View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Prefatory Note
The attached document represents the most complete and accurate version available
based on original files from the FOMC Secretariat at the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Please note that some material may have been redacted from this document if that
material was received on a confidential basis. Redacted material is indicated by
occasional gaps in the text or by gray boxes around non-text content. All redacted
passages are exempt from disclosure under applicable provisions of the Freedom of
Information Act.

Content last modified 1/12/2024.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Report to the FOMC
on Economic Conditions
and Monetary Policy

Book A
Economic and Financial Conditions:
Outlook, Risks, and Policy Strategies
June 1, 2018

Prepared for the Federal Open Market Committee
by the staff of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Domestic Economic Developments and Outlook
The economy continues to expand at an above-trend pace. We judge that the
economy is currently operating somewhat above its sustainable level and will move
further beyond this level over the medium term; we expect inflation will run close to
2 percent on a sustained basis over the medium term.
In the labor market, payroll employment gains in April and May averaged
191,000 per month, substantially above the pace we estimate to be consistent with no
change in resource utilization. During the same period, the unemployment rate fell to
3.9 percent in April and then further to 3.8 percent in May after having held steady at
4.1 percent over the previous six months. Meanwhile, the incoming spending data led us
to revise up our projection for real GDP growth in the first half of this year by
½ percentage point to an annual rate of 2¾ percent.
Our projection that the economy will expand at an above-trend pace over the
medium term reflects the influence of expansionary fiscal policy and solid foreign
growth. We forecast that real GDP growth will slow from 2¾ percent this year to
1¾ percent in 2020 as monetary policy continues to tighten. The projected average pace
of growth over the next three years is a little less than in the April Tealbook, primarily in
response to the higher exchange value of the dollar in this projection; we have also
assumed that supply constraints will hold back GDP growth a bit more than in the
previous Tealbook. Even so, by the end of the medium term, real output is projected to
be 3 percent above our estimate of its potential. Correspondingly, the unemployment rate
is expected to be 3.4 percent at the end of 2020, 0.1 percentage point higher than in our
previous projection but nonetheless about 1¼ percentage points below our estimate of its
natural rate.
Consumer price inflation has moved up from the low readings seen last year.
Core PCE prices rose 1.8 percent over the 12 months ending in April, and we expect the
12-month change to edge up to 2 percent this summer. Core inflation is projected to rise
to 2 percent in 2019 and to 2.1 percent by 2020 as resource utilization tightens further
and underlying inflation inches up. Total PCE prices are expected to increase 2.1 percent
this year, a little more than core prices, boosted by an increase in energy prices. After
this year, total inflation—at 1.9 percent in 2019 and 2.0 percent in 2020—is restrained a

Page 1 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Comparing the Staff Projection with Other Forecasts
The staff’s projection for real GDP growth in 2018 is the same as the projections
from both the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) and the Blue Chip consensus
and a touch higher than the Blue Chip in 2019. The staff’s unemployment rate forecast
is 0.1 to 0.2 percentage point below the outside forecasts in both 2018 and 2019. The
staff’s projections for total CPI inflation in 2018 is a touch higher than the outside
forecasts and the same as the outside forecasts for 2019. The staff forecasts for total
and core PCE inflation are the same or lower than the forecasts from the SPF.

Comparison of Tealbook and Outside Forecasts
2018

2019

2.8
2.8
2.8

2.4
2.3
n.a.

Unemployment rate (Q4 level)
June Tealbook
Blue Chip (05/10/18)
SPF median (05/11/18)

3.6
3.7
3.8

3.4
3.6
n.a.

CPI inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
June Tealbook
Blue Chip (05/10/18)
SPF median (05/11/18)

2.6
2.5
2.5

2.2
2.2
2.2

PCE price inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
June Tealbook
SPF median (05/11/18)

2.1
2.1

1.9
2.1

Core PCE price inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
June Tealbook
SPF median (05/11/18)

1.9
2.2

2.0
2.1

GDP (Q4/Q4 percent change)
June Tealbook
Blue Chip (05/10/18)
SPF median (05/11/18)

Note: SPF is the Survey of Professional Forecasters, CPI is the consumer price index,
and PCE is personal consumption expenditures. Blue Chip does not provide results for
overall and core PCE price inflation. The Blue Chip consensus forecast includes input from
about 50 panelists, and the SPF about 40. Roughly 20 panelists contribute to both surveys.
Source: Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Page 2 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Tealbook Forecast Compared with Blue Chip
Real GDP

Industrial Production
Percent change, annual rate

Blue Chip consensus
Staff forecast

Percent change, annual rate

10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

-8

2011

Unemployment Rate

2013

2015

2017

2019

12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12

Consumer Price Index
Percent

Percent change, annual rate

10

8

9

6

8

4
2

7

0
6
-2
5

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

-4

4

-6

3

-8

2

2011

Treasury Bill Rate

2013

2015

2017

2019

-10

10-Year Treasury Yield
Percent

Percent

4

5.5
5.0

3

4.5
4.0

2

3.5
3.0

1

2.5
2.0

0

1.5
2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

-1

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

Note: The yield is for on-the-run Treasury securities. Over
the forecast period, the staff’s projected yield is assumed
to be 15 basis points below the off-the-run yield.
Note: The shaded area represents the area between the Blue Chip top 10 and bottom 10 averages.

Page 3 of 132

1.0

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Revisions to the Staff Projection since the Previous SEP
The FOMC most recently published its Summary of Economic Projections, or SEP, following
the March FOMC meeting. The table below compares the staff’s current economic
projection with the one we presented in the March Tealbook.
Incoming data for GDP growth have been a little stronger than our expectations in the
March Tealbook, while data on the labor market have been mixed, with a lower
unemployment rate but also slower payroll growth on average. Our projection for real
activity over the medium term has been revised down, reflecting somewhat weaker financial
conditions (a stronger dollar and lower equity prices) as well as the small rethinks that we
built into the current Tealbook regarding both supply constraints and consumer spending
from the recent tax cuts. Thus, resource utilization, as measured by the unemployment gap
or the output gap, is somewhat less tight in this projection than in the March Tealbook.
Our projection for headline inflation in 2018 is revised up a bit relative to the March
Tealbook, reflecting the rise in oil prices in recent months. We continue to expect core
inflation to edge up in coming years but by slightly less than we projected in March, given
the revisions to resource utilization and the dollar. We now project core inflation to be just
slightly above 2 percent, and headline inflation to be at 2 percent, by 2020.
With the projections for both resource utilization and inflation weaker than in the March
Tealbook, the federal funds rate path from the inertial Taylor (1999) rule that we use in our
baseline forecast now rises less steeply than in March.
Staff Economic Proj ections Compared with the March Tealbook
20 18
Variable

2017
Hl

I

2018

2019

2020

Longer run

H2

Real GDP 1
March Tea lbook

2.6
2.6

2.8
2.6

2.7
3.3

2.8
2.9

2.4
2.6

1.8
2. 1

1.7
I. 7

Unemployment rate2
March Tea lbook

4.1
4.1

3.8
3.9

3.6
3.5

3.6
3.5

3.4
3. 1

3.4
3. 1

4.7
4.7

PCE inflation 1
March Tealbook

I. 7
1.7

2.3
2.0

1.8
1.6

2. 1
1.8

1.9
2.0

2.0
2.1

2.0
2 .0

Core PCE inflation 1
March Tca lbook

1.5
1.5

2. 1
2. 1

1.7
1.8

1.9
1.9

2.0
2. 1

2.1
2.2

n.a.
n.a.

Federal funds rate 2
March Tealbook

1.20
1.20

1.74
1. 84

2.52
2.66

2.52
2.66

3.78
4.0 1

4.54
4.96

2.50
2.50

Memo:
Federal funds rate,
end of period
March Tealbook

1.38
1.38

1.77
1. 87

2.54
2.69

2.54
2.69

3.80
4.04

4.55
4.98

2.50
2.50

Output gap 2,3
March Tealbook

1.4
1.4

1.9
1.9

2.5
2.7

2.5
2.7

3.0
3.5

2.9
3.6

n.a.
n.a.

I. Percent change from final quarter of preceding period to final quarter of pe riod indicated.
2. Percent, fina l quarter of period indicated.
3. Percent difference between actual and potentia l. A negative number indicates that the economy is operating be low potential.
n.a. Not available.

Page 4 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

bit by declining energy prices. Our forecast for total PCE inflation is the same as in the
April Tealbook. Finally, as in recent Tealbooks, we have not incorporated any effects on
either real activity or inflation from higher import tariffs. 1

KEY BACKGROUND FACTORS
Fiscal Policy
•

We estimate that discretionary policy actions across all levels of government
will boost aggregate demand growth ½ percentage point in 2018,
¾ percentage point in 2019, and ½ percentage point in 2020, exclusive of
multiplier effects and offsets from reactions in interest rates and the dollar.
Roughly one-half of that medium-term impetus is due to the recent federal tax
cuts, while about one-fourth reflects the recent federal spending legislation;
most of the remainder is due to projected increases in real state and local
government expenditures. 2

•

The federal deficit is projected to rise from 3½ percent of GDP in fiscal year
2017 to 5½ percent in fiscal 2020—well above its sustainable level—with this
increase primarily reflecting the effects of the recent tax and spending bills.
o We continue to assume that in the longer term, policymakers will enact
deficit reduction measures that gradually stabilize the debt-to-GDP ratio.

Monetary Policy
•

The inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule that we use in our projection
calls for the federal funds rate to increase 1¼ percentage points in total this
year and to rise about 1 percentage point per year, on average, over the next
two years, reaching 4½ percent in the fourth quarter of 2020. This trajectory
is slightly flatter than in the April Tealbook, reflecting somewhat lower

We estimate that the effects of the steel and aluminum tariffs, in isolation, will be minimal for
both net exports and prices. Other potential tariff changes remain highly uncertain at this point and are
therefore not included in our projection.
2
Under current law, the federal spending caps decline in fiscal year 2020, reverting back to the
levels set in the Budget Control Act of 2011. Since fiscal 2012, however, policymakers have consistently
set actual appropriations above the caps. Consequently, we assume that federal appropriations will remain
constant in real terms in fiscal 2020 rather than falling back to the caps.
1

Page 5 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Key Background Factors underlying the Baseline Staff Projection

Federal Funds Rate

Long-Term Interest Rates
Percent

Percent

6

Quarterly average

11

Quarterly average
10
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

5

9

Conforming
mortgage rate
4

8

Triple-B
corporate yield

7

3

6
5

2

4

1

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

3

10-year
Treasury yield

0

2008

2010

2
2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

1

House Prices

Equity Prices

Ratio scale, 2007:Q1 = 100

Ratio scale, 2007:Q1 = 100 215
214
200
185
170
155
140

Quarter-end

Dow Jones
U.S. Total Stock Market
Index

Quarterly

120
115
110
105

125

100

110

95
90

95
CoreLogic
Index

80

85
80
75

65

70
2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

50

2008

Crude Oil Prices

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

65

Broad Real Dollar
Dollars per barrel

2007:Q1 = 100

140

115

Quarterly average

Quarterly average
Imported oil

110

120

105
100
100
West Texas
Intermediate

80
95
60
90
40

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

85

20

2008

Page 6 of 132

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

80

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

projected inflation in the near term and a narrower output gap over the
medium term.
•

The size of the SOMA portfolio continues a gradual and predictable decline as
securities are redeemed in a manner consistent with the Committee’s June
2017 Addendum to the Policy Normalization Principles and Plans and with
the process initiated in October 2017.

Other Interest Rates
•

The 10-year Treasury yield is projected to rise significantly over the medium
term from an average of about 3 percent in the current quarter to 4¼ percent
by the end of 2020. Relative to the April Tealbook, the projected yield
beyond the current quarter is revised down a bit, reflecting the slightly flatter
trajectory for the federal funds rate.

•

The 30-year fixed mortgage rate and the triple-B corporate bond yield are also
forecast to rise significantly over the medium term. The mortgage rate path is
revised in line with revisions to the path of the 10-year Treasury yield. TripleB corporate bond yields are revised down more than 10-year Treasury yields
because we now judge that the strong economic outlook results in a lower
path for credit spreads than previously assumed.

Equity Prices and Home Prices
•

Equity prices are projected to end the current quarter about ½ percent higher
than in the April Tealbook forecast, reflecting recent increases in broad equity
price indexes. Beyond the current quarter, we project stock prices to rise at an
average annual rate of around ¾ percent, similar to our previous projection.

•

We expect annual house price growth to slow from 6 percent last year to
5¼ percent this year. The projected growth in house prices this year is
slightly faster than in the April Tealbook, reflecting our response to a strong
first-quarter reading, which suggests the slowdown in house prices we have
been expecting has not yet begun to materialize. Still, we continue to expect
house price increases to moderate to a 3½ percent pace in 2019 and 2020,
reflecting both the projected rise in mortgage rates and our assessment that
house prices are modestly elevated compared with rents.

Page 7 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Foreign Economic Activity and the Dollar
•

Real GDP growth in the foreign economies is estimated to have picked up to
an annual rate of 3¼ percent in the first quarter. This reading is a bit faster
than projected in the April Tealbook, as weaker-than-expected growth in the
advanced foreign economies was more than offset by unusually strong growth
in some emerging Asian economies. Growth abroad is projected to moderate
to around 2¾ percent in the second quarter and to remain at roughly that pace
over the rest of the forecast period. The rise in financial stresses in Italy due
to political developments, a tightening of financial conditions in some
emerging market economies (EMEs), and—for net oil importers—the increase
in oil prices led us to revise down our forecast a touch. Moreover,
developments in Europe and EMEs have significantly increased downside
risks to our outlook.

•

Since the April Tealbook, the broad nominal dollar has appreciated about
4 percent amid heightened downside risks to foreign growth and increased
safe-haven demand for dollar assets. We expect the broad real dollar to
appreciate at an annual rate of about 1¾ percent through the forecast period as
market expectations for the federal funds rate move up toward the staff
forecast. Reflecting the recent appreciation, the real dollar at the end of the
forecast horizon is about 3¾ percent higher than in the April Tealbook.

Oil and Commodity Prices
•

The spot price of Brent crude oil has risen about $4 per barrel on net since the
April Tealbook, closing May 30, around $78 per barrel. Futures prices for
December 2020 have increased more, rising $7 to roughly $68 per barrel. The
rise in futures prices is consistent with the continued collapse in Venezuelan
oil production and the Administration’s decision to reinstate U.S. sanctions
against Iranian oil exports. Even after incorporating this upward revision to
futures prices, oil prices are expected to decline slowly over the forecast
period, as geopolitical risks stabilize and as supply increases on expected
loosening of OPEC restrictions and surging U.S. shale oil production. (For
further discussion, including a review of the effects of oil prices on U.S.
growth and inflation, see the box “The Recent Rise in Oil Prices.”)

Page 8 of 132

•

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

In contrast to the movements in oil prices, price changes for other
commodities have been muted. Prices for industrial metals are essentially
unchanged from the April Tealbook, outside of a minor correction in
aluminum prices following the relaxation of announced U.S. sanctions on a
large Russian producer. Aluminum prices were little changed following the
announcement that temporary exemptions from tariffs would no longer apply
to major trading partners including the European Union, Canada, and Mexico.

THE OUTLOOK FOR REAL GDP AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY
Real GDP grew at an estimated annual rate of 2¼ percent in the first quarter, and
we project growth to step up to a 3½ percent pace in the current quarter; both figures are
up about ½ percentage point relative to the April Tealbook. We estimate that output
stands nearly 2 percent above its potential level in the current quarter, a bit higher than in
the previous Tealbook. (A new exhibit titled “Cyclical Position of the U.S. Economy:
Near-Term Perspective” shows the judgmental assessment of the output gap as well as an
estimate from a statistical model.) Over the second half of the year, real GDP is expected
to rise at an annual rate of 2¾ percent, a little slower than in the April Tealbook.
•

Real PCE is reported to have increased at an annual rate of only 1 percent in
the first quarter. In our assessment, this weakness largely reflected payback
from the exceptionally strong growth in the fourth quarter of last year. PCE
growth is anticipated to step up to a 3 percent pace in the current quarter. We
expect consumer spending to rise at a 2¼ percent pace in the second half of
the year; this projection is revised down slightly from the previous Tealbook
because some of the unexpected second quarter strength in spending was on
energy items, which we think will unwind in the second half. For the year as
a whole, our projection for PCE growth is little revised from the April
Tealbook.

•

Business investment is projected to rise at an annual rate of about 7½ percent
in the first half of the year. We expect continued solid gains in coming
quarters, supported by still-favorable financial conditions, elevated business
sentiment and profit expectations, recent tax legislation, and the salutary
effects of high oil prices on activity in the drilling and mining sector.

Page 9 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

The Recent Rise in Oil Prices
Oil prices have increased about 50 percent over the past year, with the spot price
of Brent crude oil rising from about $50 per barrel to about $75 per barrel
(figure 1). For most of the period, further-dated futures prices remained
relatively stable, in the range of $55 per barrel; however, since the time of the
April Tealbook, futures prices have moved up appreciably, reaching nearly
$70 per barrel.
Both supply and demand factors have contributed to the oil price increase. In
particular, the broad-based improvement in the outlook for the global economy
was a key driver of the price increase in the second half of 2017. In recent
months, supply concerns have become more prevalent, affecting both spot and
further-dated futures prices. Despite sharply rising U.S. production, markets
have been attuned to escalating conflict between Saudi Arabia and Iran as well as
the precipitous decline in Venezuelan oil production amid the country’s economic
and political crisis. Prices also increased after President Trump announced on
May 8 that the United States was withdrawing from the Iran nuclear deal and
that sanctions against Iranian oil exports would be reinstated.
We expect oil prices to decline slowly through 2020 as geopolitical risks stabilize
and as supply, including U.S. shale oil production, grows to meet demand. In
addition, higher prices have put pressure on OPEC’s November 2016 agreement
with certain non-OPEC countries to restrain production. A stated aim of the
agreement was to reduce the glut in global inventories, and, in recent months,
inventory levels have fallen rapidly toward long-run averages. In response to
both lower inventories and higher prices, OPEC leaders have recently expressed a
willingness to discuss relaxing the production agreement at their upcoming
meeting in June, reducing some of the upward pressure on prices. That said, we
do think that some of the recent increase in prices is likely to be long lasting, and,
in line with futures prices, we have increased our forecast for the price of oil at
the end of 2020 by about $7 per barrel relative to the April Tealbook.

Page 10 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

What is the expected effect of the recent rise in oil prices on the U.S. economy?
To begin with, higher oil prices are likely to depress consumption. In particular,
the increase in oil prices since last year is estimated to have translated into a
roughly $250 annual increase in expenditures on gasoline for each household, on
average, from about $1850 to $2100. However, as indicated in figure 2, the share
of net oil imports in U.S. GDP has declined substantially as U.S. oil production has
grown rapidly over the past decade, so higher oil prices now imply much less of a
redistribution of purchasing power overseas than in the past. Accordingly, much
of the negative effect on GDP from lower consumer spending is likely to be
offset by increased production and investment in the growing oil sector. In our
projection, a $10 per barrel increase in the long-run price of oil from current levels
would lower the level of GDP by only about 5 basis points after three years, as
the drag on consumption is largely offset by higher oil investment and
production. This restraint is about one-fourth as large as it was a decade ago and
should get smaller still as U.S. oil production grows, as seen in figure 3, and the
net oil import share shrinks to zero.
Indeed, as U.S. oil trade moves into balance, the offsetting effects of a change in
the relative price of oil might be expected to net out within the domestic
economy. However, it is also possible that the marginal propensities to consume
and invest differ sufficiently across U.S. oil consumers and producers such that
increases in oil prices would still have a negative effect on overall GDP.
Even with zero net oil imports, changes in oil prices will still influence consumer
price inflation. We currently estimate that a permanent $10 per barrel rise in the
price of oil from its current level increases core inflation by less than
0.1 percentage point after two years and increases headline inflation by a
cumulative ¼ percentage point, with most of the effects occurring in the
first year.

Page 11 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Cyclical Position of the U.S. Economy: Near-Term Perspective
(Percent change at annual rate from final quarter
of preceding period except as noted)
Measure

2015

2016

2017

2018
Q1

2018
Q2

2018
Q3

Output gap1
Previous Tealbook

-.1
-.1

.3
.3

1.4
1.4

1.6
1.5

1.9
1.7

2.2
2.1

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

2.0
2.0

1.8
1.8

2.6
2.6

2.2
1.7

3.4
2.9

2.7
3.0

Measurement error in GDP
Previous Tealbook
Potential output
Previous Tealbook

-.3
-.3
1.5
1.5

-.2
-.2
1.6
1.6

-.1
-.1
1.5
1.5

-.1
-.1
1.7
1.7

.3
.0
1.7
1.7

.0
.0
1.7
1.7

Note: The output gap is the percent difference between actual and potential output; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating
below potential. The change in the output gap is equal to real GDP growth less the contribution of measurement error less the growth rate of
potential output. For quarterly figures, the growth rates are at an annual rate, and this calculation needs to be multiplied by 1/4 to obtain
the quarterly change in the output gap.
1. Percent, average for the final quarter in the period.

Judgmental Output Gap

Model-Based Output Gap
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook
90 percent
70 percent

Percent

5
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook
90 percent
70 percent

4
3

2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Shaded regions show the distribution of historical
revisions to the staff’s estimates of the output gap.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

4
3

2

2

1

1

0

0

-1

-1

-2

-2

-3

2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Shaded regions denote model-computed uncertainty
bands.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

Unemployment Rate

-3

Core PCE Price Inflation
Percent

Unemployment rate
Previous Tealbook
Natural rate of unemployment*
90 percent
70 percent

5

Percent change, 12-month change

7.0

Core
Previous Tealbook
Underlying inflation

6.5
6.0

3.0
2.5
2.0

5.5
1.5
5.0
1.0

4.5

.5

4.0
3.5
2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Shaded regions show the distribution of historical
revisions to the staff’s estimates of the natural rate.
*Staff estimate including the effect of EEB.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
staff assumptions.

2015
2016
2017
2018
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis; staff assumptions.

Page 12 of 132

.0

•

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Residential investment has been edging lower so far this year, and we expect
to see a decline of about ½ percent for the year as a whole, as housing activity
is held back by rising mortgage rates and a constrained supply of construction
workers and developable lots. Our projection is weaker in coming quarters
than in the April Tealbook, as we now judge that the rising path of interest
rates will weigh on residential investment more heavily than we previously
assumed.

•

We estimate that real government purchases will grow 1 percent in the first
half of this year and then pick up to a 2 percent pace in the second half, as the
recent federal budget legislation translates into higher federal government
purchases.

•

Net exports added 0.1 percentage point to real GDP growth in the first quarter,
and we expect it to add almost ¼ percentage point in the second. Our firstquarter estimate is about ½ percentage point stronger than we expected in the
April Tealbook, as imports came in weaker and exports stronger than we
projected. In the second half of the year, net exports are expected to be
neutral for real GDP growth, about ¼ percentage point weaker than in the
April Tealbook, as the higher dollar restrains export growth.

•

Manufacturing production increased at an annual rate of 1½ percent in the
first quarter, about half the pace projected in the April Tealbook.
Manufacturing output was strong in April, but the data on manufacturing
hours for May and the available product data suggest production pulled back
last month. Meanwhile, the new orders indexes in the national and regional
manufacturing surveys remain clustered near the high end of their range
during this expansion, and, accordingly, we expect that manufacturing output
growth will return to a solid pace in the coming months.

Over the medium term, we project real GDP growth to slow from about
2¾ percent this year to 2½ percent next year and then further to 1¾ percent in 2020.
Although fiscal policy remains expansionary and foreign growth remains solid, monetary
policy becomes progressively more restrictive.
•

Compared with the April Tealbook, our forecast for real GDP growth beyond
2018 is weaker on net. As noted previously, the higher path for the dollar is

Page 13 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Summary of the Near-Term Outlook for GDP
(Percent change at annual rate except as noted)
2018:Q2

2018:Q3

2018:H2

Measure

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Real GDP
Private domestic final purchases
Personal consumption expenditures
Residential investment
Nonres. private fixed investment
Government purchases
Contributions to change in real GDP
Inventory investment1
Net exports1

2.9
2.8
2.2
-2.1
8.0
1.2

3.4
3.2
2.9
-.9
6.1
1.0

3.0
3.2
2.6
5.0
6.2
2.2

2.7
3.0
2.4
-.7
7.8
1.9

2.9
3.1
2.5
5.0
5.6
2.4

2.7
2.9
2.3
.3
6.7
1.8

.1
.1

.3
.2

-.3
.2

-.2
-.1

-.4
.2

-.1
.0

1. Percentage points.

Recent Nonfinancial Developments (1)

Manufacturing IP ex. Motor Vehicles
and Parts

Real GDP and GDI
4-quarter percent change
Gross domestic product
Gross domestic income

3-month percent change, annual rate

8

15

6
Apr.
Q1

20

4

10
5
0

2

-5
0

-10

-2

-15
-20

-4
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

-6

-25
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Board, G.17 Statistical Release,
"Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization."

Sales and Production of Light Motor
Vehicles
Millions of units, annual rate

Real PCE Growth
6-month percent change, annual rate

22

Apr.
18
Sales

-30

6
4
2

May

14
0
10
-2

Production
6

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Ward’s Communications; Chrysler; General Motors;
FRB seasonal adjustments.

2

-4

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

Page 14 of 132

-6

June 1, 2018

Recent Nonfinancial Developments (2)
Single-Family Housing Starts and Permits
Millions of units
(annual rate)
Adjusted permits
Starts

Home Sales
2.1
1.8

7.5

Millions of units
(annual rate)

1.2
Apr.

1.2

5.5
5.0
4.5

0.6

4.0

0.9
Apr.
0.6

3.5

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0.0

0.3

New single-family
homes (right scale)

3.0
2.5

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0.0

Source: For existing, National Association of Realtors;
for new, U.S. Census Bureau.

Note: Adjusted permits equal permit issuance plus starts
outside of permit-issuing areas.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

Nondefense Capital Goods ex. Aircraft

Nonresidential Construction Put in Place

Ratio scale, billions of dollars
Orders

1.5

Existing homes
(left scale)

6.0

0.9

0.3

1.8

7.0
6.5

1.5

Millions of units
(annual rate)

Billions of chained (2009) dollars

71

Apr.

450

Apr.
66

400

61

350

56

300

51

250

Shipments

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
Note: Data are 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

2018

46

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Nominal CPIP deflated by BEA prices through
2017:Q4 and by the staff’s estimated deflator thereafter.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

Inventory Ratios

Exports and Non-oil Imports
Months

Billions of dollars

1.9

Mar.

1.7

Mar.
Census book-value data

220
200

1.6
Apr.

260
240

1.8

Staff flow-of-goods system

200

Non-oil imports

180

1.5

160

1.4

140
120

1.3

100
1.2
1.1

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Flow-of-goods system inventories include manufacturing
and mining industries and are relative to consumption. Census
data cover manufacturing and trade, and inventories are relative
to sales.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau; staff calculations.

Exports
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Forecasts are linear interpolations of quarterly values.
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis; U.S. Census Bureau.

Page 15 of 132

80
60

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Federal Reserve System Nowcasts of 2018:Q2 Real GDP Growth
(Percent change at annual rate from previous quarter)

Federal Reserve Entity

Type of model

Nowcast
as of
May 30,
2018

Federal Reserve Bank
Boston
New York



Mixed-frequency BVAR

3.4



Factor-augmented autoregressive model combination
Factor-augmented autoregressive model combination,
financial factors only
Dynamic factor model

2.4
2.3

Bayesian regressions with stochastic volatility
Tracking model

2.7
3.6



Tracking model combined with Bayesian vector
autoregressions (VARs), dynamic factor models, and
factor-augmented autoregressions (known as
GDPNow)

4.1



Dynamic factor models
Bayesian VARs

2.2
3.3



Dynamic factor models
News index model
Let-the-data-decide regressions

2.8
3.7
2.8



Accounting-based tracking estimate

2.8



Board staff’s forecast (judgmental tracking model)1
Monthly dynamic factor models (DFM-45)
Mixed-frequency dynamic factor model (DFM-BM)

2.9
3.1
3.8




Cleveland




Atlanta

Chicago



St. Louis




Kansas City
Board of Governors




Memo: Median of
Federal Reserve
System nowcasts

1

3.0

3.0

The June Tealbook forecast, finalized on May 31, 2018, is 3.4 percent.

Page 16 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

one important reason for this adjustment. Moreover, we have assumed that
the supply constraints we expect to be associated with the high level of
resource utilization will attenuate the transmission of increased aggregate
demand into increased output by a bit more than we had previously penciled
in. In addition, we now judge that the boost to consumer spending from the
tax cuts will be a little smaller than we had previously written down. 3 Other
revisions to conditioning assumptions were generally small. 4 In all, the level
of GDP is about ¼ percent lower at the end of 2020 than in our previous
projection.
•

Real GDP growth is projected to outpace potential growth through 2019 and
runs essentially in line with potential in 2020, resulting in a further tightening
of resource utilization over the medium term. At the end of 2020, real GDP
exceeds its potential level by 3 percent—¼ percentage point less than in the
April Tealbook but still indicative of a very tight economy.

•

The box “Alternative View: A Strong but Precarious Projection” highlights
the difficulty of engineering a soft landing to the current expansion and argues
that the risk of a recession over the projection period is substantially elevated.

•

With the federal government expected to run historically large and rising
deficits over the medium term, national saving is projected to trend downward
as a share of GDP. Nevertheless, private investment trends upward as a share
of the economy, with the widening gap between domestic investment and
national saving financed by increased inflows of foreign capital.

THE OUTLOOK FOR THE LABOR MARKET
On balance, the April and May employment reports point to a continued
tightening in the labor market and by a little more than we had expected.

Our assessment that the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act will provide a bit less impetus to consumption
than we had previously assumed reflects our weighing a little more heavily the fact that the tax cuts are
tilted toward high-income earners who likely have a lower marginal propensity to consume.
4
The slower population growth forecast by the Census Bureau led us to reduce the levels of both
actual and potential output by 0.1 percent by the end of the medium term.
3

Page 17 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Alternative View: A Strong but Precarious Projection
Engineering a soft landing to the current expansion, as we have penciled into the projection, will
prove increasingly precarious. I use a simple logit regression framework to show that while the
probability of a recession in the near future is small, the odds increase substantially further along
the staff’s baseline projection. This analysis is consistent with the Federal Reserve’s historical
difficulty with engineering a soft landing. Looking at real‐time data in staff forecasts preceding the
Great Recession, I illustrate how this framework correctly warned of an elevated risk of a recession
in the near term that the staff did not fully take into account. In accordance with best practices, the
staff is not currently forecasting a recession directly. However, this analysis shows that we are
forecasting conditions that have presaged previous recessionary episodes and should consider
either weakening the forecast or forecasting a recession in the early 2020s.
Specifically, I estimate a logit on data from 1965:Q1 to 2018:Q1 where the left‐hand side is an
indicator of “recession within four quarters” that is generated using NBER recession dating. The
right‐hand side consists of the term spread between the 10‐year Treasury yield and the federal
funds rate, the term premium on 10‐year Treasury yields, the spread of triple‐B‐rated bonds over
Treasury yields, and the staff’s judgmental output gap.1 Financial conditions and expectations are
represented in the logit by the spreads and premiums, and the real side of the economy is
represented by the output gap. All of the explanatory variables are statistically significant
predictors of recessions.2
Figure 1 shows the recession probability generated by the logit using the June Tealbook projection.
From 2020 to 2023, the probability of a recession beginning during the following four quarters is
high. Analysis of the logit attributes the high probability to our projections of a high output gap, a
term spread that turns negative in mid‐2020, and an increasing triple‐B spread. The recession

Note: This alternative view was prepared by David S. Miller.
1 The term premium and triple‐B spread are calculated based on the FRB/US model’s structure and the
specification of their corresponding interest rates.
2 The specification is robust to using the 10‐year Treasury premium to modify the term spread variable rather
than stand as a separate explanatory variable and to replacing the output gap with the unemployment gap.

Page 18 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

probability exceeds 0.6 by the end of 2020, a threshold that foreshadows almost every recession in
the post‐1965 period.
To show that this framework could have forecast the Great Recession while the staff did not, I use
similar logits to calculate the near future recession probability using real‐time staff projections from
three Greenbooks that precede, and coincide with, the start of the Great Recession. Each logit is
estimated on data from 1965:Q1 until the most recent data available at the time of the
corresponding Greenbook. The left‐hand side is the indicator of “recession within four quarters”
but is generated from NBER recession data that do not include the Great Recession. The right‐hand
side includes the same variables as the original logit.3
Figure 2 shows an elevated risk of a recession within the next four quarters starting in 2006, which
is rising with each Greenbook. By the end of 2007—corresponding to when the NBER would later
determine the Great Recession began—the real‐time recession probability is high enough that,
based on the logit, a recession was a likely outcome. While the staff had slightly weakened its near‐
term projection by the December 2007 Greenbook, we did not take into account the high, and
increasing, probability of a recession within four quarters.4
The current projection suffers from dissonance: It is inconsistent with the probability of recession
it implies. The staff projection is very strong and does not explicitly forecast a recession. However,
according to my analysis, the projection implies a very high and rising probability of a recession.
One way to address this dissonance would be to modify the unobserved components of the
projection by changing the estimate of potential output, the natural rate of unemployment, or r*
to produce a lower output gap and steeper term spread. However, if we believe that the current
medium‐term projection is our best forecast through 2020, then the analysis presented here
suggests that we should pencil in an outright recession in 2021 or 2022 (we currently project that
GDP will grow more slowly than its potential rate, but not a recession).

3 These vintage Greenbooks did not contain the triple‐B yield and spread. I include the triple‐B spread in these
logits to maintain consistency with the first logit and make the reported probabilities comparable. The spread
would have been observable in real time.
4 The December 2007 Greenbook forecast real GDP growth in 2008 at 1½ percent compared with a forecast of
2¼ percent in the January 2007 Greenbook. Forecasts of real GDP growth in 2009 and later are similar in both
Greenbooks.

Page 19 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Alternative Measures of Slack
The red line in each panel is the staff’s measure of the unemployment rate gap (right axis).

Output Gaps

Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Gap*
Percentage points

FRB/US
EDO* production function gap
FRBNY
PRISM
FRBCHICAGO

Q1

May

2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
2018
* EDO is Estimated, Dynamic, Optimization-based model.
Source: Federal Reserve Board; PRISM: Federal Reserve
Board Bank of Chicago; Federal Reserve Board Bank of
Philadelphia, PRISM Model Documentation (June 2011);
FRBNY: Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff
Report 618 (May 2013, revised April 2014).

Jobs Hard to Fill Gap*

27.6

Percentage points

Percentage points

18.4

Percentage points

Percentage points

6

28.8

6

4

19.2

2

9.6

0

0.0

-2

-9.6

-2

-4

-19.2

-4

-6

-28.8

6

2.52

4

Apr.

2
0

May

2000
2003
2006
2009
Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Job Openings Gap*

Percentage points

2012

2015

2018

Percentage points

Unemployment rate gap
Private job openings rate

4

-6

6
4

1.26
9.2

2
May

-0.0
-9.2

0

2
May

0.00

-2

0
-2

-1.26
Apr.

-18.4

-4

-4
Mar.

-27.6

-6
2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
2018
Note: Percent of small businesses surveyed with at least one
"hard to fill" job opening. Seasonally adjusted by Federal Reserve
Board Staff.
Source: National Federation of Independent Business,
Small Business Economic Trends Survey.

Job Availability Gap*

99.0

Percentage points

-2.52

2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
2018
Note: Job openings rate is the number of job openings divided
by employment plus job openings.
Source: Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey; U.S.
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current
Employment Statistics; Conference Board, Help Wanted OnLine.

Involuntary Part-Time Employment Gap
Percentage points

6

5.34

Percentage points

Percentage points

4
49.5

6
4

2.67
2

0.0

0
May

May
0.00

2
0

-2

-49.5

-2
-2.67

-4
-99.0

-6

2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
2018
Note: Percent of households believing jobs are plentiful minus
the percent believing jobs are hard to get.
Source: Conference Board.

-6

-4
-5.34

2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
2018
Note: Percent of employment.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey.

* Plots the negative of the gap to have the same sign as the unemployment rate gap.
Note: The shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Output gaps are
multiplied by negative 0.54 to facilitate comparison with the unemployment rate gap. Manufacturing capacity utilization gap is constructed by
subtracting its average rate from 1972 to 2013. Other gaps were constructed by subtracting each series’ average in 2004:Q4 and 2005:Q1.

Page 20 of 132

-6

•

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Total nonfarm payrolls rose 159,000 in April and 223,000 in May. The threemonth moving average ending in May of 179,000 was about 15,000 stronger
than our April Tealbook expectation and is well above the range of 80,000 to
110,000 monthly job gains that we judge to be consistent with no change in
resource utilization.5 We anticipate that total payroll employment gains will
average 195,000 per month in the third quarter.

•

An alternative estimate of private employment growth that combines the BLS
information together with data from the payroll processing firm ADP points to
private job gains of 166,000 in May. The moving average of this alternative
estimate over the three months ending in May stands at 176,000, essentially
the same as the three-month moving average of the published total
payroll gains.

•

The unemployment rate fell to 3.9 percent in April and then further to
3.8 percent in the May employment report—a downward surprise of
0.2 percentage point relative to the April Tealbook projection. We now
project the unemployment rate to be 3.7 percent next quarter, 0.1 percentage
point lower than in the last Tealbook.

•

The labor force participation rate (LFPR) ticked down in April and then fell
another 0.1 percentage point to 62.7 percent in May. For the past few years,
the participation rate has moved essentially sideways, on net, indicating some
tightening along this margin relative to its declining trend.

We continue to expect the labor market will tighten further over the medium term,
in line with above-trend GDP growth. We also continue to assume that, in an extremely
tight labor market, a larger-than-usual amount of the tightening in resource utilization
will manifest in a higher LFPR and workweek rather than in a lower unemployment rate. 6
•

Total payroll gains are projected to slow gradually from an average monthly
pace of about 195,000 this year to 130,000 in 2020 as GDP decelerates. This

This range assumes that the labor force participation rate declines in line with the staff’s estimate
of its trend. With an unchanged participation rate, the pace of monthly job gains required to keep the
unemployment rate constant ranges from 120,000 to 150,000.
6
Were we to maintain our usual Okun’s law relationship, the unemployment rate at the end of the
projection would be ¼ percentage point lower.
5

Page 21 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

trajectory is a touch lower than in our previous forecast, in line with the
downward revision to real output.
•

We project the unemployment rate to decline ½ percentage point this year—
similar to its decline in 2017—and to reach 3.6 percent in the fourth quarter,
unchanged from our previous projection. The jobless rate moves down further
in 2019, ending the year at 3.4 percent, and then moves sideways in 2020,
remaining about 1¼ percentage points below our estimate of its natural rate.
The projected unemployment rate at the end of 2020 is 0.1 percentage point
higher than in our April Tealbook projection, consistent with the somewhat
narrower output gap at the end of the medium term.

•

The LFPR is projected to end this year at 62.7 percent and then to hold steady
through 2020, as sustained job gains and rising real wages continue to draw
individuals into the labor force while also slowing outflows. When judged
against its declining trend, which is driven largely by population aging, the
flat profile of the LFPR is consistent with substantial further labor market
tightening. At the end of 2020, the LFPR is projected to be 0.6 percentage
point above our estimate of its trend and unchanged from the April Tealbook.

•

We project that labor productivity in the business sector will increase an
average of 1 percent per year over the forecast period—a touch faster than its
average pace over the past five years, though somewhat less than our estimate
of its structural pace. 7

THE OUTLOOK FOR INFLATION
Total consumer price inflation is currently close to 2 percent after having been
depressed by transitory factors last year.
•

The 12-month change in core PCE prices stood at 1.8 percent in April, about
the same as in March and a little below our expectations in the April
Tealbook. The small downside surprise in core inflation was concentrated in
the nonmarket component, from which we take little signal for future

Productivity tends to grow more slowly than its structural pace when the labor market becomes
tight, possibly because workers hired in a tight labor market have lower productivity, on average, relative to
workers hired during a slack labor market.
7

Page 22 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

inflation. We project that the 12-month change will edge up to 2 percent in
July and August. (The Dallas Fed’s trimmed mean measure rose 1.7 percent
over the 12 months ending in April, about the same as over the preceding
12 months.)
•

Total PCE prices rose 2 percent over the 12 months ending in April, and we
expect the 12-month change to move up to 2½ percent by July. The faster
pace of total PCE price inflation relative to core reflects both previous large
increases in consumer energy prices and our expectation for further increases
over the next few months.

•

We expect core import prices to increase at a 2¾ percent pace in the first half
of 2018, ½ percentage point less than in the April Tealbook projection based
on recent dollar appreciation. We project core import prices will be roughly
unchanged in the second half, reflecting the strengthening dollar, slowly
declining commodity prices, and moderate foreign inflation. Our projection
for import price inflation in the second half is also significantly lower than in
the April Tealbook.

•

Measures of longer-term inflation expectations have moved little, on balance,
since the April Tealbook. Median expectations over the next 5 to 10 years
from the University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers were 2.5 percent in
May, unchanged from the April reading and close to where they have been
over the past couple of years. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s
Survey of Consumer Expectations reported that the median inflation
expectation 3 years ahead rose 0.1 percentage point in April to 3.0 percent.
Finally, the TIPS-based measure of 5-to-10-year-forward inflation
compensation edged down to 2.1 percent.

•

The box “Inflation Perceptions and Inflation Expectations” uses new data
from the Michigan survey to compare inflation expectations with perceptions
of realized inflation.

Core inflation is projected to edge up from 1.9 percent this year to 2.0 percent in
2019 and to 2.1 percent in 2020, as the further tightening of the economy and a gradual

Page 23 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Inflation Perceptions and Inflation Expectations
Given the presumed role of inflation expectations in influencing actual inflation, it is
important to understand the survey evidence on expectations. Currently, however, there
are many unanswered questions about measures of expected inflation from household
surveys like the University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers. For example, it is not clear
how to interpret the fact that consumers tend to expect future inflation that is higher
than official estimates of past inflation. Do survey respondents actually expect inflation
to be higher in the future than it is now, or do they think current inflation has been higher
than indicated by the official statistics? And, does the downward drift in households’
long-term inflation expectations that began in mid-2014 reflect a decrease over time in
their perceptions of past inflation? That is, are households’ expectations somewhat
adaptive?
Insight may come from better understanding individuals’ perceptions of recent
inflation—namely, what consumers think inflation has been in the past. In 2016, the
University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers began asking the following questions on
inflation perceptions four times a year. 1
Short-term perceptions: During the past 12 months, do you think that prices in
general went up or went down, or stayed where they were a year ago? By about
what percent do you think prices went (up/down), on the average, during the
past 12 months?
Long-term perceptions: What about prices over the past 5 to 10 years? Do you
think prices now are higher, about the same, or lower than they were 5 to
10 years ago? By about what percent per year do you think prices went
(up/down), on the average, during the past 5 to 10 years?
Figures 1 and 2 summarize the distributions of responses on long-term inflation
perceptions and expectations from the February 2018 survey. The two distributions are

Note: Weighted using households’ weights in the survey.
Source: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Federal Reserve Board staff calculations.
1 The Federal Reserve Board contracted the University of Michigan Survey Research Center to

include these questions. The perceptions questions are worded consistently with the questions on
inflation expectations and are posed in February, May, August, and November.

Page 24 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

similar, with the bulk of the responses falling between 1 and 5 percent, but the
distribution of perceptions has slightly more responses in the right tail. (Note that
inflation experiences differ across households, and the distribution of perceptions could
reflect, at least in part, these differences.)
Figure 3 plots the median responses for both short- and long-term inflation perceptions
and expectations. As illustrated by the black lines, median long-term inflation
expectations (the solid line) have been quite similar to median long-term perceptions
(the dashed line). These median readings suggest that households do not expect
inflation to increase relative to what they perceive to have experienced over the past 5 to
10 years, even though the median expectations are higher than official estimates of
inflation. Median short-term inflation perceptions (red dashed line), on the other hand,
have run lower than long-term inflation perceptions as well as both short- and long-term
expectations. One natural interpretation is that households have perceived inflation as
being relatively low over the past few years, compared with the past 5 to 10 years, and
that they expect it to move up to the level of the past 5 to 10 years both over the near
term and the longer term. Measured official inflation was indeed low in 2015 and 2016.
However, headline inflation has moved up more recently, and median short-term
perceptions show just a hint of that upward drift.
The University of Michigan Survey Research Center began collecting the data on inflation
perceptions after the downward drift in long-term expectations was largely complete,
making it impossible to assess whether perceptions have declined in conjunction with
expectations. Nevertheless, the cross-sectional aspect of the data provides some
suggestive evidence on this issue. Figure 4 shows a scatterplot of individual responses to
the two long-term inflation questions and indicates that those who perceive inflation to
have been higher in the past also expect inflation to be higher in the future. 2 In addition,
people who revised up their answer about long-term perceptions between surveys also
tended to revise up their long-term expectations (not shown). These correlations
suggest that the downward drift in expectations that began in 2014 could have reflected
lower perceptions, possibly in response to the recent low inflation. We hope to learn
much more from these data in the future.

Source: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Federal Reserve Board staff calculations.

2 This result holds even when controlling for demographics.

Page 25 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Survey Measures of Longer-Term Inflation Expectations

CPI Next 10 Years

CPI Forward Expectations
Percent

Percent

3.0

2.5

Apr. Q2
May

2.0

Q2

SPF median, 6 to 10 years ahead
Blue Chip mean, 7 to 11 years ahead
Primary dealers median, 5 to 10 years ahead
Consensus Economics mean, 6 to 10 years ahead

1.5

SPF median
Livingston Survey median
1.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: SPF is Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

PCE Next 10 Years

2.5

Mar.

Dec.

3.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Blue Chip
Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Bank of New York;
Consensus Economics.

2.0

1.5

1.0

PCE Forward Expectations
Percent

Percent

3.0

3.0

SPF median, 6 to 10 years ahead
Primary dealers median, longer run
2.5

2.5

SPF median
Q2

Q2
2.0

2.0

May

1.5

1.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Surveys of Consumers

1.5

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Primary dealers data begin in August 2012.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Federal
Reserve Bank of New York.

1.0

Survey of Business Inflation Expectations
Percent

Percent

4.0

3.5

4.0

3.5

Mean increase in unit costs, next 5 to 10 years
Q2

3.0

3.0

Apr.
2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

May
FRBNY median increase in prices, 3 years ahead
Michigan median increase in prices, next 5 to 10 years

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY) Survey
of Consumer Expectations reports expected 12-month inflation
rate 3 years from the current survey date. FRBNY data begin
in June 2013.
Source: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers;
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Survey of Consumer
Expectations.

1.5

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Survey of businesses in the Sixth Federal Reserve
District. Data begin in February 2012.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

Page 26 of 132

1.5

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

increase in our judgmental underlying inflation trend more than offset restraint from the
projected deceleration in core import prices. 8
•

With oil prices expected to decline slowly over the medium term, total PCE
price inflation is projected to run a bit below core inflation after this year and
to be 2.0 percent in 2020.

•

Relative to the April Tealbook, the forecast for core PCE price inflation has
revised down a touch in 2018 and 2019, reflecting the incoming data, the
lower path for core import prices, and the slightly lower degree of resource
utilization in this projection.

•

We continue to assume that the supply constraints that attenuate the
transmission of aggregate demand into output in an extremely tight economy
will also result in slightly higher inflation than would otherwise be the case.

The data we received on wages since the April Tealbook were, on balance,
slightly stronger than expected. We continue to project a gradual acceleration in labor
compensation.
•

The employment cost index (ECI) increased at an annual rate of 4.0 percent in
the three months ending in March, 1.4 percentage points higher than the
forecast we wrote down in the April Tealbook. We expect this compensation
measure will increase 2¾ percent this year and next before edging up to
3 percent in 2020 as resource utilization tightens further.

•

Average hourly earnings rose 2.7 percent over the year ending in May, in line
with our expectations in the April Tealbook. We expect the 12-month change
in average hourly earnings to remain close to this pace through the near term.

•

Over the medium term, growth in compensation per hour (CPH) is projected
to step up from last year’s pace of 2¾ percent to 3½ percent this year and to
4 percent in each of the next two years.

8

to 2020.

In total, the underlying judgmental trend is assumed to increase 10 basis points from 2017

Page 27 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

•

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

The Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta’s Wage Growth Tracker remained at
3.3 percent in April, near the middle of its range over the past couple of years.

THE LONG-TERM OUTLOOK
•

We continue to assume that the natural rate of unemployment will be
4.7 percent and that potential output growth will be 1.7 percent per year in the
longer run.

•

We have maintained our assumption that the real equilibrium federal funds
rate that will prevail in the longer run will be ½ percent. The nominal yield on
10-year Treasury securities in the longer run is assumed to stand at
3.4 percent; thus, after the SOMA portfolio has returned to its normal size and
composition, the term premium is assumed to be 90 basis points.

•

We expect that the Federal Reserve’s holdings of securities will continue to
put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates, though to a diminishing
extent over time. The SOMA portfolio is projected to have returned to a
normal size by mid-2021.

•

With these assumptions, real GDP growth slows further to 1½ percent in 2021
and stays slightly above 1 percent in 2022 and 2023, as the federal funds rate
is above its neutral level and the support from fiscal policy wanes. The
unemployment rate moves up gradually from 3½ percent in 2021 toward its
assumed natural rate in subsequent years.

•

PCE price inflation hovers around 2.1 percent in 2022 and 2023 before edging
back down to the Committee’s long-run objective in later years.

•

With output materially above its potential level and inflation slightly above
the Committee’s 2 percent objective, the nominal federal funds rate rises to
about 4¾ percent at the end of 2021—2¼ percentage points higher than its
assumed long-run value. Thereafter, the federal funds rate moves gradually
back toward its long-run value.

Page 28 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Projections of Real GDP and Related Components
(Percent change at annual rate from final quarter
of preceding period except as noted)
2018
Measure

2017
H1

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

2018

2019

2020

H2

2.6
2.6

2.8
2.3

2.7
2.9

2.8
2.6

2.4
2.6

1.8
2.1

2.9
2.9

2.6
1.7

2.8
3.3

2.7
2.5

2.5
2.7

1.8
2.1

Personal consumption expenditures
Previous Tealbook

2.8
2.8

2.0
1.7

2.3
2.5

2.2
2.1

2.6
2.7

2.3
2.5

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

2.6
2.6

-1.3
-3.1

.3
5.0

-.5
.9

.6
1.7

1.5
3.3

Nonresidential structures
Previous Tealbook

5.0
5.0

11.9
9.5

7.1
5.9

9.5
7.7

2.4
2.0

.4
.5

Equipment and intangibles
Previous Tealbook

6.7
6.7

6.4
6.1

6.5
5.5

6.5
5.8

4.2
4.2

1.6
2.0

Federal purchases
Previous Tealbook

1.0
1.0

1.4
-1.2

3.4
4.8

2.4
1.8

4.0
4.1

3.0
3.3

.5
.5

.8
.7

.9
1.0

.9
.9

1.0
1.0

1.0
1.0

Exports
Previous Tealbook

5.0
5.0

4.6
4.2

5.0
6.3

4.8
5.2

4.0
5.2

3.0
3.6

Imports
Previous Tealbook

4.7
4.7

2.8
4.4

3.8
3.5

3.3
3.9

4.5
4.4

4.3
4.8

Final sales
Previous Tealbook

State and local purchases
Previous Tealbook

Contributions to change in real GDP
(percentage points)
Inventory change
Previous Tealbook

-.3
-.3

.2
.6

-.1
-.4

.1
.1

.0
-.1

.0
.0

Net exports
Previous Tealbook

-.1
-.1

.1
-.2

.0
.2

.1
.0

-.2
.0

-.3
-.3

Real GDP
4-quarter percent change
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Page 29 of 132

2020

-6

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Components of Final Demand

Personal Consumption Expenditures
4-quarter percent change

Residential Investment
4-quarter percent change

5

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

20
15

4

10
3
5
2
0
1

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-5

0

2013

Equipment and Intangibles

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-10

Nonresidential Structures

4-quarter percent change

4-quarter percent change

12

25
20

10

15

8

10
6
5
4
0
2

-5

0
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-10

-2

2013

Government Consumption and Investment
4-quarter percent change

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-15

Exports and Imports
4-quarter percent change

3

10

2
Exports

1

5

0
-1
-2

0

-3

Imports

-4
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-5

2013

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Page 30 of 132

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-5

June 1, 2018

Aspects of the Medium-Term Projection
Personal Saving Rate

Wealth-to-Income Ratio
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Ratio

10
9

7.2
6.8

8
6.4

7
6

6.0

5

5.6

4

5.2

3
4.8

2
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

1

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: Ratio of household net worth to disposable personal
income.
Source: For net worth, Federal Reserve Board, Financial
Accounts of the United States; for income, U.S. Dept. of
Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Single-Family Housing Starts

4.4

Equipment and Intangibles Spending
Millions of units

Share of nominal GDP

2.00

12

1.75
11

1.50
1.25

10

1.00
9

0.75
0.50

8

0.25
2000
2005
2010
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

2015

2020

0.00

Federal Surplus/Deficit
4-quarter moving average

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

7

Current Account Surplus/Deficit
Share of nominal GDP

Current
Previous Tealbook

Share of nominal GDP

6

1

4

0

2

-1

0

-2

-2
-3
-4
-4

-6

-5

-8

-6

-10
2000
2005
2010
Source: Monthly Treasury Statement.

2015

2020

-12

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 31 of 132

-7

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Cyclical Position of the U.S. Economy: Longer-Term Perspective
Output Gap

Unemployment Rate
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Percent

8
Unemployment rate
Previous Tealbook
Natural rate of unemployment*
Previous Tealbook

6
4
2

12
10

0

8

-2
-4

6

-6

4

-8
-10
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: Shaded regions show the 70 percent and 90 percent
confidence intervals of the distribution of historical revisions to the
staff’s estimates of the output gap.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

2
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: Shaded regions show the 70 percent and 90 percent
confidence intervals of the distribution of historical revisions to the
staff’s estimates of the natural rate.
*Staff estimate including the effect of EEB.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

Actual and Structural Labor Productivity

Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Rate
Percent

(Business sector)
90

2005

2010

2015

2020

Chained (2009) dollars per hour

Actual
Structural

85
Average rate from
1972 to 2017

2000

14

68
64

80

60

75

56

70

52

65

48

60

44
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis;
staff assumptions.

Source: Federal Reserve Board, G.17 Statistical Release,
"Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization."

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Decomposition of Potential Output
(Percent change, Q4 to Q4, except as noted)
Measure
Potential output
Previous Tealbook
Selected contributions1
Structural labor productivity2
Previous Tealbook
Capital deepening
Multifactor productivity
Structural hours
Previous Tealbook
Labor force participation
Previous Tealbook
Memo:
Output gap3
Previous Tealbook

1974-95

19962000

3.1
3.1

3.5
3.4

2.7
2.6

1.8
1.6

1.7
1.6
.7
.7
1.6
1.6
.4
.4

3.0
2.9
1.5
1.1
1.0
1.2
-.1
-.1

2.7
2.8
1.0
1.5
.8
.8
-.2
-.2

-1.5
-1.9

2.5
2.4

.2
.8

2001-07 2008-10 2011-15

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

1.4
1.2

1.6
1.4

1.5
1.5

1.7
1.7

1.8
1.9

1.9
1.9

1.7
1.4
.3
1.2
.4
.0
-.5
-.5

1.1
.8
.5
.3
.5
.6
-.6
-.6

1.0
.8
.5
.3
.8
.8
-.3
-.3

1.1
1.0
.5
.4
.2
.2
-.3
-.3

1.2
1.1
.6
.5
.7
.7
-.3
-.3

1.3
1.2
.6
.5
.6
.6
-.2
-.2

1.4
1.3
.6
.6
.6
.6
-.2
-.2

-5.5
-4.2

-.1
-.1

.3
.3

1.4
1.4

2.5
2.4

3.0
3.1

2.9
3.2

Note: For multiyear periods, the percent change is the annual average from Q4 of the year preceding the first year shown to Q4 of the last year shown.
1. Percentage points.
2. Total business sector.
3. Percent difference between actual and potential output in the final quarter of the period indicated. A negative number indicates that the economy
is operating below potential.

Page 32 of 132

June 1, 2018

The Outlook for the Labor Market
2018
Measure

2017
H1

Output per hour, business1
Previous Tealbook

2018

2019

2020

H2

.9
.9

1.6
.7

1.0
1.6

1.3
1.2

.9
.9

.9
.9

183
183

205
199

187
191

196
195

158
181

129
160

180
180

206
197

180
180

193
188

148
170

119
150

Labor force participation rate3
Previous Tealbook

62.7
62.7

62.8
62.8

62.7
62.7

62.7
62.7

62.7
62.7

62.7
62.7

Civilian unemployment rate3
Previous Tealbook

4.1
4.1

3.8
4.0

3.6
3.6

3.6
3.6

3.4
3.3

3.4
3.3

Nonfarm payroll employment2
Previous Tealbook
Private employment2
Previous Tealbook

1. Percent change from final quarter of preceding period at annual rate.
2. Thousands, average monthly changes.
3. Percent, average for the final quarter in the period.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; staff assumptions.

Inflation Projections
2018
Measure

2017

2018

2019

2020

1.8
1.7

2.1
2.1

1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

1.0
.9

2.0
2.1

1.5
1.5

2.3
2.3

2.3
2.3

7.6
7.6

7.9
7.6

4.5
-.4

6.2
3.5

-1.3
-1.9

-1.0
-1.1

Excluding food and energy
Previous Tealbook

1.5
1.5

2.1
2.4

1.7
1.7

1.9
2.0

2.0
2.1

2.1
2.1

Prices of core goods imports1
Previous Tealbook

1.3
1.3

2.7
3.2

.2
1.3

1.4
2.3

.6
.6

.6
.6

Mar.
2018

Apr.
2018

May
20182

June
20182

July
20182

Aug.
20182

2.0
2.1

2.0
2.1

2.2
2.4

2.4
2.5

2.5
2.5

2.4
2.4

1.8
1.9

1.8
1.9

1.9
2.0

1.9
2.1

2.0
2.1

2.0
2.1

H1

H2

1.7
1.7

2.3
2.5

Food and beverages
Previous Tealbook

.7
.7

Energy
Previous Tealbook

Percent change at annual rate from
final quarter of preceding period
PCE chain-weighted price index
Previous Tealbook

12-month percent change
PCE chain-weighted price index
Previous Tealbook
Excluding food and energy
Previous Tealbook

1. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.
2. Staff forecast.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Page 33 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Labor Market Developments and Outlook (1)

Measures of Labor Underutilization
Percent

Percent
13

U-5*
Unemployment rate
Part time for
economic
reasons**

Unemployment rate
Previous Tealbook
Natural unemployment rate with EEB adjustment
Previous Tealbook

12
11
10
9
8

5
4

4
3
2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

9

6

5

2004

10

7

6

2

11

8

7
May

12

3
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2

* U-5 measures total unemployed persons plus all marginally attached to the labor force as a percent of the labor force plus persons marginally
attached to the labor force.
** Percent of Current Population Survey employment.
EEB Extended and emergency unemployment benefits.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Level of Payroll Employment*
130

Millions

Millions

Millions
150
May

Total (right axis)
Private (left axis)
125

145

120

140

115

135

Total
Previous Tealbook

155
153
151
149
147
145
143
141

110

130

105

125

139
137

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

135

* 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Change in Payroll Employment*
Thousands

Thousands

400

May

Total
Previous Tealbook

200
0

Total
Private
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

350
300
250

-200

200

-400

150

-600

100

-800

50

-1000

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 34 of 132

2019

2020

0

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Labor Market Developments and Outlook (2)
Labor Force Participation Rate*
Percent
Labor force participation rate
Previous Tealbook
Estimated trend**

Percent

67.5

Labor force participation rate
Previous Tealbook
Estimated trend**

67.0
66.5

64.5
64.0

66.0
63.5

65.5
65.0

63.0

64.5
64.0
May

62.5

63.5
63.0

62.0

62.5
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

62.0

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

61.5

* Published data adjusted by staff to account for changes in population weights.
** Includes staff estimate of the effect of extended and emergency unemployment benefits.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; staff assumptions.

Initial Unemployment Insurance Claims*
Thousands

Hires, Quits, and Job Openings
700
650
600

Percent
Hires*
Openings**
Quits*

550

400
May 26

3.5
3.0

350

2.5

300

2.0
1.5

200
150

4.5

Mar.

250

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
* 4-week moving average.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and
Training Administration.

5.0

4.0

500
450

5.5

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
* Percent of private nonfarm payroll employment, 3-month
moving average.
** Percent of private nonfarm payroll employment plus
unfilled jobs, 3-month moving average.
Source: Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey.

1.0

Labor Force Participation Rate by
Racial/Ethnic Group, 25 to 54 years old

Unemployment Rate by
Racial/Ethnic Group
Percent
Asian
Black
Hispanic
White

20

16

Percent
Asian
Black
Hispanic
White

86
84
82

12
80
8

4

May

78
76

May
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0

Note: These categories are not mutually exclusive, as the
ethnicity Hispanic may include people of any race. The Current
Population Survey defines Hispanic ethnicity as those who report
their origin is Mexican, Puerto Rican, Cuban, Central American,
or South American (and some others). 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey.

Page 35 of 132

74
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Note: These categories are not mutually exclusive, as the
ethnicity Hispanic may include people of any race. The Current
Population Survey defines Hispanic ethnicity as those who report
their origin is Mexican, Puerto Rican, Cuban, Central American,
or South American (and some others). 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey.

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Inflation Developments and Outlook (1)
(Percent change from year-earlier period)

Headline Consumer Price Inflation
Percent
CPI
PCE

Percent

6
PCE - Current Tealbook
PCE - Previous Tealbook

5

5
4

4
Apr.

3

3
2

2
1
1

0
-1

0
-2
-3
-1
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Source: For CPI, U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for PCE, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Measures of Underlying PCE Price Inflation
Percent
Trimmed mean PCE
Market-based PCE excluding food and energy
PCE excluding food and energy

Percent

4.0
Core PCE - Current Tealbook
Core PCE - Previous Tealbook

3.5

3.5
3.0

3.0

2.5

2.5
Apr.

2.0
2.0
1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5
0.0
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Source: For trimmed mean PCE, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; otherwise, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

0.0

Labor Cost Growth
Percent
Employment cost index
Average hourly earnings
Compensation per hour

Percent

7

Compensation per hour - Current Tealbook
Compensation per hour - Previous Tealbook

6
5

6
5
4

4
May

3
3
2

Q1
Q1

2
1

1

0

0
-1
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Note: Compensation per hour is for the business sector. Average hourly earnings are for the private nonfarm sector. The employment cost
index is for the private sector.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 36 of 132

-1

June 1, 2018

Inflation Developments and Outlook (2)
(Percent change from year-earlier period, except as noted)

Commodity and Oil Price Levels
Dollars per barrel
1967 = 100
220
Brent crude oil history/futures (right axis)
1680
168
CRB spot commodity price index (left axis)
1420
142
1200
120
1000
100
800
80
2200

600
400

May 30

1000

1967 = 100

Dollars per barrel

Brent crude oil history/futures (right axis)
CRB spot commodity price index (left axis)

900

140

800

120

700

100

60

600

80

40

500

60

400
200

160

May 30

40

20
300
20
2015
2016
2017
2018
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Note: Futures prices (dotted lines) are the latest observations on monthly futures contracts.
Source: For oil prices, U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Agency; for commodity prices, Commodity Research Bureau (CRB).

Energy and Import Price Inflation
18

Percent

Percent
PCE energy prices (right axis)
Core import prices (left axis)

15
12

60

10

50

8

40

6

9

30

4

6

20

2

10

0

Apr.

3
0

0

-2

-3

-10

-4

-6

-20

-6

-9

-30

-8

-12

-40

-10

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Percent

Percent
PCE energy prices (right axis)
Core import prices (left axis)

Apr.

2015

2016

2017

2018

30
25
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
-25
-30

Source: For core import prices, U.S. Dept. of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for PCE, U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Long-Term Inflation Expectations and Compensation
Percent
5-to-10-year-ahead TIPS compensation
Michigan median next 5 to 10 years
SPF PCE median next 10 years

4.0
3.5
May

Percent

4.5

3.0

5-to-10-year-ahead TIPS compensation
Michigan median next 5 to 10 years
SPF PCE median next 10 years

4.0
3.5

May

2.5
Q2
Apr.

2.0
1.5

4.5

3.0
2.5

Apr.
Q2

2.0
1.5

1.0
1.0
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Based on a comparison of an estimated TIPS (Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities) yield curve with an estimated nominal off-the-run
Treasury yield curve, with an adjustment for the indexation-lag effect.
SPF Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Source: For Michigan, University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; for SPF, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; for TIPS, Federal
Reserve Board staff calculations.
Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 37 of 132

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

The Long−Term Outlook

(Percent change, Q4 to Q4, except as noted)

Measure

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Longer run

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

2.8
2.6

2.4
2.6

1.8
2.1

1.5
1.5

1.1
1.0

1.1
1.0

1.7
1.7

Civilian unemployment rate1
Previous Tealbook

3.6
3.6

3.4
3.3

3.4
3.3

3.6
3.5

3.8
3.8

4.1
4.1

4.7
4.7

PCE prices, total
Previous Tealbook

2.1
2.1

1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

2.0
2.0

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0

Core PCE prices
Previous Tealbook

1.9
2.0

2.0
2.1

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.2

2.2
2.2

2.0
2.0

Federal funds rate1
Previous Tealbook

2.52
2.59

3.78
3.82

4.54
4.66

4.79
4.97

4.73
4.85

4.44
4.48

2.50
2.50

10-year Treasury yield1
Previous Tealbook

3.6
3.6

4.1
4.2

4.3
4.4

4.2
4.3

4.1
4.1

3.9
3.9

3.4
3.4

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Real GDP

Unemployment Rate
4−quarter percent change

Percent
4

10
Unemployment rate

3

9

2
1
Potential GDP

0
−1

8

Natural rate
with EEB
adjustment

7
6

−2

5

−3

4

−4

Real GDP

−5
2005

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

3
2005

PCE Prices

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

Interest Rates
4−quarter percent change

Percent
4

Total PCE prices

10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0

Triple−B corporate
3
10−year Treasury
2

PCE prices
excluding
food and
energy

1
0

Federal
funds rate

−1
2005

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

2005

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

Note: In each panel, shading represents the projection period, and dashed lines are the previous Tealbook.
Page 38 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Evolution of the Staff Forecast
Change in Real GDP
Percent, Q4/Q4
4

2016

3

2

2017

2018
2019

2020
1

9/10 10/22 12/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20 3/9 4/20 6/8 7/20

2014

2015

9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2016

4/21 6/2 7/14

9/8 10/2012/1 1/19 3/9 4/20 6/1

2017

0

2018

Tealbook publication date

Unemployment Rate
Percent, fourth quarter
6.0
2016

5.5
5.0

2017

2018

4.5
2019

4.0
2020

3.5
3.0

9/10 10/22 12/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20 3/9 4/20 6/8 7/20

2014

2015

9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2016

4/21 6/2 7/14

9/8 10/2012/1 1/19 3/9 4/20 6/1

2017

2.5

2018

Tealbook publication date

Change in PCE Prices excluding Food and Energy
Percent, Q4/Q4
2.5
2018

2017

2020

2019

2.0

1.5

2016

1.0

0.5

9/10 10/22 12/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20 3/9 4/20 6/8 7/20

2014

2015

9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2016

2017

Tealbook publication date

Page 39 of 132

4/21 6/2 7/14

9/8 10/2012/1 1/19 3/9 4/20 6/1

2018

0.0

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 40 of 132

June 1, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

International Economic Developments and Outlook
Headlines over the intermeeting period pointed to heightened political risks and
increased financial stress in several countries. These negative developments have come
against the backdrop of still-robust foreign economic activity but have increased
downside risks to our outlook. Real GDP in the foreign economies accelerated to an
annual pace of 3¼ percent in the first quarter, as a slowdown in the advanced foreign
economies and Mexico. We anticipate growth in the current quarter to move down to
2¾ percent. A pickup in the AFEs, as weather-related disruptions in Japan and Europe
subside, should be more than offset by a step-down in the emerging market economies
(EMEs), in part because of the payback from the first-quarter surge. We expect growth
abroad to remain at 2¾ percent, its potential pace, through 2020.
Balancing a number of factors, we revised down our forecast a bit over the next
several quarters and left it about unchanged thereafter. Despite media commentary on a
weakening momentum of global growth, recent data readings have been a mix of positive
and negative surprises, with no clear-cut implications for the overall outlook. Oil prices
have increased some, but this increase has roughly offsetting effects on importers and
exporters. The dollar has appreciated strongly, which should provide some stimulus to
our trading partners. However, some EMEs with large macroeconomic imbalances
registered a tightening of their financial conditions, which should temper their growth a
bit. Finally, political developments in Italy have increased financial stresses and should
restrain growth in Italy and have some adverse spillovers to other euro-area countries.
Although our baseline outlook is only little changed, we see increased prominence
of two risks. First, the situation in Italy could become more precarious and have
significantly greater spillovers to other euro-area countries than in our baseline, a
possibility explored in our “Heightened Risk of Euro-Area Breakup” alternative scenario
in the Risks and Uncertainty section. Second, although the recent rise in financial
stresses and capital outflows has been mostly limited to relatively vulnerable EMEs (see
the box “Recent Financial Pressures in Emerging Market Economies”), there could be a
broader and more persistent ratcheting up of EME stress, a possibility discussed in the
“EME Turbulence and Stronger Dollar” alternative scenario.

Page 41 of 132

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

economies (AFEs) was more than offset by outsized growth in some emerging Asian

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018 (Corrected)

Recent Financial Pressures in Emerging Market Economies

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Since the April Tealbook, financial stresses have risen in emerging market economies (EMEs),
with credit spreads widening, bond and equity funds experiencing outflows, and currencies
depreciating against the dollar. In this discussion, we look more closely at the potential
factors contributing to this turn in sentiment, including rising U.S. Treasury yields, spillovers
from idiosyncratic developments in select countries, and heightened focus on EME
vulnerabilities more broadly. Among EME asset prices, we concentrate on exchange rates,
where the movements have been the most sizable.
The rise in financial stress has been especially pronounced for Turkey and Argentina, whose
currencies have depreciated about 11 percent and 19 percent, respectively, since the April
Tealbook and whose credit spreads have moved up sharply. Turkey and Argentina are also
the two EMEs with the most significant macroeconomic vulnerabilities. In both countries,
concerns have risen about the laxity of fiscal and monetary policies, the independence of the
central bank, and the reliance on external financing. These vulnerabilities likely rendered the
countries susceptible to shifts in market conditions.
However, the recent stresses have not been limited to Turkey and Argentina, suggesting
that a common factor may have triggered the selloff in EME assets. Indeed, the notion that
EMEs were hit by a common shock finds some support in that EMEs have been affected
roughly in proportion to their vulnerabilities. As seen in figure 1, when recent EME currency
depreciations are plotted against our relative vulnerability rankings, they line up well.1

1 Our vulnerability ranking is constructed by first ordering 16 EMEs according to six indicators of

vulnerability: (1) current account deficit as a percent of GDP, (2) gross government debt as a percent of
GDP, (3) average annual inflation over the past three years, (4) the five‐year change in bank credit to the
private sector as a share of GDP, (5) the ratio of external debt to exports, and (6) the ratio of foreign
exchange reserves to GDP. By construction, the higher the rankings on each measure, the higher the
vulnerability. We average the rankings across indicators for each EME. Thus, the values can theoretically
range from 1 (least vulnerable) to 16 (most vulnerable).

Page 42 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Exactly what shock might have led to a shift in investor sentiment toward EMEs, however, is
unclear. One possibility is that developments in Argentina and Turkey have served as a
wake‐up call to investors, leading to a broad repricing of risk in EME assets. Alternatively,
some other common shocks, such as the rise in U.S. interest rates, may have increased
pressures on EMEs. To provide an assessment, we use an empirical model relating EME
currency movements to key underlying drivers. These drivers are the 2‐year U.S. Treasury
yield to capture the general level of U.S. interest rates and near‐term monetary policy path,
the slope of the U.S. Treasury yield curve (10‐year minus 2‐year) as a proxy for the
opportunity cost of investing in dollar‐denominated EME bonds, U.S. high‐yield corporate
bond spreads as an indicator of broad credit market conditions for risky debt, and the VIX
index to capture general risk sentiment. The model is estimated on weekly data separately
for each EME currency to allow potentially different responses to U.S. variables depending
on country‐specific fundamentals and risk characteristics.2 On average, U.S. interest rates
and risk sentiment explain around 20 percent of the variation in EME currencies over the
post‐crisis period, with the three interest rate variables accounting for most of the
explanatory power.3 Additionally, countries that are assessed as more vulnerable tend to
have larger sensitivities to changes in U.S. interest rates and the VIX.
Regarding the recent movements (figure 2), the average EME currency depreciated about
5 percent against the dollar from mid‐April through the third week of May, while the 2‐ and
10‐year Treasury yields rose 19 basis points and 24 basis points, respectively.4 During this

2 In our analysis, we include the 16 countries shown in figure 1.

All right‐hand‐side variables are in first‐
difference form.
3 A 10 basis point increase in the 2‐year U.S. Treasury yield, the term spread, and the high‐yield spread
are associated with 0.5 percent, 0.25 percent, and 0.3 percent depreciation of the average EME currency,
respectively.
4 Since the third week of May, the average EME currency is little changed, on net, although increased
political uncertainty in Italy weighed on risk sentiment and put downward pressure on Treasury yields and
risky asset prices. See the Financial Market Developments section for a detailed discussion.

Page 43 of 132

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

period, the model‐based path moved down only 1½ percent, suggesting a material but
relatively modest role for the rise in the Treasury yields. However, it is notable that during
the period from last October to early February, EME currencies appreciated relative to the
dollar even as 2‐ and 10‐year U.S. Treasury yields increased significantly, suggesting that the
link between Treasury yields and EME currencies is relatively loose. Nonetheless, it is also
possible that the recent sharp depreciation in EME currencies reflects some catch‐up
following their earlier failure to respond to rising interest rates in the United States.
At this point, concerns about EME financial stresses should not be overstated. EME
sovereign bond spreads and broad measures of EME financial stress, shown in figure 3,
remain well below levels seen in other recent stress episodes such as that in early 2016
associated with concerns about China. The fact that EMEs with lower vulnerabilities have
not been as affected suggests that investors have continued to differentiate between
countries based on economic fundamentals. Moreover, incoming data for the EMEs
continue to point to robust growth. As such, the recent tightening of financial conditions
has left little imprint on our overall EME forecast. However, this tightening points to the
possibility of more severe financial stresses, as described in the “EME Turbulence and
Stronger Dollar” alternative scenario in the Risks and Uncertainty section.

Page 44 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Oil prices have put upward pressure on foreign inflation in the first half of the
year, and, with further oil price increases and currency depreciations since the April
Tealbook, we revised up our inflation forecast for the second half of the year. In the
AFEs, we expect inflation to edge down to 1¾ percent by the end of the year, as oil
prices decline, and to remain near that pace thereafter. With underlying inflation
pressures expected to be contained over the next few years, we continue to assume a
gradual withdrawal of monetary policy stimulus in the AFEs. Indeed, we pushed back
the next policy rate hikes by the Bank of Canada (BOC), the Bank of England (BOE),
uncertainties about the outlook. In contrast, the increase in oil prices coupled with capital
outflows and currency depreciations have led some EMEs to tighten monetary policy.
Argentina, Indonesia, the Philippines, and Turkey raised their policy rates, and Brazil,
contrary to expectations, did not cut its rate.

ADVANCED FOREIGN ECONOMIES


Euro area. Real GDP growth slowed from 2.7 percent in the fourth quarter to
1.6 percent in the first, partly owing to temporary factors, such as labor strikes and
severe cold in both France and Germany. Key survey indicators (such as PMIs) have
softened further this quarter but remain at levels consistent with solid growth.
Accordingly, we project growth to rebound to just above 2 percent in the current
quarter, before decelerating to 1½ percent by 2019. This forecast is about
½ percentage point lower in 2018 and ¼ percentage point lower in 2019 relative to
the April Tealbook, primarily reflecting recent and expected financial tensions and
uncertainty generated by political developments in Italy.
In Italy, we expect a protracted period of political uncertainty and elevated financial
stress as antiestablishment parties push for substantial fiscal easing and challenge
European institutions. That said, our baseline outlook assumes that internal political
conflicts and market pressures ultimately prevent the Italian government from
implementing radical proposals such as creating a parallel currency. In addition,
while we expect some spillovers to other euro-area countries, our baseline envisions
that investors ultimately retain confidence in the integrity of the euro area and its
institutions, including its financial backstops. Accordingly, while Italian growth is
projected to fall close to zero later this year and in 2019, overall euro-area growth
should moderate to near its potential rate and remain there over the forecast period.

Page 45 of 132

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

and the European Central Bank (ECB) on weaker-than-expected data and elevated

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

However, much uncertainty attends this projection, and a resurgence of severe
financial stresses in the euro area is a clear downside risk.
Higher oil prices should further boost inflation from 2 percent in the first quarter to
2¼ percent in the second and third quarters. However, with core inflation projected
to rise very slowly from around 1 percent this quarter, we expect headline inflation to
fall back to 1½ percent by 2019 as retail energy prices stabilize before edging higher
in 2020 as slack diminishes. Given increased downside risks and slightly weaker
outlooks for growth and inflation, we now expect the ECB to wait until the fourth
Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

quarter of 2019 to begin raising its policy rate, two quarters later than previously
assumed.


United Kingdom. Real GDP growth plunged unexpectedly from 1.6 percent in the
fourth quarter to a mere 0.4 percent in the first, partly owing to a weather-related
contraction in the construction sector. Growth is expected to rebound to 1½ percent
in the current quarter. This figure is ¼ percentage point lower than in the April
Tealbook, as most data, such as April PMIs and confidence indicators, suggest a bit
less momentum than expected. Thereafter, growth should edge up to 1¾ percent,
supported by accommodative monetary policy.
Headline inflation is projected to remain unchanged at 2½ percent in the second
quarter, as the boost from higher energy prices is offset by weaker-than-expected core
inflation readings. Thereafter, we continue to expect inflation to fall to the BOE’s
2 percent target by the end of 2020. With the recent weakness in economic activity,
we now anticipate that the BOE will delay hiking rates until the third quarter of 2018,
one quarter later than assumed in the April Tealbook. This path takes the policy rate
from 0.5 percent to 1½ percent by the end of forecast period, ¼ percentage point
lower than assumed in April.



Japan. Real GDP contracted 0.6 percent in the first quarter, well below the
1¼ percent expansion forecast in the April Tealbook. The contraction seems largely
driven by a big step-down in inventory investment and the effects of bad weather on
private consumption. Incoming indicators have been mixed but, on net, suggest
growth will rebound to 1¼ percent in the current quarter. We expect that growth will
move down to a near-potential pace of ¾ percent by next year.

Page 46 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Inflation appears set to turn negative in the second quarter, as data through May
indicate that food and durable goods prices declined sharply. As higher oil prices
feed through to consumer prices and food prices stabilize, inflation should return to
positive territory in the third quarter. We assume that underlying inflation pressures
will remain quite subdued despite a very tight labor market, and we project inflation
to be just 1 percent in 2020. Accordingly, we assume that the Bank of Japan will
maintain a highly accommodative policy stance throughout the forecast period,
waiting until late 2020 to lift its target for the 10-year Japanese government bond



Canada. Real GDP growth slowed to 1.3 percent in the first quarter, from
1.7 percent in the fourth, reflecting strong imports, a sharp contraction in residential
investment, and a slowdown in private consumption growth. Although first-quarter
growth was ¾ percentage point below our April estimate, we are taking little signal
going forward, as monthly indicators point to solid underlying momentum late in the
quarter. Moreover, recent indicators, including the April employment report and
manufacturing PMI, suggest that growth will step up to almost 2½ percent this
quarter. Thereafter, we expect growth to continue at around that pace through early
2019, before slowing to just below 2 percent in 2020. Relative to the April Tealbook,
this projection is somewhat stronger in the second half of 2018 and in 2019 because
of higher oil prices.
We have inflation slowing from 3 percent in the current quarter to the BOC’s
2 percent target by mid-2019. As resource utilization continues to increase, the BOC
is expected to gradually raise its policy rate from the current 1.25 percent to 3 percent
in 2020. With data having come in a bit weaker, we now expect the next rate hike to
be in the third quarter of this year, a quarter later than assumed in the April Tealbook.

EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES


China. Growth continues to be solid, rising to 7.2 percent in the first quarter and
projected to be 6¾ percent this quarter. Economic activity has been boosted by
strong external demand and a recovery in industrial activity following the removal of
production caps on high-polluting industries. However, fixed investment and retail
sales have decelerated, suggesting that the tighter regulations on shadow banking
activity are starting to affect the real economy. We expect growth to moderate further

Page 47 of 132

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

yield above zero.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

to 6¼ percent in the second half of this year and to edge down to 6 percent by 2020,
in line with potential.
The proposed U.S. tariffs on about $50 billion of Chinese imports, if implemented,
would have a limited direct effect on the Chinese economy, as these goods account
for a small share of China’s GDP. However, a substantial broadening of the tariffs to
additional products could indeed pose a material risk to the outlook for China and the
emerging Asian region as a whole.

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Inflation has been very subdued, at an estimated 1¼ percent this quarter, because of
falling food prices. We expect inflation to rise temporarily to 3 percent next quarter,
as food prices normalize and higher oil prices pass through to retail fuel prices, but to
settle at 2½ percent by the end of this year.


Other Emerging Asia. Real GDP growth in emerging Asia excluding China jumped
to 5.7 percent in the first quarter, 1¼ percentage point higher than projected in the
April Tealbook, owing in large part to outsized export growth in Hong Kong and
strong domestic demand in India and Thailand. Furthermore, activity rebounded in
Korea, as expected, after a fourth-quarter contraction. Growth in the region should
moderate to 3¼ percent in the second quarter, as activity in Hong Kong and Thailand
normalizes. Thereafter, we expect growth to settle at around 3¾ percent. This
projection is down a touch for the rest of this year on higher oil prices and about
unchanged thereafter.



Mexico. Mexican real GDP grew at a robust 4.6 percent pace in the first quarter, up
from 3.6 percent in the fourth and well above our April Tealbook forecast. Industrial
output rebounded after a lackluster 2017, boosted by oil production, construction, and
exports, particularly of autos. These data, together with an upward revision to the
projection for U.S. manufacturing growth, led us to revise up second-quarter growth
to 3 percent, notwithstanding some tightening in financial conditions amid the recent
selloff of EME assets and more Mexico-specific concerns related to NAFTA and the
July presidential elections. We see growth remaining at around 3 percent over the
forecast period, supported by strong external demand, diminished fiscal drag, and
higher real incomes.
Headline inflation is expected to continue declining to 3 percent this quarter, from
4 percent in the first. Although this drop partly reflects the fading effect of past food

Page 48 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

price increases, core inflation also continues to fall. Consistent with this decline, the
Bank of Mexico kept its policy rate unchanged at its May meeting but emphasized
that it is monitoring the potential pass-through from the recent depreciation of
the peso.


Brazil. Brazilian GDP grew 1.8 percent in the first quarter, up from 1 percent in the
fourth, supported by a rebound in exports and a modest pickup in household demand.
Nevertheless, growth was significantly weaker than expected, and falling PMIs and
confidence indicators in April suggest that this weakness extended into the second
widespread strikes by truck drivers, these data led us to slash our growth estimate in
the second quarter 1 percentage point, to just over 1½ percent. We continue to see
the pace of activity climbing gradually to 3 percent by 2019, although political
uncertainty ahead of this October’s presidential election remains a key downside risk.
Given significant economic slack, we expect inflation to edge down to a subdued
2¾ percent in the second quarter, well below the inflation target. However, noting
the recent volatility in financial markets, the central bank stood pat in its previous
meeting, pausing an easing cycle that had begun in late 2016.



Argentina. In the face of rapidly escalating pressure on the peso, Argentine
authorities announced on May 8 that they were seeking an IMF program. This
decision followed several unsuccessful attempts by the central bank to shore up
market confidence, including three intermeeting policy rate hikes that raised the
overnight rate a cumulative 12.75 percentage points to 40 percent. The deterioration
in market sentiment is rooted in growing concerns about persistently high fiscal
deficits, the independence of the central bank, and the increasing dependence on
external financing. We marked down growth considerably this year. We expect
confidence will improve and activity will pick up again in 2019. However, there is a
material risk that Argentina’s macroeconomic adjustment process could be costlier
and more prolonged than predicted.



Turkey. Turkey has also come under substantial market pressure in recent weeks,
with the lira plunging close to 20 percent and credit spreads rising sharply. The
central bank responded to the turmoil by significantly tightening its monetary policy,
reversing some of the currency depreciation. Along with Argentina, Turkey’s
economy stands out among EMEs for its macroeconomic fragility, including

Page 49 of 132

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

quarter. Together with somewhat tighter financial conditions and the recent

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

widening fiscal and current account deficits and double-digit inflation amid growing
concerns about the central bank’s independence. Moreover, political uncertainty has
increased, with snap presidential and parliamentary elections called for late June
reducing the likelihood that the government will take the necessary policy actions to

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

address the country’s economic imbalances in the near term.

Page 50 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Page 51 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

The Foreign GDP Outlook

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Real GDP*

Percent change, annual rate

H1

2017
Q3

Q4

1. Total Foreign
Previous Tealbook

3.1
3.2

2.6
2.5

2.

Advanced Foreign Economies
Previous Tealbook
Canada
Euro Area
Japan
United Kingdom

3.2
3.1
4.3
2.8
2.3
1.1

Emerging Market Economies
Previous Tealbook
China
Emerging Asia ex. China
Mexico
Brazil

3.0
3.2
7.0
4.1
1.4
3.4

3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.

Q1

2018
Q2

2019

2020

H2

2.8
2.7

3.1
2.9

2.8
2.9

2.8
2.9

2.7
2.8

2.7
2.7

2.1
2.1
1.7
2.8
2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0
1.7
2.7
.6
1.6

1.2
1.9
1.3
1.6
-.6
.4

2.1
2.1
2.4
2.1
1.3
1.4

1.9
2.0
2.3
1.6
.9
1.6

1.7
1.8
2.1
1.5
.2
1.7

1.7
1.7
1.8
1.6
.9
1.7

3.0
2.8
6.6
5.1
-.2
1.1

3.6
3.4
6.5
3.3
3.6
.9

5.0
3.9
7.2
5.7
4.6
1.8

3.5
3.7
6.7
3.3
3.0
1.6

3.6
3.7
6.3
3.9
2.7
2.4

3.8
3.8
6.2
3.8
2.9
3.0

3.7
3.7
5.9
3.7
3.0
2.6

* GDP aggregates weighted by shares of U.S. merchandise exports.

Total Foreign GDP

Foreign GDP
Percent change, annual rate

Percent change, annual rate

5.5

Current
Previous Tealbook

8

Current
Previous Tealbook
5.0

7

4.5

6
Emerging market economies

4.0

5

3.5

4

3.0

3

2.5

2

2.0

1

1.5

0
Advanced foreign economies

1.0
2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

-1
2010

Page 52 of 132

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

The Foreign Inflation Outlook

Consumer Prices*

H1

2017
Q3

Q4

1. Total Foreign
Previous Tealbook

2.5
2.5

2.3
2.3

2.

Advanced Foreign Economies
Previous Tealbook
Canada
Euro Area
Japan
United Kingdom

1.3
1.3
1.4
1.5
-.1
3.3

Emerging Market Economies
Previous Tealbook
China
Emerging Asia ex. China
Mexico
Brazil

3.3
3.3
1.0
2.0
8.0
2.7

3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.

Q1

2018
Q2

2019

2020

H2

3.0
3.0

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.6

2.8
2.5

2.6
2.5

2.4
2.4

1.2
1.2
1.4
1.0
.7
2.4

2.1
2.1
3.0
1.7
1.9
3.0

2.6
2.6
3.6
2.0
2.5
2.4

1.7
1.9
3.0
2.2
-1.7
2.4

1.9
1.6
2.4
1.9
1.2
2.6

1.9
1.8
2.1
1.5
2.3
2.4

1.6
1.7
2.0
1.6
1.0
2.1

3.1
3.1
2.2
2.0
5.4
2.3

3.7
3.7
2.9
3.2
5.0
3.6

2.6
2.7
1.5
2.2
4.1
3.1

2.4
3.1
1.3
2.5
3.1
2.7

3.3
3.2
2.7
3.3
3.7
4.3

3.1
3.0
2.5
3.1
3.4
4.3

3.0
2.9
2.5
3.0
3.2
4.3

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Percent change, annual rate

* CPI aggregates weighted by shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

Foreign Monetary Policy
AFE Central Bank Balance Sheets

AFE Policy Rates
Percent

Percent of GDP

3.5

EME Policy Rates
Percent

100

3.0

15

Brazil

80

12

60

9

2.5
2.0
1.5

Japan
China*

Canada

40

1.0

United Kingdom

Mexico

0.5
20

Japan

3

United Kingdom

0.0
Euro area

Korea
Canada

-0.5
2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020

6

Euro area

0
2010

2012

2014

Page 53 of 132

2016

2018

0
2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
* 1-year benchmark lending rate.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Recent Foreign Indicators
Nominal Exports

Industrial Production
Jan. 2011 = 100

Foreign
AFE*

Jan. 2011 = 100

125

EME**

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

120
115

125
120
115

110
105

110

100

105

95
100

90

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

85
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

95
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Australia, Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Hong Kong, India,
Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand.

* Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, U.K.
** Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, India, Indonesia,
Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Russia, Singapore,
Taiwan, Thailand.

Retail Sales

Employment
12-month percent change

4-quarter percent change

8

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

6

3.0
2.5
2.0

4
1.5
2
1.0
0

0.5

-2
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

0.0
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Brazil, Chile, China, Korea, Mexico, Singapore, Taiwan.

* Includes Australia, Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, Israel, Korea, Mexico,
Philippines, Russia, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand, Turkey.

Consumer Prices: Advanced Foreign Economies

Consumer Prices: Emerging Market Economies

12-month percent change

12-month percent change

2.5

Headline
Core*

Headline*
Ex. food--Emerging Asia**
Ex. food--Latin America**

2.0

7
6
5
4

1.5

3
1.0

2
1

0.5

0
0.0
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Note: Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, U.K.
* Excludes all food and energy; staff calculation.
Source: Haver Analytics.

2018

-1
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia,
Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand.
** Excludes all food; staff calculation. Latin America excludes Argentina
and Venezuela.

Page 54 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Evolution of Staff’s International Forecast

Total Foreign GDP
Percent change, Q4/Q4

2017

2018

4

3
2019

2

12/10 1/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22

2015

9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20

3/9 4/20

6/8 7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18 3/2

2016

4/20 6/1 7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1 1/18

2017

3/8 4/19 6/1

1

2018

Tealbook publication date

Total Foreign CPI
Percent change, Q4/Q4

2017

3.0

2019
2.5

2018

2020

2.0

12/10 1/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22

2015

9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20

3/9 4/20

6/8 7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18 3/2

2016

4/20 6/1 7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1 1/18

2017

3/8 4/19 6/1

1.5

2018

Tealbook publication date

U.S. Current Account Balance
Percent of GDP

-2

-3
2020
2017

-4

2019
2018

-5

12/10 1/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22

2015

9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20

3/9 4/20

6/8 7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18 3/2

2016

2017
Tealbook publication date

Page 55 of 132

4/20 6/1 7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1 1/18

2018

3/8 4/19 6/1

-6

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

2020

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 56 of 132

June 1, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Financial Market Developments
Outside of this box, the Financial Market Developments section of the Tealbook is
based on information that was available by 5:00 p.m. EDT on May 31. On June 1, at
8:30 a.m. EDT, the Bureau of Labor Statistics published its Employment Situation
Report for May 2018. While the release was reportedly interpreted by market
participants as stronger than expected, by 9:00 a.m. (30 minutes after the official
release), long-term interest rates were only a few basis points above their levels at
5:00 p.m. on May 31, and equity index futures were up by about ½ percent.
Domestic financial markets were buffeted by increased concerns about the
outlook for foreign growth and political developments in Italy. On net, Treasury yields
moved down some, market-based measures of the expected levels of the federal funds
rate at the ends of 2019 and 2020 decreased moderately, and the dollar appreciated
notably as a range of AFE and EME currencies and sovereign bonds came under
pressure. However, broad domestic stock price indexes increased, on net, as generally



Sovereign spreads in peripheral Europe and several vulnerable EMEs widened
dramatically. The broad dollar index increased about 1¾ percent over the
intermeeting period.



Yields on 2- and 10-year Treasury securities both fell about 10 basis points on
net. The decline in 10-year nominal Treasury yields was due in roughly equal
parts to declines in TIPS yields and inflation compensation.



Broad domestic equity price indexes increased about 2 percent, while the VIX
was about flat on net. Risk spreads on investment- and speculative-grade
corporate bonds widened moderately, by about 10 basis points and 25 basis
points, respectively.



A straight read of market quotes implies that the probability of a rate increase
at the June meeting inched up further to near certainty, with roughly one
additional hike priced in for the period from July through the end of this year.

Page 57 of 132

Financial Markets

strong corporate earnings reports helped support prices.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Foreign Developments
10-Year Sovereign European Peripheral Spreads

10-Year AFE Sovereign Yields

Percent
Portugal
Italy
Spain

May
FOMC

Daily

Percent
United States
United Kingdom
Germany
Japan

3.5

Daily
May
FOMC

4.0

2.5
2.5
May
31

1.5
May
31

1.0

0.5

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.
2018

Apr.

-0.5

May

Jan.

Source: Bloomberg.

Feb.

Mar.
2018

Apr.

-0.5

May

Source: Bloomberg.

Equity Indexes

Exchange Rates
May 1, 2018 = 100
Broad index
Euro
Japanese yen

Daily

May 1, 2018 = 100

110
S&P 500
DJ Euro Stoxx
DJ Euro Bank Stoxx
EME

May
FOMC

105
Dollar
appreciation

May
31

Daily

May
FOMC

115

100

Financial Markets

May
31

95

95

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.
2018

Apr.

90

May

Jan.

Source: Bloomberg.

Feb.

Mar.
2018

Apr.

75

May

Note: EME stocks represented by MSCI local-currency index.
Source: Bloomberg; MSCI.

EME Exchange Rates

Emerging Market Flows and Spreads
May 1, 2018 = 100

Mexican peso
Turkish lira
Brazilian real
Argentine peso

Daily

140

15

May
FOMC

Billions of dollars
Basis points
500
Weekly bond flows (left scale)
Weekly equity flows (left scale)
450
May
FOMC

10

May
31

120
Dollar
appreciation

May
31

400
350

5
300
100

250

0

200
Jan.

Feb.

Source: Bloomberg.

Mar.
2018

Apr.

May

80

-5

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.
2018

Apr.

May

Note: Emerging market bond spreads over zero-coupon Treasury securities.
Flows data exclude intra-China flows. Monthly figures are averaged.
Source: EPFR; J.P. Morgan.

Page 58 of 132

150

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

A staff model that adjusts market rates for estimated term premiums implies
roughly two hikes over the same period.


A straight read of market quotes also suggests that the expected levels of the
federal funds rate for the end of 2019 and the end of 2020 each fell about
15 basis points—adjusting for term premiums, they fell an estimated 8 basis
points and 5 basis points, respectively.

FOREIGN DEVELOPMENTS
Political developments that amplified risks and macroeconomic data releases that
signaled a moderation in growth abroad weighed on prices of foreign risk assets over the
intermeeting period. These foreign developments, together with a still-solid economic
outlook for the United States, supported the dollar.
In Europe, financial markets reacted negatively to the political upheaval in Italy,
which was viewed as potentially undermining the country’s progress on fiscal
consolidation and rekindling fears about euro-area stability. Markets were also
concerned by the prospect of snap elections in Spain. Peripheral European 10-year
sovereign spreads jumped—123 basis points in Italy, 94 basis points in Greece, 52 basis
points in Portugal, and 44 basis points in Spain—and Italian sovereign CDS spreads also
expected euro-area PMI data, drove German long-term sovereign yields 22 basis points
lower. In the United Kingdom, the combination of risk-off sentiment and lower-thanexpected inflation data for April contributed to an 18 basis point decline in 10-year
sovereign yields. Investors revised down their expected policy paths in Europe; policy
rates implied by straight reads of overnight index swap rates in the euro area and the
United Kingdom fell 15 basis points at the 2-year horizon. On net, the dollar appreciated
by about 2½ percent against the euro and the pound.
The value of euro-area bank equities declined sharply, as investors were highly
attentive to political stresses in Italy and Spain, weakening macroeconomic data, and
ongoing restructuring troubles at Deutsche Bank. Euro-area bank stock indexes declined
14 percent, with Italian bank equity prices falling 20 percent. Broader measures of equity
prices declined much less, on net, as other sectors benefited from currency weakness and
lower interest rates in the core economies.

Page 59 of 132

Financial Markets

widened dramatically. The resulting flight-to-safety flows, along with weaker-than-

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Policy Expectations and Treasury Yields
Cumulative Number of 25 bps Rate Hikes Priced into Futures
Markets for Each FOMC Meeting over the Remainder of 2018
Number of hikes

Implied Federal Funds Rate
Percent
2.2

Most Recent: May 31, 2018
Last FOMC: May 1, 2018

5

Most recent: May 31, 2018
Last FOMC: May 1, 2018

2.0

4
With model−based
term premium

1.8
1.6

3

1.4
With zero
term premium

1.2

2

1.0
1
Aug. 1

June 13

Sept. 26

Nov. 8

2018

Dec. 19

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

Note: Zero term premium path is estimated using overnight index swap quotes
with a spline approach and a term premium of zero basis points. Model−based term
premium path is estimated using a term structure model maintained by Board staff
and corrects for term premium.
Source: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

Note: Expected number of rate increases implied by a binomial tree fitted to
settlement prices on federal funds futures contracts. The "Most Recent" path takes into
account the anticipated effect of the adjustment in IOER discussed in the May FOMC
meeting minutes.
Source: CME Group; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

Selected Interest Rates

Financial Markets

Percent
2.85
2.80
2.75
2.70
2.65
2.60
2.55
2.50
2.45
2.40
2.35
2.30
2.25

Percent
May FOMC
minutes

April CPI

May FOMC
statement
April
employment
report

Iran deal
withdrawal
announcement

April retail sales

3.25

Political turmoil
in Italy

10−year
Treasury yield
European
(right scale)
PMI

3.20
3.15
3.10

release

3.05
3.00
2.95

2−year
Treasury yield
(left scale)

2.90
May 31
4:00 p.m.

2.85
2.80
2.75

May 4

May 9

May 14

May 17

May 22

May 25

2.70

May 30

Note: 5−minute intervals, 8:00 a.m. to 4:00 p.m. Data shown are for 2018.
Source: Bloomberg.

Treasury Yield Curve

TIPS−Based Inflation Compensation
Percent

Percent

3.5

Most recent: May 31, 2018
Last FOMC: May 1, 2018

May
FOMC

5 to 10 years ahead
May
31

3.0

2.5

2.0

1.5
2.5
1.0
Next 5 years*
2.0
2

5

10

20
Maturity in years

Note: Smoothed yield curve estimated from off-the-run Treasury coupon
securities. Yields shown are those on notional par Treasury securities with
semiannual coupons.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board staff
estimates.

30

Jan.

May Sept.
2016

Jan.

May Sept.
2017

Jan. May
2018

0.5

Note: Estimates based on smoothed nominal and inflation-indexed Treasury yield
curves.
* Adjusted for lagged indexation of Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities (carry effect).
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board
staff estimates.

Page 60 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Against the backdrop of the notable increase in U.S. interest rates since late 2017,
recent political developments in several fragile EMEs have intensified concerns about
emerging economies’ financial vulnerabilities, leading to a sharp appreciation of the
dollar against these currencies over the intermeeting period. (For more details, see the
box “Recent Financial Pressures in Emerging Market Economies” in the International
Economic Developments and Outlook section.) Exchange rates depreciated against the
dollar by 22 percent in Argentina, 10 percent in Turkey, and 6 percent in Brazil following
adverse domestic developments (both economic and political). The Mexican peso
depreciated by about 5 percent amid political uncertainty and an absence of progress in
NAFTA negotiations. Equity indexes in some EMEs declined by up to 11 percent, while
broad measures of EME equity prices decreased by up to 4 percent. EME mutual funds
saw slight net outflows, and EME sovereign spreads widened about 29 basis points
on net.

DOMESTIC DEVELOPMENTS
FOMC communications over the intermeeting period—including the May FOMC
statement and the May FOMC meeting minutes—elicited only minor reactions in asset
markets. However, the Committee’s characterization of inflation in both the statement
and the minutes garnered substantial attention. In particular, market commentaries noted
and the addition of the word “symmetric” to characterize the inflation objective over the
medium term. Market participants also noted a reference in the FOMC minutes
suggesting that a temporary period with inflation modestly above 2 percent would be
consistent with the Committee’s symmetric objective.
Quotes on federal funds futures contracts suggest that the market-implied
probability for the next rate hike occurring at the June FOMC meeting inched up further
to near certainty. A straight read of market quotes suggests that roughly one additional
rate hike is priced in for the period from July through the end of this year, while a staff
model that adjusts for estimated term premiums implies that market participants expect
roughly two hikes over the same period. Both of these readings are little changed from
the time of the May FOMC meeting.
At horizons beyond the end of this year, market-based measures of the expected
path of the federal funds rate fell somewhat, with most of the declines occurring late in
the intermeeting period as concerns regarding political developments in Europe
Page 61 of 132

Financial Markets

the passages stating that both headline and core inflation have moved “close to 2 percent”

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Corporate Asset Market Developments
Intraday S&P 500 Index
May 1, 2018, 4:00 p.m. = 100
April CPI

April retail sales

May FOMC
statement

European
PMI
release

April
Iran deal
employment
withdrawal
report
announcement

May FOMC
Minutes
release

107
106

Political turmoil
in Italy

105
104
103
May
31

102
101
100
99
98
97

May 3

May 10

May 17
2018

May 24

May 31

Note: Data are spaced at 5-minute intervals from 9:30 a.m. to 4:00 p.m.
Source: Bloomberg.

Implied Volatility on S&P 500 (VIX)

S&P 500 Industry Indexes

Log scale, percent

May 1, 2018 = 100
Daily

S&P 500
S&P Utilities
S&P Technology

Daily

May
FOMC

May
FOMC

VIX
Realized volatility

115

20

May
31
May
31

100

Financial Markets

50

10

5
85
Nov.
2017

Jan.

Mar.
2018

May

2012

Source: Bloomberg.

2016

2018

Source: Chicago Board Options Exchange; Bloomberg.

10-Year Corporate Bond Yields

10-Year Corporate Bond Spreads
Percent

Basis points
11 400

Daily

2014

May
FOMC

High-yield
Triple-B

800

Daily

8

May
FOMC

High-yield
(right scale)
Triple-B (left scale)

10 350
9

Basis points

300

600

250
500

7
6
May
31

2012

2014

2016

5

200
May
31

150

4

100

3

50

400
300
200

2018

Source: Staff estimates of smoothed yield curves based on Merrill Lynch
bond data.

700

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: Spreads over 10-year Treasury yield.
Source: Staff estimates of smoothed yield curves based on Merrill Lynch
bond data and smoothed Treasury yield curve.

Page 62 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

intensified. On net, a straight read of market quotes suggests that the expected path fell
15 basis points at the end of 2019 and 13 basis points at the end of 2020. However, after
a staff model is used to adjust for term premiums, those decreases in the expected path
were estimated to be only 8 basis points and 5 basis points, respectively. Regarding the
level of the path in the medium term, a straight read of market quotes suggests that
market participants expect approximately two hikes cumulatively in 2019 and 2020
(approximately three after adjusting for term premiums).
Longer-term nominal Treasury yields fell somewhat, on net, since the May
FOMC meeting, with 10-year yields decreasing 13 basis points. The decline was about
equally split between TIPS yields and inflation compensation. Yields experienced some
notable one-day moves, particularly late in the period. Following the release of the
advance estimate of April retail sales, long-term yields moved up about 7 basis points.
Subsequently, however, yields declined in reaction to weaker-than-expected European
PMI prints and, shortly thereafter, in response to political developments in Italy. (For
analysis of the information content of the yield curve for the probability of recession, see
the box “Don’t Fear the Long-Term Spread.”)
Option-adjusted spreads on current-coupon MBS over Treasury yields remained
about unchanged over the intermeeting period. Overall, we continue to see limited
program, although market participants reportedly expect that MBS spreads might widen
as the volume of reinvestments declines later this year.1
Broad U.S. equity price indexes increased 2 percent, on net, since the May FOMC
meeting. Stock prices were buoyed by first-quarter earnings reports that generally beat
expectations, particularly for the technology sector, which outperformed the broader
market. However, the turbulence abroad and, to a lesser degree, mounting concerns over
the potential for trade wars weighed on equity prices at times. Option-implied volatility
on the S&P 500 at the one-month horizon—the VIX—was about flat, on net, remaining
just a couple of percentage points above the very low levels that prevailed before early
February.

Since the start of balance sheet normalization in October 2017 through late May 2018, the
Federal Reserve’s holdings of Treasury securities have decreased by $79 billion, and its holdings of agency
securities have decreased by $42 billion, as reported in the weekly H.4.1 statistical release.
1

Page 63 of 132

Financial Markets

effects on MBS prices from the implementation of the balance sheet normalization

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Don’t Fear the Long‐Term Spread
Commonly cited measures of the term spread, such as the difference between the 10‐year and
2‐year nominal Treasury yields, have dropped over the past several years (figure 1, blue line). This
trend has raised some concerns because low term spreads appear to have statistical power for
predicting recessions over the coming year.1 In this discussion, we document that for predicting
recessions, a “long‐term spread”—the spread in yields between a far‐off maturity such as 10 years
and a shorter maturity such as 1 or 2 years—is inferior to a more economically intuitive alternative,
a “near‐term spread.”
We focus on the difference between 5‐quarter‐ahead and 1‐quarter‐ahead forward interest rates
(figure 1, red line). This near‐term spread is driven largely by the market’s expectations for the path
of the federal funds rate over the year ahead. Indeed, the near‐term spread co‐varies closely with a
survey‐based measure of such expectations, the dotted red line. Currently, the near‐term spread is
not much below its long‐run average level. Looking ahead, the staff projection suggests that the
near‐term spread will decline, on net, as the policy rate trends toward its neutral level.2 If instead
the near‐term spread becomes decidedly negative, that would signal that market participants expect
the Fed to significantly lower rates in the year ahead, presumably owing to an economic slowdown.
Consistent with this reasoning, our empirical analysis finds that a relatively low near‐term spread
implies a higher probability of a recession over the next four quarters, similar to findings using
long‐term spreads. Moreover, we find that, after conditioning on a near‐term spread, long‐term
spreads offer no additional predictive power for past recessions.

Financial Markets

Figure 1: Spreads of Yields and Market‐Expected Paths of Short Rates

1 The predictive value of long‐term spreads has not diminished of late, as confirmed in Michael D. Bauer and
Thomas M. Mertens (2018), “Economic Forecasts with the Yield Curve,” FRBSF Economic Letter 2018‐07 (San
Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, March 5); and Peter Johansson and Andrew Meldrum (2018),
“Predicting Recession Probabilities Using the Slope of the Yield Curve,” FEDS Notes (Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 1). The latter paper also finds that when the first three principal
components of the yield curve are included as regressors, the current probability of recession is lower than is
implied by conditioning on the term slope alone.
2 Over the forecast period, constructing the long‐term spread required interpolation from the yields included in
the staff projection; the near‐term spread is driven largely by the inertial Taylor rule that the staff uses to set the
path of short ‐term interest rates.

Page 64 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Our analysis is based on a probit model, estimated on data from 1972:Q1 to 2018:Q1, where the
probability of transition to recession in the four quarters ahead is a function of the near‐term and
long‐term spreads and, in some specifications, added controls. In this model, the near‐term spread
is highly significant; all else being equal, when it falls from its mean level by one standard deviation
(80 basis points), the probability of recession increases by almost 40 percentage points. In
contrast, the coefficient on the long‐term spread is economically small and not statistically
different from zero.3 As shown in figure 2, the fitted conditional probabilities of recession from our
model (red line) show somewhat sharper spikes before recessions than a model using only the
long‐term spread (blue line).
While the predicted recession probabilities from the two models generally track each other fairly
closely, a noticeable divergence appears in the forecast period. The model based on long‐term
spreads suggests that the probability of recession will move up considerably as the long‐term
spread falls well below its long‐run mean level. However, the model based on the near‐term
spread suggests that the probability of recession will increase much less, as short‐term rates in the
staff’s projection flatten but do not invert in the medium term.
The forecast aside, the main lesson we take away from this exercise is that the current near‐term
spread, which arguably serves as a proxy for market expectations of Federal Reserve policy,
suggests the market is putting fairly low odds on a recession‐induced rate cut over the next four
quarters. More generally, our findings do not support appealing to the long‐term spread for a
different signal about year‐ahead economic growth.

Financial Markets

Figure 2: Estimated Probabilities of Recession

3 Controls included the level of the 30‐day Treasury bill rate and the “excess bond premium” from Simon

Gilchrist and Egon Zakrajsek (2012), “Credit Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations,” American Economic Review,
vol. 102 (June), pp. 1692–720. The controls were included in separate estimations to test whether our main findings
are robust to the inclusion of the controls. Figure 2 shows results from a specification without the controls to
isolate and illustrate the effect of the near‐term slope.
In another departure from the standard literature, we drop from the estimation any observations in which the
economy was already in recession in the previous quarter. This choice enables us to estimate the probability of
transition into recession, rather than the probability of either transitioning or remaining in recession, which most
studies estimate. This change lowers the current recession probability estimate based on the far‐term spread from
about 30 percent to 20 percent. We also drop observations during which the effective lower bound was binding,
following other recent studies.

Page 65 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Short−Term Funding Markets and Federal Reserve Operations
Nonfinancial CP Spreads

CD Spreads to OIS
Percentage points

Percentage points
1.2

Overnight double−A
1−month double−A
Overnight A2/P2
1−month A2/P2

May
FOMC

0.8

1.0

May
31

May
FOMC

3−month
1−month

May
31

0.8

0.7
0.6
0.5

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.2
0.1

0.0
0.0

May

Aug.

Nov.

Feb.

2017

−0.2

−0.1

−0.4

−0.2

May

May

2018

Selected Money Market Rates

May
FOMC

Financial Markets

Triparty Treasury repo
1−month Treasury bill
Federal funds
Eurodollar

Nov.

Feb.

2017

Basis points

Daily

Aug.

May
2018

Note: Certificate of deposit (CD) rates are a 5−day moving average.
OIS is overnight index swap.
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation.

Note: Overnight commercial paper (CP) spreads are to federal funds rate.
1−month CP spreads are to overnight index swap rates.
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation.

ON RRP Take−Up, by Type
Daily

200

May
FOMC

Government MMFs
Prime MMFs
Other

180

May
30

Billions of dollars

220

500
450

160

400

140

350

120

300

100

250

80

200

60

150

40

May
31

20
0
Oct.
Jan.
2016

Apr.

July
2017

Oct.

Jan.

50
0

Note: ON RRP is overnight reverse repurchase agreement; MMF is money
market fund.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Cumulative Change in Net Treasury Positions

ON RRP Take−Up on Month−Ends

Billions of dollars
Foreign official holdings
Primary dealer holdings

100

Jan. Apr. July Oct. Jan. Apr. July Oct. Jan. Apr.
2018
2016
2017

Apr.
2018

Note: Federal funds rate is a weighted median. Shaded area is the target range for
the federal funds rate. Repo is repurchase agreement.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board Form
FR 2420, Report of Selected Money Market Rates.

Weekly

550

Billions of dollars
140

May
FOMC

120

350
300

100

250

80
60

200

40

150

20
100

0

50

−20
−40
Jan. 1

Jan. 22

Feb. 12 Mar. 5

Mar. 26 Apr. 16
2018

May 7

0

May 30

Source: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, "Factors Affecting
Reserve Balances"; Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2004A, Weekly Report of Dealer
Positions.

July

Sept
2017

Nov.

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Page 66 of 132

Jan.

Mar.
2018

May

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Over the intermeeting period, spreads of yields on nonfinancial corporate bonds
over those of comparable-maturity Treasury securities widened moderately for both
investment- and speculative-grade firms, with speculative-grade bond spreads up by
about 25 basis points. However, these spreads remain low by historical standards.

SHORT-TERM FUNDING MARKETS AND FEDERAL RESERVE OPERATIONS
Over the intermeeting period, short-term funding markets remained generally
stable despite still-elevated spreads of some private money market instruments to rates
reflecting the expected path of the federal funds rate.2 Spreads on both nonfinancial
commercial paper and certificates of deposit, particularly at one-month and longer tenors,
have edged down further since the previous FOMC meeting. Similarly, the three-month
U.S. dollar LIBOR decreased slightly over the intermeeting period, while OIS rates were
little changed, leading to a narrowing of the LIBOR–OIS spread. While some of the
factors contributing to pressures in short-term funding markets have eased recently, the
three-month LIBOR–OIS spread remains significantly wider than at the start of the year.
Because elevated rates on other short-term investments offered an attractive
alternative for market participants, take-up at the Federal Reserve’s ON RRP facility

The implied rate on July federal funds futures declined about 3½ basis points after
the release of the May FOMC minutes, which noted the possibility of a technical
adjustment of the administered IOER rate to a level 5 basis points below the top of the
target range for the federal funds rate. Reportedly, market participants generally expect
the adjustment, which is intended to keep the federal funds rate well within the FOMC’s
target range, to be announced during the June FOMC meeting.

On May 7, the CME began trading one- and three-month futures on the Secured Overnight
Financing Rate (SOFR), one of the Fed’s new overnight Treasury repo rates. Despite limited trading so far,
the launch was in line with expectations and is an important step in the transition from LIBOR to SOFR.
2

Page 67 of 132

Financial Markets

remained low, averaging about $5 billion per day.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Financial Markets

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 68 of 132

June 1, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Financing Conditions for Businesses and Households
Data received over the intermeeting period indicate that financing conditions for
businesses and households remain supportive of economic activity on balance.
•

Bank lending to businesses and the issuance of institutional leveraged loans
were strong in April, offsetting seasonal weakness in corporate bond issuance.
Corporate earnings increased notably in the first quarter in part because of the
enactment of the new tax legislation, and spreads on corporate debt and
institutional leveraged loans remained low.

•

Mortgage credit has remained widely available for most borrowers; for
borrowers with low credit scores, conditions remain tight but have continued
to ease. Growth in home-purchase mortgages has slowed a bit and refinancing
activity has continued to be muted in recent months, with both developments
partly reflecting the rise in mortgage rates earlier this year.

•

Financing conditions in consumer credit markets were little changed in the
first few months of 2018, on balance, and remained largely supportive of
growth in household spending. However, consumer credit grew at a slower
pace in the first quarter compared with the rapid pace observed late last year,
and the supply of consumer credit to borrowers with subprime credit scores
continued to tighten.

BUSINESS FINANCING CONDITIONS
Nonfinancial Corporations
Financing conditions for nonfinancial corporations remained accommodative over
the intermeeting period. Although corporate bond spreads widened, on net, particularly
issuance of corporate bonds in April was below its average pace over the previous few
months; however, this step-down likely reflects the typical slowdown that occurs during
the corporate earnings reporting season. Preliminary data for May suggests that corporate
bond issuance has returned to a moderate pace.

Page 69 of 132

Financing Conditions

for speculative-grade borrowers, they remained low by historical standards. Gross

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Business Finance
Gross Issuance of Nonfinancial
Corporate Bonds

Commercial and Industrial Loans
Billions of dollars

Billions of dollars
120

Monthly rate
Speculative-grade
Investment-grade

100
H1

H2 Q1

30

Monthly rate, s.a.

Apr.

Large banks
Small banks
Foreign banks

80

25
20
15

60

Apr.

10

Q1

40
H1

H2

5

20

0

0
2011

2013

2015

2017

-5

2018

2011

Note: Bonds are categorized by Moody's, Standard & Poor's, and Fitch.
Source: Mergent Fixed Income Securities Database.

2013

2015

2017

Source: Staff calculations, Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2644, Weekly
Report of Selected Assets and Liabilities of Domestically Chartered Commercial
Banks and U.S. Branches and Agencies of Foreign Banks.

Institutional Leveraged Loan Issuance,
by Purpose

Average Spread of New-Issue Institutional
Leveraged Loans

Billions of dollars

Basis points
100

Monthly rate

2018

Monthly

H1

Refinancings
New money

B+/B
BB/BB-

80
H2 Q1 Apr.

60
40
Apr.

20
0
2011

2013

2015

2017

2018

2006

Source: Thomson Reuters LPC LoanConnector.

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

Delinquency Rate in CMBS Pools

Billions of dollars
Monthly rate
C&I Loans
Institutional leveraged loans
Bonds

Q1 Apr.
H1

2013

2015

2018

Note: Breaks in the series represent periods with no issuance. Spreads are
calculated against 3-month LIBOR. The spreads do not include up-front fees.
Source: S&P LCD.

Selected Components of Net Debt Financing,
Nonfinancial Firms

2011

650
600
550
500
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100

H2

2017

Percent
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20

10
8
Apr.

6
4
2
0

2018

Note: C&I is commercial and industrial.
Source: Federal Reserve Board; Thomson Reuters LPC; Mergent Fixed
Income Securities Database.

12

Monthly

2003

2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

Note: The delinquency rate is the percent of commercial mortgages in CMBS
pools 30 days or more past due.
Source: Citigroup.

Page 70 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Growth of outstanding C&I loans was strong in April at both large and small
domestic banks as well as at foreign banks. This stronger C&I loan growth follows a
period of weaker growth that was attributed in the April SLOOS to weak loan demand,
stemming in part from the widespread availability of internal funds and financing from
other sources of credit. Preliminary data for May suggests some moderation of C&I
loan growth.
The market for institutional leveraged loans continued to suggest highly
accommodative conditions. Issuance volume remained strong in April, with the proceeds
continuing to be mostly targeted toward refinancing. New money issuance was roughly
in line with average levels earlier this year, suggesting little change in the demand to raise
new funds through this market. Spreads on newly issued institutional leveraged loans
were close to their post-crisis lows in April, with preliminary data for May suggesting
that spreads narrowed further for higher-rated loans and were roughly unchanged for
lower-rated loans.
All told, net debt financing for the corporate sector in April continued at a
moderate pace. With respect to the composition of net debt financing, strong net issuance
of C&I and institutional leveraged loans in April was partly offset by a net paydown in
corporate bonds outstanding.
The credit quality of nonfinancial corporations remained stable over the
intermeeting period. Although the aggregate leverage ratio for nonfinancial corporations
remained high, the ratio of interest expense to cash flow remained near multidecade lows,
reflecting low yields on corporate debt and strong corporate earnings. The first-quarter
earnings reporting season, which began in April but continued into the current
intermeeting period, saw earnings announcements that significantly and broadly beat
Wall Street forecasts. Wall Street analysts have also slightly revised up their forecasts for
the remainder of the year.

nonfinancial corporate bond upgrades somewhat outpaced the very small volume of bond
downgrades in April. The six-month trailing bond default rate ticked up in April to about
the midpoint of its historical range, while the KMV year-ahead expected default rate in
April was similar to that in March and stands just below the median of its historical range.

Page 71 of 132

Financing Conditions

Other measures also point to stable corporate credit quality. The volume of

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

The volume of equity issuance through initial offerings in April was about in line
with its average pace over the past few years, while the volume for seasoned offerings
decreased a bit from its robust pace in the first quarter, in part because of the earnings
blackout period that also affected corporate bond issuance. Completed stock repurchases
in the first quarter were at their highest levels in two years, partly reflecting increased
cash distributions to shareholders following the tax reform.

Small Businesses
Credit market conditions for small businesses remained relatively accommodative
over the intermeeting period, and data on new commercial loans and leases to small
businesses from Thomson Reuters/PayNet suggest that originations have picked up in
recent months. Measures of small business sentiment—including those with respect to
plans for expansion and capital expenditure—are little changed and remain near postcrisis highs. Recent indicators of loan performance remain strong, with delinquency rates
near historical lows.

Commercial Real Estate
Financing conditions for commercial real estate (CRE) also remained
accommodative. Even so, the growth of CRE loans held by banks ticked down in April.
While growth slowed across all three major CRE loan types, the slowdown was most
pronounced for construction and land development loans.
Spreads on commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS) were little changed
over the intermeeting period, remaining near their post-crisis lows. CMBS issuance, in
general, has been robust this year, although it softened somewhat in April, partly
reflecting seasonal factors. Market participants expect issuance to continue to decline in
the near term because of competition from alternate lending sources such as direct loans
from banks and nonbank financial institutions, a reduction in the volume of maturing precrisis-era loans that need to be refinanced, and fewer property acquisitions. Meanwhile,
the delinquency rate on mortgages in CMBS pools continued to decline, with borrowers’
ability to refinance maturing loans boosted by rising property values and low spreads on
newly issued securities.

MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT FINANCING CONDITIONS
Over the intermeeting period, debt financing continued to be readily available to
municipalities at fairly attractive terms. Yields on 20-year general obligation (GO) bonds
Page 72 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

decreased slightly more than yields on Treasury securities of comparable maturity. In
addition, gross issuance in April was solid, as issuance continued to recover from the
slow pace recorded at the start of the year. Compared with the same month last year,
issuance for new capital expenditures was up slightly, while issuance earmarked for
refinancing was essentially the same. On aggregate, the credit quality of GO bonds
remained stable in April, with modest numbers of upgrades and downgrades in
credit ratings.

HOUSEHOLD FINANCING CONDITIONS
Residential Real Estate
Over the intermeeting period, rates on 30-year conforming mortgages declined, on
net, about in line with yields on agency MBS and longer-term Treasury securities.
Growth in home-purchase mortgages has slowed a bit and refinancing activity has
continued to be muted in recent months, in part reflecting the notable increase in
mortgage rates earlier this year. That said, conditions in the residential mortgage market
appeared to be healthy on balance. The delinquency rate on residential mortgages, which
had ticked up following Hurricanes Harvey and Irma, retreated in February and March.
In addition, financing conditions in the residential mortgage market remained
accommodative for most borrowers. The maximum allowed debt-service-to-income ratio
for borrowers with high credit scores edged up in the first quarter, with current levels near
but still below the pre-crisis peak. For borrowers with low credit scores, conditions
remain tight but have continued to ease.

Consumer Credit
Financing conditions in consumer credit markets were little changed in the first
few months of 2018 and remained largely supportive of growth in household
spending. Growth in consumer credit slowed a bit in the first quarter, as credit card

Household demand for consumer credit appeared to remain solid in recent months.
Responses to the Michigan survey suggested that while consumers generally expect
further interest rate increases, their demand for vehicles or other durable goods
remains strong.
Supply of credit to consumers with subprime credit scores continued to tighten,
likely contributing to a slowing in new extensions of auto loans to subprime borrowers.
Page 73 of 132

Financing Conditions

balances edged down slightly after having surged in the fourth quarter of last year.

Authorized for Public Release
Household Finance

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Mortgage Rate and MBS Yield

Purchase and Refinance Activity
Percent

Daily

May
FOMC

6.0
5.5

30-year conforming
fixed mortgage rate

5.0
4.5
May
30

4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5

MBS yield

2.0
1.5

2014

2015

2016

June 1, 2018

2017

700

Thousands of originations

Thousands of originations
Monthly

600

2000

500

Home purchase
(left scale)

1500

400
1000

Refinance
(right scale)

300

Apr.

500

200
100

0

2018

2003

2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

Note: The mortgage-backed securities (MBS) yield is the Fannie Mae 30-year
current-coupon rate.
Source: For MBS yield, Barclays; for mortgage rate, Optimal Blue.

Note: The data are seasonally adjusted by Federal Reserve Board staff.
Source: For values prior to 2017, data reported under the Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act of 1975; for values in and after 2017, staff estimates.

Delinquencies on Prime Mortgages

Maximum Allowed Debt-Service-to-Income
Ratio for Residential Morgages
Percent

Monthly

DTI ratio
8

Quarterly

70

6
4

90
80

FICO >= 720

Mar.

2500

60
50

FICO <= 620
Q1

40
30

2

20
10

0

0
2000

2003

2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

2002

Note: The delinquency rate is the percent of loans 90 or more days past due
or in foreclosure.
Source: LPS Applied Analytics/Black Knight.

2010

2014

2018

Source: For frontiers shown with circles, McDash and CoreLogic; for frontiers
shown with solid lines, Optimal Blue.

Delinquency Rates on Consumer Loans for
Subprime Borrowers

Consumer Credit Flows
Billions of dollars
Monthly rate

2006

Student loans
Auto loans
Credit cards

30
25

Percent
Quarterly

22
20

20

H2
H1
Q1

18

15

16

Credit cards

10

14

5

Q1

0

8

Auto loans

-10

6

-15
2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

4
2000

Note: The data are seasonally adjusted by Federal Reserve Board staff.
Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Page 74 of 132

12
10

-5

2008

24

2003

2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

Note: Delinquency rates measure the percent of balances that are at least
30 days past due, excluding severe derogatory loans. Subprime refers to
credit scores below 620. Credit scores lagged 4 quarters. 4-quarter moving
average.
Source: FRBNY/Equifax Consumer Credit Panel.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

This tightening of credit supply for subprime borrowers comes against a backdrop of
some signs of deterioration in the credit performance of loans extended to such borrowers
over recent years, such as higher delinquency rates on auto and credit card loans. That
said, the likelihood of success in opening a new credit account of any kind—a measure
that is helpful in tracking credit supply conditions—remained near its pre-crisis peak for

Financing Conditions

subprime borrowers.

Page 75 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 76 of 132

June 1, 2018

June 1, 2018

Risks and Uncertainty
ASSESSMENT OF RISKS
As in the April Tealbook, we view the uncertainty around our forecast of
economic activity as being in line with the average over the past 20 years, the benchmark
used by the FOMC.
We judge the risks around our projection for real GDP growth as being balanced.
On the upside, the impetus to economic growth could be greater than we expect. For
instance, business sentiment and profit expectations have rallied, apparently in response
to the recent changes to fiscal policy and prospects for deregulation; our models that take
these indicators into account predict a faster pace of business investment than we have
built into the projection. On the downside, the recent tax cuts could produce a smaller
boost to aggregate demand than we have written down. For instance, consumers in the
upper part of the income distribution, toward whom the tax benefits are skewed, could
have even lower marginal propensities to consume than we have assumed. Another
possibility is that the economic spillovers stemming from political turmoil in Italy could
be substantial.
While we have left our assessment of risks unchanged for now, we are grappling
with staff and outside analysis indicating that some aspects of our forecast are consistent
with a more substantial slowdown in economic activity than we currently project.1 For
instance, the box “Alternative View: A Strong but Precarious Projection” argues that the
constellation of paths for the output gap, federal funds rate, 10-year Treasury yield, and
bond spreads in our projection has, in the past, been consistent with a recession. More
generally, the staff is not very good at forecasting recessions, which historically have
generated sharp increases in the unemployment rate. As we analyze these issues further,
we will continue to reassess the balance of risks.
With regard to inflation, we still see average uncertainty and balanced risks
around our projection. To the downside of our modal outlook, the inflation expectations
relevant for wage and price setting could currently be lower than in the baseline or may

Indeed, these analyses motivated our move to temper the strength of real activity in the baseline
projection over the past two Tealbooks.
1

Page 77 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Risks & Uncertainty

Time-Varying Macroeconomic Risk
Unemployment Rate

Percent

90%
70%
50%

6

May 2018

5

95th

0.4

4

85th

0.2

2

50th

-0.2

1

15th

-0.6

5th

-0.9

3

0
-1
-2
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

GDP Growth

Percent

May 2018

4
2

95th

1.9

0

85th

1.2

-2

50th

0.1

-4

15th

-1.0

-6

5th

-1.7

-8
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

CPI Inflation

1990

1995

2000

2005

Percent

2010

7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3

May 2018
95th

1.8

85th

1.1

50th

0.1

15th

-0.8

5th

-1.3

2015

Note: The exhibit shows estimates of quantiles of the distribution of errors for four-quarter-ahead staff
forecasts. The estimates are conditioned on indicators of real activity, inflation, financial market strain,
and the volatility of high-frequency macroeconomic indicators. The tables show selected quantiles of the
predictive distributions for the respective variables as of the current Tealbook. Dashed lines denote the
median 15ᵗʰ and 85ᵗʰ percentiles. Gray shaded bars indicate recession periods as defined by the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Page 78 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Effective Lower Bound Risk Estimate

ELB Risk since Liftoff
Percent

50

40

Current-quarter ELB risk = 8%
30

20

10

0
Mar. 2016

June 2016

Sept. 2016

Dec. 2016

Mar. 2017

June 2017

Sept. 2017

Dec. 2017

Mar. 2018

June 2018

ELB Risk over the Projection Period
Percent

20

15

10

5

0
2018:Q2

2018:Q4

2019:Q2

2019:Q4

2020:Q2

2020:Q4

Note: The figures show the probability that the federal funds rate reaches the effective lower
bound (ELB) over the next 3 years starting in the given quarter. Details behind the computation of
the ELB risk measure are provided in the box "A Guidepost for Dropping the Effective Lower
Bound Risk from the Assessment of Risks" in the Risks and Uncertainty section of the April 2017
Tealbook A. The lower panel computes ELB risk over a forward-looking moving 3-year window
using stochastic simulations in FRB/US beginning in the current quarter. The simulations are
computed around the Tealbook baseline.

Page 79 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

not edge up in the coming years as we have assumed. To the upside, with the economy
projected to be moving further above its long-run potential, inflation may increase more
than in the staff forecast, consistent with the predictions of models that emphasize
nonlinear effects of economic slack on inflation. Our judgmental assessments of typical
uncertainty and balanced risks are consistent with the statistical estimates of the timevarying risks for the inflation forecast.

ALTERNATIVE SCENARIOS
To illustrate some of the risks to the outlook, we construct alternatives to the
baseline projection using simulations of staff models. The first scenario illustrates the
outcomes associated with a recession triggered by a sharp correction in asset valuations.
The second scenario examines the consequences of a more severe manifestation of supply
constraints than is built into the baseline projection. In contrast, in the third scenario, the
extended period of very high resource utilization envisioned in the baseline projection
leads to persistent positive effects on the productive capacity of the economy—a form of
“positive hysteresis.” The fourth scenario illustrates the consequences of a lower natural
rate of unemployment that is initially misperceived by the central bank. In the fifth
scenario, we analyze the effects of a heightened risk of a breakup of the euro area that
reverberates around the global economy. The sixth scenario considers the possibility that
financial turbulence in emerging market economies (EMEs) leads to a global economic
slowdown and a stronger appreciation of the dollar.
We simulate each of these scenarios using one of three staff models that embed
different macroeconomic structures and dynamics.2 With one exception, the federal
funds rate is governed by the same policy rule as in the baseline; the first scenario, which
features a recession, allows for a more aggressive monetary policy response in the early
quarters of the simulation. In addition, the size and composition of the SOMA portfolio
are assumed to follow the baseline paths in all of the scenarios.

2
The three models used are: (1) FRB/US, which is a large-scale macroeconometric model of the
U.S. economy; (2) a calibrated New Keynesian DSGE model with search and matching frictions in the
labor market similar to that described in Mark L. Gertler, Luca Sala, and Antonella Trigari (2008), “An
Estimated Monetary DSGE Model with Unemployment and Staggered Nominal Wage Bargaining,”
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 40 (8), pp. 1713–64; and (3) SIGMA, which is a calibrated
multicountry DSGE model.

Page 80 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Financial Correction with Return to Effective Lower Bound [FRB/US]
Asset valuations in equity and corporate bond markets are still considered to be at
an elevated level despite some easing from earlier this year. In this scenario, we assume
a correction in asset prices that leads to persistently higher risk premiums and a
curtailment of credit to households and businesses. In addition, we assume negative
shocks to consumption, investment, and aggregate labor hours beyond those implied by
the initial tightening of financial conditions. These negative shocks could be interpreted
as changes in sentiment (or animal spirits) but also possibly as further adverse effects of
tighter leverage constraints and disruption in the supply of credit that are not captured by
the standard equations of the FRB/US model. Finally, consistent with the historical
tendency of the Committee to cut rates aggressively in downturns, we assume that, at the
onset of the recession, the federal funds rate is determined by the non-inertial Taylor rule.
With stock market prices falling about 25 percent by the end of 2018 and the
triple-B corporate bond spread rising about 200 basis points above the baseline, real GDP
contracts for several consecutive quarters beginning in the fourth quarter of 2018. The
unemployment rate increases 2¾ percentage points—roughly the historical average of the
increases observed in the recessions that have occurred in the post–World War II
period—reaching 6½ percent in late 2019. Core and headline PCE inflation fall
½ percentage point below the baseline by early 2020. With policymakers reacting
quickly to the downturn, the federal funds rate returns to the effective lower bound in the
second quarter of 2019 and stays there until the end of 2020; thereafter, it gradually
increases and reaches about 3 percent by the end of 2023.3

Supply Constraints [Gertler, Sala, and Trigari Model]
In the baseline projection, the unemployment rate declines to a little below
3½ percent by early 2019 and remains below the staff’s estimate of the natural rate for a
number of years. However, with the economy operating so far above its potential level,
supply constraints could bind even more severely than we have assumed in the baseline
projection. For instance, when the unemployment rate is unusually low, filling a vacancy
becomes more difficult, which could imply a reduced pace of hiring and a substantially
With the inertial Taylor rule, the Committee would cut rates less aggressively. As a result, the
federal funds rate would not reach the effective lower bound and economic outcomes would be worse; the
unemployment rate would be ½ percentage point higher at its peak, and real GDP growth would be
¾ percentage point lower at its trough.
3

Page 81 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Alternative Scenarios
Risks & Uncertainty

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

2018
Measure and scenario
H1

H2

2019 2020 2021 202223

Real GDP
Tealbook baseline and extension
Financial correction with return to ELB
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Misperceived lower natural rate
Heightened risk of euro-area breakup
EME turbulence and stronger dollar

2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8

2.7
-.1
2.8
2.8
2.8
1.2
2.5

2.4
-1.0
2.3
2.8
2.5
1.5
1.7

1.8
.9
1.7
2.2
1.9
2.0
1.5

1.5
2.7
1.5
2.0
1.7
1.9
1.6

1.1
2.7
1.0
1.3
1.2
1.3
1.3

Unemployment rate1
Tealbook baseline and extension
Financial correction with return to ELB
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Misperceived lower natural rate
Heightened risk of euro-area breakup
EME turbulence and stronger dollar

3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

3.6
4.9
3.6
3.6
3.5
3.8
3.6

3.4
6.5
3.6
3.4
3.2
4.1
3.7

3.4
6.2
3.7
3.2
3.1
4.1
3.9

3.6
5.4
3.8
3.3
3.1
4.2
4.1

4.1
4.1
4.3
3.8
3.4
4.5
4.4

Total PCE prices
Tealbook baseline and extension
Financial correction with return to ELB
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Misperceived lower natural rate
Heightened risk of euro-area breakup
EME turbulence and stronger dollar

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3

1.8
1.7
2.6
1.8
1.8
.5
1.2

1.9
1.5
2.6
1.9
1.9
1.1
1.6

2.0
1.5
2.5
2.0
1.9
1.6
2.0

2.0
1.8
2.4
2.1
2.0
1.8
2.2

2.1
2.0
2.3
2.1
2.0
2.0
2.3

Core PCE prices
Tealbook baseline and extension
Financial correction with return to ELB
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Misperceived lower natural rate
Heightened risk of euro-area breakup
EME turbulence and stronger dollar

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

1.7
1.6
2.5
1.7
1.7
.8
1.3

2.0
1.6
2.7
2.1
2.0
1.3
1.8

2.1
1.6
2.6
2.1
2.0
1.7
2.1

2.1
1.9
2.4
2.1
2.0
1.9
2.2

2.2
2.0
2.3
2.2
2.1
2.0
2.3

Federal funds rate1
Tealbook baseline and extension
Financial correction with return to ELB
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Misperceived lower natural rate
Heightened risk of euro-area breakup
EME turbulence and stronger dollar

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7

2.5
1.2
2.5
2.5
2.5
2.4
2.3

3.8
.1
3.9
3.7
3.8
2.7
3.5

4.5
.2
4.8
4.5
4.6
3.3
4.3

4.8
.9
5.0
4.7
4.8
3.7
4.6

4.4
2.9
4.6
4.3
4.4
3.9
4.3

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 82 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

steeper rise in wages. We illustrate these risks using simulations from a nonlinear New
Keynesian model with costly search and matching frictions in the labor market. In this
model, recruiting costs and wages are higher when the unemployment rate is low because
firms have to spend more time and resources looking for and attracting workers.4
With greater supply constraints, the unemployment rate continues to decline until
mid-2019, but only by ¼ percentage point, ¼ percentage point less than in the baseline
projection, and this gap persists over the forecast horizon. However, GDP growth is
close to the baseline throughout the projection horizon as, in this model, more-intense
utilization of capital compensates for the reduction in labor input. Because of higher
recruiting costs and faster wage growth, inflation is significantly higher and peaks at
2¾ percent in early 2020. Monetary policymakers are assumed to infer resource slack
from the unemployment rate, and the federal funds rate is slightly above the baseline as
the effect of higher inflation dominates the effect of the smaller unemployment gap.

Positive Hysteresis [FRB/US]
In contrast to the previous scenario, the hot labor market in the baseline projection
is assumed in this scenario to have persistent positive effects on the productive capacity
of the economy, a phenomenon often referred to as “positive hysteresis.” Specifically,
we assume that persistent exposure to a hot economy reduces exits from the labor force
and generates additional entrants, causing the trend labor force participation rate to rise
about 1 percentage point above the baseline by the end of 2023. Furthermore, we assume
that the experience that workers gain through greater employment lowers the natural rate
of unemployment ½ percentage point by the end of 2023. Both of these favorable
developments are assumed to be recognized in real time by monetary policymakers. 5
In this scenario, potential output rises, on average, about ¼ percentage point more
per year over the projection period than in the baseline. This additional room to grow
allows real GDP growth to run at a similar increment above the baseline. As a result, the
Since the previous round, we have made a few technical refinements in the implementation of
this scenario, which we believe allow us to more accurately quantify the marginal effects of the model’s
nonlinearities on the simulated outcomes. The paths of the unemployment rate and inflation in this scenario
are slightly lower in this round than they would have been under the previous round’s implementation.
5
We modeled this alternative scenario by augmenting the usual specifications in FRB/US for the
natural rate of unemployment and the trend labor force participation rate with endogenous hysteresisgenerating components.
4

Page 83 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Forecast Confidence Intervals and Alternative Scenarios
Confidence Intervals Based on FRB/US Stochastic Simulations
Tealbook baseline and extension
Financial correction with return to ELB
Supply constraints

Positive hysteresis
Misperceived lower natural rate

Real GDP

Heightened risk of euro−area breakup
EME turbulence and stronger dollar

Unemployment Rate
4−quarter percent change

Percent
7.0

5

6.5
4

70 percent
interval

6.0
3

5.5
5.0

2

4.5
1
4.0
0

3.5
3.0

−1

2.5

90 percent
interval

−2
2.0
−3

2017

2019

2021

1.5

2023

2017

PCE Prices excluding Food and Energy

2019

2021

2023

Federal Funds Rate

4−quarter percent change

Percent
4.5

8

4.0

7

3.5

6

3.0

5

2.5

4

2.0
3
1.5
2
1.0
1
0.5
0
0.0
2017

2019

2021

2023

2017

Page 84 of 132

2019

2021

2023

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

output gap is little changed. The unemployment rate is close to the baseline until the
middle of 2019 because increases in labor force participation offset the effect of greater
gains in employment. After 2019, the unemployment rate follows a lower trajectory and
is a little more than ¼ percentage point below the staff projection by 2023. With inflation
and the output gap roughly at the baseline, the federal funds rate is little changed.6

Misperceived Lower Natural Rate of Unemployment [FRB/US]
Over the past several years, the staff has lowered its estimate of the natural rate of
unemployment. Today’s lower natural rate could reflect low-frequency changes in
various demographic factors such as the age and educational distribution of the
population. In this scenario, we entertain the possibility that these factors have reduced
the natural rate of unemployment by a larger amount than is assumed in the baseline.
Specifically, we assume that the natural rate of unemployment has been 3¾ percent for
the past few years and will remain at that level in the future. Furthermore, policymakers
and the staff continue, for a time, to misperceive the level of the natural rate; their
perceptions converge to the true level only gradually, and that convergence is not
complete by the end of 2023.
Given the lower natural rate, the unemployment rate in the scenario declines
½ percentage point more than in the baseline, reaching about 3 percent in 2020. Because
policymakers revise their view of the natural rate downward only gradually, the gap
between the unemployment rate and the perceived natural rate is larger, albeit by a small
amount, than in the baseline. With inflation only a touch lower and the perceived output
gap not much different from the baseline, the path for the federal funds rate is little
changed. Had policymakers fully and immediately recognized the lower natural rate, the
perceived output gap would have been substantially smaller and the federal funds rate
would have been about ¼ percentage point lower during the first two years of the
simulation. The unemployment rate would have fallen ¾ percentage point below the
baseline in 2020, ¼ percentage point further than in the case of misperception.

If we instead assumed that policymakers learn only slowly about the improvement in potential
output, the federal funds rate would follow a steeper trajectory than shown in this scenario, reaching almost
5¼ percent by the end of 2021. In that case, the effect of positive hysteresis on the unemployment rate is
about half of that under this scenario.
6

Page 85 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Selected Tealbook Projections and 70 Percent Confidence Intervals Derived
from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors and FRB/US Simulations
Measure
Real GDP
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
Civilian unemployment rate
(percent, Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
PCE prices, total
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
PCE prices excluding
food and energy
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
Federal funds rate
(percent, Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
FRB/US stochastic simulations

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2.8

2.4

1.8

1.5

1.1

1.1

1.5–4.3
2.1–3.6

.2–3.9
1.1–3.9

-.8–3.2
.3–3.3

...
-.1–3.2

...
-.6–2.9

...
-.8–2.9

3.6

3.4

3.4

3.6

3.8

4.1

3.2–3.9
3.1–3.9

2.5–4.5
2.6–4.1

2.1–5.0
2.3–4.4

...
2.3–4.9

...
2.5–5.3

...
2.7–5.6

2.1

1.9

2.0

2.0

2.1

2.1

1.4–2.6
1.5–2.5

1.0–3.5
.9–2.7

1.0–3.4
.9–2.9

...
.9–3.1

...
.9–3.2

...
.9–3.3

1.9

2.0

2.1

2.1

2.1

2.2

1.6–2.2
1.5–2.3

1.4–2.7
1.1–2.8

...
1.1–3.0

...
1.1–3.1

...
1.0–3.2

...
1.0–3.3

2.5

3.8

4.5

4.8

4.7

4.4

2.3–2.7

3.1–4.6

3.4–5.9

3.2–6.7

2.8–6.9

2.2–6.7

Note: Shocks underlying FRB/US stochastic simulations are randomly drawn from the 1969–2016 set of
model equation residuals. Intervals derived from Tealbook forecast errors are based on projections made
from 1980 to 2016 for real GDP and unemployment and from 1998 to 2016 for PCE prices. The intervals
for real GDP, unemployment, and total PCE prices are extended into 2020 using information from the
Blue Chip survey and forecasts from the CBO and CEA.
. . . Not applicable.

Page 86 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Prediction Intervals Derived from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors

Q4 Level,
Percent

Unemployment Rate
Historical revisions

Tealbook forecasts

Augmented
Tealbook 1

median
15% to 85%
5% to 95%
data/forecast
range

Q4/Q4,
Percent

PCE Inflation

13

Risks & Uncertainty

Historical
Distributions

Forecast Error Percentiles

4

11

3

9
2
7
1
5
0

3

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

1

2015

1980 to 2017
Q4/Q4,
Percent

Real GDP Growth

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-1
1998 to 2017
Q4/Q4,
Percent

Core PCE Inflation

8

4

6

3

4
2
2
1
0
0

-2

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-4

2015

1980 to 2017

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-1
1998 to 2017

Historical Distributions
Unemployment Rate

PCE Inflation

Real GDP Growth

Annual, Percent
25
median
15% to 85%
5% to 95%
20
2.5% to 97.5%
range

Annual, Percent

Annual, Percent

20

16

12

12

12

8

8

4

4

0

0

-4

-4

-8

-8

-8

-12

-12

-12

0
-4

5
0
1980 to
2017

Annual, Percent

4

10

1930 to 1947 to
2017
2017

16

16

8

15

Core PCE Inflation

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1980 to
2017
2017
2017

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1998 to
2017
2017
2017

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1998 to
2017
2017
2017

Note: See the technical note in the appendix for more information on this exhibit.
1. Augmented Tealbook prediction intervals use 1- and 2-year-ahead forecast errors from Blue Chip, CBO, and CEA to extend the Tealbook prediction
intervals through 2020.

Page 87 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Heightened Risk of Euro-Area Breakup [SIGMA]
In our baseline, we marked down the outlook for euro-area growth on the
assumption that ongoing political uncertainty in Italy will generate moderate financial
stresses in other euro-area countries. Our scenario considers a substantially worse
outcome in which a populist government steers Italy on a course that threatens its
solvency or its continued membership in the euro area. By weakening investor
confidence in European institutions and causing anxiety about a possible breakup of the
euro area, these developments plunge the euro area into a prolonged period of financial
stress, flagging confidence, and recession. While we assume that financial markets
gradually recover after the Italian government reverses course and the EU authorities take
forceful policy actions, the crisis nonetheless has sizable adverse spillovers to the United
States and the rest of the world.
Specifically, our scenario assumes that euro-area GDP falls about 4 percent below
the baseline by the end of 2019 as both sovereign and private credit conditions tighten
dramatically, though somewhat less than during the 2011–12 European debt crisis, and
household and business confidence declines. Investment-grade U.S. corporate bond
spreads rise about 75 basis points, flight-to-safety flows boost the trade-weighted dollar
10 percent above its baseline path, and the term premium on long-term U.S. Treasury
securities declines 30 basis points. Financial conditions also tighten markedly in
economies outside Europe and the United States.
Weaker foreign activity and the stronger dollar cause U.S. real net exports to fall
relative to the baseline, while lower confidence and tighter financial conditions in the
United States depress domestic demand. All told, U.S. real GDP expands only
1¼ percent in the second half of 2018 and 1½ percent in 2019. The U.S. unemployment
rate is about ¾ percentage point higher than in the baseline in late 2019 and remains
above the baseline through 2022. Lower resource utilization and falling import prices
reduce U.S. core PCE inflation to about 1¼ percent by 2019. The federal funds rate
follows a shallower path, about 1 percentage point below the baseline on average from
2019 to 2021.

EME Turbulence and Stronger Dollar [SIGMA]
In our baseline, we continue to expect solid growth in most EMEs despite some
increases in financial stresses. Even so, EMEs face a number of vulnerabilities, including

Page 88 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

high sovereign and private debt, that may be exacerbated by ongoing U.S. monetary
policy normalization, especially if investor confidence is weakened by heightening
geopolitical risks, rising trade tensions, or political uncertainties. In this scenario, we
assume that EME economies experience a broad-based deterioration of financial
conditions that is accompanied by substantial capital outflows and currency depreciation,
generating sizable adverse spillovers to the United States and advanced foreign
economies.
Specifically, this scenario assumes that declining confidence fuels an ongoing
flight from EME assets, causing credit spreads to widen substantially and EME
currencies to depreciate sharply. Flight-to-safety flows into dollar-denominated assets
reduce the term premiums on U.S. Treasury securities 30 basis points and cause corporate
bond spreads to rise 50 basis points both in the United States and in the advanced foreign
economies. All told, foreign GDP growth runs ¾ percentage point below the baseline in
2019, while the broad real dollar appreciates by 10 percent.
Weaker foreign activity, the appreciation of the dollar, and tighter financial
conditions restrain the pace of economic expansion in the United States. U.S. GDP
growth moderates to 1¾ percent in 2019, about ¾ percentage point less than in the
baseline. Core PCE inflation is still below 2 percent in 2019, about ¼ percentage point
lower than the baseline. The federal funds rate follows a shallower path than in
the baseline.

Page 89 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Alternative Model Forecasts
(Percent change, Q4 to Q4, except as noted)
2018
Measure and projection

2019

2020

March
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

March
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

March
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Real GDP
Staff
FRB/US
EDO

2.9
2.1
2.3

2.8
2.5
2.8

2.6
2.0
2.3

2.4
1.7
2.3

2.1
1.7
2.4

1.8
1.3
2.3

Unemployment rate1
Staff
FRB/US
EDO

3.5
3.9
4.2

3.6
3.8
4.0

3.1
3.9
4.4

3.4
3.8
4.2

3.1
4.0
4.7

3.4
4.0
4.5

Total PCE prices
Staff
FRB/US
EDO

1.8
2.0
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.0

2.0
1.8
1.9

1.9
1.8
1.8

2.1
1.8
2.0

2.0
1.8
1.9

Core PCE prices
Staff
FRB/US
EDO

1.9
2.1
2.0

1.9
2.0
1.9

2.1
1.9
1.9

2.0
1.9
1.8

2.2
1.8
2.0

2.1
1.9
1.9

Federal funds rate1
Staff
FRB/US
EDO

2.7
2.4
2.4

2.5
2.4
2.4

4.0
3.2
3.1

3.8
3.1
3.1

5.0
3.5
3.5

4.5
3.4
3.5

1. Percent, average for Q4.

Estimates of the Short-Run Real Natural Rate of Interest
Percent, annual rate
....

Median
Range across models

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Note: Estimates are based on the four models from the System DSGE project; for more
information, see the box "Estimates of the Short-Run Real Natural Rate of Interest" in the March
2016 Tealbook. The gray shaded bar indicates a period of recession as defined by the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Page 90 of 132

12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Assessment of Key Macroeconomic Risks

Probability of Inflation Events
(4 quarters ahead)
Probability that the 4-quarter change in total
PCE prices will be . . .

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Greater than 3 percent
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.07
.06

.07
.07

.02
.05

.11
.09

Less than 1 percent
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.11
.13

.11
.10

.12
.06

.11
.12

Probability of Unemployment Events
(4 quarters ahead)
Probability that the unemployment rate
will . . .

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Increase by 1 percentage point
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.01
.00

.02
.02

.14
.16

.02
.06

Decrease by 1 percentage point
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.13
.35

.03
.04

.04
.05

.12
.02

Probability of Near-Term Recession
Probability that real GDP declines in
the next two quarters
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Factor
Model

.01
.01

.01
.02

.04
.05

.04
.05

.00
.02

Note: “Staff” represents stochastic simulations in FRB/US around the staff baseline; baselines for FRB/US, BVAR, EDO, and
the factor model are generated by those models themselves, up to the current-quarter estimate. Data for the current quarter are
taken from the staff estimate for the second Tealbook in each quarter; if the second Tealbook for the current quarter has not yet
been published, the preceding quarter is taken as the latest historical observation.

Page 91 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 92 of 132

June 1, 2018

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Appendix
Technical Note on “Prediction Intervals Derived from
Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors”
This technical note provides additional details about the exhibit “Prediction Intervals
Derived from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors.” In the four large fan charts, the black dotted
lines show staff projections and current estimates of recent values of four key economic variables:
average unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of each year and the Q4/Q4 percent change for
real GDP, total PCE prices, and core PCE prices. (The GDP series is adjusted to use GNP for
those years when the staff forecast GNP and to strip out software and intellectual property
products from the currently published data for years preceding their introduction. Similarly, the
core PCE inflation series is adjusted to strip out the “food away from home” component for years
before it was included in core.)
The historical distributions of the corresponding series (with the adjustments described
above) are plotted immediately to the right of each of the fan charts. The thin black lines show
the highest and lowest values of the series during the indicated time period. At the bottom of the
page, the distributions over three different time periods are plotted for each series. To enable the
use of data for years prior to 1947, we report annual-average data in this section. The annual data
going back to 1930 for GDP growth, PCE inflation, and core PCE inflation are available in the
conventional national accounts; we used estimates from Lebergott (1957) for the unemployment
rate from 1930 to 1946.1
The prediction intervals around the current and one-year-ahead forecasts are derived from
historical staff forecast errors, comparing staff forecasts with the latest published data. For the
unemployment rate and real GDP growth, errors were calculated for a sample starting in 1980,
yielding percentiles of the sizes of the forecast errors. For PCE and core PCE inflation, errors
based on a sample beginning in 1998 were used. This shorter range reflects both more limited
data on staff forecasts of PCE inflation and the staff judgment that the distribution of inflation
since the mid-1990s is more appropriate for the projection period than distributions of inflation
reaching further back. In all cases, the prediction intervals are computed by adding the percentile
bands of the errors onto the forecast. The blue bands encompass 70 percent prediction-interval
ranges; adding the green bands expands this range to 90 percent. The dark blue line plots the
median of the prediction intervals. There is not enough historical forecast data to calculate
meaningful 90 percent ranges for the two inflation series. A median line above the staff forecast
means that forecast errors were positive more than half of the time.

Stanley Lebergott (1957), “Annual Estimates of Unemployment in the United States,
1900–1954,” in National Bureau of Economic Research, The Measurement and Behavior of Unemployment
(Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press), pp. 213–41.
1

Page 93 of 132

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Because the staff has produced two-year-ahead forecasts for only a few years, the
intervals around the two-year-ahead forecasts are constructed by augmenting the staff projection
errors with information from outside forecasters: the Blue Chip consensus, the Council of
Economic Advisers, and the Congressional Budget Office. Specifically, we calculate prediction
intervals for outside forecasts in the same manner as for the staff forecasts. We then calculate the
change in the error bands from outside forecasts from one year ahead to two years ahead and
apply the average change to the staff’s one-year-ahead error bands. That is, we assume that any
deterioration in the performance between the one- and two-year-ahead projections of the outside
forecasters would also apply to the Tealbook projections. Limitations on the availability of data
mean that a slightly shorter sample is used for GDP and unemployment, and the outside
projections may only be for a similar series, such as total CPI instead of total PCE prices or
annual growth rates of GDP instead of four-quarter changes. In particular, because data on
forecasts for core inflation by these outside forecasters are much more limited, we did not
extrapolate the staff’s errors for core PCE inflation two years ahead.
The intervals around the historical data in the four fan charts are based on the history of
data revisions for each series. The previous-year, two-year-back, and three-year-back values as
of the current Tealbook forecast are subtracted from the corresponding currently published
estimates (adjusted as described earlier) to produce revisions, which are then combined into
distributions and revision intervals in the same way that the prediction intervals are created.

Page 94 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Monetary Policy Strategies
In this section, we discuss a range of strategies for setting the federal funds rate
and compare the associated interest rate paths and macroeconomic outcomes with those
in the Tealbook baseline projection. The near-term prescriptions are little changed from
those in the previous Tealbook. Over the medium term, the Tealbook baseline projection
features somewhat lower levels of resource utilization, on average, than the projection
completed in April. Consequently, the prescriptions arising from most of the strategies
are slightly more accommodative than those in the previous Tealbook. In the box
“Learning and Misperceptions of Policy Strategies,” we explore the economic
consequences of a change in policy strategy when the public is uncertain about
policymakers’ reaction function and has to learn about the new policy strategy over time.

NEAR-TERM PRESCRIPTIONS OF SELECTED SIMPLE POLICY RULES
The top panel of the first exhibit shows near-term prescriptions for the federal
funds rate from four policy rules: the Taylor (1999) rule (also known as the “balanced
approach” rule), the Taylor (1993) rule, a first-difference rule, and a flexible price-level
targeting (FPLT) rule. These near-term prescriptions take as given the staff’s baseline
projections for the output gap and core inflation, shown by the black lines in the middle
panels, and for the gap between the unemployment rate and the natural rate of
unemployment (not shown). The top and middle panels also provide the staff’s baseline
path for the federal funds rate, which is constructed using an inertial version of the Taylor
(1999) rule. 1
Here and in the simple policy rule simulations, we have replaced the nominal
income targeting (NIT) rule that has appeared in past Tealbooks with one of the FPLT
rules discussed in the April Tealbook. 2 Like the nominal income targeting rule, the FPLT
rule aims to reverse past deviations of inflation from policymakers’ objective rather than
letting “bygones be bygones.” However, it differs from the NIT rule by specifying that
We provide details on each of these simple rules in the appendix to this section. Except for the
first-difference rule, which has no intercept term, the simple rules examined here use intercept terms that
are consistent with a real federal funds rate of 50 basis points in the longer run.
2
In the April Tealbook, this rule was featured in the special exhibit of the Monetary Policy
Strategies (MPS) section under the name “FPLT, equal responses (2011:Q4).” This rule has also been
analyzed in the research literature (for example, Chung and others, 2015).
1

Page 95 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Policy Rules and the Staff Projection
Near−Term Prescriptions of Selected Simple Policy Rules1

Monetary Policy Strategies

(Percent)

2018:Q3

2018:Q4

Taylor (1999) rule
Previous Tealbook

4.46
4.57

4.65
4.75

Taylor (1993) rule
Previous Tealbook

3.44
3.60

3.50
3.65

First−difference rule
Previous Tealbook projection

2.12
2.18

2.47
2.59

Flexible price−level targeting rule
Previous Tealbook projection

1.63
1.66

1.54
1.61

Addendum:
Tealbook baseline

2.15

2.52

*
Key Elements of the Staff Projection
Federal Funds Rate

PCE Prices ex. Food and Energy

GDP Gap
Percent

Percent
4

7

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

4−quarter change

Percent
3.0

6
5

3

2.5

2

2.0

1

1.5

4
3
2
1

2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023

0

2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023

0

2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023

A Medium−Term Notion of the Equilibrium Real Federal Funds Rate2
(Percent)

Current
Value

Previous
Tealbook

Tealbook baseline
FRB/US r*
Average projected real federal funds rate

3.19
1.50

3.40
1.53

SEP−consistent baseline
FRB/US r*
Average projected real federal funds rate

1.49
.61

*
1. For rules that have a lagged policy rate as a right−hand−side variable, the lines denoted "Previous Tealbook projection"
report prescriptions based on the previous Tealbook's staff outlook for inflation and the output gap, but conditional on the
current−Tealbook value of the lagged policy rate.
2. The "FRB/US r*" is the level of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12−quarter period (beginning in the
current quarter) in the FRB/US model, sets the output gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period given either the
Tealbook or SEP−consistent projection. The SEP−consistent baseline corresponds to the March 2018 median SEP
responses. The "Average projected real federal funds rate" is calculated under the Tealbook and SEP−consistent baseline
projections over the same 12−quarter period as FRB/US r*.
Page 96 of 132

1.0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

the federal funds rate reacts to the unemployment rate gap and a price gap defined using
the core PCE price index, rather than the output gap and a price gap defined using the
GDP deflator. 3 The FPLT rule we consider uses equal coefficients on the unemployment
and price gaps and has the same degree of interest rate inertia as the inertial Taylor
(1999) rule used in the Tealbook baseline. 4 Like the NIT rule that preceded it, the FPLT
rule uses a target path for prices that equals the actual price level in 2011:Q4—which is
the quarter just before the Committee announced its 2 percent inflation objective—and
that rises at a 2 percent annual rate thereafter.
•

The staff forecast for the variables that enter these rules has changed very
little; consequently, the prescriptions of the policy rules are nearly the same as
in the April Tealbook.

•

The prescriptions of the Taylor (1999) and Taylor (1993) rules, which do not
feature interest rate smoothing terms, remain well above the corresponding
policy rates in the Tealbook baseline.

•

Unlike the other rules and the Tealbook baseline policy, which call for raising
the federal funds rate in the near term, the FPLT rule, in an effort to eliminate
the shortfall in the core PCE price index of about 2½ percent, prescribes levels
for the federal funds rate in the second and third quarters that remain within
the current target range.

A MEDIUM-TERM NOTION OF THE EQUILIBRIUM REAL FEDERAL
FUNDS RATE
The bottom panel of the first exhibit reports estimates of a medium-term concept
of the equilibrium real federal funds rate generated under two baselines: the Tealbook
The use of the core PCE price index in the rule is consistent with the other rules in the MPS
section that respond to core PCE inflation. If the rule responded to the headline PCE price level, then the
rule would prescribe more volatile policy rates. Moreover, in the event of an increase in oil prices, such a
rule would prescribe higher policy rates in order to offset the effect of this increase on the aggregate price
level, thereby reducing aggregate demand to put downward pressure on non-oil prices.
4
The sensitivity of the FPLT rule to the cyclical position of the economy is similar to the Taylor
(1993) rule. The FRB/US model roughly satisfies the empirical regularity known as Okun’s law by
generating changes in the unemployment gap that are roughly half as large and of the opposite sign as
changes in the output gap. Hence, a coefficient of negative 1 on the unemployment gap (as in the FPLT
rule) has implications similar to those of a coefficient of 0.5 on the output gap (as in the Taylor
(1993) rule).
3

Page 97 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

baseline and a projection consistent with the medians in the March 2018 Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP). 5 In both cases, simulations of the FRB/US model are used
to generate an estimate of r*. This r* concept, labeled “FRB/US r*,” corresponds to the
level of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period starting in
the current quarter, would bring the output gap to zero in the final quarter of that period.
This concept of r* is a summary of the projected underlying strength of the real
economy; because it is based on a single criterion, it does not take into account other
considerations, such as achieving the inflation objective or avoiding sharp changes in the

Monetary Policy Strategies

federal funds rate.
•

At 3.19 percent, the estimate of Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r* in this
quarter is 21 basis points below the corresponding value computed using
information from the April Tealbook. The downward revision reflects the fact
that the projected output gap is slightly smaller in 2021 than in the April
Tealbook.

•

At about 1½ percent, the SEP-consistent FRB/US r* is significantly lower
than the Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r*. The difference stems from the fact
that the SEP-consistent projection has output exceeding potential by a
considerably smaller amount over the medium term than does the current
Tealbook forecast. This smaller anticipated output gap occurs despite the fact
that the median path for the real federal funds rate implied by SEP projections
averages almost 1 percentage point lower than the corresponding path in the
Tealbook.

SIMPLE POLICY RULE SIMULATIONS
The second exhibit reports results from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US
model under the Taylor (1999) rule, the Taylor (1993) rule, the first-difference rule, and
the FPLT rule. These simulations reflect the endogenous responses of the output gap and

To construct a baseline projection consistent with median SEP responses for the FRB/US model,
the staff interpolated annual SEP information to a quarterly frequency and assumed that, beyond 2020 (the
final year reported in the March 2018 SEP), the economy transitions to the longer-run values in a smooth
and monotonic way. The staff also posited economic relationships to project variables not covered in the
SEP. For example, the staff assumed an Okun’s law relationship to recover an output gap from the
deviation of the median SEP unemployment rate from the median SEP estimate of its longer-run value.
5

Page 98 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

inflation to the different federal funds rate paths implied by the policy rules. 6 The
simulations for each rule are carried out under the assumptions that policymakers commit
to following that rule in the future and that financial market participants, price setters, and
wage setters correctly anticipate that monetary policy will follow through on this
commitment and are aware of the implications for interest rates and the macroeconomy.
The exhibit also reports the extended Tealbook baseline projection.
•

Under the Tealbook baseline, the federal funds rate rises to about 2½ percent
by the end of this year. Over the subsequent two years, it increases by about
1 percentage point per year, bringing the rate to slightly above 4½ percent in
the fourth quarter of 2020.

•

The Taylor (1999) rule calls for an immediate and substantial increase in the
federal funds rate, and the prescribed values remain above the corresponding
Tealbook baseline values through early 2022. This higher path is associated
with only a modestly higher trajectory for the real 10-year Treasury yield than
in the baseline through the middle of 2020 and a slightly lower path thereafter,
as the Taylor (1999) rule calls for somewhat lower values of the federal funds
rate for a sustained period later in the simulation period. Because wage and
price setting today is influenced by expected future outcomes in FRB/US, and
because the Taylor (1999) rule calls for somewhat more accommodative
policy later in the simulation, current inflation is a touch higher than in the
baseline projection. The path for the unemployment rate lies above the
Tealbook baseline path over the next few years, but subsequently takes a bit
longer to return to its natural rate. In the box “Learning and Misperceptions
of Policy Strategies,” we examine the implications for macroeconomic
outcomes of departing from the assumption that the public immediately
understand the new policy in the context of this simulation.

•

The Taylor (1993) rule also calls for an immediate sharp increase in the
federal funds rate. Because the Taylor (1993) rule responds less strongly to
projected output exceeding its assumed potential level, the prescriptions of
this rule are lower than those of the Taylor (1999) rule over the period shown.

Because of the endogenous responses of the output gap and inflation to the different federal
funds rate paths, the near-term prescriptions from the dynamic simulations can differ from those shown in
the top panel of the first exhibit.
6

Page 99 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Learning and Misperceptions of Policy Strategies

Monetary Policy Strategies

In the simple policy rule simulations reported in this Tealbook, the Taylor (1999) rule initially
raises the federal funds rate more than 220 basis points above the Tealbook baseline.
Despite this abrupt tightening, inflation is higher than in the Tealbook baseline, and the
unemployment rate rises only modestly above the Tealbook baseline. These counterintuitive
outcomes arise because financial market participants as well as price and wage setters are
assumed to have model-consistent expectations (MCE): They immediately recognize how the
policy rule has changed and perfectly anticipate the more accommodative policy that the
Taylor (1999) rule prescribes in later years in the simulation.
In this discussion, we consider the alternative assumption that the public only gradually
comes to understand a change in policy strategy. Specifically, we assume that the public is
initially uncertain about the parameters of the new policy rule and that their beliefs about
likely parameter values evolve over time through a process of learning from the observed
values of the federal funds rate and information about the state of the economy.1 In the
short run there can be misperceptions about the new policy strategy. The economic
outcomes associated with changes in the monetary policy rule under learning can be
considerably different from those under MCE.
We illustrate how this learning process can affect economic outcomes using a scenario in
which policymakers initially follow the prescriptions of the inertial version of the Taylor (1999)
rule, as in the Tealbook baseline, and then in the third quarter of 2018 switch to the noninertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule. We carry out three sets of simulations using the
small FRB/US (sFRB) model. 2 In the first simulation, the public has model-consistent
expectations and thus immediately understands the properties of the new policy rule. In the
second and third simulations, the public does not directly observe how the policy rule has
changed and is uncertain about the smoothing coefficient on the lagged federal funds rate as
well as the value of the intercept term in the rule. 3 Beliefs about the intercept capture a
variety of reasons the public might believe the FOMC to be undertaking a persistent deviation
from the policy rule, including changes in policymakers’ assessment of the equilibrium real
federal funds rate or the inflation target. The two learning simulations differ only in their
assumptions about the public’s initial or prior beliefs about the relative likelihood of different
kinds of policy changes.
Figure 1 shows the evolution of the economy in the scenario under MCE and under learning,
along with the Tealbook baseline. The simulation under MCE is virtually identical to the one
for the Taylor (1999) rule shown earlier in the Monetary Policy Strategies section, which uses
1

For a complete description of the information structure and the learning process, see Martin
Bodenstein, James Hebden, and Fabian Winkler (2018), “Learning and Misperception: Implications for
Monetary Policy Strategies,” memorandum, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of
Monetary Affairs, June 1.
2
sFRB is a simplified, linear version of FRB/US designed to mimic its properties for a small set of key
variables. Under MCE, the simulations carried out in FRB/US and sFRB are very similar.
3
For simplicity, we assume that the public knows the true rule parameters with certainty until 2018:Q2
and remains certain throughout the simulation about the response coefficients on inflation and the output
gap. The values of these two coefficients are the same in both rules considered here.

Page 100 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

the full FRB/US model. Despite an immediate and sharp tightening in which the federal funds
rate jumps above 4 percent, inflation runs slightly higher under the Taylor (1999) rule than
the inertial version of the rule.
By contrast, in the simulation labeled “Learning (less informed prior),” switching to the noninertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule induces a large fall in inflation; moreover, inflation
remains below the Committee’s 2 percent objective through 2022. At the same time, the
unemployment rate increases by more than under MCE. This difference in economic
outcomes under learning stems from the way in which the public interprets the large and
unexpected increase in the federal funds rate in 2018:Q3. 4 In the near term, in this simulation,
the public attributes the sharp increase in the federal funds rate partly to a lower value of the
smoothing coefficient in the policy rule, but also partly to a higher value of the intercept. As a
result of this misperception, the public anticipates a significant and sustained tightening of
policy. These expectations of tighter policy are reflected in a large run-up in the real 10-year
Treasury yield that persists for several quarters.
Figure 2 illustrates the misperception about the future policy path. The figure shows paths
for the real federal funds rate as expected by the public as of selected dates, as well as the
realized path of the federal funds rate. In 2018:Q3, the public anticipates a path for the real
federal funds rate that is considerably higher than the realized path. This divergence of
anticipated and realized paths occurs because, as noted above, the public misinterprets the
removal of policy inertia as an increase in the intercept that leads to persistently tighter
policy. In contrast, the actual path of the federal funds rate realized under the Taylor (1999)
rule lies below the corresponding path under MCE because the rule reacts to the fall in
inflation and resource utilization caused by the public’s misperceptions.
Over time, the public revises its perception of the policy rule in light of how policy actions
respond to economic outcomes and adjusts its estimates of the intercept and the smoothing
coefficient. The perceived parameters of the policy rule gradually move toward their true
values. In figure 1, the economy gradually converges to its path under MCE. In figure 2,
anticipated and realized policy paths converge.
In a situation in which the federal funds rate is changed by a historically large amount,
predicting how the public will form its expectations is ultimately a speculative exercise. The
simulation just described represents only one of many plausible outcomes. In particular, the
effects of learning depend on the public’s initial or prior beliefs about the predictability of
policymakers’ actions. To illustrate this point, we conduct an alternative simulation labeled
“Learning (more informed prior),” where the public is assumed to believe that changes in the
intercept term of the rule are less likely, and changes in the smoothing coefficient are more
likely, than in the previous simulation. These prior beliefs are closer to the actual change in
the policy strategy, and, in this sense, are more informed. As a result, misperceptions about
the future path of policy are smaller, and economic outcomes in figure 1 are more similar to
those obtained under MCE.

4

The state of the economy at the time of the announcement greatly influences the extent to which
learning affects economic outcomes when the rule is changed. In a situation in which the inertial and the
non-inertial versions of the Taylor (1999) rule both prescribed similar values, announcing a change from the
former to the latter rule would lead to only minor changes in the observed path of the federal funds rate.
Accordingly, allowing for learning would have only minor effects on economic outcomes.

Page 101 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

Monetary Policy Strategies

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Page 102 of 132

June 1, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

The prescriptions from the Taylor (1993) rule are higher than the Tealbook
baseline over the next two years, though, starting in the third quarter of 2020,
the path for the federal funds rate falls below the baseline path for a sustained
period. As a result, current inflation is higher, and the real 10-year Treasury
yield is lower, than their corresponding values in the Tealbook projection.
The more accommodative conditions engender a more pronounced
undershooting of the unemployment rate below its natural rate beyond the
medium term.
•

The path for the federal funds rate prescribed by the first-difference rule is
somewhat above the path in the Tealbook baseline through 2020, but runs
below the baseline path for some years thereafter. The latter divergence
occurs because the first-difference rule, which responds to the expected
change in the output gap rather than to its level, reacts to projected output
exceeding its assumed potential level by progressively smaller amounts
beyond the next three years. The associated lower path of the federal funds
rate, in conjunction with expectations of higher inflation in the future, implies
lower longer-term real interest rates than in the Tealbook baseline. Thus, the
first-difference rule generates outcomes for the unemployment rate that are
lower, and outcomes for inflation that are higher, than the corresponding
outcomes in the Tealbook baseline projection.

•

The FPLT rule seeks to compensate for the cumulative shortfall of core PCE
inflation from an annual rate of 2 percent since the end of 2011. The FPLT
rule calls for keeping the federal funds rate below 1¾ percent until the third
quarter of 2019, and maintaining a markedly slower pace of increases
thereafter than in the Tealbook baseline. This prescription generates a higher
rate of inflation in coming years that eventually undoes the 2½ percent
shortfall of the core PCE price index relative to a path that rises 2 percent per
year beginning in 2011:Q4. 7 Because the simulation embeds the assumptions
that policymakers can credibly commit to closing this gap over time and that
financial market participants, price setters, and wage setters correctly
anticipate the ensuing long period of low federal funds rates, the path of the

Using the headline measure of PCE prices, the 2018:Q1 price-level gap is about 4 percent,
1.5 percentage points larger than the gap based on core PCE prices. Accordingly, a rule that responded to
headline PCE prices rather than to core PCE prices would prescribe an even more accommodative policy.
7

Page 103 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Simple Policy Rule Simulations
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
8

Taylor (1999) rule
Taylor (1993) rule
First−difference rule
Flexible price−level targeting rule
Tealbook baseline

5.5

Staff's estimate of the natural rate
7
5.0

6
5

4.5
4

Monetary Policy Strategies

3
4.0
2
1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

3.5

0
3.0

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
4

2.5

3
2017

2
1

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2.0

PCE Inflation
Percent

4−quarter average

0

2.5

−1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

−2

2.0

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield
Percent
3.0

2.5

2.0
1.5
1.5

1.0

0.5

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

0.0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Note: The policy rule simulations in this exhibit are based on rules that respond to core inflation rather than to
headline inflation. This choice of rule specification was made in light of a tendency for current and near−term core
inflation rates to outperform headline inflation rates as predictors of the medium−term behavior of headline inflation.

Page 104 of 132

1.0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

real 10-year Treasury rate drops below the Tealbook baseline for the next five
years. The unemployment rate is substantially lower than in the Tealbook
baseline and all other simulations shown, dropping below 2½ percent
in 2021. 8
•

Compared with the April Tealbook, the prescriptions of the simple rules are
around ¼ percentage point lower by the end of 2021.

OPTIMAL CONTROL SIMULATIONS UNDER COMMITMENT
The third exhibit displays optimal control simulations under various assumptions
about policymakers’ preferences, as captured by four specifications of the loss function. 9
The concept of optimal control employed here corresponds to a commitment policy under
which the plans that policymakers make today constrain future policy choices; such a
constraint may result in improved economic outcomes. 10
The first three of the four optimal control policies prescribe much higher paths for
the federal funds rate than the path in the baseline staff projection, for two reasons. First,
high levels of the real federal funds rate are necessary to push the unemployment rate up
to its natural rate, because, consistent with recent historical experience, the
unemployment rate does not respond strongly to changes in real interest rates in the
FRB/US model. Second, because monetary policy actions are assumed to be understood
and fully credible, the front-loading of policy tightening is not disruptive. In practice,
however, if the FOMC were to raise the real federal funds rate as high and as quickly as
prescribed by the first three optimal control policies, macroeconomic outcomes could be
less benign than shown here because of the confusion and financial market disruption that
such an abrupt change in policy might engender. 11 In contrast, the fourth optimal control
The unemployment rate subsequently rises to a level near its natural rate in 2031, while core PCE
inflation falls from a peak of 2.3 percent in 2020 to 2 percent in 2031.
9
The box “Optimal Control and the Loss Function” in the Monetary Policy Strategies section of
the June 2016 Tealbook B offers motivations for these specifications. The appendix in this Tealbook
section provides technical details on the optimal control simulations.
10
Under the optimal control policies, policymakers achieve the displayed economic outcomes by
making promises that bind future policymakers to take actions that will not be optimal from the perspective
of those future policymakers (that is, the promises are time inconsistent). It is assumed that these promises
are taken as credible by wage and price setters and by financial market participants.
11
The simulation results hinge on the assumptions that agents in the model have perfect foresight
and are certain that policymakers will implement the prescribed path for the federal funds rate. We discuss
an alternative assumption about expectations using simple policy rules in the box “Learning and
Misperceptions of Policy Strategies.”
8

Page 105 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
5.5

18

Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Tealbook baseline

Staff's estimate of the natural rate

16
14

5.0

12
10

4.5

Monetary Policy Strategies

8
6

4.0

4
2
2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

3.5

0
3.0

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
10

2.5

8
2017

6
4
2

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2.0

PCE Inflation
Percent

4−quarter average

2.5

0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

−2

2.0

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield
Percent
4

3

1.5
2

1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

1.0

Note: Each set of lines corresponds to an optimal control policy under commitment in which policymakers minimize a
discounted weighted sum of squared deviations of 4−quarter headline PCE inflation from the Committee's 2 percent objective,
of squared deviations of the unemployment rate from the staff's estimate of the natural rate, and of squared changes in the
federal funds rate. The weights vary across simulations. See the appendix for technical details and the box "Optimal Control
and the Loss Function" in the June 2016 Tealbook B for a motivation.
Page 106 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

policy allows the unemployment rate to decline to levels last experienced during the
1950s. Such a development might likewise entail outcomes different from those
predicted by the simulations.
•

The first simulation, labeled “Equal weights,” presents the case in which
policymakers are assumed to place equal weights on keeping headline PCE
inflation close to the Committee’s 2 percent objective, on keeping the
unemployment rate close to the staff’s estimate of the natural rate of
unemployment, and on keeping the federal funds rate close to its previous
value. Under this strategy, the path for the federal funds rate is significantly
higher than the Tealbook baseline path in order to temper the projected sizable
undershooting by the unemployment rate of its natural rate over the next
several years in the Tealbook baseline—an outcome that policymakers with
the equal-weights loss function judge to be costly. 12 The small projected
deviations of inflation from 2 percent in the Tealbook baseline entail
relatively small losses and so have little influence on optimal policy.
Moreover, a relatively rapid closing of the unemployment gap generates only
slightly lower inflation because, in the FRB/US model, the response of
inflation to the level of resource utilization is limited.

•

The second simulation, “Large weight on inflation gap,” is based on a loss
function that assigns a cost to deviations of inflation from 2 percent that is five
times larger than the specification with equal weights but is otherwise
identical to that specification. Even though the losses associated with
undershooting the inflation objective are larger in coming years, the resulting
optimal strategy is only marginally more accommodative than in the “Equal
weights” case, for two reasons. First, inflation is already close to the
Committee’s 2 percent objective. Second, in the FRB/US model,
policymakers face an unappealing tradeoff because inflation responds only
weakly to resource utilization.

•

The third simulation, “Minimal weight on rate adjustments,” uses a loss
function that assigns only a very small cost to changes in the federal funds rate

When we use the March 2018 SEP-consistent baseline as the underlying projection, the federal
funds rate under the optimal control simulation with equal weights peaks at around 5 percent, compared
with about 8 percent under the Tealbook baseline.
12

Page 107 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

but that is otherwise identical to the loss function with equal weights. This
simulation seeks to return the unemployment rate to its natural rate even faster
than under the equal-weights specification. As a result, the federal funds rate
soars above 11 percent at the end of 2018 and then averages around 7 percent
from 2020 through 2023.
•

The fourth simulation, “Asymmetric weight on ugap,” uses a loss function
that assigns no cost to deviations of the unemployment rate from the natural

Monetary Policy Strategies

rate when the unemployment rate is below the natural rate, but the loss
function is identical to the specification with equal weights when the
unemployment rate is above the natural rate. Under this strategy, the path of
the federal funds rate is considerably below the path in the optimal control
simulation with equal weights and below the Tealbook baseline path
throughout the period shown. With the asymmetric loss function,
policymakers choose this initially more accommodative path for the policy
rate because their desire to keep inflation close to 2 percent is not tempered by
an aversion to undershooting the natural rate of unemployment. The tighter
labor market keeps inflation closer to 2 percent than in the case of equal
weights. Starting in the middle of the 2020s (not shown), the unemployment
rate runs a little above its natural rate for several years as policymakers act to
contain the inflationary pressures stemming from the prolonged period of
elevated resource utilization.
The next four exhibits tabulate the simulation results for key variables under the
policy rule and optimal control simulations described previously.

Page 108 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Outcomes of Simple Policy Rule Simulations
(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Outcome and strategy

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.5
3.5
2.7
1.6
2.5

5.1
4.2
4.1
1.8
3.8

5.1
4.4
4.4
2.3
4.5

5.0
4.3
4.4
2.8
4.8

4.7
4.2
4.0
3.2
4.7

4.3
3.9
3.6
3.3
4.4

Real GDP
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.6
2.7
2.8
3.0
2.8

2.2
2.6
2.6
3.4
2.4

1.8
2.1
2.0
2.5
1.8

1.7
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.5

1.3
1.3
1.3
1.0
1.1

1.2
1.1
1.2
.8
1.1

Unemployment rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.7
3.6
3.6
3.5
3.6

3.7
3.4
3.4
2.9
3.4

3.6
3.3
3.2
2.5
3.4

3.7
3.3
3.3
2.5
3.6

3.8
3.5
3.4
2.9
3.8

4.0
3.7
3.6
3.4
4.1

Total PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.3
2.0

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.4
2.1

Core PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0
1.9

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.3
2.0

2.1
2.3
2.2
2.3
2.1

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.4
2.1

2.2
2.4
2.3
2.4
2.1

2.2
2.4
2.3
2.4
2.2

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 109 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Outcomes of Simple Policy Rule Simulations, Quarterly
(4-quarter percent change, except as noted)

2018

2019

Monetary Policy Strategies

Outcome and strategy
Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7

4.5
3.5
2.2
1.6
2.1

4.5
3.5
2.7
1.6
2.5

4.6
3.7
3.2
1.6
2.9

4.7
3.8
3.6
1.6
3.2

4.9
4.1
3.9
1.7
3.5

5.1
4.2
4.1
1.8
3.8

Real GDP
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8

2.9
2.9
2.9
2.9
2.9

2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8

2.6
2.7
2.8
3.0
2.8

2.7
2.9
3.0
3.3
2.9

2.3
2.7
2.8
3.4
2.7

2.2
2.6
2.7
3.5
2.6

2.2
2.6
2.6
3.4
2.4

Unemployment rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1

3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

3.7
3.7
3.7
3.7
3.7

3.7
3.6
3.6
3.5
3.6

3.7
3.5
3.5
3.3
3.5

3.6
3.5
3.4
3.1
3.4

3.7
3.4
3.4
3.0
3.4

3.7
3.4
3.4
2.9
3.4

Total PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8

2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.1
1.9

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.1
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
1.9

Core PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.1
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.3
2.0

1. Percent, average for the quarter.

Page 110 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Outcomes of Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment
(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Outcome and strategy

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.5
3.5
11.5
2.0
2.5

6.0
6.0
8.7
2.5
3.8

7.1
6.9
6.3
3.0
4.5

7.1
6.9
6.4
3.5
4.8

6.6
6.4
7.5
3.9
4.7

5.8
5.5
6.8
4.1
4.4

Real GDP
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.5
2.6
2.1
2.9
2.8

1.4
1.5
.6
2.9
2.4

1.1
1.2
1.7
2.1
1.8

1.4
1.4
1.9
1.6
1.5

1.4
1.4
1.5
.9
1.1

1.4
1.4
1.4
.8
1.1

Unemployment rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.7
3.7
3.9
3.5
3.6

4.0
4.0
4.7
3.2
3.4

4.4
4.3
4.7
3.0
3.4

4.7
4.5
4.7
3.1
3.6

4.7
4.6
4.6
3.5
3.8

4.7
4.5
4.6
4.0
4.1

Total PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1

1.7
1.7
1.7
2.0
1.9

1.7
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.9
2.0
1.9
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1

Core PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.8
1.9
1.8
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
2.0

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
2.1

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.2
2.2

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 111 of 132

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

June 1, 2018

Outcomes of Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment, Quarterly
(4-quarter percent change, except as noted)

2018

2019

Monetary Policy Strategies

Outcome and strategy
Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7

2.7
2.7
8.8
1.9
2.1

3.5
3.5
11.5
2.0
2.5

4.3
4.3
11.8
2.1
2.9

5.0
5.0
10.9
2.2
3.2

5.5
5.5
9.8
2.4
3.5

6.0
6.0
8.7
2.5
3.8

Real GDP
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8

2.9
2.9
2.9
2.9
2.9

2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8

2.5
2.6
2.1
2.9
2.8

2.4
2.5
1.7
3.1
2.9

1.9
2.0
.9
3.0
2.7

1.6
1.6
.4
3.0
2.6

1.4
1.5
.6
2.9
2.4

Unemployment rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1

3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

3.7
3.7
3.7
3.7
3.7

3.7
3.7
3.9
3.5
3.6

3.7
3.7
4.3
3.4
3.5

3.8
3.7
4.5
3.3
3.4

3.9
3.9
4.6
3.2
3.4

4.0
4.0
4.7
3.2
3.4

Total PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8

2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1

1.8
1.8
1.8
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
1.7
1.9
1.9

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.9
1.9

1.7
1.7
1.7
2.0
1.9

Core PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.9
1.8
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
1.8
1.9
1.9

1.7
1.8
1.7
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
2.0

1. Percent, average for the quarter.

Page 112 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Appendix
Implementation of the Simple Rules and Optimal Control Simulations
The monetary policy strategies considered in this section of Tealbook A typically fall into
one of two categories. Under simple policy rules, policymakers set the federal funds rate
according to a reaction function that includes a small number of macroeconomic factors. Under
optimal control policies, policymakers compute a path for the federal funds rate that minimizes a
loss function meant to capture policymakers’ preferences over macroeconomic outcomes. Both
approaches recognize the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate. Unless otherwise noted, the
simulations embed the assumption that policymakers will adhere to the policy strategy in the
future and that financial market participants, price setters, and wage setters not only believe that
policymakers will follow through with their strategy, but also fully understand the
macroeconomic implications of policymakers doing so. Such policy strategies are described as
commitment strategies.
The two approaches have different merits and limitations. The parsimony of simple rules
makes them relatively easy to communicate to the public, and, because they respond only to
variables that are central to a range of models, proponents argue that they may be more robust to
uncertainty about the structure of the economy. However, simple rules omit, by construction,
other potential influences on policy decisions; thus, strict adherence to such rules may, at times,
lead to unsatisfactory outcomes. By comparison, optimal control policies respond to a broader set
of economic factors; their prescriptions optimally balance various policy objectives. And,
although this section focuses on policies under commitment, optimal control policies can more
generally be derived under various assumptions about the degree to which policymakers can
commit. That said, optimal control policies assume substantial knowledge on the part of
policymakers and are sensitive to the assumed loss function and the specifics of the
particular model.
Given the different strengths and weaknesses of the two approaches, they are probably
best considered together as a means to assess the various tradeoffs policymakers may face when
pursuing their mandated objectives.

POLICY RULES USED IN THE MONETARY POLICY STRATEGIES SECTION
The table “Simple Rules” that follows gives expressions for four simple policy rules
reported in the Monetary Policy Strategies section. It also reports the expression for the inertial
version of the Taylor (1999) rule; the staff uses that inertial version, augmented with a small
temporary intercept adjustment, in the construction of the Tealbook baseline projection. 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡
denotes the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by a strategy for quarter t; for quarters prior to
the projection period under consideration, 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 corresponds to the historical data in the economic
projection. The right-hand-side variables include the staff’s projection of trailing four-quarter
core PCE price inflation for the current quarter and three quarters ahead (𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 and 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 ), the
output gap estimate for the current period (𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 ), and the forecast of the three-quarter-ahead
Page 113 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

annual change in the output gap (𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 − 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡−1 ). The value of policymakers’ longer-run
inflation objective, denoted 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 , is 2 percent.

The flexible price-level targeting rule responds to a price gap and an unemployment rate
gap. The price gap is defined as 100 times the difference between the log of the core PCE price
level, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 , and the log of the target price-level path, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗. The 2011:Q4 value of the target path is set
to the 2011:Q4 value of the core PCE price level, and, subsequently, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ is assumed to grow at a
2 percent annual rate. The unemployment gap is defined as the difference between the
unemployment rate, 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 , and the staff’s estimate of its natural rate, 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ .

Monetary Policy Strategies

Simple Rules

Taylor (1999) rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Inertial Taylor (1999) rule
First-difference rule
Flexible price-level
targeting rule

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 0.5𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 )
𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.5�𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 � + 0.5Δ4 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + (𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 − 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ ) − (𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 − 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ ))

The first two of the selected rules were studied by Taylor (1993, 1999), whereas the
inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule and rules that depend on a price gap like the FPLT rule
have been featured prominently in analysis by Board staff. 1 An FPLT rule similar to the one
above is also analyzed by Chung and others (2014).
Where applicable, the intercepts of the simple rules, denoted 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 , are constant and chosen
so that they are consistent with a 2 percent longer-run inflation objective and an equilibrium real
federal funds rate in the longer run of 0.5 percent. 2 The prescriptions of the first-difference rule
do not depend on the level of the output gap or the longer-run real interest rate; see
Orphanides (2003).

NEAR-TERM PRESCRIPTIONS OF SELECTED POLICY RULES
The “Near-Term Prescriptions of Selected Policy Rules” reported in the first exhibit are
calculated taking as given the Tealbook projections for inflation and the output gap. When the
Tealbook is published early in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the current and next
quarters. When the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the
next two quarters. Rules that include a lagged policy rate as a right-hand-side variable are
conditioned on the lagged federal funds rate in the Tealbook projection for the first quarter shown
For applications, see, for example, Erceg and others (2012).
All nominal and real federal funds rates reported in the Monetary Policy Strategies section are
expressed on the same 360-day basis as the published federal funds rate. Consistent with the methodology
in the FRB/US model, the simple rules are first implemented on a fully compounded, 365-day basis and
then converted to a 360-day basis.
1
2

Page 114 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

and then conditioned on their simulated lagged federal funds rate for the second quarter shown.
To isolate the effects of changes in macroeconomic projections on the prescriptions of these
inertial rules, the lines labeled “Previous Tealbook projection” report prescriptions that are
conditional on the previous Tealbook projections for inflation and the output gap but that use the
value of the lagged federal funds rate in the current Tealbook for the first quarter shown.

A MEDIUM-TERM NOTION OF THE EQUILIBRIUM REAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
The bottom panel of the exhibit “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection” provides
estimates of one notion of the equilibrium real federal funds rate that uses alternative baselines:
the Tealbook baseline and another one consistent with median responses to the latest Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP). The simulations are conducted using the FRB/US model, the staff’s
large-scale econometric model of the U.S. economy. “FRB/US r*” is the real federal funds rate
that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period (beginning in the current quarter), makes the output
gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period, given either the Tealbook or the SEPconsistent economic projection. 3 This measure depends on a broad array of economic factors,
some of which take the form of projected values of the model’s exogenous variables. The
measure is derived under the assumption that agents in the model form VAR-based
expectations—that is, agents use small-scale statistical models so that their expectations of future
variables are determined solely by historical relationships.
The “Average projected real federal funds rate” for the Tealbook baseline and the SEPconsistent baseline reported in the panel are the corresponding averages of the real federal funds
rate under the Tealbook baseline projection and SEP-consistent projection, respectively,
calculated over the same 12-quarter period as the Tealbook-consistent and SEP-consistent
FRB/US r*. For a given economic projection, the average projected real federal funds rates and
the FRB/US r* may be associated with somewhat different macroeconomic outcomes even when
their values are identical. The reason is that, in the FRB/US r* simulation, the real federal funds
rate is held constant over the entire 12-quarter period, whereas, in the economic projection, the
real federal funds rate can vary over time.

FRB/US MODEL SIMULATIONS
The results presented in the exhibits “Simple Policy Rule Simulations” and “Optimal
Control Simulations under Commitment” are derived from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US
model. Each simulated policy strategy is assumed to be in force over the whole period covered
by the simulation; this period extends several decades beyond the time horizon shown in the
exhibits. The simulations are conducted under the assumption that market participants as well as
price and wage setters form model-consistent expectations and are predicated on the staff’s
extended Tealbook projection, which includes the macroeconomic effects of the Committee’s
large-scale asset purchase programs. When the Tealbook is published early in a quarter, all of the
simulations begin in that quarter; when the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, all of the
simulations begin in the subsequent quarter.

For a discussion of the equilibrium real federal funds rates in the longer run and other concepts
of equilibrium interest rates, see Gust and others (2016).
3

Page 115 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

COMPUTATION OF OPTIMAL CONTROL POLICIES UNDER COMMITMENT

Monetary Policy Strategies

The optimal control simulations posit that policymakers minimize a discounted weighted
sum of squared inflation gaps (measured as the difference between four-quarter headline PCE
price inflation, 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 , and the Committee’s 2 percent objective), squared unemployment gaps
(𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 , measured as the difference between the unemployment rate and the staff’s estimate of
the natural rate), and squared changes in the federal funds rate. In the following equation, the
resulting loss function embeds the assumption that policymakers discount the future using a
quarterly discount factor, 𝛽𝛽 = 0.9963:
𝑳𝑳𝒕𝒕 = �

𝑇𝑇

𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃
𝜷𝜷𝝉𝝉 �𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋 (𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏
− 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 )𝟐𝟐 + 𝜆𝜆𝑢𝑢,𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 (𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 )𝟐𝟐 + 𝜆𝜆𝐿𝐿 (𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡+𝝉𝝉 − 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡+𝝉𝝉−𝟏𝟏 )𝟐𝟐 �.

𝝉𝝉=𝟎𝟎

The exhibit “Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment” considers four
specifications of the weights on the inflation gap, the unemployment gap, and the rate change
components of the loss function. The box “Optimal Control and the Loss Function” in the
Monetary Policy Strategies section of the June 2016 Tealbook B provides motivations for the four
specifications of the loss function.
The first specification, “Equal weights,” assigns equal weights to all three components at
all times. The second specification, “Large weight on inflation gap,” attaches a relatively large
weight to inflation gaps. The third specification, “Minimal weight on rate adjustments,” places
almost no weight on changes in the federal funds rate. 4 The fourth specification, “Asymmetric
weight on ugap,” uses the same weights as the equal-weights specification whenever the
unemployment rate is above the staff’s estimate of the natural rate, but it assigns no penalty to the
unemployment rate falling below the natural rate. The table “Loss Functions” shows the weights
used in the four specifications. The optimal control policy and associated outcomes depend on
the relative (rather than the absolute) values of the weights.

Loss Functions

Equal weights
Large weight
on inflation gap
Minimal weight on
rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight
on ugap

𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋
1

5

1

1

𝜆𝜆𝑢𝑢,𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏

𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 < 0

𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 ≥ 0

1

1

1

1

0

1
1

1

𝜆𝜆𝐿𝐿
1

1

0.01
1

The inclusion of a minimal but strictly positive weight on changes in the federal funds rate helps
ensure a well-behaved numerical solution.
4

Page 116 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

For each of these four specifications of the loss function, the optimal control policy is the
path for the federal funds rate that minimizes the loss function in the FRB/US model, subject to
the effective lower bound constraint on nominal interest rates, under the assumption that market
participants and wage and price setters employ model-consistent expectations and conditional on
the staff’s extended Tealbook projection. Policy tools other than the federal funds rate are taken
as given and subsumed within the Tealbook baseline. The path chosen by policymakers today is
assumed to be credible, meaning that the public sees this path as a binding commitment on
policymakers’ future decisions; the optimal control policy takes as given the initial lagged value
of the federal funds rate but is otherwise unconstrained by policy decisions made prior to the
simulation period. The discounted losses are calculated over a horizon that ends sufficiently far
in the future so that extending the horizon further would not affect the policy prescriptions shown
in the exhibits.

REFERENCES
Chung, Hess, Edward Herbst, and Michael T. Kiley (2014). “Effective Monetary Policy
Strategies in New Keynesian Models: A Reexamination,” NBER Macroeconomics
Annual, vol. 29 (1), pp. 289−344.
Erceg, Christopher, Jon Faust, Michael Kiley, Jean-Philippe Laforte, David López-Salido,
Stephen Meyer, Edward Nelson, David Reifschneider, and Robert Tetlow (2012). “An
Overview of Simple Policy Rules and Their Use in Policymaking in Normal Times and
Under Current Conditions,” memorandum to the Federal Open Market Committee, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Divisions of International Finance,
Monetary Affairs, and Research and Statistics, July 18.
Gust, Christopher, Benjamin K. Johannsen, David López-Salido, and Robert Tetlow (2016).
“r*: Concepts, Measures, and Uses,” memorandum to the Federal Open Market
Committee, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Monetary
Affairs, October 13.
Orphanides, Athanasios (2003). “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983−1022.
Taylor, John B. (1993). “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39 (December), pp. 195−214.
--------- (1999). “A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed.,
Monetary Policy Rules. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 319−41.

Page 117 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Monetary Policy Strategies

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 118 of 132

June 1, 2018

3.3
4.1
5.3
5.3
4.4
4.7
4.8
4.7
5.1
4.8
4.7
4.3

3.7
5.3
4.6
4.8
4.9
4.5

3.4
4.5
4.7
4.7
4.2

Quarterly
2017:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
2018:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
2019:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Two-quarter2
2017:Q2
Q4
2018:Q2
Q4
2019:Q2
Q4

Four-quarter3
2016:Q4
2017:Q4
2018:Q4
2019:Q4
2020:Q4

Page 119 of 132

3.4
4.5
4.9
4.5
3.9

3.7
5.3
5.0
4.7
4.8
4.2

3.3
4.1
5.3
5.3
4.2
5.8
4.8
4.7
4.7
4.9
4.3
4.1

06/01/18

1.8
2.6
2.6
2.6
2.1

2.1
3.0
2.3
2.9
2.8
2.4

1.2
3.1
3.2
2.9
1.7
2.9
3.0
2.9
2.9
2.7
2.6
2.3

04/20/18

1.8
2.6
2.8
2.4
1.8

2.1
3.0
2.8
2.7
2.6
2.3

1.2
3.1
3.2
2.9
2.2
3.4
2.7
2.8
2.7
2.5
2.3
2.3

06/01/18

Real GDP

1.6
1.7
2.1
1.9
2.0

1.2
2.1
2.5
1.7
1.9
1.9

2.2
.3
1.5
2.7
2.8
2.2
1.8
1.5
1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0

04/20/18

1.6
1.7
2.1
1.9
2.0

1.2
2.1
2.3
1.8
2.0
1.8

2.2
.3
1.5
2.7
2.6
2.0
2.0
1.7
2.0
1.9
1.8
1.8

06/01/18

PCE price index

1.9
1.5
2.0
2.1
2.1

1.4
1.6
2.4
1.7
2.1
2.1

1.8
.9
1.3
1.9
2.5
2.2
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1

04/20/18

Greensheets

1.8
1.5
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.9
1.5
1.9
2.0
2.1

1.4
1.6
2.1
1.7
2.1
1.9

1.8
.9
1.3
1.9
2.3
2.0
1.6
1.7
2.2
2.1
1.9
2.0

06/01/18

4.9
4.4
3.9
3.3
3.3

-.3
-.6
-.5
-.3
.0

-.4
-.2
-.1
-.4
-.3
.0

4.6
4.3
4.3
4.1
4.1
4.0
3.8
3.6
3.4
3.3
3.3
3.3

04/20/18

4.9
4.4
3.8
3.4
3.4

-.3
-.6
-.5
-.2
.0

-.4
-.2
-.3
-.2
-.2
.0

4.6
4.3
4.3
4.1
4.1
3.8
3.7
3.6
3.5
3.4
3.4
3.4

06/01/18

Core PCE price index Unemployment rate1

Authorized for Public Release

Annual
2016
2.8
2.8
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2
1.8
2017
4.1
4.1
2.3
2.3
1.7
1.7
1.5
2018
4.8
4.9
2.6
2.8
2.1
2.1
2.0
2019
4.8
4.7
2.8
2.6
1.8
1.9
2.0
2020
4.4
4.1
2.2
2.0
2.0
1.9
2.1
1. Level, except for two-quarter and four-quarter intervals.
2. Percent change from two quarters earlier; for unemployment rate, change is in percentage points.
3. Percent change from four quarters earlier; for unemployment rate, change is in percentage points.

04/20/18

Interval

Nominal GDP

Changes in GDP, Prices, and Unemployment
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

Page 120 of 132

5
5

Change in priv. inventories2
Previous Tealbook2
16
16

3.0
3.0
3.2
5.5
-.1
2.9

.7
.7
1.3
2.4
-.2
.2
39
39

-654
-654
7.0
14.1

6.8
6.8
7.0
7.0
6.3
6.3

12.8
12.8

4.0
4.0
13.7
4.8
2.3

3.4
3.4
4.8
4.8

2.9
2.9

Q4

-598
-598
2.1
-.7

4.7
4.7
8.4
8.4
-7.0
-7.0

-4.7
-4.7

2.2
2.2
8.6
2.3
1.1

2.4
2.4
2.2
2.2

3.2
3.2

Q3

20
58

1.1
-1.2
1.7
1.8
1.6
.8

-651
-676
4.2
2.8

9.2
5.7
7.7
5.8
14.2
5.6

-1.7
-4.1

1.0
1.2
-2.6
.4
1.8

2.1
.7
2.1
1.6

2.2
1.7

Q1

33
62

1.0
1.2
1.1
2.0
-.3
.9

-643
-671
5.0
2.8

6.1
8.0
5.1
6.4
9.6
13.5

-.9
-2.1

2.9
2.2
7.8
2.4
2.3

3.1
2.8
3.2
2.8

3.4
2.9

Q2

25
47

1.9
2.2
3.5
4.2
2.5
.9

-646
-663
5.8
5.0

7.8
6.2
7.1
5.8
10.0
7.5

-.7
5.0

2.4
2.6
4.8
1.9
2.1

2.9
3.3
3.0
3.2

2.7
3.0

Q3

2018

25
30

1.7
2.7
3.2
4.0
2.1
.9

-642
-651
4.2
2.7

5.6
5.0
5.9
5.3
4.3
4.2

1.2
5.1

2.3
2.5
3.6
2.6
2.1

2.8
3.3
2.8
3.0

2.8
2.9

Q4

23
20

1.6
1.7
2.6
3.0
2.0
1.0

-640
-642
4.5
3.1

5.1
4.7
5.8
5.5
2.8
2.3

-.8
1.6

2.6
2.8
2.1
2.7
2.7

2.8
3.1
2.8
3.0

2.7
2.9

Q1

19
16

2.3
2.3
4.4
5.5
2.8
1.0

-652
-650
4.0
4.9

4.3
4.3
4.7
4.8
3.1
2.7

1.4
1.6

2.6
2.7
2.1
2.7
2.6

2.5
2.8
2.8
2.9

2.5
2.7

Q2

19
18

2.2
2.2
4.3
5.0
3.3
1.0

-669
-659
4.2
5.6

3.4
3.5
3.7
4.0
2.2
1.8

.9
1.8

2.5
2.6
2.0
2.6
2.6

2.3
2.5
2.6
2.7

2.3
2.6

Q3

2019

20
10

2.4
2.4
4.6
5.3
3.6
1.0

-682
-663
3.4
4.4

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.6
1.6
1.4

.8
1.8

2.5
2.5
2.0
2.6
2.6

2.2
2.5
2.4
2.5

2.3
2.3

Q4

15
15

.7
.7
1.0
2.3
-.9
.5

-622
-622
5.0
4.7

6.3
6.3
6.7
6.7
5.0
5.0

2.6
2.6

2.8
2.8
7.3
3.1
2.1

2.9
2.9
3.3
3.3

2.6
2.6

20171

26
49

1.4
1.2
2.4
3.0
1.5
.9

-646
-665
4.8
3.3

7.1
6.2
6.5
5.8
9.5
7.7

-.5
.9

2.2
2.1
3.3
1.8
2.1

2.7
2.5
2.8
2.6

2.8
2.6

20181

20
16

2.1
2.2
4.0
4.7
2.9
1.0

-661
-654
4.0
4.5

3.7
3.7
4.2
4.2
2.4
2.0

.6
1.7

2.6
2.7
2.1
2.7
2.6

2.5
2.7
2.7
2.8

2.4
2.6

20191

20
5

1.8
1.9
3.0
3.3
2.7
1.0

-720
-696
3.0
4.3

1.3
1.7
1.6
2.0
.4
.5

1.5
3.3

2.3
2.5
1.7
2.4
2.3

1.8
2.1
2.1
2.4

1.8
2.1

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
2. Billions of chained (2009) dollars.

-.2
-.2
1.9
4.7
-1.9
-1.5

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

6.7
6.7
6.6
6.6
7.0
7.0

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook
-614
-614
3.5
1.5

-7.3
-7.3

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

Net exports2
Previous Tealbook2
Exports
Imports

3.3
3.3
7.6
4.2
2.3

3.0
3.0
3.3
3.3

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

3.1
3.1

Q2

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

2017

Greensheets
Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product and Related Items
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

Page 121 of 132

38
38

Change in priv. inventories1
Previous Tealbook1

55
55

-2.2
-2.2
-2.1
-3.9
1.0
-2.3

-447
-447
2.2
.3

5.2
5.2
5.5
5.5
4.1
4.1

15.7
15.7

1.3
1.3
7.2
.8
.6

1.7
1.7
2.3
2.3

1.3
1.3

2012

79
79

-2.8
-2.8
-6.7
-7.1
-6.0
-.1

-405
-405
5.9
2.5

4.8
4.8
4.5
4.5
5.8
5.8

6.8
6.8

2.0
2.0
5.2
2.6
1.3

2.0
2.0
2.6
2.6

2.7
2.7

2013

Greensheets

68
68

.5
.5
-1.2
-4.0
3.5
1.5

-428
-428
3.0
6.2

6.1
6.1
5.3
5.3
8.8
8.8

6.3
6.3

3.6
3.6
8.7
2.8
3.0

2.9
2.9
4.1
4.1

2.7
2.7

2014

101
101

1.6
1.6
1.2
.0
2.9
1.9

-545
-545
-1.8
2.9

.3
.3
3.3
3.3
-9.1
-9.1

10.3
10.3

3.0
3.0
6.4
2.8
2.6

2.0
2.0
2.9
2.9

2.0
2.0

2015

33
33

.4
.4
-.3
-1.4
1.2
.8

-586
-586
.6
2.7

.7
.7
-.1
-.1
3.5
3.5

2.5
2.5

2.8
2.8
7.0
2.5
2.3

1.9
1.9
2.5
2.5

1.8
1.8

2016

15
15

.7
.7
1.0
2.3
-.9
.5

-622
-622
5.0
4.7

6.3
6.3
6.7
6.7
5.0
5.0

2.6
2.6

2.8
2.8
7.3
3.1
2.1

2.9
2.9
3.3
3.3

2.6
2.6

2017

26
49

1.4
1.2
2.4
3.0
1.5
.9

-646
-665
4.8
3.3

7.1
6.2
6.5
5.8
9.5
7.7

-.5
.9

2.2
2.1
3.3
1.8
2.1

2.7
2.5
2.8
2.6

2.8
2.6

2018

20
16

2.1
2.2
4.0
4.7
2.9
1.0

-661
-654
4.0
4.5

3.7
3.7
4.2
4.2
2.4
2.0

.6
1.7

2.6
2.7
2.1
2.7
2.6

2.5
2.7
2.7
2.8

2.4
2.6

2019

20
5

1.8
1.9
3.0
3.3
2.7
1.0

-720
-696
3.0
4.3

1.3
1.7
1.6
2.0
.4
.5

1.5
3.3

2.3
2.5
1.7
2.4
2.3

1.8
2.1
2.1
2.4

1.8
2.1

2020

Authorized for Public Release

1. Billions of chained (2009) dollars.

-3.0
-3.0
-4.0
-4.1
-3.9
-2.3

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

9.0
9.0
9.2
9.2
8.0
8.0

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook
-459
-459
4.2
3.5

6.0
6.0

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

Net exports1
Previous Tealbook1
Exports
Imports

1.5
1.5
4.8
.4
1.4

1.5
1.5
2.6
2.6

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

1.7
1.7

2011

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product and Related Items
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

Page 122 of 132

.0
.0
.1
.2
-.1
-.2
.1
.1

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

Change in priv. inventories
Previous Tealbook

.8
.8

.1
.1
.1
.1
.0
.0

.4
.4
.3
.1

.6
.6
.8
.8
-.2
-.2

-.2
-.2

1.5
1.5
.6
.3
.5

2.4
2.4
1.9
1.9

3.2
3.2

Q3

-.5
-.5

.5
.5
.2
.2
.0
.3

-1.2
-1.2
.8
-2.0

.8
.8
.7
.7
.2
.2

.5
.5

2.8
2.8
1.0
.7
1.1

3.4
3.4
4.1
4.1

2.9
2.9

Q4

.1
1.0

.2
-.2
.1
.1
.0
.1

.1
-.5
.5
-.4

1.1
.7
.7
.6
.4
.2

-.1
-.2

.7
.8
-.2
.1
.8

2.1
.7
1.8
1.4

2.2
1.7

Q1

.3
.1

.2
.2
.1
.1
.0
.1

.2
.1
.6
-.4

.8
1.0
.5
.6
.3
.4

.0
-.1

2.0
1.5
.6
.4
1.1

3.1
2.7
2.8
2.4

3.4
2.9

Q2

-.2
-.3

.3
.4
.2
.2
.1
.1

-.1
.2
.7
-.8

1.0
.8
.7
.6
.3
.2

.0
.2

1.6
1.8
.4
.3
1.0

2.9
3.3
2.6
2.7

2.7
3.0

Q3

2018

.0
-.4

.3
.5
.2
.2
.1
.1

.1
.3
.5
-.4

.7
.6
.6
.5
.1
.1

.0
.2

1.6
1.7
.3
.4
1.0

2.8
3.3
2.4
2.6

2.8
2.9

Q4

-.1
-.2

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

.1
.2
.5
-.5

.7
.6
.6
.5
.1
.1

.0
.1

1.8
1.9
.2
.4
1.3

2.8
3.1
2.4
2.6

2.7
2.9

Q1

-.1
-.1

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

-.2
-.1
.5
-.7

.6
.6
.5
.5
.1
.1

.1
.1

1.8
1.9
.2
.4
1.2

2.5
2.7
2.4
2.5

2.5
2.7

Q2

.0
.0

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

-.3
-.2
.5
-.8

.4
.5
.4
.4
.1
.1

.0
.1

1.7
1.8
.1
.4
1.2

2.3
2.5
2.2
2.3

2.3
2.6

Q3

2019

.0
-.2

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

-.2
.0
.4
-.7

.3
.3
.2
.3
.1
.0

.0
.1

1.7
1.7
.1
.4
1.2

2.2
2.5
2.1
2.1

2.3
2.3

Q4

-.3
-.3

.1
.1
.1
.1
.0
.1

-.1
-.1
.6
-.7

.8
.8
.6
.6
.1
.1

.1
.1

2.0
2.0
.5
.5
1.0

2.9
2.9
2.8
2.8

2.6
2.6

20171

.1
.1

.2
.2
.2
.1
.0
.1

.1
.0
.6
-.5

.9
.8
.6
.6
.3
.2

.0
.0

1.5
1.4
.3
.3
1.0

2.7
2.5
2.4
2.3

2.8
2.6

20181

.0
-.1

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

-.2
.0
.5
-.7

.5
.5
.4
.4
.1
.1

.0
.1

1.8
1.8
.2
.4
1.2

2.4
2.7
2.3
2.4

2.4
2.6

20191

.0
.0

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.3
-.3
.4
-.7

.2
.2
.2
.2
.0
.0

.1
.1

1.6
1.7
.1
.3
1.1

1.8
2.1
1.8
2.0

1.8
2.1

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.

.2
.2
.4
-.2

.8
.8
.6
.6
.2
.2

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook

Net exports
Previous Tealbook
Exports
Imports

-.3
-.3

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

2.2
2.2
.6
.6
1.1

2.9
2.9
2.8
2.8

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

3.1
3.1

Q2

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

2017

Contributions to Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product
(Percentage points, annual rate except as noted)

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

2.2
2.2
1.6
1.6
.6
.5
-1.0
-1.0
2.5
2.5

ECI, hourly compensation2
Previous Tealbook2

Business sector
Output per hour
Previous Tealbook
Compensation per hour
Previous Tealbook
Unit labor costs
Previous Tealbook

Page 123 of 132

Core goods imports chain-wt. price index3
Previous Tealbook3
1.1
1.1

3.2
3.2
4.2
4.1
.9
.9

3.1
3.1

2.1
2.1
1.8
1.8

1.5
1.5
8.4
8.4
.2
.2
1.3
1.3
1.0
1.0

2.1
2.1

Q3

1.5
1.5

-.4
-.4
2.1
1.7
2.6
2.2

1.9
1.9

3.3
3.3
2.2
2.2

2.7
2.7
27.7
27.7
.2
.2
1.9
1.9
1.5
1.5

2.3
2.3

Q4

2.8
2.8

.8
.8
4.1
3.9
3.3
3.0

4.0
2.6

3.5
3.5
3.0
3.0

2.6
2.8
12.9
12.7
.2
.2
2.3
2.5
2.3
2.3

1.9
2.7

Q1

2.6
3.6

2.4
.7
1.8
2.7
-.6
2.0

2.4
2.4

2.0
2.2
1.9
2.3

2.0
2.2
3.1
2.6
1.7
1.6
2.0
2.2
2.2
2.2

2.3
1.8

Q2

.6
.9

1.0
1.6
4.0
3.8
2.9
2.1

2.5
2.4

2.1
1.8
2.2
2.1

1.7
1.5
.2
-2.2
2.3
2.3
1.7
1.7
1.5
1.4

1.8
1.8

Q4

Greensheets

-.2
1.8

1.0
1.6
3.6
3.8
2.6
2.2

2.4
2.4

2.7
2.2
2.2
2.3

2.0
1.8
9.0
1.4
1.8
2.0
1.6
1.8
1.6
1.7

2.1
1.8

Q3

2018

.8
.7

1.2
.9
4.0
3.9
2.8
2.9

2.8
2.6

2.3
2.1
2.5
2.4

2.0
1.9
-1.1
-2.3
2.3
2.3
2.2
2.0
2.0
1.8

1.9
2.2

Q1

.6
.6

1.0
1.0
4.0
3.9
3.0
2.9

2.8
2.7

2.2
2.2
2.5
2.5

1.9
1.9
-1.3
-1.8
2.3
2.3
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.4
2.0

Q2

.6
.6

.8
.9
4.0
3.9
3.1
3.0

2.8
2.7

2.1
2.2
2.4
2.5

1.8
1.9
-1.3
-1.7
2.3
2.3
1.9
2.1
1.8
1.9

2.0
2.0

Q3

2019

.5
.5

.8
.6
4.0
3.9
3.1
3.3

2.8
2.7

2.1
2.2
2.4
2.5

1.8
2.0
-1.3
-1.6
2.3
2.3
2.0
2.1
1.8
1.9

1.8
2.0

Q4

1.3
1.3

.9
.9
2.8
2.7
1.8
1.8

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.1
1.7
1.7

1.7
1.7
7.6
7.6
.7
.7
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.9
1.9

20171

1.4
2.3

1.3
1.2
3.4
3.5
2.0
2.3

2.8
2.5

2.6
2.4
2.3
2.4

2.1
2.1
6.2
3.5
1.5
1.5
1.9
2.0
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

20181

.6
.6

.9
.9
4.0
3.9
3.0
3.0

2.8
2.7

2.2
2.2
2.5
2.5

1.9
1.9
-1.3
-1.9
2.3
2.3
2.0
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.1

20191

.6
.6

.9
.9
4.0
3.9
3.0
3.0

2.9
2.7

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.5

2.0
2.0
-1.0
-1.1
2.3
2.3
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.1

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
2. Private-industry workers.
3. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.

.1
.1
.8
.8

.3
.3
-16.0
-16.0
2.0
2.0
.9
.9
.3
.3

1.0
1.0

Q2

Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook

CPI

PCE chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook
Energy
Previous Tealbook
Food
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy, market based
Previous Tealbook

GDP chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook

Item

2017

Changes in Prices and Costs
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

2.2
2.2
-.1
-.1
.5
.5
.6
.6
4.3
4.3

ECI, hourly compensation1
Previous Tealbook1

Business sector
Output per hour
Previous Tealbook
Compensation per hour
Previous Tealbook
Unit labor costs
Previous Tealbook

Page 124 of 132

Core goods imports chain-wt. price index2
Previous Tealbook2
.1
.1

-.1
-.1
5.9
5.9
6.0
6.0

1.8
1.8

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
2.3
2.3
1.2
1.2
1.8
1.8
1.5
1.5

1.9
1.9

2012

-1.5
-1.5

1.9
1.9
-.1
-.1
-2.0
-2.0

2.0
2.0

1.2
1.2
1.7
1.7

1.2
1.2
-2.5
-2.5
.7
.7
1.5
1.5
1.1
1.1

1.6
1.6

2013

.3
.3

.1
.1
2.9
2.9
2.8
2.8

2.3
2.3

1.2
1.2
1.7
1.7

1.2
1.2
-6.5
-6.5
2.6
2.6
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.6
1.6

2014

-3.7
-3.7

.7
.7
3.1
3.1
2.4
2.4

1.9
1.9

.4
.4
2.0
2.0

.4
.4
-16.2
-16.2
.3
.3
1.3
1.3
1.1
1.1

1.0
1.0

2015

-.2
-.2

1.1
1.0
-.1
-.2
-1.2
-1.2

2.2
2.2

1.8
1.8
2.2
2.2

1.6
1.6
2.2
2.2
-1.7
-1.7
1.9
1.9
1.5
1.5

1.5
1.5

2016

1.3
1.3

.9
.9
2.8
2.7
1.8
1.8

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.1
1.7
1.7

1.7
1.7
7.6
7.6
.7
.7
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.9
1.9

2017

1.4
2.3

1.3
1.2
3.4
3.5
2.0
2.3

2.8
2.5

2.6
2.4
2.3
2.4

2.1
2.1
6.2
3.5
1.5
1.5
1.9
2.0
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

2018

.6
.6

.9
.9
4.0
3.9
3.0
3.0

2.8
2.7

2.2
2.2
2.5
2.5

1.9
1.9
-1.3
-1.9
2.3
2.3
2.0
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.1

2019

.6
.6

.9
.9
4.0
3.9
3.0
3.0

2.9
2.7

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.5

2.0
2.0
-1.0
-1.1
2.3
2.3
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.1

2020

Authorized for Public Release

1. Private-industry workers.
2. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.

3.3
3.3
2.2
2.2

2.7
2.7
12.0
12.0
5.1
5.1
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9

2011

Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook

CPI

PCE chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook
Energy
Previous Tealbook
Food
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy, market based
Previous Tealbook

GDP chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook

Item

Greensheets
Changes in Prices and Costs
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

60.1
59.8

Employment-to-Population Ratio3
Employment-to-Population Trend3

1.2
16.8
4.1
2.7
2.7
3.7
3.7
2.8
10.9
17.2
2.0

Housing starts6
Light motor vehicle sales6

Income and saving
Nominal GDP5
Real disposable pers. income5
Previous Tealbook5
Personal saving rate3
Previous Tealbook3

Page 125 of 132

Corporate profits7
Profit share of GNP3

Gross national saving rate3
Net national saving rate3
17.7
2.6

18.1
11.2

5.3
.7
.7
3.4
3.4

1.2
17.1

-1.5
-1.5
-2.1
-2.1
74.4
74.4

1.2
1.2

60.2
59.7

142
4.3
4.3
4.7
4.7

Q3

16.8
1.6

-.2
11.1

5.3
1.2
1.1
2.7
2.6

1.3
17.7

7.7
7.8
5.2
5.5
75.2
75.2

1.4
1.4

60.1
59.7

221
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

Q4

16.9
1.8

-2.2
10.9

4.2
3.3
4.3
3.1
3.3

1.3
17.1

2.3
4.5
1.4
3.1
75.2
75.6

1.6
1.5

60.3
59.6

218
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

Q1

16.8
1.7

4.0
10.9

5.8
1.7
1.7
2.8
3.2

1.3
17.1

6.3
4.4
4.0
2.5
75.7
75.8

1.9
1.7

60.4
59.6

191
3.8
4.0
4.7
4.7

Q2

2018

16.6
1.5

.5
10.8

4.8
2.6
2.5
2.9
3.2

1.2
17.3

2.0
2.9
2.1
2.7
75.9
76.0

2.2
2.1

60.4
59.5

195
3.7
3.8
4.7
4.7

Q3

16.6
1.5

2.0
10.7

4.7
3.1
2.0
3.1
3.1

1.3
17.2

4.0
2.9
3.1
2.1
76.2
76.2

2.5
2.4

60.5
59.5

179
3.6
3.6
4.7
4.7

Q4

16.5
1.2

3.6
10.7

4.7
4.3
4.9
3.5
3.6

1.3
17.2

3.4
2.0
2.4
1.9
76.4
76.3

2.7
2.6

60.5
59.5

172
3.5
3.4
4.7
4.7

Q1

16.5
1.2

7.3
10.8

4.9
2.2
2.1
3.4
3.5

1.3
17.1

2.3
1.5
2.1
2.1
76.6
76.5

2.8
2.8

60.6
59.4

161
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

Q2

2019

16.4
1.1

4.2
10.8

4.3
1.8
1.8
3.2
3.3

1.3
17.0

1.2
.9
1.9
1.7
76.7
76.7

3.0
3.0

60.6
59.4

155
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

Q3

16.3
.9

2.8
10.8

4.1
2.2
1.9
3.2
3.1

1.3
16.9

1.0
1.0
1.4
1.2
76.8
76.7

3.0
3.1

60.6
59.4

145
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

Q4

Greensheets

16.8
1.6

2.7
11.1

4.5
1.9
1.8
2.7
2.6

1.2
17.1

3.0
3.0
1.8
1.9
75.2
75.2

1.4
1.4

60.1
59.7

182
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

20171

16.6
1.5

1.0
10.7

4.9
2.7
2.6
3.1
3.1

1.3
17.2

3.7
3.7
2.6
2.6
76.2
76.2

2.5
2.4

60.5
59.5

196
3.6
3.6
4.7
4.7

20181

16.3
.9

4.5
10.8

4.5
2.6
2.7
3.2
3.1

1.3
17.0

2.0
1.4
1.9
1.7
76.8
76.7

3.0
3.1

60.6
59.4

158
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

20191

15.8
.2

1.9
10.6

3.9
2.4
2.2
3.3
3.0

1.3
16.7

1.1
1.3
1.0
1.3
76.9
77.1

2.9
3.2

60.5
59.2

129
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise indicated.
2. Average monthly change, thousands.
3. Percent; annual values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
4. Percent difference between actual and potential output; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating below potential.
Annual values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
5. Percent change, annual rate.
6. Level, millions; annual values are annual averages.
7. Percent change, annual rate, with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.

5.0
5.0
2.4
2.4
74.9
74.9

Industrial production5
Previous Tealbook5
Manufacturing industr. prod.5
Previous Tealbook5
Capacity utilization rate - mfg.3
Previous Tealbook3

.8
.8

190
4.3
4.3
4.8
4.8

Employment and production
Nonfarm payroll employment2
Unemployment rate3
Previous Tealbook3
Natural rate of unemployment3
Previous Tealbook3

Output gap4
Previous Tealbook4

Q2

Item

2017

Other Macroeconomic Indicators

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

58.5
60.7
-4.7
-4.7
3.2
3.2
2.8
2.8
74.5
74.5
.6
12.7
3.6
1.7
1.7
5.8
5.8
6.8
12.3
16.1
.8

Employment-to-Population Ratio2
Employment-to-Population Trend2

Output gap3
Previous Tealbook3

Industrial production4
Previous Tealbook4
Manufacturing industr. prod.4
Previous Tealbook4
Capacity utilization rate - mfg.2
Previous Tealbook2

Housing starts5
Light motor vehicle sales5

Income and saving
Nominal GDP4
Real disposable pers. income4
Previous Tealbook4
Personal saving rate2
Previous Tealbook2

Page 126 of 132

Corporate profits6
Profit share of GNP2

Gross national saving rate2
Net national saving rate2
18.0
2.9

.6
12.0

3.2
5.1
5.1
9.2
9.2

.8
14.4

2.2
2.2
1.4
1.4
74.7
74.7

-3.9
-3.9

58.7
60.3

179
7.8
7.8
5.6
5.6

2012

18.2
3.1

4.7
12.0

4.3
-2.8
-2.8
4.7
4.7

.9
15.5

2.3
2.3
1.1
1.1
75.1
75.1

-3.0
-3.0

58.5
60.2

192
7.0
7.0
5.4
5.4

2013

19.5
4.7

7.4
12.4

4.3
4.9
4.9
5.9
5.9

1.0
16.5

3.4
3.4
1.4
1.4
76.3
76.3

-.9
-.9

59.3
60.1

250
5.7
5.7
5.1
5.1

2014

19.0
4.1

-11.1
10.7

3.1
3.2
3.2
6.1
6.1

1.1
17.4

-3.3
-3.3
-1.6
-1.6
75.4
75.4

-.1
-.1

59.4
59.9

226
5.0
5.0
4.9
4.9

2015

17.2
2.1

8.7
11.3

3.4
.2
.2
3.6
3.6

1.2
17.5

-.5
-.5
-.1
-.1
74.4
74.4

.3
.3

59.8
59.8

195
4.7
4.7
4.8
4.8

2016

16.8
1.6

2.7
11.1

4.5
1.9
1.8
2.7
2.6

1.2
17.1

3.0
3.0
1.8
1.9
75.2
75.2

1.4
1.4

60.1
59.7

182
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

2017

16.6
1.5

1.0
10.7

4.9
2.7
2.6
3.1
3.1

1.3
17.2

3.7
3.7
2.6
2.6
76.2
76.2

2.5
2.4

60.5
59.5

196
3.6
3.6
4.7
4.7

2018

16.3
.9

4.5
10.8

4.5
2.6
2.7
3.2
3.1

1.3
17.0

2.0
1.4
1.9
1.7
76.8
76.7

3.0
3.1

60.6
59.4

158
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

2019

15.8
.2

1.9
10.6

3.9
2.4
2.2
3.3
3.0

1.3
16.7

1.1
1.3
1.0
1.3
76.9
77.1

2.9
3.2

60.5
59.2

129
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

2020

Authorized for Public Release

1. Average monthly change, thousands.
2. Percent; values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
3. Percent difference between actual and potential output; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating below potential.
Values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
4. Percent change.
5. Level, millions; values are annual averages.
6. Percent change, with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.

174
8.7
8.7
5.9
5.9

2011

Employment and production
Nonfarm payroll employment1
Unemployment rate2
Previous Tealbook2
Natural rate of unemployment2
Previous Tealbook2

Item

Greensheets
Other Macroeconomic Indicators
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

Page 127 of 132

.4
.4
.4
.1
.2
.1
-.3
.4

Fiscal indicators2
Fiscal effect (FE)4
Discretionary policy actions (FI)
Previous Tealbook
Federal purchases
State and local purchases
Taxes and transfers
Cyclical
Other
.5
.1
.1
.0
.1
.1
-.1
.4

3
14

2020

3,594
4,774
-1,180
-5.4
-5.3
-3.0
2.4
-6.9
81.9

2.1
1.5
4.5
1.0
2.6
.9
-.6

1.8
1.3
3.7
1.0
2.4
.7
-.6

Real percent change, annual rate

-4.9
-4.9
-2.9
1.9
-6.2
79.2

Percent of GDP

3,437
4,462
-1,024

Billions of dollars

2019

3.0
1.3
10.6
20.6
1.2
-.1
-1.2

-4.6
-4.6
-2.9
1.7
-5.3
75.0

770
994
-225

Q4

-0
3

2
9

1
9

-3
1

Average net change in monthly payrolls, thousands

1.4
.9
3.3
.8
2.7
.5
-.4

-3.8
-3.9
-2.1
1.6
-4.6
77.8

3,337
4,092
-755

2018

-1
-1

1.1
1.0
1.0
-2.2
3.3
.5
.6

-7.5
-7.5
-5.9
1.6
-8.2
77.2

727
1,102
-375

Q1

.0
.2
.2
.1
.1
.0
-.2
-.1

.3
.5
.6
.2
.1
.3
-.2
-.1

.9
.7
.8
.3
.1
.3
-.1
.4

.8
.5
.5
.2
.1
.2
.0
.3

.2
.6
.6
.2
.3
.1
-.2
-.3

-.2
.5
.1
.1
.1
.3
-.1
-.6

Percentage point contribution to change in real GDP, annual rate

-1
3

.7
.4
2.4
-1.9
1.9
.2
-1.1

-3.5
-3.5
-2.1
1.4
-3.8
76.5

3,316
3,982
-665

2017

2017

.2
.5
.6
.1
.1
.3
-.2
.0

-2
3

1.0
.4
3.2
2.2
1.7
.3
-.5

.7
.2
2.6
2.0
-.3
76.6

1,058
1,024
33

Q2

2018

.6
.6
.8
.2
.1
.3
-.3
.2

1
4

1.9
1.2
4.9
2.2
2.6
.7
-.6

-3.7
-3.8
-2.6
1.1
-4.8
76.4

782
970
-189

Q3

Greensheets

Authorized for Public Release

1. Annual values stated on a fiscal year basis. Quarterly values not seasonally adjusted.
2. Annual values refer to the change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
3. Percentage point contribution to change in real disposable personal income, annual basis.
4. The FE measure captures the total contribution of the government sector to the growth of real GDP (excluding multiplier effects). It equals the sum
of the direct contributions to real GDP growth from all changes in federal purchases and state and local purchases, plus the estimated contribution to real
household consumption and business investment that is induced by changes in transfer and tax policies. FI (fiscal impetus) is the portion of FE attributable
to discretionary fiscal policy actions (for example, a legislated change in tax revenues).

3
10

1.6
1.9
.4
.0
3.2
.7
-1.4

Government in the NIPA2
Purchases
Consumption
Investment
State and local construction
Real disposable personal income
Contribution from transfers3
Contribution from taxes3

Government employment
Federal
State and local

-3.2
-3.2
-1.9
1.3
-3.1
76.7

-2.4
-2.4
-1.2
1.2
-2.0
72.9
.4
.6
-.5
-2.3
.2
.3
.2

3,268
3,853
-585

2016

3,250
3,688
-438

2015

Unified federal budget1
Receipts
Outlays
Surplus/deficit
Percent of GDP
Surplus/deficit
Previous Tealbook
Primary surplus/deficit
Net interest
Cyclically adjusted surplus/deficit
Federal debt held by public

Item

Staff Projections of Government-Sector Accounts and Related Items
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

3.0
3.0
2.2
2.6
-.3
3.7
2.7
2.2
3.5
1.2
2.6
.0
9.2
9.3
3.2

Consumer prices 2
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

Page 128 of 132

2

2.3
2.3
1.2
1.4
.7
2.4
1.0
1.7
3.1
2.1
2.2
2.2
5.5
5.4
2.3

2.6
2.5
2.1
1.7
2.0
1.9
2.8
3.0
3.0
5.7
5.7
6.6
.3
-.2
1.1

Q3

GDP aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. exports.
Foreign CPI aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

2.0
2.0
.4
.2
.1
3.0
.3
.3
3.1
1.6
.7
2.1
6.8
6.7
2.3

3.2
3.1
3.4
4.6
2.0
1.0
2.9
2.6
3.1
5.1
2.6
7.0
1.5
1.4
2.4

Q2

3.0
3.0
2.1
3.0
1.9
3.0
1.7
2.3
3.7
3.0
.5
2.9
5.4
5.0
3.6

2.8
2.7
1.9
1.7
.6
1.6
2.7
2.5
3.6
4.5
-.8
6.5
3.0
3.6
.9

Q4

2.6
2.6
2.6
3.6
2.5
2.4
2.0
1.1
2.6
1.8
1.6
1.5
4.7
4.1
3.1

3.1
2.9
1.2
1.3
-.6
.4
1.6
1.2
5.0
6.3
4.4
7.2
3.9
4.6
1.8

2.1
2.6
1.7
3.0
-1.7
2.4
2.2
2.4
2.4
1.7
2.7
1.3
3.8
3.1
2.7

2.8
2.9
2.1
2.4
1.3
1.4
2.1
2.0
3.5
4.6
3.1
6.7
2.5
3.0
1.6

2.9
2.6
2.2
2.6
1.5
2.6
2.2
2.6
3.5
3.1
3.5
2.9
4.6
3.9
4.3

2.7
2.9
1.9
2.3
.9
1.6
1.8
1.8
3.5
4.8
3.3
6.3
2.3
2.6
2.4

2.6
2.5
1.7
2.2
.9
2.5
1.7
2.1
3.2
2.8
3.5
2.5
4.1
3.4
4.3

2.8
2.9
1.9
2.3
.8
1.6
1.5
1.7
3.7
4.9
3.4
6.3
2.6
2.8
2.5

2.5
2.4
1.6
2.2
.8
2.5
1.5
2.1
3.1
2.8
3.2
2.5
4.0
3.6
4.3

2.8
2.9
1.8
2.3
.8
1.6
1.4
1.6
3.8
4.8
3.2
6.3
2.8
2.9
3.0

2.5
2.4
1.6
2.1
.9
2.4
1.5
2.2
3.1
2.7
3.1
2.5
3.9
3.5
4.3

2.8
2.8
1.7
2.1
.8
1.6
1.4
1.5
3.8
4.7
3.2
6.2
2.9
2.9
3.0

2.4
2.4
1.6
2.0
1.0
2.3
1.5
2.3
3.0
2.7
3.1
2.5
3.7
3.3
4.3

2.9
2.9
2.0
2.1
3.1
1.7
1.5
1.5
3.8
4.7
3.1
6.2
2.9
3.0
3.0

2.8
2.8
2.5
2.0
6.5
2.3
1.5
2.4
3.0
2.7
3.1
2.5
3.7
3.3
4.3

2.5
2.5
1.3
2.1
-3.8
1.7
1.6
1.5
3.8
4.7
3.1
6.1
2.9
3.0
3.0

------------------------------------Projected-----------------------------------2018
2019
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Authorized for Public Release

1 Foreign

3.0
3.2
3.0
4.0
2.6
1.3
2.6
3.6
3.0
5.4
4.0
6.9
1.4
1.5
4.4

Q1

Real
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

GDP 1

Measure and country

2017

Foreign Real GDP and Consumer Prices: Selected Countries
(Quarterly percent changes at an annual rate)

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

Page 129 of 132

3.4
3.4
2.2
2.7
-.3
4.6
2.9
2.6
4.3
4.4
3.9
4.6
4.1
3.5
6.7

Consumer prices 2
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

2 Foreign

2.3
2.3
1.3
1.0
-.2
2.6
2.3
1.9
3.1
2.6
1.7
2.1
4.4
4.1
5.6

2.2
2.2
.3
.7
.3
1.5
-1.1
.2
4.2
5.8
2.1
8.0
3.0
3.0
2.6
2.4
2.4
1.0
1.0
1.4
2.1
.8
1.4
3.4
3.1
1.1
2.9
4.2
3.6
5.8

3.0
3.0
2.5
3.6
2.8
2.6
.8
1.6
3.5
5.4
3.5
7.6
1.7
1.2
2.6

2013

2.0
2.0
1.2
2.0
2.6
.9
.2
.4
2.7
1.8
1.0
1.5
4.9
4.2
6.5

2.9
2.8
2.0
2.5
-.3
3.3
1.5
1.9
3.7
5.0
2.8
7.1
2.7
3.4
-.1

2014

Greensheets

GDP aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. exports.
CPI aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

3.2
3.2
1.8
3.1
.2
1.3
.5
2.4
4.6
5.1
2.9
8.7
4.0
3.9
2.6

Real GDP 1
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

2012

1.4
1.4
.4
1.3
.1
.1
.2
.2
2.1
1.5
.9
1.5
3.4
2.3
10.4

2.0
2.1
1.2
.3
1.2
2.1
2.0
1.3
2.9
4.5
3.2
6.8
1.5
2.8
-5.5

2015

1.9
1.9
.9
1.4
.3
1.2
.7
1.0
2.7
2.0
1.5
2.1
4.3
3.3
7.1

2.7
2.7
1.9
2.0
1.5
2.0
1.9
1.9
3.4
4.9
2.6
6.8
2.1
3.3
-2.4

2016

2.6
2.6
1.5
1.8
.6
3.0
1.4
1.6
3.4
2.0
1.5
1.8
6.7
6.6
2.8

2.9
2.9
2.6
3.0
1.8
1.4
2.8
2.9
3.2
5.2
2.8
6.8
1.5
1.6
2.2

2017

2.5
2.6
2.0
2.8
.8
2.5
2.0
2.1
2.9
2.4
2.8
2.1
4.3
3.6
3.6

2.9
2.9
1.8
2.1
.6
1.3
1.7
1.7
3.9
5.2
3.6
6.6
2.8
3.2
2.1
2.6
2.5
1.9
2.1
2.3
2.4
1.5
2.2
3.1
2.8
3.2
2.5
3.8
3.4
4.3

2.7
2.8
1.7
2.1
.2
1.7
1.5
1.5
3.8
4.7
3.1
6.2
2.9
2.9
3.0

2.4
2.4
1.6
2.0
1.0
2.1
1.6
2.3
3.0
2.7
3.0
2.5
3.5
3.2
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
1.8
.9
1.7
1.6
1.4
3.7
4.6
3.0
5.9
3.0
3.0
2.6

-------------Projected------------2018
2019
2020

Authorized for Public Release

1 Foreign

2011

Measure and country

Foreign Real GDP and Consumer Prices: Selected Countries
(Percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
June 1, 2018

Page 130 of 132

U.S. current account balance
Previous Tealbook
Current account as percent of GDP
Previous Tealbook
Net goods & services
Investment income, net
Direct, net
Portfolio, net
Other income and transfers, net

U.S. current account balance
Previous Tealbook
Current account as percent of GDP
Previous Tealbook
Net goods & services
Investment income, net
Direct, net
Portfolio, net
Other income and transfers, net

-444.6
-444.6
-2.9
-2.9
-548.6
219.2
288.7
-69.5
-115.1

2011

-451.5
-451.5
-2.4
-2.4
-551.4
215.2
297.3
-82.1
-115.3

Q1

Q3

-426.2
-426.2
-2.6
-2.6
-536.8
216.1
285.5
-69.4
-105.5

Q4

2013

-373.0
-373.0
-2.1
-2.1
-489.5
221.3
276.7
-55.4
-104.8

2014

Q2

Q3

2016

-575.4
-564.4
-2.8
-2.8
-644.7
214.4
327.6
-113.2
-145.1

-434.6
-434.6
-2.4
-2.4
-500.4
192.7
266.5
-73.8
-126.9

-451.7
-451.7
-2.4
-2.4
-504.8
186.8
258.8
-72.0
-133.7

Billions of dollars

2015

-547.6
-548.3
-2.7
-2.7
-641.7
233.1
323.1
-90.0
-139.0

Q4

Q1

-466.2
-466.2
-2.4
-2.4
-568.4
231.4
305.1
-73.7
-129.2

-673.6
-641.8
-3.2
-3.0
-646.9
112.3
294.5
-182.2
-139.0

Q2

-714.8
-670.5
-3.3
-3.1
-657.8
88.2
294.5
-206.3
-145.1

Q3

-749.7
-696.5
-3.5
-3.2
-675.7
67.1
297.4
-230.3
-141.1

Q4

-572.0
-565.4
-2.8
-2.8
-645.8
215.5
322.4
-106.8
-141.7

-698.7
-662.0
-3.3
-3.1
-659.1
104.2
298.6
-194.4
-143.8

-842.2
-787.6
-3.8
-3.5
-714.3
15.9
302.8
-286.9
-143.8

-------------Projected------------2018
2019
2020

-656.6
-639.2
-3.1
-3.1
-655.8
149.2
308.0
-158.8
-150.0

2017

-599.6
-583.7
-2.9
-2.8
-643.4
185.0
320.7
-135.7
-141.1

Billions of dollars, s.a.a.r.

Q1

------------------------------------Projected-----------------------------------2018
2019

-565.6
-565.1
-2.8
-2.8
-653.5
229.6
318.0
-88.4
-141.7

Annual Data

-512.6
-512.6
-2.6
-2.6
-615.5
243.7
310.5
-66.8
-140.8

-349.5
-349.5
-2.1
-2.1
-461.9
215.4
283.3
-67.9
-103.1

-405.9
-405.9
-2.1
-2.1
-541.1
248.9
318.1
-69.2
-113.8

2012

-495.0
-495.0
-2.6
-2.6
-565.8
217.8
294.3
-76.5
-147.0

Q2

2017

Quarterly Data

U.S. Current Account

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release
June 1, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

Abbreviations
AFE

advanced foreign economy

BLS

Bureau of Labor Statistics

BOC

Bank of Canada

BOE

Bank of England

CDS

credit default swap

C&I

commercial and industrial

CMBS

commercial mortgage-backed securities

CME

Chicago Mercantile Exchange

CPH

compensation per hour

CPI

consumer price index

CRE

commercial real estate

DSGE

dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

ECB

European Central Bank

ECI

employment cost index

EDO model

Estimated Dynamic Optimization-based model (a medium-scale
New Keynesian DSGE model of the U.S. economy)

ELB

effective lower bound

EME

emerging market economy

EU

European Union

FOMC

Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee

FPLT

flexible price-level targeting

FRB/US model

A large-scale macroeconometric model of the U.S. economy

GDP

gross domestic product

GO

general obligation

IMF

International Monetary Fund

IOER

interest on excess reserves
Page 131 of 132

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

June 1, 2018

LFPR

labor force participation rate

LIBOR

London interbank offered rate

MBS

mortgage-backed securities

MCE

model-consistent expectations

Michigan survey

University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers

NAFTA

North American Free Trade Agreement

NBER

National Bureau of Economic Research

NIT

nominal income targeting

OIS

overnight index swap

ON RRP

overnight reverse repurchase agreement

OPEC

Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries

PCE

personal consumption expenditures

PMI

purchasing managers index

repo

repurchase agreement

SEP

Summary of Economic Projections

sFRB

small FRB/US

SIGMA

A calibrated multicountry DSGE model

SLOOS

Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices

SOFR

Secured Overnight Financing Rate

SOMA

System Open Market Account

S&P

Standard & Poor’s

SPF

Survey of Professional Forecasters

TFP

total factor productivity

TIPS

Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities

VIX

one-month-ahead option-implied volatility on the S&P 500 index

Page 132 of 132