remarked,
the strength of consumer demand suggested that inventories would
not act as a depressant during the second half.

Spending for

plant and equipment would be stronger than estimated earlier.
The flow of funds into mortgages might well be greater--although
at higher interest rates--and consequent reductions in home
building less than thought earlier.

Finally, he doubted whether

Federal Government spending actually would be cut by $6 billion
even if the pending bill passed.

Notwithstanding Mr. Brimmer's

comment, he thought judgments on that score were relevant to the
Committee's policy deliberations--although, of course, such
judgments might be wrong.
Therefore, Mr. Bopp said, taking a longer-run view, he
would be reluctant to move now toward less monetary restraint
simply to offset the proposed fiscal package.
calculated risk in that position, of course.

There was a
Given lags in its

effects, monetary policy might not be able to counteract an
overkill from fiscal action.

And in view of the social unrest

6/18/68

-83

that could develop from a significant increase in the unemployment
rate, that was a serious risk to take.

Nevertheless, he was

inclined to take that risk for both domestic and international
reasons.

However, he recognized the possibility that the Committee

might have to ease suddenly and decisively on short notice.

If

such action proved necessary, the even-keel requirements that would
prevail during most of the second half of the year might have to
be assigned lesser priority.
Although he would not favor moving in anticipation of the
tax bill, Mr. Bopp observed, he would not want to counteract the
more relaxed atmosphere likely to prevail in money and capital
markets if the bill was passed.

The Board's staff described a

continuation of recently prevailing conditions in the money market
as implying increases in the bank credit proxy at annual rates of
3 to 6 per cent in June and 1 to 4 per cent in July.

Although

that, too, suggested less restraint than in recent months, it
seemed to him appropriate and it would make action of an overt
nature easier if and when it should be needed.

That judgment was

consistent with alternative A of the directive drafts.
In conclusion, Mr. Bopp said he would favor holding an
interim Committee meeting if any member thought one was needed.
Mr. Kimbrel reported that the liquidity positions of
Sixth District member banks had begun to show more effects of the

-84

6/18/68

somewhat tighter policy the System had been following.

During

the first week in June District country banks as a group were in
a net borrowed reserve position for the first time this year,
although the reserve city banks had been in a net borrowed reserve
position for several months.

During the last half of May and so

far in June, borrowing by country banks had exceeded borrowing by
reserve city banks, measured both in dollar volume and in the
number of borrowing banks.

Then, of course, the tighter conditions

had been reflected in higher interest rates banks were charging
their customers.

The quarterly interest rate survey results for

May showed that new business loans made by the large reporting
banks bore an average rate of 6.6 per cent, compared with 6.3 per
cent in February.
Despite the broadening effects of the more restrictive
policy upon Sixth District member bank borrowing, it was hard for
Mr. Kimbrel to find much evidence of a major shift in the banks'
lending policies.

Borrowing did not seem to be a response to

widespread runoffs in deposits.

As a matter of fact, at District

banks in May both time and demand deposits increased on a
seasonally adjusted basis.

Large commercial banks in the District

had been able to hold on to their large denomination CD's fairly
well.

A decline during the first week of June, the first in eight

weeks, was accounted for almost entirely by a runoff at one bank.

6/18/68

-85

Seasonally adjusted loans in May were down slightly from April,
but in early June loans at the large banks advanced moderately.
In May, total investments at all member banks were up on a
seasonally adjusted basis.
Mr. Kimbrel commented that the latest indicators of
District economic conditions showed few effects of credit
restraint.

Manufacturing and nonmanufacturing employment

declined in April after seasonal adjustment.

Retail sales

dropped, and consumers borrowed less from banks.

However, those

figures reflected in part work stoppages and special circumstances.
He was told that preliminary indicators for May suggested the
April pause was temporary.
So far as the Sixth District was concerned, Mr. Kimbrel
was not convinced that monetary policy had been too restrictive.
There was always a danger in generalizing on the basis of limited
observation, but the national picture gave him the same impression.
Of course, Mr. Kimbrel said, he recognized that any effects
of monetary policy generally showed up only after some time lag.
It was the appreciation of a time lag, he supposed, that suggested
to some persons that the Committee should immediately ease
monetary policy following passage of legislation increasing
Federal taxes and reducing expenditures, lest it be guilty of
overkill.

There was, of course, much to be said for that point

6/18/68
of view.

-86
On the other hand, the best of economic forecasts and

projections had a certain amount of imprecision.

The Committee

hoped the fiscal package would help cool the overheated economy,
but it did not know how soon it would do so nor to what extent.
It seemed to Mr. Kimbrel, therefore, to be premature to
shift immediately towards an easier policy when the Committee had
observed neither the effects of its past policy on slowing down
inflationary developments nor the effects of a change in fiscal
policy.

Moreover, an immediate overt move toward ease could well

dissipate the hoped-for increase in confidence both at home and
abroad that the nation was getting its fiscal and monetary affairs
under control.

For those and other reasons, he favored alternative

A for the directive.
Mr. Francis commented that total demand for goods and
services continued to rise excessively, causing increased
inflationary pressures, further deterioration in the nation's
balance of payments, and misallocation of resources.

The green

book projection of demand for the third quarter seemed low to him
in view of recent policy actions and the current economic momentum.
Two of the basic causes of the excessive demands were the fiscal
actions of the Government and the rapid monetary growth.
Even if Congress passed a 10 per cent tax increase and a
$6 billion cut in spending soon, Mr. Francis said, the very rapid

-87

6/18/68

monetary expansion should be moderated to assure a more balanced
economic growth.

He suggested that the increase in the money

supply, which had been at a 7 per cent annual rate, be held to a
3 to 4 per cent range and that interest rates should be permitted
to seek their equilibrium level in response to changing market
forces.

Less expansionary fiscal actions would tend to make that

task easier, and the Committee should not lose the opportunity.
Mr. Francis noted that some comments this morning, as well
as the staff presentation at the Committee's last meeting,
indicated that passage of the pending fiscal package would cause
the level of interest rates to decline from current levels in the
near future.

In fact, that drop in interest rates had been

considered by some to be a necessity in the face of fiscal
restraint.

Over the past year the System had aggressively

advocated fiscal restraint as a necessity to rational stabiliza
tion policy.

Yet now that such restraint appeared likely, there

seemed to be growing fear of its destabilizing impact.
Mr. Francis did not .share those views.

It was his

conclusion that much of the impact of the tax-spending cut
package had been discounted in both prices and inventories by
market participants.

Those fiscal measures were generally

expected to be temporary, and thus much of the tax burden on
consumers would probably come from reduced saving and much of

6/18/68

-88

the burden on corporations would probably come from increased
borrowing, causing offsetting upward forces on interest rates.
The tax measure, because of its temporary nature, might actually
cause some acceleration of investment spending, to gain additional
benefit from depreciation in the early months.
Then, too, Mr. Francis continued, despite the Government's
fiscal actions, the recent excesses in the economy were apt to
continue to place upward pressure on interest rates for some
time.

Inflation would probably be present for a long time, and

expectations of higher prices would make borrowing attractive
because repayments were made in depreciated dollars.

Also,

business inventories were now low relative to sales in some lines
as a result of the surge in consumer spending; as they were
rebuilt, credit demands would strengthen.
Mr. Francis observed that there were risks of either
setting rates too high and unduly restraining activity or pushing
them too low and excessively stimulating the economy.

It appeared

to him that it would be more prudent for the System to expect and
allow continued high interest rates for a few months, even assuming
passage of the tax increase and spending cut.

The risks of such

an approach to the economy seemed to him to be less than those of
the opposite approach.

Higher rates would also be of some benefit

to the critical balance of payments situation.

Once the inflational

6/18/68

-89

psychology began to weaken, rates would decline and at that time
the System should not retard them.

However, prematurely to

anticipate a rate decline ahead of market forces could unduly
aggravate an already serious inflationary situation.
Mr. Francis' recommendation was to firm money market
pressures slightly during the next three weeks, assuming that
the surtax and spending cuts were implemented.

If they were not,

he would let short-term interest rates rise about one-half to a
full percentage point, and would recommend the appropriate
accompanying actions with regard to discount rates and Regulation (
Those actions would be taken with a view to moderating the very
rapid rate of monetary growth of the past sixteen months.
Mr. Francis preferred alternative A of the directive
drafts.
Mr. Robertson made the following statement:
One way or another, we have to deal with two key
policy questions today--what kind of monetary policy to
maintain until such time as the fiscal restraint package
is assured, and what kind to follow thereafter.
So long as fiscal-action remains a hope and not a
reality, I think we are best advised to hold our monetary
posture just about where it is. There can be no doubt we
still need this much restraint--major economic indicators
do not show any significant slowing of inflationary
pressures. At the same time, with the money market a
bit less taut than the extreme reached--partly through
inadvertence--in early May, we have a set of financial
conditions that stops short of generating major
distortions. In a nutshell, our current policy is
firm, but not too firm--and that is just where I want
to be right now.

6/18/68

-90-

Immediately ahead of us is the key House vote on
the fiscal package. I expect this to turn out favorably,
but I think the results should be in before we make any
policy adjustment. After affirmative action on the
fiscal side is actually in hand, then we can turn to
the welcome task of adapting our policy to deal with
an economy in which fiscal policy is acting as a brake
rather than an accelerator.
Even so, I think we ought to move cautiously. The
kind of fiscal restraint we are contemplating is a
mixture of fairly certain and highly uncertain elements.
The tax increase will come on stream promptly, but its
depressing effects on income are scheduled to last only
one year. The proposed spending cuts have to be regarded
as more problematical, since they probably have to take
place primarily in the first half of calendar 1969, by
which time they will have had to run the gauntlet of a
new Administration and Congress. In these circumstances,
I think the proper strategy for monetary policy is to
relax only gradually, making use of all available
governmental and market information to judge the
strength and timing of the actual fiscal bite into
economic activity.
A good way of doing this in the short run, I think,
is to allow the initial market appraisal of the fiscal
action to set the speed and extent of any rate declines
between now and our next meeting. That means to me that
the Trading Desk should follow along behind any declines
in the bill and other short-term rates, adjusting
operations enough to avoid exercising an upward tug
that might reverse the bill rate decline. I do not
regard this as abdicating to the market; rather, it
means we are making use of the market's appraisal to
set the first stage of our response, with the second
stage being a balanced reassessment of appropriate
interest rates and rates of money and credit growth at
our next meeting, when we will have the benefit of an
extra few weeks of perspective.
The most I would be willing to do in the way of an
overt System initiative in the interim would be to pull
back down the interest rate on repurchase agreements to
5-1/2 per cent. As you know, I saw more problems than
gains from the start in the experimental increase in
the repurchase rate above the discount rate, and I would
be glad to see it disappear. Furthermore, its reduction
on the heels of the tax bill passage would be a kind of

-91

6/18/68

mini-signal to the market that the worst of System
pressure is behind them.
With these views, I would be prepared to vote in
favor of directive alternative B as drafted by the staff
with the amendments suggested by Mr. Swan. I would, of
course, be agreeable to an earlier meeting of the
Committee, but I doubt we will have much information
available prior to the middle of July.
Chairman Martin said he would favor holding an interim
meeting of the Committee if the fiscal package was voted down.
He also would want such a meeting if the vote was postponed,
because further delays might produce problems in financial markets
nearly as serious as those that would result from a negative vote.
If the vote was favorable, however, he thought there would be
little purpose in meeting before July 16, partly because
relatively little new economic information would be available
before that date.
The Chairman then remarked that the Committee members did
not seem to be far apart today in their views on policy.

At the

outset of the meeting he had been prepared to vote for alternative
B for the directive.

However, he could accept alternative A--which

most members seemed to prefer--if it was interpreted as the
Manager had suggested.

The difference between the two alternatives

was not great, particularly if the bank credit proviso that
Mr. Swan had proposed was added to alternative B.
Mr. Maisel said he thought the choice between the two
alternatives would make relatively little difference if the

-92

6/18/68

Committee planned to hold an interim meeting.

If such a meeting

was not planned, however, the fact that alternative B took account
of the expected fiscal action, and A did not, seemed to him to
make a great deal of difference.
Mr. Brimmer agreed, noting that he had indicated earlier
that he would favor alternative B if the Committee did not plan
to hold an interim meeting.
Mr. Daane commented that he did not see much difference
between alternative A as interpreted by the Manager and alternativ
B if one was thinking about the expected declines in bill rates;
the Desk would not resist such declines under either alternative.
The real difference related to the Desk's reaction to any
subsequent reversal of the downward movement, which would be
resisted under B but not under A.

He gathered, however, that such

a reversal was not likely to occur until late in the period before
the Committee's next scheduled meeting.

Accordingly, he thought

there was little need for an interim meeting if the vote in
Congress was favorable.

He would favor such a meeting if the

fiscal package did not pass.
Mr. Mitchell agreed that there would be relatively little
new economic information for review at an interim meeting.

There

would, however, be information on the market's reaction to
enactment of the fiscal package.

As had been indicated, if the

-93

6/18/68

Committee adopted alternative A today and did not schedule an
interim meeting, the Desk would not resist any upward pressures
on bill rates that might occur in July.

That could lead to

problems, particularly since the Treasury would be engaged in a
financing operation then.
Chairman Martin remarked that prospective Treasury
financing was one reason he preferred alternative B.

While he

thought it would be reasonable for the Committee to decide today
to permit market forces to have some play in the coming period,
he would have some question about the desirability of meeting in
the midst of a Treasury financing to consider an overt change in
policy.

Also relevant was the fact that the Treasury would be

back in the market in late July in connection with its August
refunding.

While he favored alternative B, however, as he had

mentioned earlier he could accept alternative A.
Mr. Holmes referred to Mr. Sherrill's comment that it
would be undesirable to permit bill rates to rise to the upper
end of the range indicated in the blue book.

If alternative A

was adopted the Committee might want to consider whether the Desk
should be instructed to resist any such tendency.
Mr. Swan said he strongly preferred alternative B.

While

the difference between alternatives A and B was narrow if the
former was interpreted as suggested by the Manager, it was not at

-94

6/18/68

all evident from the language of A that such an interpretation
was intended.

Thus, adoption of A was likely to confuse readers

of the published record with respect to the Committee's intentions
Chairman Martin and Mr. Galusha expressed agreement with
Mr. Swan's observation.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that the choice between alternatives
A and B still seemed to him to depend on whether the Committee
planned to hold an interim meeting.

If not, he thought adoption

of alternative B was much the safer course.
Chairman Martin said that developments might well make it
desirable to hold an interim meeting.

He thought, however, the

Committee should act today on the assumptions that the fiscal
package would be passed and that there would be no need to meet
before July 16.

On that basis, he agreed that alternative B was

the better choice for the directive.
In reply to a question by Mr. Hickman, Mr. Holmes said
that under alternative A, unless the Committee instructed
otherwise, bill rates would be permitted to rise to the upper
limit of the 5-1/2 to 5-7/8 per cent range.

Under alternative B

the Desk would be given a mandate to resist increases in bill
rates after initial declines.
Mr. Hickman then said that while he continued to prefer
alternative A to B he would favor adopting an upper limit for the

-95

6/18/68

bill rate somewhat below 5-7/8 per cent since a rate that high
might well result in disintermediation.
Mr. Brimmer asked how probable the Manager thought it was
that there would be upward pressures on bill rates during the
Treasury financing, assuming that the fiscal package was enacted.
Mr. Holmes replied that some such pressures were likely,
but he could not say how strong they would be.

Large bill

purchases for System account probably would be needed to keep
net borrowed reserves in their recent range, and those purchases
would offer a major moderating influence on upward pressures.
Also, the Desk would normally resist bill rate increases if they
were sufficiently marked to affect the Treasury financing
adversely.
Mr. Daane commented that alternative B would be improved
if the bank credit proviso suggested by Mr. Swan were added, and
that B had an advantage over A
fiscal legislation.

in that it referred to the pending

However, while he could accept alternative B

he was still concerned about the possible implication that the
Committee was rushing to ease monetary policy immediately upon
enactment of the fiscal package.

He would be more inclined to

favor B if it were interpreted to call for cushioning any upward
movements in the bill rate rather than preventing them from
occurring.

6/18/68

-96
Chairman Martin repeated that he thought the members were

not particularly far apart in their policy views.

In his judgment

the references to "resisting" any bill rate increases that might
follow initial declines were generally intended to mean cushioning
rises rather than choking them off completely.
The Chairman then suggested that the Committee vote on a
directive with a first paragraph consisting of the staff's draft,
with the amendment to the final sentence Mr. Swan had suggested;
and a second paragraph consisting of alternative B, with amendments
to include the bank credit proviso proposed by Mr. Swan and the
additional phrase suggested by Mr. Mitchell.
Mr. Brill said he thought it would be desirable to clarify
the Committee's intent with respect to the bank credit projections
mentioned in the proposed additional proviso.

For alternative A,

the blue book projected bank credit growth at annual rates in the
ranges of 3 to 6 per cent in June and 1 to 4 per cent in July.
For B, however, the blue book said only that "bank credit
expansion in July would likely be toward the upper end of the
range indicated above, or larger...."

That language might be

taken to imply a projection of bank credit growth in July at a
rate ranging up to, perhaps, 6 per cent under alternative B.
Mr. Maisel remarked that he had had the need for such
clarification in mind when he had suggested earlier that the

-97-

6/18/68

Committee accept a range of 3 to 6 per cent as the expectation
for bank credit growth in both June and July.
Mr. Swan noted that he also had suggested acceptance of
such a projection for purposes of the proviso clause.
Chairman Martin commented that it was well that the point
had been clarified.
By unanimous vote, the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
was authorized and directed, until
otherwise directed by the Committee,
to execute transactions in the
System Account in accordance with
the following current economic
policy directive:
The information reviewed at this meeting indicates
that the very rapid increase in over-all economic
activity is being accompanied by persisting inflationary
pressures. Enactment of fiscal restraint measures now
under consideration in Congress, however, would be
expected to contribute to a considerable moderation of
the rate of advance in aggregate demands. Growth in
bank credit and time and savings deposits has been
relatively small on average in recent months, although
the money supply has expanded considerably as U.S.
Government deposits have declined. Both short- and
long-term interest rates have receded from the advanced
levels reached in May, mainly in reaction to enhanced
expectations of fiscal restraint. The U.S. foreign
trade balance and over-all payments position continue
to be a matter of serious concern. In this situation,
it is the policy of the Federal Open Market Committee
to foster financial conditions conducive to resistance
of inflationary pressures and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's balance of payments, while
taking account of the potential impact of developments
with respect to fiscal legislation.
To implement this policy, System open market
operations until the next meeting of the Committee

6/18/68

-98-

shall be conducted with a view to maintaining generally
firm but orderly conditions in the money market;
provided, however, that if the proposed fiscal legisla
tion is enacted operations shall accommodate tendencies
for short-term interest rates to decline in connection
with such affirmative congressional action on the
pending fiscal legislation so long as bank credit
expansion does not exceed current projections.
It was agreed that the next meeting of the Committee would
be held on July 16, 1968, at 9:30 a.m.

Chairman Martin noted that

as discussed earlier, a meeting would be called before that date
if developments suggested that that was desirable.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

ATTACHMENT A
June 17,

1968

Drafts of Current Economic Policy Directive for Consideration by th
Federal Open Market Committee at its Meeting on June 18, 1968

FIRST PARAGRAPH
The information reviewed at this meeting indicates that
the very rapid increase in over-all economic activity is being
accompanied by persisting inflationary pressures. Enactment of
fiscal restraint measures now under consideration in Congress,
however, would be expected to contribute to a considerable
moderation of the rate of advance in aggregate demands. Growth
in bank credit and time and savings deposits has been relatively
small on average in recent months, although the money supply has
expanded considerably as U.S. Government deposits have declined.
Both short- and long-term interest rates have receded from the
advanced levels reached in May, mainly in reaction to enhanced
expectations of fiscal restraint. The U.S. foreign trade balance
and over-all payments position continue to be a matter of serious
concern. In this situation, it is the policy of the Federal Open
Market Committee to foster financial conditions conducive to
resistance of inflationary pressures and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's balance of payments, while taking
account of the potential impact on financial markets of develop
ments with respect to fiscal legislation.
SECOND PARAGRAPH
Alternative A
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a
view to maintaining firm conditions in the money market; provided,
however, that operations shall be modified if bank credit appears
to be deviating significantly from current projections or if
unusual pressures should develop in financial markets.
Alternative B
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a
view to maintaining generally firm but orderly conditions in the
money market; provided, however, that operations shall accommodate
tendencies for short-term interest rates to decline in connection
with affirmative congressional action on pending fiscal legislation

-2
Alternative C
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a
view to maintaining generally firm but orderly conditions in the
money market; provided, however, that somewhat less firm money
market conditions shall be sought in the event of affirmative
congressional action on pending fiscal legislation.