View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

BOARD OF

GOVERNORS
OF THE

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
WASHINGTON

June 17, 1963.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL
TO:

Federal Open Market Committee

FROM:

Mr. Young

Attached for your information is a special memorandum
prepared by Mr. Coombs on the present position of the dollar.
It is being circulated for discussion at tomorrow's meeting of

the Federal Open Market Committee at Chairman Martin's request.

Ralph A. Young, Secretary,
Federal Open Market,dommittee.

Attachment

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
June 12, 1963.
To:

Chairman Martin and President Hayes

From:

C. A.

Subject:

Present Position of the Dollar

EC'D IN RECORDS SECTION

Coombs

Under the policy instructions of the U. S. Treasury and the
Federal Open Market Committee, the Foreign Function of the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York is charged with the operational responsibilities of (a)
keeping watch over the foreign exchange and other international financial
markets and (b) defending the dollar through exchange operations undertaken in consultation with foreign central banks.

In so doing, our trading

desk is in constant touch with developments in the European and New York
markets.

Each month at Basle, we confer with all of the major European

central banks at the Bank for International Settlements.

At these meetings

in Basle and elsewhere, we have negotiated the London Gold Pool arrangements, the Federal Reserve swap network, and the placement of Treasury

foreign currency bonds.

Sizable operations in both spot and forward ex-

change in defense of the dollar have been carefully coordinated with the
foreign central banks concerned through daily telephone communications.
From this vantage point of operational responsibility, we have
been reporting with mounting apprehension that the continuing deficits in
our balance of payments were progressively undermining the international
strength of the dollar.
phase.

In our judgment, we have now reached a critical

The dollar has become vulnerable to a break in confidence which

might occur almost without warning and with devastating consequences.

Such a loss of faith in the dollar has been so far staved off,
despite the ominous growth of our demand liabilities to foreigners and the
deep erosion of our gold stock, by several repetitions of the President's

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-2pledge on gold, by the modestly improving trend in our payments balance in
1961 and 1962, and by the reinforcement of the international financial
system in the form of increased IMF resources, our exchange operations
under the Federal Reserve swap network and other cooperative arrangements,
and U. S. Treasury issue of foreign currency bonds.
Full credence is still given to the President's pledge on gold.
But the balance of payments program designed to fulfill the pledge now
gives the impression of having become stalled while the deficit runs on at
a dangerously high rate.
of our currency defenses.

This has ominous implications for the strength
As originally conceived and agreed by all

governments and central banks concerned, the international credit facilities
available through the Federal Reserve swap network, the Treasury's foreign
currency bond issues, and the Fund, are designed to finance payments
deficits which can be reversed within a reasonable period of time.

The

central bank swap lines are intended to deal with essentially short-term
flows of funds expected to prove reversible in no more than a year's time.
The Treasury's foreign currency bond issues carry maturities so far of no
more than two years.

While drawings upon the IMF may run on from three

to five years, repayments by borrowing countries have generally been
effected in a much shorter span of time.
In the light of this general understanding of the nature and
function of these international credit facilities, the European central
banks would be prepared, either through an increase in swap lines or other
arrangements, to provide almost unlimited credit facilities to cope with
an emergency situation such as the Cuban crisis.

Similarly, the European

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-3central banks and governments would probably be prepared to accept very
sizable increases in our issues of foreign currency bonds or massive
United States drawings upon the Fund if our payments deficit seemed
attributable to a cyclical or similar problem likely to run its course
within a year or two.

But the European central banks and governments are

not prepared to finance chronic deficits in the United States balance of
payments over an indefinite period of time.
unmistakably

This attitude has been made

clear to United States officials, and we are in fact already

confronted with pressures by certain European financial officials to subject Federal Reserve swap drawings and Treasury issues of foreign currency
bonds, so far conducted on a bilateral basis, to the multilateral surveillance and approval of all of our European creditors.
There is here involved, as there has been for some time past, a
bargaining encounter between Europe as the creditor and the United States
as the debtor, as to which should bear the brunt of the corrective adjustments required.

Europe has placed a heavy stake on the integrity of the

dollar, and a United States refusal to take corrective action might conceivably force Europe to take up a larger share of mutual defense costs
and foreign aid or to extend other concessions.

A more likely outcome,

however, is that the European countries would finance our deficits for
some time further, but with increasing reluctance, with stiffer terms, and
with prejudice to United States prestige and influence abroad.
Moreover, by insisting upon such unwilling financing by Europe,
the United States would simply dig still deeper the hole in which we are
now stuck.

Piling up further debt to finance further heavy deficits would

only make the task of eventually restoring equilibrium correspondingly

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-4harder.

Such debts, whether incurred under

central bank swaps, Treasury

foreign currency bonds, or Fund drawings, must sooner or later be repaid.
This would require corrective action drastic enough to produce a surplus
rather than just a balance in our payments accounts.

Meanwhile, we should

have dissipated during reasonably fair weather the credit resources we
must have to survive the speculative storms.

Perhaps most unfortunate of

all, abuse of the present network of credit facilities would blight the
highly promising prospect that such credit facilities may in good time contribute a large part to a permanent solution to the problem of international
liquidity.

It is no answer to these financing problems to suggest sweeping

reforms of the international financial system based upon a United States
gold guarantee of its dollar liabilities.
to abroad as "instant gold", are

Such schemes, cynically referred

non negotiable not only in the short run but

probably even in the longer run, and meanwhile serve only to cast discredit
on the dollar.

Comments by two European central bank governors on gold

guarantee schemes may be cited:
"If the United States should show any official interest in
the Triffin, Maudling, or other gold guarantee schemes, we would
conclude that your balance of payments was out of control.......
"Resort to gold guarantees is the last resort of a poor
debtor."
This impending crisis in financing United States payments deficits
has so far gone largely unnoticed by the foreign exchange markets which

have been impressed almost to the point of complacency by the success of
central bank cooperation in beating back the speculative challenges of
the German mark revaluation, the Berlin crisis, the Canadian devaluation,

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-5the world-wide stock market break, and the Cuban crisis.

Such demonstra-

tions of central bank cooperation, plus the massive piling up of official
ammunition against speculation, have persuaded the exchange markets that
for the time being speculation against any major currency parity would be
a losing game.
But it would be foolhardy to imagine that we can long maintain
this disparity between the surface calm of the exchange markets and the
turbulent undercurrents being generated by a continuation of heavy United
States payments deficits which Europe is reluctant to finance.

And it

would be even more foolhardy to assume that market expectations will adjust

only gradually to the underlying deterioration in our balance of payments
position and thereby leave us ample time to make the policy adjustments
required.

Experience rather suggests that market expectations will shift

abruptly, perhaps explosively, and confront us with the necessity of far
more drastic action than the moderate corrective measures which would now
suffice.
The nature of a speculative run on the dollar would partly
depend on the event which triggered the break in confidence.

While we

are in a sense at the mercy of any massive conversion of dollars into gold
by the Bank of France, the Bundesbank, the Bank of Italy, or other
European central banks, we would feel reasonably confident that none of

these central banks will take action along these lines either from
hostility or from panic.

More likely is the prospect of stiffer resistance

by these banks to our requests for credit accommodation plus the initiation
or stepping up of gold purchases on a regular but moderate scale.

More

dangerous is the risk that the smaller countries of Europe, Latin America,

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-6Africa, and Asia would be panicked, as they were in the closing months of

1960, into gold purchases aggregating a very sizable amount.

Even more

dangerous, private demand for gold on the London gold market might abruptly
snowball to such proportions as to overwhelm the $300 million in gold available to the Gold Pool.

You will recall that the Pool lost $45 million in

only two days following the Cuban crisis.

Perhaps most dangerous of all is

the risk that the Russians--and possibly even some of our allies who favor
a higher gold price--might through various maneuvers try to push us over the
cliff of a dollar devaluation.

Whether through technical naivete or an

excess of caution, the Russians have so far not only failed to exert pressure
on the dollar during periods of strain but have, with almost uncanny timing,
made heavy sales of gold just when we needed it most.

But it would be

imprudent to assume the Russians will continue to be so cooperative in the
international financial arena.
There is very little new to be said about the policy decisions required to bring about an approximate balance in our payments accounts.
Reviewing the main factors governing our trade and current account surplus,
we are inclined to think that we must work very hard indeed even to maintain

our present surplus, and that it would be imprudent to count upon a substantial
growth of this surplus to finance our heavy burdens
foreign aid, and military spending abroad.

of foreign investment,

The solution therefore lies

primarily in cutting back such payments on investment, foreign aid,

and

military account, and in encouraging the repatriation of short-term capital
that has moved abroad in large volume in recent years.
We obviously can make no effective judgment as to where economies

can safely be effected in either military spending or foreign aid.

But we

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-7can and do make the judgment that the full burden of the adjustment cannot
be forced on the private capital sector alone.
On capital account, the outflow since 1959 may be broken down
into the following major categories:
U. S. Capital Outflow - 1959-62
(in billions of dollars)

A.

B.

C.

1959

1960

1961

1962

Long term
1.

Direct

- 1.4

- 1.7

- 1.5

- 1.4

2.

Portfolio

- 0.6

- 0.7

- 0.8

- 1.0

3.

Other

- 0.3

- 0.2

- 0.3

- 0.2

Short term

- 2.3

- 2.6

- 2.6

- 2.6

1.

Bank lending

+ 0.1

- 0.7

- 1.0

- 0.3

2.

Other

-

0.2

- 0.7

- 0.5

- 0.2

-

0.1

- 1.4

- 1.5

- 0.5

+ 0.4

- 0.6

- 0.6

- 1.0

+ 0.3

- 2.0

- 2.1

- 1.5

Errors and
omissions

B. plus C.

With respect to direct investment by United States industry in
plant and equipment abroad, such investment in long-term foreign assets will
eventually bring a heavy return flow of dividend and other earnings.

Mean-

while, however, so heavy a buildup of long-term corporate investment abroad
is straining our international liquidity position.

Among the various policy

measures which might be employed to slow down the pace of such direct
investment, there may be some room for officially urging United States
corporations investing abroad to rely more heavily upon foreign sources of

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-8financing rather than channeling capital funds from the head office to the
foreign subsidiary.

Less easy credit conditions in the United States might

also induce some shift of the burden of financing such direct investment
to foreign financial markets.

But any effort to impose direct govern-

mental controls upon direct investment abroad would have a shattering
effect upon business confidence both here and abroad, while the problem of
managing such controls would be an administrative nightmare.
With respect to portfolio

investment abroad, the outflow of $1

billion registered in 1962 may well move up to a considerably higher figure
in 1963.

The heavy volume of such foreign issues in this market reflects

not only the comparatively low level of long rates here but probably even
more importantly the limited availability of long-term capital funds in
other markets.

While some moderate reduction of such foreign long-term

borrowing in our market might be accomplished by a moderate rise of longterm rates, a major curtailment in this type of capital outflow through
credit restraint would probably require rate increases so drastic as to
seriously threaten domestic economic expansion.

Moreover, much depends upon

the nature and purpose of such foreign flotations in our capital market.

In

the case of most Western European borrowers, such flotations have further
enriched their central bank's dollar surplus position and thereby presented
us with the absurd contingency that the U. S. Treasury might have to finance
such foreign borrowing by transfers of gold.

Secretary Dillon's Rome speech

in May 1962 served to discourage European borrowing in this market and the
Secretary's recent suggestion that United States underwriters should actively
encourage foreign subscription to new foreign issues in this market also
seems likely to have a useful effect.

On the other hand, the recent heavy

issues in this market by Canadian governmental and corporate entities may

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-9hardly more than suffice to finance Canada's current account deficit with
the United States,

Even if such borrowing should result in increases in

the Bank of Canada's reserves, there is relatively little risk that these
reserve increases will be converted into gold.

Some United States officials

have urged that official controls over such foreign security issues would
be preferable to other alternatives, such as cuts in military and economic
aid spending abroad.

In our judgment, however, introduction of controls

would involve a highly dangerous gamble with foreign confidence in the
dollar.

A somewhat less risky approach, if action to restrain foreign

security issues in this market should be deemed essential, would be to
encourage early reporting of foreign governmental issues in this market.
At the present moment, we become informed of prospective foreign government borrowing operations in this market only after our underwriters have
entered into negotiations with the foreign government concerned and, on
numerous occasions, only after the deal has pretty well jelled.

Such delayed

reporting has on occasion handicapped our efforts to avoid an undue bunching
up of such issues.
While possibilities of effectively reducing long-term capital
outflows may thus be fairly closely limited, the chances of effecting
sizeable reductions in short-term outflows or encouraging inflows are much
more promising.

From 1960 through 1962 total short-term outflows (including

here in this category for rough-estimate purposes the "errors and omissions"
item although some part of this item is attributable to other causes) have
amounted to $5.6 billion.

In 1962 recorded short-term outflows, plus the

errors and omissions item, amounted to $1.5 billion.

This total represented

a significant decline from the 1961 total of $2.1 billion and probably partly
reflects the two-way squeeze of some declines in short rates abroad and

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-10some modest rise in snort rates in this market.

In our

judgment, it is

unlikely that we shall see during 1963 any further declines of short rates
in the major financial centers abroad;

in fact, we already see evidence

of a renewed firming of these rates as foreign central banks struggle to
control an inflationary trend of prices and wages.
In the absence of a shift of Federal Reserve credit policy towards
lesser ease, the combination of greater liquidity and low rates relatively
in the United States as compared with foreign financial centers will probably
continue to generate sizeable outflows of short-term funds in the form of
bank lending, acceptance financing, and short-term investment.

Even more

serious, there are ominous indications that United States corporate
treasurers are becoming increasingly aware of investment opportunities in
the so-called "Euro-dollar market" where 90-day rates have been fluctuating
around the 3-3/4 per cent level, as compared with our Treasury bill rate
of roughly 3 per cent.

During the past three years, U. S. corporations have

steadily increased their U. S. dollar time deposits with Canadian banks
operating in the Euro-dollar market with the latest reported total
approaching $500 million, while unreported placements with other foreign
banks might well amount to several hundred million dollars more.

So long

as a sizeable differential between rates in the United States and the Eurodollar market remains, there is a great risk that U. S. corporate placements
in the Euro-dollar market will continue to grow rapidly and, in the process,
shift dollars into the hands of foreigners and thereby enlarge the deficit.
Any weakening of confidence in the dollar would result in heavy additional
outflows in the form of speculative "leads and lags" in commercial and other
payments.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020

-11The disparity between credit conditions in New York and foreign
financial centers has adversely affected not only our balance of payments
accounts but also the willingness of foreign commercial banks and other
foreign private holders of dollars to leave their money in New York.
Foreign commercial banks and other private holders of dollars have open
to them a range of alternative uses for such dollar funds as they may
acquire and if, in the process of shifting these funds out of New York, the
dollars involved are sold to foreign central banks, the United States
becomes exposed to the risk of central bank conversions of such dollars
into gold.

Action has already been taken to provide an inducement to foreign

central banks to hold dollars on deposit in New York by exempting such central
bank time deposits from the Regulation

Q ceiling. Foreign central bank

decisions whether or not to convert dollars into gold are relatively
insensitive to interest rate considerations, however, while foreign commercial banks and other private lenders are acutely sensitive to relative
interest rate levels here and abroad in allocating funds to one market
rather than another.

At the present moment, neither the U. S. Treasury bill

rate nor the maximum of 2-1/2 per cent allowable on 90-day time deposit
placements under Regulation

Q permit the New York financial community to

keep a solid grip on foreign private balances.

So far this year there has

been a substantial rise in foreign private dollar holdings, but this appears
to be mainly the result of an increase in the liabilities of American banks
to their branches abroad, probably reflecting Euro-dollar market activity.
Foreign private holdings of time deposits and U. S. Government securities,
on the other hand, have not risen at all,

Even a slight tightening of

credit markets abroad tends to bring about sizeable repatriations of dollar

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-12short-term investments, with the efiedt of further increasing the dollar
reserves of the foreign central bank concerned.
In our judgment, a moderate tightening of credit policy involving
an increase in the Federal Reserve discount rate to 3-1/2 per cent, a contraction of free reserves sufficient to push the Treasury bill rate up close
to the 3-1/2 per cent level, and an adjustment upward of the Regulation

Q

ceiling on 90-day deposits to at least 3-1/2 per cent, would have a major
effect on the short-term capital balance.

We believe that New York com-

mercial banks tend to give preference to domestic as compared with foreign
customers, and that the tightening of bank liquidity positions would have
a stronger restraining effect upon foreign than upon domestic lending.

A

rise of Treasury bill and time deposit rates to a 3-1/2 per cent level
probably would not be fully matched by a sympathetic rise in the Euro-dollar
rate, with consequent restraint upon United States corporate deposits in
that market.

Moreover, the level of the Euro-dollar rate is heavily

dependent upon policy decisions of several foreign central banks which have
in the past alternately encouraged and discouraged borrowing by their commercial banks in the Euro-dollar market.

We have some hope that these

foreign central banks might be willing, at least temporarily, to restrain
borrowing activities by their commercial banks in the Euro-dollar market
with consequent lessening of any upward pressures on the rate.
A tightening of credit policy would not only have a restraining
effect upon the outflow of short-term capital, but might well enable us to
exploit a favorable technical position.

The heavy outflow of short-term

funds in recent years has had as its counterpart the emergence of a sizeable
short position in dollars on the exchange markets.

A contraction in the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 3/17/2020
-13availability of short-term credit from United States lenders or investors
should therefore generate a sizeable, and perhaps very substantial, demand
for dollars, with consequent beneficial effects on the rate of the dollar
against most European currencies.

Such buying pressure on the dollar would,

after a certain point, induce the European central banks to feed dollars
into the market from their exchange reserves or, in the case of high gold
ratio countries, to resell gold to the United States.

Most Continental

European central banks would welcome such a running down in their dollar
holdings and even in their gold holdings.

Finally, action of the type

suggested above would have a most salutary effect upon foreign confidence
in the dollar and might bring about further sizeable return flows of funds
to this country as the "leads and lags" reversed themselves.
Such credit policy action by the Federal Reserve would, of course,
be largely frustrated if the Continental European central banks were to
make corresponding and competitive adjustments in their own policies.

We

have strong reason to believe, however, that the Continental European banks,
who have long urged such a tightening of credit policy by the Federal
Reserve, would not do so.

On the other hand, even a moderate tightening of

credit policy in the United States might put some pressure on the British
and Canadian markets, and the Bank of England and the Bank of Canada might
find themselves compelled to take action in line with ours.

If so, this

would represent a much needed strengthening of the international financial

position of all three countries vis-a-vis the Continent and would help to
restore a generally improved balance
markets.

in the international financial