View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Prefatory Note
The attached document represents the most complete and accurate version available
based on original files from the FOMC Secretariat at the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Please note that some material may have been redacted from this document if that
material was received on a confidential basis. Redacted material is indicated by
occasional gaps in the text or by gray boxes around non-text content. All redacted
passages are exempt from disclosure under applicable provisions of the Freedom of
Information Act.

Content last modified 01/05/2018.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC – Restricted Controlled (FR)

Report to the FOMC
on Economic Conditions
and Monetary Policy

Book B
Monetary Policy:
Strategies and Alternatives
July 26, 2012

Prepared for the Federal Open Market Committee
by the staff of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

The top panel of the first exhibit, “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection,”
provides near-term prescriptions for the federal funds rate from five selected policy rules:
the Taylor (1993) rule, the Taylor (1999) rule, the outcome-based rule, the firstdifference rule, and the nominal income targeting rule.1 These prescriptions take as given
the staff’s baseline projections for real activity and inflation in the second half of this
year. Medium-term prescriptions derived from dynamic simulations of each rule are
discussed below. Because the revisions to the staff outlook for inflation and the output
gap are small, the near-term and medium-term prescriptions from these policy rules—as
well as the prescriptions from optimal control policy that are discussed below—are
similar to those reported in the June Tealbook.
As shown in the left-hand columns, the near-term prescriptions from all but one of
the rules keep the federal funds rate at the effective lower bound in both the third and
fourth quarters of this year. The exception is the Taylor (1993) rule, which embeds a
relatively small response to the output gap; it prescribes a funds rate target of about 150
basis points for the second half of the year. The right-hand columns display the rule
prescriptions that arise in the absence of the lower-bound constraint. The outcome-based
rule and the first-difference rule prescribe fund rates that are somewhat below zero for the
next two quarters, whereas the Taylor (1999) rule and the nominal income targeting rule
prescribe rates well below zero. The more accommodative prescriptions under these two
rules reflect their stronger contemporaneous response to the staff estimate of a sizable
negative output gap. The Tealbook baseline projections for the output gap and inflation
are shown in the bottom half of the exhibit, titled “Key Elements of the Staff Projection.”
Compared with the previous Tealbook, the staff outlook for the output gap is slightly
wider in 2012 and 2013, but little changed thereafter; the outlook for inflation is about the
same as last time. The slight widening in the near-term output gap projection has nudged
down the near-term prescriptions from the unconstrained rules a bit.
The first exhibit also reports the Tealbook-consistent estimate of short-run r*,
which is generated by the FRB/US model when conditioned on the staff’s outlook for the
economy. The short-run r* estimate corresponds to the real federal funds rate that, if
maintained, would return output to its potential in twelve quarters. With the staff’s
1

Details for each rule appear in Explanatory Note A.

Page 1 of 55

Strategies

Monetary Policy Strategies

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Strategies

Policy Rules and the Staff Projection

Near-Term Prescriptions of Selected Policy Rules
Constrained Policy

Unconstrained Policy

2012Q3

2012Q4

2012Q3

2012Q4

Taylor (1993) rule
Previous Tealbook

1.50
1.52

1.55
1.59

1.50
1.52

1.55
1.59

Taylor (1999) rule
Previous Tealbook

0.13
0.13

0.13
0.13

-0.88
-0.73

-0.84
-0.64

Outcome-based rule
Previous Tealbook

0.13
0.13

0.13
0.13

-0.02
0.04

-0.21
-0.08

First-difference rule
Previous Tealbook

0.13
0.13

0.13
0.13

-0.15
-0.07

-0.37
-0.24

Nominal income targeting rule
Previous Tealbook

0.13
0.13

0.13
0.13

-0.49
-0.41

-0.99
-0.86

Memo: Equilibrium and Actual Real Federal Funds Rate

Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r* estimate
Actual real federal funds rate

Current
Tealbook

Current Quarter Estimate
as of Previous Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

-2.79
-1.73

-2.71

-2.93
-1.79

Key Elements of the Staff Projection
GDP Gap
3
2

PCE Prices ex. Food and Energy
Percent
3

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

1

0

0

-1

-1

-2

-2

-3

-3

-4

-4

-5

-5

-6

-6

-7

-7
2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

Four-quarter percent change
3.0

2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5

2

1

-8

3.0

-8

0.0

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

0.0

Note: Estimates of r* may change at the beginning of a quarter even when the staff outlook is unchanged because the twelve-quarter horizon covered by
the calculation has rolled forward one quarter. Therefore, whenever the Tealbook is published early in the quarter, the memo includes a third column
labeled "Current Quarter Estimate as of Previous Tealbook."

Page 2 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

medium-term projection for the output gap little changed since the June Tealbook, the
actual real federal funds rate.
The second exhibit, “Policy Rule Simulations,” reports dynamic simulations using
the FRB/US model that incorporate the endogenous responses of inflation and the output
gap to the different paths of the federal funds rate prescribed by the constrained versions
of the five policy rules described above. The model is adjusted to match the staff’s
baseline outlook for the economy and then simulated using each of the respective policy
rules. Each rule is implemented from now onward, under the assumption that private
agents fully understand and anticipate the implications of each rule for future real
activity, inflation, and interest rates.2 For comparison, the exhibit also displays the
Tealbook baseline paths, which are conditioned on the prescriptions of the outcomebased rule.
The Tealbook baseline path and the simulated outcomes under the other four rules
are similar to those shown in June. In the Tealbook baseline, the federal funds rate is at
the effective lower bound until the fourth quarter of 2014, one quarter later than in the
June Tealbook, and then increases gradually to just above 4 percent by the end of the
decade. The Taylor (1999) rule leads to a path for the federal funds rate that nearly
replicates the baseline path.3 The Taylor (1999) rule and the outcome-based policy rule
therefore produce very similar economic conditions, characterized by a slow convergence
of the unemployment rate to the staff’s estimate of the effective natural rate of
unemployment by 2020.4 In addition, inflation, after declining initially to below 1.5

2

The staff’s baseline forecast incorporates the effects of the large-scale asset purchase programs
that the FOMC undertook in past years, as well as the effects of the ongoing maturity extension program
and the modifications to the Federal Reserve’s reinvestment policies that were announced last September.
Via this procedure, the policy rule simulations incorporate the effects of these balance sheet policies; the
rules themselves are not directly adjusted for the effects of balance sheet policies.
3
The outcome-based rule and the Taylor (1999) rule have similar longer-run properties, especially
with respect to the response to the level of the output gap; however, their short-run responses are typically
more distinct. Currently, two offsetting forces lead to the similar funds rate prescriptions: On the one
hand, the outcome-based rule includes a term for the change in the output gap which, because of the
projected pickup in output growth in 2014 and beyond, tends to prescribe faster increases in the funds rate
relative to the Taylor (1999) rule. On the other hand, the outcome-based rule includes lags of the federal
funds rate whose presence tends to slow the pace of increase in the funds rate. Currently, these two forces
are almost precisely offsetting each other, leading, on net, to similar funds rate prescriptions.
4
The staff’s estimate of the effective natural rate of unemployment declines from 6.2 percent in
the third quarter of 2012 to 5.25 percent by the end of 2017.

Page 3 of 55

Strategies

current-quarter estimate of r* remains near 2.75 percent, well below the estimated

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Strategies

Policy Rule Simulations
Nominal Federal Funds Rate
7

6

Real Federal Funds Rate
Percent
7

Taylor (1993) rule
Taylor (1999) rule
Nominal income targeting rule
First-difference rule
Tealbook baseline

6

5

Percent
4

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

0

-1

-1

-2

-2

5

4

4

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

0

-1

4

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

-1

-3

Unemployment Rate
10

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

-3

PCE Inflation
Percent
10

3.0

Four-quarter average

Percent
3.0

9

9

2.5

2.5

8

8

2.0

2.0

7

7

1.5

1.5

6

6

1.0

1.0

5

5

0.5

0.5

4

0.0

4

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

Note: The policy rule simulations in this exhibit are based on rules that respond to core inflation. This choice
of rule specification was made in light of the tendency for current and near-term core inflation rates to outperform
headline inflation rates as predictors of the medium-term behavior of headline inflation.
Page 4 of 55

0.0

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

percent—due in part to the transitory effects of energy price movements—gradually

Under the nominal income targeting rule, the initial tightening of the funds rate
occurs at the beginning of 2015, and policy remains more accommodative than under the
other rules for several years thereafter. This more accommodative policy is reflected in a
more rapid decline in unemployment with inflation hovering near 2 percent from mid2013 onward.
As both the Taylor (1993) rule and the first-difference rule lead to increases in the
federal funds rate that occur earlier than those under the other rules, these two rules are
associated with a higher path for the unemployment rate and lower inflation through the
end of the decade. As noted above, because the Taylor (1993) rule does not respond
strongly to the level of the output gap, this rule implies an immediate departure of the
funds rate from its effective lower bound; the prescribed 135 basis point increase in the
funds rate causes real activity and inflation to slow relative to the baseline, prompting a
partial reversal of the initial rate hike. While the first-difference rule does not prescribe
an increase in the funds rate until the second quarter of 2014, it implies policy rates for
the following years that run a bit higher than under the other rules. Reflecting the
forward-looking price- and wage-setting behavior assumed in these simulations, the
Taylor (1993) and the first-difference rule thus generate fairly similar outcomes for
inflation, despite the differences in their funds rate prescriptions.
As shown in the third exhibit, “Constrained vs. Unconstrained Optimal Control
Policy,” the largely unchanged outlook for real activity and inflation imply that funds rate
prescriptions from optimal control simulations of the FRB/US model are very similar to
those reported in June.6 In these simulations, policymakers are assumed to place equal
5

If the Taylor (1999) rule were modified to incorporate a response to the lagged federal funds rate,
the prescribed funds rate would rise more slowly, implying a more accommodative policy stance than
either the outcome-based policy rule or the Taylor (1999) rule without lagged adjustment. The outcomes
under this “inertial Taylor rule” are similar to the nominal income targeting rule except that the
unemployment path is slightly higher and there is a bit more overshooting of inflation in the second half of
the decade. The “inertial Taylor rule” is discussed more extensively in the memo by Christopher Erceg,
Jon Faust, Michael Kiley, Jean-Philippe Laforte, David López-Salido, Steve Meyer, Edward Nelson, David
Reifschneider, and Robert Tetlow titled “An Overview of Simple Policy Rules and Their Use in
Policymaking in Normal Times and Under Current Conditions,” sent to the Committee on July 18, 2012.
6
The optimal policy simulations incorporate the assumptions about underlying economic
conditions used in the staff’s baseline forecast, including the assumptions about balance sheet policy
described above.

Page 5 of 55

Strategies

increases to the 2 percent goal.5

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Strategies

Constrained vs. Unconstrained Optimal Control Policy
Nominal Federal Funds Rate
8
7
6

Real Federal Funds Rate
Percent
8

Current Tealbook: Constrained
Previous Tealbook: Constrained
Current Tealbook: Unconstrained
Tealbook baseline

7

4

Percent
4

3

3

2

2

1

1

6

5

5

4

4

3

3

0

0

2

2

-1

-1

1

1
-2

-2

-3

-3

-4

-4

0

0

-1

-1

-2

-2

-3

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

-3

-5

Unemployment Rate
10

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

-5

PCE Inflation
Percent
10

Four-quarter average
3.0

Percent
3.0

9

9

2.5

2.5

8

8

2.0

2.0

7

7

1.5

1.5

6

6

1.0

1.0

5

5

0.5

0.5

4

0.0

4

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

Page 6 of 55

2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020

0.0

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

weights on keeping headline PCE inflation close to the Committee’s 2 percent goal, on
unemployment, and on minimizing changes in the federal funds rate. The simulations
indicate that, with the federal funds rate constrained to remain positive, the optimal path
for the federal funds rate does not rise above the effective lower bound until the second
quarter of 2016, unchanged from the path reported in the June Tealbook.7
The constrained optimal control policy keeps the funds rate lower for longer than
any of the other policy rules discussed above, and this policy would promote a faster pace
of economic recovery than in the staff’s baseline outlook, in addition to keeping inflation
close to the Committee’s goal of 2 percent. In this simulation, the gap between the
unemployment rate and the staff’s estimate of the effective natural rate of unemployment
is closed by mid-2016, and the unemployment rate subsequently runs slightly below its
natural rate for a few years. Inflation initially exhibits a marginally smaller decline than
in the Tealbook baseline before increasing to the 2 percent objective by mid-2013 and
then overshooting slightly, peaking at 2.3 percent in 2018 and gradually returning to the
2 percent objective thereafter. The more rapid convergence to the Committee’s assumed
objectives (and the subsequent temporary overshooting) occur because policymakers
respond to the lower bound constraint by promising to keep interest rates low for an
extended period of time. As this policy is assumed to be completely credible, it boosts
inflation expectations and reduces real interest rates during the first years of the
simulation.
If the nominal federal funds rate could fall below zero, the funds rate, under the
optimal unconstrained policy, would decrease to 2.6 percent in the fourth quarter of
2013 and return to positive territory by the end of 2015. Under these conditions, the
unemployment rate would decline more rapidly than under the optimal constrained policy
and close the gap with the estimated natural rate of unemployment by early 2015.
Inflation would rise back to 2 percent by mid-2013, a pattern much like that in the
constrained simulation. In subsequent years, inflation would slightly overshoot the
2 percent objective—but less persistently than in the constrained case—moving up to

7

Although the loss function uses headline inflation instead of core inflation, the real federal funds
rate shown in the upper right panel of the exhibit is calculated as the difference between the nominal funds
rate and a four-quarter moving average of core PCE inflation. Core PCE inflation is used to compute the
real rate for this illustrative purpose because it provides a less volatile measure of inflation expectations
than does a four-quarter moving average of headline inflation.

Page 7 of 55

Strategies

keeping the unemployment rate close to the staff’s estimate of the effective natural rate of

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

2.25 percent by mid-decade before returning to the 2 percent mark by the beginning of
Strategies

2020.
The optimal control simulations discussed above assume that policymakers can
credibly commit to future policy actions, which constrains the choices of future
policymakers. If instead, policymakers lack the ability to commit (that is, they must set
policy under discretion), their ability to manage private sector expectations of inflation
and other variables would be greatly limited because they cannot bind future
policymakers to carry out their plan. Under such circumstances, monetary policy would
be less stimulative than under commitment, and the federal funds rate would depart from
the effective lower bound in the third quarter of 2015 (not shown), three quarters earlier
than in the commitment case depicted in the exhibit. Accordingly, the unemployment
rate would decline more slowly, and inflation would rise more gradually back to the 2
percent goal.
The fourth exhibit, “Outcomes under Alternative Policies,” tabulates the
simulation results for key variables under the selected policy rules described above.

Page 8 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Outcomes under Alternative Policies
2012

Measure and scenario
H1

2013 2014 2015 2016

H2

Real GDP
Extended Tealbook baseline
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Constrained optimal control

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4

1.6
1.3
1.6
1.5
1.9
2.0

2.1
1.5
2.1
1.7
2.7
3.0

3.2
2.9
3.2
2.9
3.7
4.0

3.6
3.7
3.6
3.5
3.9
4.2

3.5
3.7
3.4
3.5
3.5
3.6

Unemployment rate1
Extended Tealbook baseline
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Constrained optimal control

8.2
8.2
8.2
8.2
8.2
8.2

8.3
8.3
8.3
8.3
8.3
8.3

8.1
8.4
8.1
8.3
7.9
7.7

7.8
8.3
7.8
8.2
7.3
7.0

7.2
7.7
7.2
7.6
6.5
6.1

6.5
6.9
6.5
7.0
5.8
5.3

Total PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Constrained optimal control

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.6

1.1
1.0
1.2
0.9
1.5
1.6

1.5
1.3
1.5
1.2
1.9
2.1

1.4
1.2
1.4
1.0
1.8
2.0

1.6
1.3
1.6
1.2
2.0
2.1

1.7
1.5
1.7
1.3
2.1
2.2

Core PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Constrained optimal control

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

1.5
1.4
1.6
1.3
1.9
2.1

1.6
1.4
1.6
1.3
2.0
2.2

1.6
1.4
1.6
1.3
2.1
2.2

1.7
1.4
1.7
1.3
2.1
2.2

1.7
1.5
1.8
1.4
2.2
2.3

Federal funds rate1
Extended Tealbook baseline
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Constrained optimal control

0.2
0.2
0.2
0.2
0.2
0.2

0.1
1.4
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1

0.1
0.8
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1

0.4
1.2
0.2
0.8
0.1
0.1

1.5
1.9
1.5
1.8
0.8
0.1

2.6
2.7
2.6
2.9
2.0
0.9

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 9 of 55

Strategies

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Authorized for Public Release

Strategies

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 10 of 55

July 26, 2012

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Monetary Policy Alternatives
This Tealbook presents three policy alternatives—labeled A, B, and C—for the
Committee’s consideration. As always, the Committee could blend elements of the draft
statements to construct its desired statement.
The alternatives differ in their characterization of the incoming data. The draft
statements for Alternatives A and B begin by noting that “economic activity decelerated
somewhat over the first half of this year.” In contrast, Alternative C offers the more
upbeat depiction that “the economy has been expanding moderately this year.”
and note that the unemployment rate remains elevated. Alternative C does not describe
unemployment as elevated; instead, it points to further gains in employment.
Alternatives A and B note, as in the previous statement, that business fixed investment
has “continued to advance” but that household spending “appears to be rising at a
somewhat slower pace than earlier in the year.” Alternative C simply states that private
domestic demand has continued to advance. Alternatives A and B remark, as in the
previous statement, that the housing sector remains depressed, while Alternative C drops
this reference. With respect to prices, Alternatives B and C mention the recent decline in
inflation and attribute it mainly to lower prices of crude oil and gasoline. Alternative A
says that inflation has been “subdued” in recent months. Each statement notes that
longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable.
All three alternatives contain the same characterization of the medium-term
outlook for real activity as the June statement, indicating that the Committee expects
economic growth to be “moderate over coming quarters and then to pick up very
gradually.” The draft statements continue to highlight the downside risks to the outlook
from strains in global financial markets; they also offer the option of pointing to
downside risks stemming from issues relating to U.S. fiscal policy. Some participants
may see the fiscal risks as likely to increase as the “fiscal cliff” at the end of the year
approaches, and so want to note them directly in the statement for this meeting.
However, others may want to avoid involving the Committee in fiscal debates at this time
and also may be concerned that the fiscal issues will not be clearly resolved for some
time, making the reference in the statement difficult to remove at a future meeting. With
respect to the outlook for inflation, Alternatives A and B retain the language indicating

Page 11 of 55

Alternatives

Alternatives A and B observe that employment growth has been slow in recent months

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

that the Committee expects that inflation over the medium term will “run at or below the
rate that it judges most consistent with its dual mandate,” while Alternative C includes a
projection that inflation over the medium term will run at “about” the mandate-consistent
level.
The alternatives provide different options regarding balance sheet policies.
Alternative A offers the Committee a choice between two new large-scale asset purchase
programs. The first reflects an incremental, open-ended approach, calling for the
purchase of $45 billion of longer-term Treasury securities per month and $30 billion of
agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS) per month and continuing at least until the
Committee observes sustained improvement in labor market conditions, provided that
Alternatives

projected medium-term inflation is close to target and longer-term inflation expectations
remain stable. The second is discrete in nature, with purchases of $600 billion of longerterm Treasury securities and $400 billion of agency MBS by the end of the third quarter
of 2013 at a combined pace of about $75 billion per month.1 Under either version of
Alternative A, the Committee would end the maturity extension program (MEP) and
reinstate the policy of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at auction. In contrast,
Alternative B and Alternative C would simply continue the MEP through year-end, as
announced in June, and maintain the Committee’s existing policies of reinvesting
principal payments on agency debt and agency MBS and redeeming maturing Treasury
securities.
Under all three alternatives, the Committee would maintain the 0 to ¼ percent
target range for the federal funds rate. The B version of the statement offers the option of
extending the anticipated period of exceptionally low federal funds rates to mid-2015.
Alternative A extends the expected date of policy liftoff to at least mid-2015; it also alters
the forward guidance by replacing the specific reference to “low rates of resource
utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation”—which some may find too negative in
tone—with more positive language: “To support sustained improvement in labor market
conditions and to help ensure that inflation is close to its mandate-consistent level over
the medium run, the Committee expects to maintain a highly accommodative stance for

1

See the memo “Market Functioning and Limits on Asset Purchases” by staff in the Division of
Monetary Affairs at the Board of Governors and in the Markets Group at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York for an assessment of the amount of additional Treasury securities and agency MBS that the Federal
Reserve could purchase over the next two years without causing a meaningful deterioration in market
functioning.

Page 12 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

monetary policy as the economic recovery strengthens.” Under Alternative C the
Committee could alter the forward guidance either by making the anticipated date of the
first increase in the funds rate a year earlier, or by replacing the current forward
guidance—including the date—with new language that describes the factors the
Committee will consider in deciding when to raise its target for the funds rate.
Finally, Alternative A notes the possibility of a reduction in the remuneration rate
on excess reserves from 25 basis points to 15 basis points in order to provide a modest
amount of additional policy stimulus.
The following table highlights key elements of the differences in the policy
draft statements and then by a summary of the arguments for each alternative.

Page 13 of 55

Alternatives

actions associated with the alternative statements. The table is followed by complete

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Table 1: Overview of Policy Alternatives for the August 1 FOMC Statement
Selected
Elements

August Alternatives

June
Statement

A

B

C

Balance Sheet

Alternatives

MEP

continue to purchase at
current pace Treasury
securities with remaining
maturities of 6 to 30 years
and sell or redeem equal
amount with remaining
maturities of approx. 3
years or less through the
end of 2012

Additional
Purchases

none

end the program

continue the program through the end of the year
as announced in June

$45 billion of Treasury
securities per month and $30
billion of agency MBS per
month, until Committee
observes sustained
improvement in labor market
conditions, as long as
projected medium-term
inflation is close to its
mandate-consistent level and none
longer-term inflation
expectations remain stable

none

OR
$600 billion of longer-term
Treasury securities and $400
billion of agency MBS by
end of third quarter of 2013
Reinvestment
Policies

principal payments of
agency debt and MBS into
agency MBS; suspend
Treasury rollovers

reinstitute the policy of
rolling over maturing
unchanged
Treasury securities at auction

Page 14 of 55

unchanged

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Table 1: Overview of Policy Alternatives for the August 1 FOMC Statement
(continued)

Selected
Elements

August Alternatives

June
Statement

A

B

C

Forward Rate Guidance
at least through late 2013

Guidance

Rationale

at least through
late 2014

economic conditions—
including low rates of
resource utilization and a
subdued outlook for
inflation over the medium
run—are likely to warrant

at least through
mid-2015

unchanged

unchanged

OR

OR

at least through
mid-2015

consider range of factors,
including actual and
projected labor market
conditions, medium-term
outlook for inflation, &
risks to achievement
of Committee objectives

to support sustained
improvement in labor market
conditions and to help ensure
that inflation is close to its
unchanged
mandate-consistent level over
the medium run, … as the
economic recovery
strengthens

unchanged
OR
unchanged
OR
none

Future Policy Action

none

regularly review the pace and
composition of its securities
purchases in light of the
economic outlook and its
ongoing assessments of the
efficacy and costs of the
closely monitor
program
incoming information
on economic and
OR
financial developments

regularly review size and
composition of securities
holdings;

regularly review the size and
composition of its balance
sheet in light of the outlook
for inflation and labor market
conditions

Future Actions

prepared to take further
action as appropriate

prepared to make
adjustments as appropriate

will provide additional
accommodation as
needed

prepared to adjust
holdings as necessary

to promote a stronger
economic recovery &
sustained improvement in
labor market conditions in
a context of price stability

unchanged

unchanged

to promote maximum
employment and price
stability

Page 15 of 55

Alternatives

OR

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

JUNE FOMC STATEMENT

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in April suggests
that the economy has been expanding moderately this year. However, growth in
employment has slowed in recent months, and the unemployment rate remains
elevated. Business fixed investment has continued to advance. Household spending
appears to be rising at a somewhat slower pace than earlier in the year. Despite some
signs of improvement, the housing sector remains depressed. Inflation has declined,
mainly reflecting lower prices of crude oil and gasoline, and longer-term inflation
expectations have remained stable.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee expects economic growth to remain
moderate over coming quarters and then to pick up very gradually. Consequently, the
Committee anticipates that the unemployment rate will decline only slowly toward
levels that it judges to be consistent with its dual mandate. Furthermore, strains in
global financial markets continue to pose significant downside risks to the economic
outlook. The Committee anticipates that inflation over the medium term will run at
or below the rate that it judges most consistent with its dual mandate.
3. To support a stronger economic recovery and to help ensure that inflation, over time,
is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate, the Committee expects to
maintain a highly accommodative stance for monetary policy. In particular, the
Committee decided today to keep the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to ¼
percent and currently anticipates that economic conditions—including low rates of
resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over the medium run—are
likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through
late 2014.
4. The Committee also decided to continue through the end of the year its program to
extend the average maturity of its holdings of securities. Specifically, the Committee
intends to purchase Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6 years to 30
years at the current pace and to sell or redeem an equal amount of Treasury securities
with remaining maturities of approximately 3 years or less. This continuation of the
maturity extension program should put downward pressure on longer-term interest
rates and help to make broader financial conditions more accommodative. The
Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments from
its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities. The Committee is prepared to take further action as
appropriate to promote a stronger economic recovery and sustained improvement in
labor market conditions in a context of price stability.

Page 16 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

AUGUST FOMC STATEMENT—ALTERNATIVE A

2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee expects economic growth to remain
be moderate over coming quarters and then to pick up very gradually. Consequently,
the Committee anticipates that the unemployment rate will decline only slowly
toward levels that it judges to be consistent with its dual mandate. Furthermore,
strains in global financial markets [ continue to | and issues relating to U.S. fiscal
policy ] pose significant downside risks to the economic outlook. The Committee
anticipates that inflation over the medium term will run at or below the rate that it
judges most consistent with its dual mandate.
3. To support a stronger economic recovery and to help ensure that inflation, over time,
is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate, the Committee also decided to
continue through the end of the year its program to extend the average maturity of its
holdings of securities begin a new large-scale asset purchase program.
Specifically, the Committee now intends to purchase Treasury securities with
remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years at the current pace and to sell or redeem
an equal amount of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of approximately 3
years or less increase its holdings of longer-term Treasury securities at a pace of
about [ $45 ] billion per month and of agency mortgage-backed securities at a
pace of about [ $30 ] billion per month. The Committee anticipates continuing to
add to its holdings at least until it observes sustained improvement in labor
market conditions, as long as projected medium-term inflation is close to its
mandate-consistent level and longer-term inflation expectations remain stable.
This continuation of the maturity extension program The increase in the
Committee’s securities holdings should put downward pressure on longer-term
interest rates, support mortgage markets, and help to make broader financial
conditions more accommodative. This new purchase program replaces the
previously announced maturity extension program; therefore, the Committee is
ending its sales of shorter-term Treasury securities and reinstituting its policy of
rolling over maturing Treasury securities at auction. The Committee is
maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments from its holdings of
agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed
securities. The Committee will regularly review the pace and composition of its
securities purchases in light of the economic outlook and its ongoing assessments
of the efficacy and costs of the program, and is prepared to take further action

Page 17 of 55

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in April June
suggests that the economy has been expanding moderately economic activity
decelerated somewhat over the first half of this year. However, Growth in
employment has slowed been slow in recent months, and the unemployment rate
remains elevated. Business fixed investment has continued to advance. Household
spending appears to be rising at a somewhat slower pace than earlier in the year.
Despite some signs of improvement, the housing sector remains depressed. Inflation
has declined been subdued in recent months, mainly reflecting lower prices of
crude oil and gasoline, and longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

make adjustments as appropriate to promote a stronger economic recovery and
sustained improvement in labor market conditions in a context of price stability.

Alternatives

OR
3'. To support a stronger economic recovery and to help ensure that inflation, over time,
is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate, the Committee also decided to
continue through the end of the year its program to extend the average maturity of its
holdings of securities begin a new large-scale asset purchase program.
Specifically, the Committee now intends to purchase Treasury securities with
remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years at the current pace and to sell or redeem
an equal amount of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of approximately 3
years or less [ $600 billion ] of longer-term Treasury securities and [ $400 billion ]
of agency mortgage-backed securities by the end of the third quarter of 2013, a
combined pace of about [ $75 ] billion a month. This continuation of the maturity
extension program This action should put downward pressure on longer-term
interest rates, support mortgage markets, and help to make broader financial
conditions more accommodative. This new purchase program replaces the
previously announced maturity extension program; therefore, the Committee is
ending its sales of shorter-term Treasury securities and reinstituting its policy of
rolling over maturing Treasury securities at auction. The Committee is
maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments from its holdings of
agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed
securities. The Committee will regularly review the size and composition of its
balance sheet in light of the outlook for inflation and labor market conditions
and is prepared to take further action make adjustments as appropriate to promote a
stronger economic recovery and sustained improvement in labor market conditions in
a context of price stability.
4. The Committee also decided today to keep the target range for the federal funds rate
at 0 to ¼ percent and. To support sustained improvement in labor market
conditions and to help ensure that inflation is close to its mandate-consistent
level over the medium run, the Committee expects to maintain a highly
accommodative stance for monetary policy as the economic recovery strengthens.
In particular, the Committee currently anticipates that economic conditions—
including low rates of resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over
the medium run—are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds
rate are likely to be warranted at least through late 2014 mid-2015.

Note: If policymakers decide that it is appropriate to reduce the remuneration rate on
reserve balances, the Board of Governors would issue an accompanying statement that
might read:
In a related action, the Board of Governors voted today to reduce the interest rate paid
on required and excess reserve balances from 25 basis points to 15 basis points
effective with the reserve maintenance period that begins on August 9, 2012.

Page 18 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

AUGUST FOMC STATEMENT—ALTERNATIVE B

2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee expects economic growth to remain
be moderate over coming quarters and then to pick up very gradually. Consequently,
the Committee anticipates that the unemployment rate will decline only slowly
toward levels that it judges to be consistent with its dual mandate. Furthermore,
strains in global financial markets [ continue to | and issues relating to U.S. fiscal
policy ] pose significant downside risks to the economic outlook. The Committee
anticipates that inflation over the medium term will run at or below the rate that it
judges most consistent with its dual mandate.
3. To support a stronger economic recovery and to help ensure that inflation, over time,
is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate, the Committee expects to
maintain a highly accommodative stance for monetary policy. In particular, the
Committee decided today to keep the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to ¼
percent and currently anticipates that economic conditions—including low rates of
resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over the medium run—are
likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through
[ late 2014 | mid-2015 ].
4. The Committee also decided to continue through the end of the year its program to
extend the average maturity of its holdings of securities as announced in June,
Specifically, the Committee intends to purchase Treasury securities with remaining
maturities of 6 years to 30 years at the current pace and to sell or redeem an equal
amount of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of approximately 3 years or
less. This continuation of the maturity extension program should put downward
pressure on longer-term interest rates and help to make broader financial conditions
more accommodative. The Committee and it is maintaining its existing policy of
reinvesting principal payments from its holdings of agency debt and agency
mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed securities. The Committee is
prepared to take further action as appropriate will closely monitor incoming
information on economic and financial developments and will provide additional
accommodation as needed to promote a stronger economic recovery and sustained
improvement in labor market conditions in a context of price stability.

Page 19 of 55

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in April June
suggests that the economy has been expanding moderately economic activity
decelerated somewhat over the first half of this year. However, Growth in
employment has slowed been slow in recent months, and the unemployment rate
remains elevated. Business fixed investment has continued to advance. Household
spending appears to be rising at a somewhat slower pace than earlier in the year.
Despite some further signs of improvement, the housing sector remains depressed.
Inflation has declined since earlier this year, mainly reflecting lower prices of crude
oil and gasoline, and longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

AUGUST FOMC STATEMENT—ALTERNATIVE C

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in April June
suggests that the economy has been expanding moderately this year. However,
growth in employment has slowed in recent months, and the unemployment rate
remains elevated. Employment has shown further gains. Business fixed
investment Private domestic demand has continued to advance, Household spending
appears to be rising at a somewhat slower pace than earlier in the year. Despite and
the housing sector remains depressed has shown some signs of improvement.
Inflation has declined since earlier this year, mainly reflecting lower prices of crude
oil and gasoline, and longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. The Committee expects economic growth to remain
moderate over coming quarters and then to pick up very gradually. Consequently, the
Committee anticipates that the unemployment rate will decline only slowly toward
levels that it judges to be consistent with its dual mandate. Furthermore, strains in
global financial markets [ continue to | and issues relating to U.S. fiscal policy ]
pose significant downside risks to the economic outlook. The Committee anticipates
that inflation over the medium term will run at or below about the rate that it judges
most consistent with its dual mandate.
3. To support a stronger the economic recovery and to help ensure that inflation, over
time, is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate, the Committee expects to
maintain a highly accommodative stance for monetary policy. In particular, the
Committee decided today to keep the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to ¼
percent and currently anticipates that economic conditions—including low rates of
resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over the medium run—are
likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through
late [ 2013 | 2014 ].
OR
3'. To support a stronger sustainable economic recovery and to help ensure that
inflation, over time, is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate, the
Committee expects to maintain a highly accommodative stance for monetary policy.
In particular, the Committee decided today to keep the target range for the federal
funds rate at 0 to ¼ percent and currently anticipates that economic conditions—
including low rates of resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over
the medium run—are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds
rate at least through late 2014. As rates of resource utilization rise toward levels
consistent with maximum employment, the Committee eventually will need to
make monetary policy less accommodative in order to ensure that the economy
expands at a sustainable pace and to prevent inflation from persistently
exceeding its longer-run objective. In determining the appropriate time to
increase its target for the federal funds rate, the Committee will consider a range
of factors, including actual and projected labor market conditions, the mediumterm outlook for inflation, and the risks to the achievement of the Committee’s
objectives.

Page 20 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Alternatives

4. The Committee also decided to continue through the end of the year its program to
extend the average maturity of its holdings of securities as announced in June
Specifically, the Committee intends to purchase Treasury securities with remaining
maturities of 6 years to 30 years at the current pace and to sell or redeem an equal
amount of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of approximately 3 years or
less. This continuation of the maturity extension program should put downward
pressure on longer-term interest rates and help to make broader financial conditions
more accommodative. The Committee is maintaining and to maintain its existing
policy of reinvesting principal payments from its holdings of agency debt and agency
mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed securities. The Committee
will regularly review the size and composition of its securities holdings and is
prepared to take further action as appropriate adjust those holdings as necessary to
promote maximum employment and a stronger economic recovery and sustained
improvement in labor market conditions in a context of price stability.

Page 21 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE B
The Committee might interpret the available information as indicating that,
despite some weakness in recent economic data, neither the modal economic outlook nor
the risks to the outlook have worsened materially since it last met, and conclude that it is
appropriate to make no significant change in the stance of monetary policy at this
meeting. However, members may feel that further policy accommodation would be
called for if the current situation, including little if any progress in reducing elevated
levels of unemployment and underlying inflation that is running below levels consistent
with its dual mandate, were to persist much longer. If so, members may wish to adopt a
statement that announces no new policy action and contains language similar to that of
Alternatives

the June statement, but suggests that additional policy accommodation may become
necessary fairly soon, as in Alternative B.
More specifically, FOMC participants, like the staff, may see the recent data as
suggesting that the pace of economic recovery has slowed somewhat in recent months.
Nevertheless, policymakers may continue to view this deceleration as reflecting, in part,
temporary factors and therefore anticipate that growth will strengthen going forward,
albeit very gradually, without additional policy action. Indeed, the Committee’s
assessment of the prospects for economic growth and inflation beyond the near term may
not have changed materially over the intermeeting period, and thus members may not see
the threshold for further policy action at this meeting as having been met. The
Committee may, however, still see a sizable risk that the deceleration in economic
activity could prove more pronounced or more protracted than currently expected.
Participants may also see significant downside risks from strains in global financial
markets as well as from issues relating to U.S. fiscal policy. Given these concerns, the
Committee might think it appropriate to signal that it will provide additional monetary
accommodation if economic conditions do not begin to improve soon. Consistent with
this assessment, Alternative B ends by stating that the Committee “will provide
additional accommodation as needed to promote a stronger economic recovery and
sustained improvement in labor market conditions in a context of price stability.” Such
concerns might also lead policymakers to extend the forward guidance in the statement to
“at least through mid-2015.” However, other participants may see a benefit to making a
change in the expected liftoff date in conjunction with the introduction of a new purchase
program, if such a program becomes appropriate, since the additional asset purchases

Page 22 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

would limit the possibility that the change in the liftoff date could undermine business
and consumer confidence by emphasizing the deterioration in the economic outlook.
Some members may note that the outlook has not improved despite the action
they took in June, as the effects of the continuation of the MEP have been offset by a
weakening in the likely underlying trajectory for economic activity; or they may think
that downside risks to the outlook have increased. In either case, they may be inclined
toward further balance sheet actions to foster more rapid progress toward the dual
mandate. Nevertheless, they may want to wait for additional information about the
trajectory of output and inflation to gauge the extent to which growth is likely to pick up
in response to policy actions already in place before undertaking a new policy action,
efficacy of those policy actions, as well as the potential costs and risks associated with
various policy easing measures. Indeed, some participants may have a high threshold for
additional action, either because they expect that additional asset purchases would likely
have only a very modest effect on the economic outlook or because they are concerned
that additional asset purchases could have adverse effects on inflation or negative
implications for financial stability. In light of such concerns, the Committee may want
additional time to evaluate potential policy alternatives before taking a further easing
step.
In contrast, some participants may judge that the economic recovery remains on a
sustainable path despite some temporary dampening factors and that moving toward a
somewhat less accommodative stance of policy earlier than indicated by the Committee’s
June statement will likely be appropriate to limit the risks of an undesirable increase in
inflation over the medium run. However, they may judge that, with unemployment
having leveled off and inflation having slowed from its earlier rapid pace, there is less
urgency in seeking an immediate reduction in policy accommodation. Given that the
uncertainty regarding the economic outlook is currently quite high, these participants may
also prefer to wait for further information to confirm the strength of the expansion before
making a change in the forward guidance that might have to be reversed later.
A policy decision along the lines of Alternative B would be largely in line with
the expectations of market participants. According to the Desk’s latest survey, primary
dealers do not see major changes in the statement language as the most likely outcome at
this meeting, though they anticipate some recognition of the disappointing economic

Page 23 of 55

Alternatives

especially given the higher-than-normal uncertainty about the economic outlook and the

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

data. The dealers anticipate that the first increase in the target federal funds rate will
most likely occur in early 2015, broadly consistent with the existing forward guidance.
Moreover, dealers place relatively low odds on the Committee engaging in further
balance-sheet action at this meeting, although they reportedly put material odds on
additional easing through the size of the SOMA portfolio within one year. Even though
its language points to “additional accommodation” without specifically mentioning
LSAPs, the statement of Alternative B would likely lead investors to price in higher odds
that additional LSAPs will be implemented by the Committee, perhaps as soon as at the
September meeting. As a consequence, longer-term interest rates would likely fall
somewhat, stock prices would rise, and the foreign exchange value of the dollar would

Alternatives

decline. Investors appear to see less than even odds of an extension of the expected
liftoff date in the forward guidance; as a result, if the Committee decided to adopt that
option, the effects in asset markets would likely be somewhat larger.

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE A
FOMC participants may view the information received since their last meeting as
pointing to a somewhat weaker modal economic outlook or an increase in downside risks
to the outlook, or both. Accordingly, they may feel that additional monetary policy
easing is called for at this meeting. More specifically, some participants may interpret
recent weak economic data as evidence that slow growth of consumer and business
spending is quite likely to persist and so conclude that the underlying trajectory for
economic growth is inadequate to return the unemployment rate to its mandate-consistent
level within the next few years. They may also be concerned that the continuing
overhang of foreclosed and vacant properties will restrain recovery in this sector for some
time to come. Moreover, with the inflationary effects of the earlier run-up in oil and
gasoline prices having subsided, and with inflation expectations well anchored,
participants may judge that the upside risks to inflation are small. Indeed, they may
forecast, like the staff, that the inflation rate will remain, for a few years, somewhat
below the Committee’s long-run objective of 2 percent.
These policymakers might point out that the unconstrained optimal control
simulations and four of five of the unconstrained near-term policy rule prescriptions
presented in the “Monetary Policy Strategies” section of the Tealbook continue to call for
negative federal funds rates, even with the continuation of the MEP included in the staff’s

Page 24 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

baseline scenario. As a result, the Committee might anticipate that near-zero federal
funds rates are likely to be warranted for somewhat longer than had been thought and
change the forward guidance in the statement accordingly. However, participants may
worry that providing forward guidance for the path of policy appreciably further ahead
may not be viewed as credible by markets and may thus have only a limited impact on
longer-term interest rates. Thus, they may judge that a new LSAP program is appropriate
instead of, or in addition to, an extension of the anticipated period of near-zero funds
rates, reflecting an assessment that an LSAP would not require credibility regarding
future Committee policy and would likely have larger macroeconomic effects. These
considerations may lead them to favor Alternative A.

policymakers may also judge that downside risks to that outlook, particularly from the
European crisis and issues relating to U.S. fiscal policy, have increased considerably of
late, and so prefer the policy easing contained in Alternative A. Specifically, they may
see non-trivial odds that the European crisis could ultimately impose a very substantial
drag on the U.S. recovery. In addition, some policymakers may also see a sizable
probability that the Congress will be unable to resolve contentious fiscal issues before the
turn of the year, and that fiscal policy could consequently tighten sharply at that time.
Moreover, continued uncertainty about U.S. fiscal policy and the European crisis could
restrain household spending and business investment more significantly later this year.
In addition, with a substantial fraction of unemployed workers having been jobless for
long periods, some FOMC participants might want to guard against the risk that this high
level of long-term unemployment will persist long enough to permanently depress labor
supply and potential output.
Furthermore, some participants may view the unusually large amount of
uncertainty about the outlook as a reason not to wait but instead to act aggressively—both
to reduce the likelihood that severely adverse scenarios will emerge and to provide
greater assurance to the public that policymakers are willing to act as needed to support
the recovery. This perspective could be reinforced if policymakers also saw the risks to
the economic outlook as asymmetric and weighted substantially to the downside.
Should the Committee decide to provide further monetary stimulus through
balance sheet expansion, it might increase the SOMA’s holdings of both longer-term
Treasury securities and agency MBS with the aim of putting downward pressure on

Page 25 of 55

Alternatives

In addition to judging that the baseline outlook for the economy is unsatisfactory,

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

longer-term interest rates in general while also directly supporting mortgage markets. In
particular, Alternative A provides the Committee with an option to expand the balance
sheet either through an incremental, open-ended purchase program or through a large,
discrete purchase program as in previous LSAP operations. The Committee could choose
to implement an incremental, open-ended purchase program by specifying initial monthly
rates of purchases—for example $45 billion per month of longer-term Treasury securities
and $30 billion per month of agency MBS—and by stating that it anticipates continuing
to expand the SOMA portfolio “at least until it observes sustained improvement in the
labor market,” as long as “projected medium-term inflation is close to its mandateconsistent level and longer-term inflation expectations remain stable.” Alternatively, the

Alternatives

Committee could choose to announce a fixed program to purchase an additional $600
billion of longer-term Treasury securities and $400 billion of agency MBS by the end of
the third quarter of 2013, as in paragraph 3′ of Alternative A. In either case, the new
purchase program would replace the existing MEP.
The Committee might prefer to implement a large, discrete purchase program if it
believes that investor uncertainty about the ultimate size of an open-ended program
would make it less effective than a discrete program. In contrast, members might opt for
an open-ended purchase program if they judged that such a program would boost
business and consumer confidence by emphasizing that the Committee is ready to
provide the accommodation needed to support a stronger recovery. Moreover, an openended program, if well understood by the public, would lead market participants to revise
their expectations about the total size of the purchase program in response to incoming
economic data, and so could help to buffer the economy in the face of unanticipated
shocks. Policymakers might also prefer an open-ended program if they anticipated that
greater flexibility would make it easier to calibrate the ultimate amount of purchases to
evolving economic conditions. However, if the Committee announced an open-ended
purchase program, it might want to be clear in the statement that such purchases might
not be continued indefinitely even if the economy remained weak. For example, the
Committee might choose to end the program if incoming information suggested that the
economic effects of the purchases were smaller than anticipated and that the associated
costs and risks were more substantial.
Policymakers also may see some additional benefit from reducing the interest rate
paid on required and excess reserve balances to 15 basis points; in that case, the Board
could adopt such a reduction, and that step could be noted in the press release containing

Page 26 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

the FOMC statement. Such a reduction in the rate paid on reserve balances would put
modest downward pressure on a range of money market rates, and so lower medium-term
and perhaps longer-term rates, at least to some degree. It also could mitigate concern
about the Federal Reserve appearing to subsidize banks by remunerating reserves at a rate
noticeably above that on other short-term investments. However, participants might be
concerned that a further reduction in money market rates could disrupt money markets
and so have adverse effects on the economy. The ECB’s recent decision to cut its deposit
rate to zero does not appear, thus far, to have caused severe disruptions in European
money markets, as discussed in the box “The Effects of the European Central Bank’s
Deposit Rate Cut” in Tealbook A; however, the short period of time since the
money markets suggest that it may be premature to draw conclusions about the
implications of a cut in remuneration rate on reserve balances in the United States.
Cutting the rate paid on reserve balances also would reduce depository institutions’
incentive to borrow and hold excess reserves to earn the rate paid on such reserves, likely
resulting in a further reduction in trading volume in the federal funds market and
potentially in greater volatility in the effective federal funds rate. Moreover, banks might
impose greater fees on deposit accounts, a development that could lead to a negative
response by the public. These risks would be reduced by keeping the rate paid on reserve
balances at 15 basis points rather than reducing it to zero.2
In the Desk’s survey, dealers placed only about 25 percent odds on the
Committee expanding the SOMA portfolio through additional securities purchases at this
meeting and about 65 percent odds on such an expansion sometime within the next year.
With regard to the forward guidance, only about 40 percent of dealers anticipated a
change at this meeting. Thus, a statement along the lines of Alternative A would come as
a surprise to investors and longer-term interest rates would be expected to fall. Market
participants might find an open-ended purchase program along the lines of paragraph 3
difficult to interpret because it would be a notable departure from past purchase
programs, making the size of the effect on longer-term interest rates more than usually
uncertain. Primary dealers, on average, saw about a 25 percent probability of a cut in the
remuneration rate on required and excess reserves at some point within a year, but the
probability of such a change at the August meeting was notably smaller. Thus, if the
2

Additional considerations related to possible changes in the remuneration rate on excess reserves
can be found in the memo, “Reconsidering Lowering the IOER Rate,” sent to the Committee on October
25, 2011.

Page 27 of 55

Alternatives

announcement of the decision and differences in the structures of U.S. and European

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

interest rate on excess reserves were reduced, shorter-term yields would likely decline
several basis points, in addition to the effects of any other actions the Committee
announced. The impact could be amplified by the increase in reserve balances generated
by the new purchase program and the end of sales of short-term Treasury securities under
the MEP. With any combination of the options in Alternative A, equity prices would
probably increase, and the foreign exchange value of the dollar would likely decline.

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE C

Alternatives

Smoothing through the month-to-month fluctuations in the data, FOMC
participants may see the economic recovery as continuing on a sustainable course.
Labor-market and spending data have decelerated from earlier in the year, but
participants may view this slowing as primarily attributable to temporary factors,
including possible seasonal and weather-related distortions. They may also be
encouraged by the nearly one percentage point decline in the unemployment rate since
last summer. Meanwhile, household spending and business fixed investment have
continued to advance, and some indicators of conditions in the housing sector have
continued to show improvement. Policymakers may judge that overall financial
conditions in the United States remain supportive of economic growth even though
financial strains in Europe have intensified of late. Furthermore, policymakers may
believe that monetary policy actions taken to date are sufficient to support sustained
economic recovery and may conclude that the underlying pace of growth in output will
pick up in the near-term to a rate somewhat above their assessment of the growth rate of
potential output, and so might view the projected pace of improvement in the labor
market as adequate. If so, they may prefer to maintain a policy stance similar to that at
the previous meeting and make no further changes to the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet
or the Committee’s forward guidance, or they may even wish to begin scaling back the
public’s expectations for the duration of the current low range of the federal funds rate.
These possibilities would be consistent with a statement like that in Alternative C.
Committee members whose outlook for the economy and whose assessment of
the risks has not changed significantly since the June meeting might think it imprudent to
change policy substantially at this juncture, and so may prefer to leave the forward
guidance unchanged, as offered in one option in paragraph 3. In contrast, participants
whose evolving views on the economic outlook and the appropriate path for the federal

Page 28 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

funds rate have led them to anticipate a significantly earlier first increase in the funds rate
than was indicated by the Committee’s statements so far this year, and who see the
downside risks to the outlook as manageable, might want to adjust the forward guidance
at this meeting. Alternatively, as in paragraph 3′, the FOMC could eliminate the calendar
date from its forward guidance and replace it with new language that describes in
somewhat greater detail the key economic factors that the Committee will consider in
deciding when to first increase its target for the federal funds rate. If the public
understood this new language, investors would modify their assessments of the likely
timing of the first increase in the target funds rate as these factors change over time.
A statement like those included in Alternative C, even with the option that retains
policy accommodation, resulting in higher interest rates and a decline in equity prices. A
statement that moved forward the expected date of the first increase in the funds rate—or
that included language that investors read as indicating that the date was likely to be
substantially earlier than previously thought—would greatly surprise financial market
participants. According to the Desk’s survey, the primary dealers see zero probability
that the Committee will move forward its expected date of liftoff at this meeting. Hence,
moving projected liftoff closer would likely cause a sizable adjustment in market
participants’ expectations of the policy rate path, leaving market interest rates
significantly higher at maturities beyond a year or so. If the Committee were to drop the
date from its forward guidance, investors might well be quite uncertain about the
Committee’s intentions, at least until policymakers provided additional information about
the likely path for policy. Furthermore, participants have priced in significant odds of
additional asset purchases in the near future, and the statement in Alternative C (with or
without a change in the expected liftoff date) would be read as a signal that such action
was unlikely to be forthcoming, putting further upward pressure on longer-term rates and
weighing on equity prices. Any statement along the lines of Alternative C would likely
lead to an appreciation of the dollar.

Page 29 of 55

Alternatives

the late 2014 date, would strike market participants as likely signaling a faster removal of

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

LONG-RUN PROJECTIONS OF THE BALANCE SHEET AND MONETARY BASE
The staff has prepared three scenarios for the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet that
correspond to the policy alternatives A, B, and C. The scenario corresponding to
Alternative A ends the maturity extension program (MEP) immediately, expands
holdings of longer-term securities by $1 trillion by the end of the third quarter of 2013,
and pushes the first increase of the target federal funds rate to mid-2015. The details of
this scenario mimic the language in paragraph 3' of that statement and are also roughly
consistent with the open-ended purchase program in paragraph 3 if purchases last, and are
expected to last, for a little more than a year. The scenario corresponding to Alternative
B incorporates a continuation of the MEP as announced in June and has the first increase
Alternatives

in the federal funds rate in December 2014. The third scenario corresponds to
Alternative C, in which the MEP is also completed as scheduled, but the federal funds
rate rises above the current target range in late 2013, one year earlier than in Alternative
B. Projections under each scenario are based on assumptions about the trajectory of
various components of the balance sheet. Details of these assumptions, as well as
projections for each major component of the balance sheet, can be found in Explanatory
Note D.

For the balance sheet scenario that corresponds to Alternative B, essentially all
Treasury securities with remaining maturities of approximately three years or less are

Page 30 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

either allowed to mature without reinvestment or are sold and the same amount of
Treasury securities with remaining maturities of six years to thirty years are purchased
under the MEP. The Committee’s program to reinvest principal payments from its
holdings of agency debt and MBS into agency MBS remains unchanged. These policy
choices would keep the System Open Market Account (SOMA) securities holdings
roughly constant at about $2.6 trillion until mid-2014.
In this scenario, consistent with the statement language that the federal funds rate
is expected to be at exceptionally low levels “at least through late 2014,” we assume that
the first increase in the target federal funds rate is in December 2014.3 The date of liftoff
is a key determinant of the trajectory of the balance sheet. In June 2014, six months
cease, and the balance sheet begins to contract. Because the MEP is assumed to remove
virtually all short-dated Treasury securities from the portfolio, in 2014 and in the first
half of 2015 the only contraction in the balance sheet is a result of maturing or prepaying
agency MBS and agency debt. In June 2015, six months after the initial increase in the
target federal funds rate, the Committee begins to sell its holdings of agency securities at
a pace that reduces the amount of these securities in the portfolio to zero in five years,
that is, by May 2020.4 Through these redemptions and sales, the size of the balance sheet
is normalized by April 2018.5,6 The balance sheet then begins to expand, with increases
in SOMA holdings essentially matching the growth of Federal Reserve Bank capital and
currency in circulation. The balance sheet reaches a size of $2 trillion by the end of
2020.

3

This liftoff date for the federal funds rate is two months later than that assumed in the balance
sheet projections from the June Tealbook Book B but is the same as the current staff forecast in Tealbook
Book A.
4
Consistent with the exit principles the Committee announced in the minutes of the June 2011
FOMC meeting, we assume the Committee directs the Desk to only sell agency securities during the exit
period in order to promote a timely return to an all-Treasury SOMA portfolio.
5
The tools to drain reserve balances (reverse repurchase agreements and term deposits) are not
modeled in any of the scenarios presented. Use of these tools would result in a shift in the composition of
Federal Reserve liabilities—a decline in reserve balances and a corresponding increase in reverse
repurchase agreements or term deposits—but would not produce an overall change in the size of the
balance sheet.
6
The projected timing of the normalization of the size of the balance sheet depends importantly on
the level of reserve balances that is assumed to be necessary to conduct monetary policy; currently, we
assume that level of reserve balances to be $25 billion. A higher demand for reserve balances would, all
else equal, lead to an earlier normalization of the size of the balance sheet.

Page 31 of 55

Alternatives

before the first increase in the target federal funds rate, all reinvestment is assumed to

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

In the scenario for Alternative A, the Committee is assumed to end the MEP
immediately and begin a $1 trillion LSAP program in August. The LSAP program is
assumed to include purchases of $600 billion in Treasury securities at a pace of about $45
billion per month and $400 billion in agency MBS at a pace of about $30 billion per
month. Purchases are completed by the end of the third quarter of 2013. The Committee
reinstitutes its policy to reinvest principal payments from Treasury securities at auction
and continues reinvesting principal payments from agency MBS and agency debt
securities into agency MBS. In this scenario, total assets peak at $3.9 trillion in
December 2013. In December 2014, six months prior to the assumed first increase in the
federal funds rate in June 2015, all reinvestment is assumed to cease, and the balance

Alternatives

sheet begins to contract. Six months after the lift off of the federal funds rate, sales of
agency securities begin and continue for five years. The balance sheet is normalized by
December 2018.
For the scenario that corresponds to Alternative C, the Committee completes the
current MEP as in Alternative B. In this scenario, the federal funds rate is assumed to lift
off in December 2013, one year earlier than in Alternative B. Corresponding to this
earlier increase in the federal funds rate, reinvestment of principal from maturing or
prepaying securities ends in June 2013, after which time all securities are allowed to roll
off the portfolio. Finally, sales of agency securities commence in June 2014 and last for
five years.7 Because of the earlier redemptions and sales, the size of the balance sheet is
normalized in November 2017, five months earlier than under Alternative B.
On the liability side of the balance sheet, the forecasted path for reserve balances
for Alternatives B and C remains at $1.5 trillion until the exit strategy begins, roughly the
same level as in the June Tealbook’s Alternative B. The level of reserve balances under
Alternative A peaks at $2.5 trillion—noticeably higher than in Alternative B—because of
the $1 trillion LSAP program.
In the scenario corresponding to Alternative B, the monetary base is roughly flat
from 2012 to 2013, given the trajectory for the portfolio. Once exit begins, the monetary
7

To simplify the projections, the prepayment paths for legacy agency MBS holdings and the
premiums associated with MBS reinvestment calculated under Alternative C match those for Alternative B.
This simplifying assumption likely overstates somewhat both prepayments on MBS, which are reinvested
into new MBS, and the associated premiums under Alternative C. As a result, the size of the balance sheet
is likely somewhat larger, and the date of normalization is likely a little later than would be the case if the
interest rate path was recalibrated based on this scenario.

Page 32 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

base shrinks through the second quarter of 2018, primarily reflecting a decline in reserve
balances as the balance sheet contracts. Starting in the third quarter of 2018, after reserve
balances are assumed to have stabilized at $25 billion, the monetary base begins to
expand again, in line with the growth of Federal Reserve notes in circulation. The
monetary base under Alternative A expands more rapidly in the near term than under
Alternative B due to the LSAP program and then declines at a faster pace beginning in
2015 because of a larger amount of securities redemptions and a larger volume of sales of
agency securities. The resumption in the expansion of the monetary base in Alternative
A begins in the second quarter of 2019. Under Alternative C, the monetary base

Alternatives

contracts faster than under Alternative B because of the assumed earlier liftoff.

Page 33 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Growth Rates for the Monetary Base

Alternatives

Date

Apr-12
May-12
Jun-12
Jul-12
Aug-12
Sep-12
Oct-12
Nov-12
Dec-12

Alternative B Alternative A Alternative C

-12.2
-8.7
-4.6
6.2
12.2
-4.3
-11.9
8.8
1.2

Percent, annual rate
Monthly
-12.2
-12.2
-8.7
-8.7
-4.6
-4.6
6.9
6.2
21.6
12.0
15.8
-4.4
14.5
-12.1
38.5
8.6
31.3
1.1

June Alt B

-12.2
-8.8
7.9
22.5
10.7
-3.4
-10.0
7.9
5.8

Quarterly
2011 Q3
2011 Q4
2012 Q1
2012 Q2
2012 Q3
2012 Q4
2013 Q1
2013 Q2

21.0
-5.9
5.5
-3.9
2.3
-1.5
-2.2
-2.4

2010
0.9
2011
32.9
2012
0.6
2013
0.6
2014
-1.8
2015
-4.4
2016
-16.6
2017
-18.0
2018
-7.3
Note: Not seasonally adjusted.

21.0
-5.9
5.5
-3.9
6.9
23.3
28.9
27.5

21.0
-5.9
5.5
-3.9
2.2
-1.7
-2.2
-2.4

21.0
-5.9
5.5
-2.5
10.3
-0.5
-1.0
-2.8

Annual - Q4 to Q4
0.9
0.9
32.9
32.9
8.1
0.5
28.9
-1.6
-0.2
-5.0
-6.9
-7.9
-17.7
-17.6
-19.8
-18.6
-27.4
3.7

0.9
32.9
3.2
0.2
-1.0
-6.6
-16.6
-18.1
-6.3

Page 34 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

DEBT, BANK CREDIT, AND MONEY FORECASTS
Domestic nonfinancial sector debt is projected to expand at an annual rate of 4¾
percent this year, driven by a significant expansion in federal government debt and a
modest rise in private nonfinancial debt. In the next two years, domestic nonfinancial
debt growth is expected to slow to about 4 percent, on average, as federal debt rises less
rapidly and private debt accelerates only gradually. Nonfinancial business debt is
forecasted to increase at a modest pace over the projection period, reflecting favorable
financing conditions and increasing capital expenditures. Home mortgage debt is
projected to decline again this year and edge up in the next two years, as financing
conditions are expected to remain tight, demand for owner-occupied housing is expected
consumer credit is projected to expand at an annual rate of more than 7 percent, on
average, throughout the forecast period, driven by a gradual easing of credit conditions as
well as modestly rising demand for student loans and for loans to finance purchases of
consumer durables.
Commercial bank credit is expected to increase moderately over the forecast
period. Core loans—the sum of commercial and industrial (C&I), real estate, and
consumer loans—are projected to expand modestly during the remainder of 2012 mainly
due to continued strength in C&I lending. Though C&I loans are expected to grow more
slowly after this year, core loan growth picks up somewhat in 2013 and 2014 as real
estate and consumer loan growth rises in line with the anticipated gradual improvements
in economic activity, credit quality, and banks’ willingness to lend. In contrast,
commercial real estate loans are projected to contract through mid-2013—and only rise
slightly thereafter—as high vacancy rates, depressed prices for commercial properties,
and the poor credit quality of existing loans are likely to suppress activity in this sector
for some time. Banks’ securities holdings are projected to expand at a moderate pace in
2012, with growth slowing in 2013 and 2014 as deposit growth ebbs and loan demand
strengthens.
Staff anticipates that M2 will continue to grow faster than nominal income
through the remainder of 2012 but expand more slowly than nominal income, on balance,
in 2013 and 2014. Ongoing concerns about developments in Europe and the U.S. growth
outlook will likely encourage investors to add to their already elevated allocations of M2
assets in 2012. Staff expects that a portion of the high level of M2 balances will begin to

Page 35 of 55

Alternatives

to stay weak, and house prices are forecasted to increase only slowly. Meanwhile,

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

unwind early in 2013 because of the expiration of the unlimited FDIC insurance on
noninterest-bearing transaction deposits.8 M2 balances are forecasted to continue to
unwind in 2014 as investors reallocate their portfolios toward riskier assets in line with
the projected firming in economic growth and monetary policy. Turning to the
components of M2, liquid deposits are expected to grow at a brisk pace for the remainder
of 2012 but then slow significantly in 2013 and 2014. In contrast, retail money market
funds and small time deposits are projected to decline throughout the forecast period.
Currency growth is expected to gradually decline to a pace consistent with its historical
average of 6 percent by mid-2013 and continue at that pace over the rest of the projection

Alternatives

period.

8 The

Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 provides unlimited
deposit insurance coverage for noninterest-bearing transaction accounts in excess of $250,000 from
December 31, 2010, through December 31, 2012. These deposits are estimated to have grown nearly 50
percent from December 31, 2010, and currently make up about 15 percent of M2 or about $1.5 trillion.

Page 36 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Growth Rates for M2

Monthly Growth Rates
Jan-12
Feb-12
Mar-12
Apr-12
May-12
Jun-12
Jul-12
Aug-12
Sep-12
Oct-12
Nov-12
Dec-12

Tealbook Forecast*
16.4
3.7
4.3
5.8
4.3
5.7
6.2
4.1
4.2
3.9
4.0
4.0

Quarterly Growth Rates
2012 Q1
2012 Q2
2012 Q3
2012 Q4
2013 Q1
2013 Q2
2013 Q3
2013 Q4
2014 Q1
2014 Q2
2014 Q3
2014 Q4

8.7
4.9
5.2
4.0
1.8
2.3
3.1
3.4
3.5
3.5
3.5
0.6

Annual Growth Rates
2012
2013
2014

5.8
2.7
2.8

* This forecast is consistent with nominal GDP and interest rates in the
Tealbook forecast. Actual data through July 16, 2012; projections thereafter.

Page 37 of 55

Alternatives

(Percent, seasonally adjusted annual rate)

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

DIRECTIVE
The directive that was issued in June appears on the next page, followed by drafts
for an August directive that correspond to each of the policy alternatives.
The directives for Alternatives B and C would instruct the Desk to leave the total
face value of domestic securities in the SOMA about unchanged and to take appropriate
steps to complete by the end of December 2012 the MEP of $267 billion that was
announced in June. Under Alternative A, the Committee would direct the Desk to begin
a new large-scale asset purchase program. This purchase program would replace the
previously announced maturity extension program. Specifically, the Desk would be
Alternatives

directed either to execute purchases of $600 billion of longer-term Treasury securities
and $400 billion of agency MBS by the end of the third quarter of 2013, or to begin
purchasing longer-term Treasury securities at a pace of about $45 billion per month and
agency MBS at a pace of about $30 billion per month. Each of the draft directives would
also instruct the Desk to continue the current practice of reinvesting principal payments
on all agency debt and agency MBS in agency MBS. Alternatives B and C would
continue the practice of redeeming maturing Treasury securities at auction, while
Alternative A would reinstate the policy of rolling over maturing Treasuries at auction.

Page 38 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

June 2012 Directive
The Federal Open Market Committee seeks monetary and financial conditions
that will foster price stability and promote sustainable growth in output. To further its
long-run objectives, the Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with
federal funds trading in a range from 0 to ¼ percent. The Committee directs the Desk to
continue the maturity extension program it began in September to purchase, by the end of
June 2012, Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years with a
total face value of $400 billion, and to sell Treasury securities with remaining maturities
of 3 years or less with a total face value of $400 billion. Following the conclusion of
these purchases, the Committee directs the Desk to purchase Treasury securities with
by the end of December 2012, and to sell or redeem Treasury securities with remaining
maturities of approximately 3 years or less with a total face value of about $267 billion.
For the duration of this program, the Committee directs the Desk to suspend its current
policy of rolling over maturing Treasury securities into new issues. The Committee
directs the Desk to maintain its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments on all
agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in the System Open Market Account
in agency mortgage-backed securities. These actions should maintain the total face value
of domestic securities at approximately $2.6 trillion. The Committee directs the Desk to
engage in dollar roll transactions as necessary to facilitate settlement of the Federal
Reserve's agency MBS transactions. The System Open Market Account Manager and the
Secretary will keep the Committee informed of ongoing developments regarding the
System's balance sheet that could affect the attainment over time of the Committee's
objectives of maximum employment and price stability.

Page 39 of 55

Alternatives

remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years with a total face value of about $267 billion

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

August 2012 Directive—Alternative A
The Federal Open Market Committee seeks monetary and financial conditions
that will foster price stability and promote sustainable growth in output. To further its
long-run objectives, the Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with
federal funds trading in a range from 0 to ¼ percent. The Committee directs the Desk to
continue the maturity extension program it began in September to purchase, by the end of
June 2012, Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years with a
total face value of $400 billion, and to sell Treasury securities with remaining maturities
of 3 years or less with a total face value of $400 billion. Following the conclusion of
these purchases, the Committee directs the Desk to purchase Treasury securities with
Alternatives

remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years with a total face value of about $267 billion
by the end of December 2012, and to sell or redeem Treasury securities with remaining
maturities of approximately 3 years or less with a total face value of about $267 billion
begin a new large-scale asset purchase program. This program replaces the
previously announced maturity extension program. Specifically, [ the Desk is
directed to purchase longer-term Treasury securities at a pace of about $45 billion
per month and to purchase agency mortgage-backed securities at a pace of about
$30 billion per month. | the Desk is directed to purchase $600 billion of longer-term
Treasury securities and $400 billion of agency mortgage-backed securities by the
end of the third quarter of 2013. ] For the duration of this program, the Committee
directs the Desk to suspend its current The desk is also directed to reinstate the policy
of rolling over maturing Treasury securities into new issues. The Committee directs the
Desk to maintain its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments on all agency debt
and agency mortgage-backed securities in the System Open Market Account in agency
mortgage-backed securities. These actions should maintain the total face value of
domestic securities at approximately $2.6 trillion. The Committee directs the Desk to
engage in dollar roll and coupon swap transactions as necessary to facilitate settlement
of the Federal Reserve's agency MBS transactions. The System Open Market Account
Manager and the Secretary will keep the Committee informed of ongoing developments
regarding the System's balance sheet that could affect the attainment over time of the
Committee's objectives of maximum employment and price stability.

Page 40 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

August 2012 Directive—Alternative B
The Federal Open Market Committee seeks monetary and financial conditions
that will foster price stability and promote sustainable growth in output. To further its
long-run objectives, the Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with
federal funds trading in a range from 0 to ¼ percent. The Committee directs the Desk to
continue the maturity extension program it began announced in June September to
purchase, by the end of June 2012, Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6
years to 30 years with a total face value of $400 billion, and to sell or redeem Treasury
securities with remaining maturities of 3 years or less with a total face value of $400
billion. Following the conclusion of these purchases, the Committee directs the Desk to
face value of about $267 billion by the end of December 2012, and to sell or redeem
Treasury securities with remaining maturities of approximately 3 years or less with a total
face value of about $267 billion. For the duration of this program, the Committee directs
the Desk to suspend its current policy of rolling over maturing Treasury securities into
new issues. The Committee directs the Desk to maintain its existing policy of reinvesting
principal payments on all agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in the
System Open Market Account in agency mortgage-backed securities. These actions
should maintain the total face value of domestic securities at approximately $2.6 trillion.
The Committee directs the Desk to engage in dollar roll transactions as necessary to
facilitate settlement of the Federal Reserve's agency MBS transactions. The System
Open Market Account Manager and the Secretary will keep the Committee informed of
ongoing developments regarding the System's balance sheet that could affect the
attainment over time of the Committee's objectives of maximum employment and price
stability.

Page 41 of 55

Alternatives

purchase Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years with a total

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

August 2012 Directive—Alternative C
The Federal Open Market Committee seeks monetary and financial conditions
that will foster price stability and promote sustainable growth in output. To further its
long-run objectives, the Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with
federal funds trading in a range from 0 to ¼ percent. The Committee directs the Desk to
continue the maturity extension program it began announced in June September to
purchase, by the end of June 2012, Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6
years to 30 years with a total face value of $400 billion, and to sell or redeem Treasury
securities with remaining maturities of 3 years or less with a total face value of $400
billion. Following the conclusion of these purchases, the Committee directs the Desk to
Alternatives

purchase Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years with a total
face value of about $267 billion by the end of December 2012, and to sell or redeem
Treasury securities with remaining maturities of approximately 3 years or less with a total
face value of about $267 billion. For the duration of this program, the Committee directs
the Desk to suspend its current policy of rolling over maturing Treasury securities into
new issues. The Committee directs the Desk to maintain its existing policy of reinvesting
principal payments on all agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in the
System Open Market Account in agency mortgage-backed securities. These actions
should maintain the total face value of domestic securities at approximately $2.6 trillion.
The Committee directs the Desk to engage in dollar roll transactions as necessary to
facilitate settlement of the Federal Reserve's agency MBS transactions. The System
Open Market Account Manager and the Secretary will keep the Committee informed of
ongoing developments regarding the System's balance sheet that could affect the
attainment over time of the Committee's objectives of maximum employment and price
stability.

Page 42 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Explanatory Notes
A. Policy Rules Used in “Monetary Policy Strategies”
The table below gives the expressions for the selected policy rules used in “Monetary
Policy Strategies.” In the table, ܴ௧ denotes the nominal federal funds rate for quarter t, while the
right-hand-side variables include the staff’s projection of trailing four-quarter core PCE inflation
for the current quarter and three quarters ahead (ߨ௧ and ߨ௧ାଷ|௧ ), the output gap estimate for the
current period as well as its one-quarter-ahead forecast (gapt and gapt+1|t), and the forecast of the
three-quarter-ahead annual change in the output gap (4gapt+3|t). The value of policymakers’
long-run inflation objective, denoted π*, is 2 percent. The nominal income targeting rule
responds to the nominal income gap, which is defined as the difference between nominal income
‫݊ݕ‬௧ (100 times the log of the level of nominal GDP) and a target value ‫݊ݕ‬௧∗ (100 times the log of
potential nominal GDP). Target nominal GDP in 2007:Q4 is set equal to potential real GDP in
that quarter multiplied by the GDP deflator in that quarter; subsequently, target nominal GDP
grows 2 percentage points per year faster than potential GDP.
Taylor (1993) rule

ܴ௧ ൌ 2.25 ൅ ߨ௧ ൅ 0.5ሺߨ௧ െ ߨ ∗ ሻ ൅ 0.5݃ܽ‫݌‬௧

Taylor (1999) rule

ܴ௧ ൌ 2.25 ൅ ߨ௧ ൅ 0.5ሺߨ௧ െ ߨ ∗ ሻ ൅ ݃ܽ‫݌‬௧
ܴ௧ ൌ 1.2ܴ௧ିଵ െ 0.39ܴ௧ିଶ ൅ 0.19ሾ0.79 ൅ 1.73ߨ௧
൅ 3.66݃ܽ‫݌‬௧ െ 2.72݃ܽ‫݌‬௧ିଵ ሿ

First-difference rule

ܴ௧ ൌ ܴ௧ିଵ ൅ 0.5൫ߨ௧ାଷ|௧ െ ߨ ∗ ൯ ൅ 0.5Δସ ݃ܽ‫݌‬௧ାଷ|௧

Nominal income
targeting rule

ܴ௧ ൌ 0.75ܴ௧ିଵ ൅ 0.25ሺ2.25 ൅ ߨ ∗ ൅ ‫݊ݕ‬௧ െ ‫݊ݕ‬௧∗ ሻ

The first two of the selected rules were studied by Taylor (1993, 1999). The outcomebased rule uses policy reactions estimated using real-time data over the sample
1988:Q12006:Q4. The intercept of the outcome-based rule was chosen so that it is consistent
with a 2 percent long-run inflation objective and a long-run, quarterly real interest rate of 2¼
percent, a value used in the FRB/US model. The intercepts of the Taylor (1993, 1999) rules are
set at 2¼ percent—instead of Taylor’s original value of 2 percent—for the same reason. The 2¼
percent real rate estimate also enters the long-run intercept of the nominal income targeting rule.
The prescriptions of the first-difference rule do not depend on the level of the output gap or the
long-run, quarterly real interest rate; see Orphanides (2003).
Near-term prescriptions from these rules are calculated using Tealbook projections for
inflation and the output gap. The first-difference rule, the estimated outcome-based rule, and the
nominal income targeting rule include the lagged policy rate as a right-hand-side variable. When

Page 43 of 55

Explanatory Notes

Outcome-based rule

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

the Tealbook is published early in the quarter, the lines denoted “Previous Tealbook” report rule
prescriptions based on the previous Tealbook’s staff outlook, jumping off from the actual value of
the lagged funds rate in the previous quarter. When the Tealbook is published late in the quarter,
the lines denoted “Previous Tealbook Outlook” report rule prescriptions based on the previous
Tealbook’s staff outlook, but jumping off from the average value for the policy rate thus far this
quarter.

REFERENCES
Erceg, Christopher, Michael Kiley, and David López-Salido (2011). “Alternative
Monetary Policy Frameworks.” Memo sent to the Committee on October 6, 2011.
McCallum, Bennett T., and Edward Nelson (1999). “Nominal Income Targeting in an
Open-Economy Optimizing Model,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 43 (June), pp. 553–
578.
Orphanides, Athanasios (2003). “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor
Rule,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50 (July), pp. 9831022.
Taylor, John B. (1993). “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39 (December), pp. 195214.

Explanatory Notes

Taylor, John B. (1999). “A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B.
Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago Press, pp. 319341.

Page 44 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

B. Estimates of the Equilibrium and Actual Real Rates
An estimate of the equilibrium real rate appears as a memo item in the first exhibit,
“Policy Rules and the Staff Projection.” The concept of the short-run equilibrium real rate
underlying the estimate corresponds to the level of the real federal funds rate that is consistent
with output reaching potential in twelve quarters using the projection for the economy of
FRB/US, the staff’s large-scale econometric model of the U.S. economy. This estimate depends
on a very broad array of economic factors, some of which take the form of projected values of the
model’s exogenous variables. The estimate reported is the “Tealbook-consistent” estimate of r*,
which is generated after the paths of exogenous variables in the FRB/US model are adjusted so
that they match those in the extended Tealbook forecast. Model simulations then determine the
value of the real federal funds rate that closes the output gap conditional on the exogenous
variables in the extended baseline forecast.

Explanatory Notes

The estimated actual real federal funds rate reported in the exhibit is constructed as the
difference between the federal funds rate and the trailing four-quarter change in the core PCE
price index. The federal funds rate is specified as the midpoint of the target range for the federal
funds rate on the Tealbook Book B publication date.

Page 45 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

C. FRB/US Model Simulations

Explanatory Notes

The exhibits of “Monetary Policy Strategies” that report results from simulations of
alternative policies are derived from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US model. The simulated
policy rule is assumed to be in force over the whole period covered by the simulation. For the
optimal control simulations, the dotted line labeled “Previous Tealbook” is derived from the
optimal control simulations, when applied to the previous Tealbook projection.

Page 46 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

D. Long-Run Projections of the Balance Sheet and Monetary Base
This explanatory note presents the assumptions underlying the projections provided in the
section titled “Long-Run Projections of the Balance Sheet and Monetary Base,” as well as
projections for each major component of the balance sheet.

GENERAL ASSUMPTIONS

The Tealbook projections for the scenario corresponding to Alternative B assume that
the target federal funds rate begins to increase in December 2014, consistent with the forward
guidance in the FOMC’s statement that the target federal funds rate is expected to be at
exceptionally low levels “at least through late 2014.” This date of liftoff is two months later than
that assumed in the balance sheet projections from the June Tealbook Book B for Alternative B
but is the same as the current staff forecast in Tealbook Book A. In the scenario corresponding to
Alternative A, it is assumed that the target federal funds rate begins to increase in June 2015,
consistent with the FOMC statement for this alternative that the Committee currently anticipates
that exceptionally low levels for the target federal funds rate are likely to be warrented “at least
through mid 2015.” The projection for the scenario corresponding to Alternative C assumes the
target federal funds rate lifts off in December 2013, one year earlier than in Alternative B.1 The
balance sheet projections assume that no use of short-term draining tools is necessary to achieve
the projected path for the target federal funds rate.2

1

The federal funds rate paths in Alternatives A and C are adjusted to reflect their assumed liftoff
dates that are different from the staff forecast. By the end of the forecast horizon, all federal funds rate
paths converge to the projection assumed in the July Tealbook staff forecast. The projected path of the 10year Treasury yield in Alternative A is the yield assumed in the July Tealbook staff forecast adjusted for
the expectations effect of a later target federal funds rate liftoff (see the box on “Forward Rate Guidance
and Policy Expectations” from the January 2012 Tealbook Book B) and for the term premium effect
associated with the LSAP program as well as the later liftoff date for the federal funds rate which triggers a
later start to asset redemptions and sales. For the projected path in Alternative C, we adjust the 10-year
Treasury yield to account for the change in term premiums due to the earlier lift off of the federal funds
rate.
2
If term deposits or reverse repurchase agreements were used to drain reserves prior to raising the
federal funds rate, the composition of liabilities would change: Increases in term deposits and reverse
repurchase agreements would be matched by corresponding declines in reserve balances. Presumably,
these draining tools would be wound down as the balance sheet returns to its steady state growth path, so
that the projected paths for Treasury securities presented in the Tealbook remain valid.

Page 47 of 55

Explanatory Notes

The balance sheet projections are constructed at a monthly frequency from July 2012 to
December 2020. The few balance sheet items that are not discussed below are assumed to be
constant over the projection period at the level observed on June 29, 2012. The projections for all
major asset and liability categories under each scenario are summarized in the tables that follow
the bullet points.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

ASSETS
Treasury Securities, Agency Mortgage-Backed Securities (MBS), and Agency Debt
Securities


The assumptions under Alternative B are:
o

o

o

Explanatory Notes

o

The FOMC is assumed to continue the MEP as announced in June at its current pace
through the end of 2012, directing the Desk to purchase Treasury securities with
remaining maturity of 6 years to 30 years and to sell or redeem Treasury securities
with remaining maturity of approximately 3 years or less. In total, the FOMC
purchases an additional $267 billion in longer-term Treasury securities as a result of
the MEP extension that started in July 2012.
The FOMC continues to reinvest the proceeds from principal payments on its agency
securities holdings in agency MBS until June 2014—six months prior to the assumed
increase in the target federal funds rate. Starting in June 2014, all securities are
allowed to roll off the portfolio as they mature or prepay.
The Federal Reserve begins to sell agency MBS and agency debt securities in June
2015, roughly six months after the assumed date of the first increase in the target
federal funds rate. Holdings of agency securities are reduced over five years and
reach zero by May 2020.
For agency MBS, the rate of prepayment is based on staff models using estimates of
housing market factors from one of the program’s analytical providers, long-run
average prepayment speeds of MBS, and interest rate projections from the Tealbook.
The projected rate of prepayment is sensitive to these underlying assumptions.



In the scenario corresponding to Alternative A, the Committee is assumed to begin a $1
trillion LSAP program in August 2012 under which it purchases $600 billion in Treasury
securities at a pace of about $45 billion per month and $400 billion in current coupon
agency MBS at a pace of about $30 billion per month through the third quarter of 2013.
The Treasury security purchase distribution is assumed to be identical to the distribution
used for the $600 billion Treasury security LSAP program announced in November 2010,
where the maturity of securities purchased ranged from 1.5 years to 30 years. In addition,
the Committee is assumed to end its sales of shorter-term Treasury securities and
reinstitute its policy of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at auction. The
Committee is also assumed to maintain its existing policy of reinvesting principal
payments from its holdings of agency debt and agency MBS in agency MBS. In
December 2014, six months prior to the assumed increase in the federal funds rate in
June 2015, principal payments from all securities are allowed to roll off the portfolio.
Sales of agency securities begin in June 2015 and continue for five years.



In the scenario corresponding to Alternative C, the Committee is expected to continue the
MEP at its current pace through the end of 2012 as in Alternative B. The FOMC
continues to reinvest the proceeds from principal payments on its agency securities

Page 48 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012



Because current and expected interest rates in the near term are below the average coupon
rate on outstanding Treasury securities, the market value at which these securities are
purchased will generally exceed their face value, with a larger premium for longermaturity securities. As a result, although the par value of securities holdings remains
constant under the MEP, premiums associated with securities purchases in this program,
and hence total assets, will have risen. Through July 2012, on net, premiums associated
with the MEP are about $60 billion. In Alternatives B and C, where the MEP is assumed
to continue to year end, premiums will increase on net an additional $31 billion. In
Alternative A, where an additional $600 billion in Treasury securities are purchased,
premiums are boosted by an additional $10 billion relative to the scenarios without these
Treasury securities purchases. The increase in premiums is reflected in higher total assets
and in higher reserve balances.



The large-scale asset purchase program in Alternative A would put downward pressure
on market interest rates, in particular primary and secondary mortgage rates.



The current and near-term market value of agency MBS is assumed to be four percent
above its face value. As a result, for Alternative A, the $400 billion MBS purchases will
cause unamortized premiums on the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet to rise by roughly
$16 billion relative to a scenario without these MBS purchases. The increase in
premiums is reflected in higher total assets and in higher reserve balances.



The level of central bank liquidity swaps is assumed to decline gradually, as the recent
foreign central bank swap auctions mature, and then return to zero in September 2012.



In all scenarios, a minimum level of $25 billion is set for reserve balances. Once reserve
balances drop to this level, the Desk first purchases Treasury bills to maintain this level
of reserve balances going forward. Purchases of bills continue until such securities
comprise one-third of the Federal Reserve’s total Treasury securities holdings—about the
average share prior to the crisis. Once this share is reached, the Federal Reserve buys
coupon securities in addition to bills to maintain an approximate composition of the
portfolio of one-third bills and two-thirds coupon securities.

Liquidity Programs and Credit Facilities


Credit through the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF) declines to zero
by the end of 2015, reflecting loan maturities and prepayments.

3

Projected prepayments of agency MBS reflect interest rate projections as of July 24, 2012.

Page 49 of 55

Explanatory Notes

holdings in agency MBS until June 2013—six months prior to the assumed increase in
the target federal funds rate.3 Starting in June 2013, all securities are allowed to roll off
the portfolio as they mature or prepay. The Federal Reserve begins to sell agency MBS
and agency debt securities in June 2014. Holdings of agency securities are reduced over
five years and reach zero by May 2019.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012



The assets held by TALF LLC remain at about $1 billion through 2014 before declining
to zero the following year. Assets held by TALF LLC consist of investments of
commitment fees collected by the LLC and the U.S. Treasury’s initial funding. In this
projection, the LLC does not purchase any asset-backed securities received by the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York in connection with a decision of a borrower not to
repay a TALF loan.



The assets held by Maiden Lane LLC and Maiden Lane III LLC decline to zero gradually
over time.

Explanatory Notes

LIABILITIES AND CAPITAL


Federal Reserve notes in circulation grow in line with the staff forecast for money stock
currency through the last quarter of 2014. Afterwards, Federal Reserve notes in
circulation grow at the same rate as nominal GDP, as in the extended Tealbook
projection.



The level of reverse repurchase agreements (RRPs) is assumed to remain around $70
billion, about the average level of RRPs associated with foreign official and international
accounts observed over the past three years.



Balances held in the U.S. Treasury’s General Account (TGA) follow recent patterns until
the assumed increase in the target federal funds rate in each alternative. At that point, the
TGA slowly drops back to its historical target level of $5 billion as it is assumed that the
Treasury will implement a new cash management system and invest funds in excess of $5
billion. The TGA remains constant at $5 billion over the remainder of the forecast period.



We maintain the Supplementary Financing Account (SFA) balance at its current level of
zero throughout the forecast.



Federal Reserve capital grows 15 percent per year, in line with the average rate of the
past ten years.4



In general, increases in the level of Federal Reserve assets are matched by higher levels
of reserve balances. All else equal, increases in the levels of liability items, such as
Federal Reserve notes in circulation or other liabilities, or increases in the level of
Reserve Bank capital, drain reserve balances. When increases in these liability or capital
items would otherwise cause reserve balances to fall below $25 billion, purchases of
Treasury securities are assumed in order to maintain that level of reserve balances.

4

The annual growth rate of capital affects the date of normalization of the size of the balance sheet
and the size of the SOMA portfolio. Growth in Reserve Bank capital has been modest over the past two
years; however, even if Federal Reserve capital were assumed to be constant, normalization only would be
pushed later by about a quarter.

Page 50 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

In the event that a Federal Reserve Bank’s earnings fall short of the amount necessary to
cover operating costs, pay dividends, and equate surplus to capital paid-in, a deferred
asset would be recorded. This deferred asset is recorded in lieu of reducing the Reserve
Bank’s capital and is reported on the liability side of the balance sheet as “Interest on
Federal Reserve notes due to U.S. Treasury.” This liability takes on a positive value
when weekly cumulative earnings have not yet been distributed to the Treasury and takes
on a negative value when earnings fall short of the expenses listed above. In all
scenarios, System-wide earnings are always sufficient to cover these expenses, and this
line item is set to zero.

TERM PREMIUM EFFECTS

5



Under Alternative B, the current staff estimates of the contemporaneous term premium
effect on the yield of the ten-year Treasury note is negative 70 basis points. Based on the
projection for the balance sheet, that term premium effect converges slowly toward zero
over the forecast period as the portfolio normalizes. The path of the term premium effect
is a bit more negative than in the June Tealbook Alternative B because of the later liftoff
date of the federal funds rate, which implies securities remain out of the hands of the
public for longer than in the last Tealbook.



Under Alternative A, the term premium effect is negative 89 basis points. The effect is
more negative than in Alternative B because of the assumed $1 trillion LSAP program
and later lift off date of the federal funds rate.



Under Alternative C, the term premium effect is negative 63 basis points. The effect is
less negative than in Alternative B because of the earlier assumed increase in the federal
funds rate which, in turn, leads to earlier asset redemptions and sales that push securities
back into the hands of the public sooner.

5

Staff estimates use the model outlined in the appendix of the January 18, 2012, memo “Possible
MBS Large-Scale Asset Purchase Program” written by staff at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and
the Board of Governors. More details of the model can be found in “Term Structure Modeling with Supply
Factors and the Federal Reserve’s Large Scale Asset Purchase Programs” by Li and Wei, FEDS working
paper # 37, 2012.

Page 51 of 55

Explanatory Notes



July 26, 2012

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

10-Year Treasury Term Premium Effect

Explanatory Notes

Date

2012 Q3
2012 Q4
2013 Q1
2013 Q2
2013 Q3
2013 Q4
2014 Q1
2014 Q2
2014 Q3
2014 Q4
2015 Q1
2015 Q2
2015 Q3
2015 Q4
2016 Q1
2016 Q2
2016 Q3
2016 Q4
2017 Q1
2017 Q2
2017 Q3
2017 Q4
2018 Q1
2018 Q2
2018 Q3
2018 Q4
2019 Q1
2019 Q2
2019 Q3
2019 Q4
2020 Q1
2020 Q2
2020 Q3
2020 Q4

Alternative B

-70
-66
-63
-59
-55
-51
-47
-43
-40
-36
-33
-29
-26
-24
-21
-19
-17
-15
-13
-11
-10
-9
-8
-7
-7
-6
-6
-6
-5
-5
-5
-4
-4
-4

Alternative A

Alternative C

Basis Points
Quarterly Averages
-89
-86
-82
-78
-74
-69
-64
-59
-54
-50
-45
-40
-36
-32
-29
-25
-22
-20
-17
-15
-13
-11
-9
-8
-7
-6
-5
-5
-5
-4
-4
-4
-3
-3

Page 52 of 55

-63
-60
-56
-52
-47
-44
-40
-36
-33
-30
-27
-24
-21
-19
-17
-15
-13
-11
-10
-9
-8
-7
-6
-6
-6
-5
-5
-5
-5
-5
-4
-4
-4
-3

June
Alternative B

-68
-65
-62
-58
-54
-50
-47
-43
-40
-37
-34
-31
-28
-26
-24
-22
-20
-18
-16
-15
-14
-13
-12
-11
-10
-10
-9
-9
-8
-8
-7
-7
-6
-6

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
End-of-Year Projections -- Alternative B
Billions of dollars

Jun 29, 2012

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

2,862

2,841

2,790

2,201

1,796

1,993

28

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

28

0

0

0

0

0

6

3

1

0

0

0

15

2

0

0

0

0

2,606

2,594

2,570

2,022

1,652

1,873

1,660

1,654

1,654

1,435

1,413

1,873

91

77

39

16

2

0

Agency mortgage-backed securities

855

863

878

571

237

0

Net portfolio holdings of TALF LLC

1

1

1

0

0

0

206

242

218

178

144

120

2,808

2,779

2,708

2,092

1,653

1,804

1,070

1,108

1,250

1,390

1,535

1,687

70

70

70

70

70

70

1,647

1,584

1,372

616

32

32

1,524

1,492

1,365

610

25

25

U.S. Treasury, General Account

91

90

5

5

5

5

Other Deposits

32

2

2

2

2

2

3

0

0

0

0

0

55

62

82

108

143

189

Total assets

Liquidity programs for financial firms
Primary, secondary, and seasonal credit
Central bank liquidity swaps
Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF)
Net portfolio holdings of Maiden Lane LLC,
Maiden Lane II LLC, and Maiden Lane III LLC
Securities held outright
U.S. Treasury securities
Agency debt securities

Total other assets

Total liabilities
Selected liabilities
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Reverse repurchase agreements
Deposits with Federal Reserve Banks
Reserve balances held by depository institutions

Interest on Federal Reserve Notes due
to U.S. Treasury

Total capital

Source: Federal Reserve H.4.1 statistical releases and staff calculations.
Note: Components may not sum to totals due to rounding.

Page 53 of 55

Explanatory Notes

Selected assets

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
End-of-Year Projections -- Alternative A
Billions of dollars

Jun 29, 2012

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

2,862

3,144

3,856

2,899

1,798

1,995

28

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

28

0

0

0

0

0

6

3

1

0

0

0

15

2

0

0

0

0

2,606

2,901

3,617

2,714

1,656

1,884

1,660

1,868

2,249

1,751

1,190

1,884

91

77

39

16

2

0

Agency mortgage-backed securities

855

956

1,329

947

463

0

Net portfolio holdings of TALF LLC

1

1

1

0

0

0

206

238

237

185

142

111

2,808

3,082

3,774

2,791

1,655

1,805

1,070

1,108

1,250

1,390

1,535

1,687

70

70

70

70

70

70

1,647

1,886

2,435

1,312

32

32

1,524

1,794

2,344

1,306

25

25

U.S. Treasury, General Account

91

90

90

5

5

5

Other Deposits

32

2

2

2

2

2

3

0

0

0

0

0

55

62

82

108

143

189

Total assets
Selected assets
Liquidity programs for financial firms
Primary, secondary, and seasonal credit
Central bank liquidity swaps
Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF)
Net portfolio holdings of Maiden Lane LLC,
Maiden Lane II LLC, and Maiden Lane III LLC
Securities held outright
U.S. Treasury securities
Agency debt securities

Explanatory Notes

Total other assets

Total liabilities
Selected liabilities
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Reverse repurchase agreements
Deposits with Federal Reserve Banks
Reserve balances held by depository institutions

Interest on Federal Reserve Notes due
to U.S. Treasury

Total capital

Source: Federal Reserve H.4.1 statistical releases and staff calculations.
Note: Components may not sum to totals due to rounding.

Page 54 of 55

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

July 26, 2012

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
End-of-Year Projections -- Alternative C
Billions of dollars

Jun 29, 2012

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

2,862

2,839

2,587

1,995

1,796

1,993

28

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

28

0

0

0

0

0

6

3

1

0

0

0

15

2

0

0

0

0

2,606

2,594

2,376

1,825

1,658

1,874

1,660

1,654

1,654

1,435

1,592

1,874

91

77

39

16

2

0

Agency mortgage-backed securities

855

863

683

374

64

0

Net portfolio holdings of TALF LLC

1

1

1

0

0

0

206

240

209

170

138

119

2,808

2,777

2,505

1,887

1,653

1,804

1,070

1,108

1,250

1,390

1,535

1,687

70

70

70

70

70

70

1,647

1,582

1,168

411

32

32

1,524

1,490

1,162

405

25

25

U.S. Treasury, General Account

91

90

5

5

5

5

Other Deposits

32

2

2

2

2

2

3

0

0

0

0

0

55

62

82

108

143

189

Total assets

Liquidity programs for financial firms
Primary, secondary, and seasonal credit
Central bank liquidity swaps
Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF)
Net portfolio holdings of Maiden Lane LLC,
Maiden Lane II LLC, and Maiden Lane III LLC
Securities held outright
U.S. Treasury securities
Agency debt securities

Total other assets

Total liabilities
Selected liabilities
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Reverse repurchase agreements
Deposits with Federal Reserve Banks
Reserve balances held by depository institutions

Interest on Federal Reserve Notes due
to U.S. Treasury

Total capital

Source: Federal Reserve H.4.1 statistical releases and staff calculations.
Note: Components may not sum to totals due to rounding.

Page 55 of 55

Explanatory Notes

Selected assets