View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020
July 24, 1964.
Board of Governors
Mr. Hackley

JUL

2 71964

Subject: Legality of allocations
of Government securities in System
Account to avoid Reserve Bank
reserve deficiencies

NATURE OF THE QUESTION
On several recent occasions, question has been raised
whether the procedure for allocation among the Reserve Banks of
participations in securities in the System Open Market Account, as
adopted by the Federal Open Market Committee on December 3, 1963,
is consistent with the letter and spirit of provisions of the Federal
Reserve Act regarding the maintenance by the Reserve Banks of gold
certificate reserves against Federal Reserve notes and deposits.
The present allocation procedure provides that securities
in the Account shall be reallocated on the last business day of each
statement week and of each month. It further provides that, if calculations in the morning of any business day should disclose a deficiency
(below 25 per cent) in the reserve ratio of any Reserve Bank for the
preceding day, the Manager shall make a special adjustment "as of"
such previous day to restore the combined reserve ratio of that Bank
to the average of all Banks or to such higher level as may be necessary to eliminate the deficiency. This procedure differs from that
in effect prior to December 3, 1963, in that the earlier procedure
(adopted on September 10, 1963) provided for special adjustments on
the day following each statement date "as of" the previous day to
eliminate deficiencies on the statement dates, except that, if a Bank
anticipated a deficiency on any other day (between statement dates),
the Bank might arrange with the Manager to make the necessary special
adjustment to raise the Bank's ratio for that day. In net effect, the
difference is simply that the Manager now is required to make special
adjustments on a day between statement dates "as of" the previous day
if necessary to avoid deficiencies on such previous day, whereas previously adjustments were made between statement dates only if a Reserve
Bank anticipated a possible deficiency and made arrangements with the
Manager to make an adjustment on a particular day.
Whether a special adjustment between statement dates is made
at the initiative of a Reserve Bank through advance arrangements with
the Manager or is made by the Manager on an "as of" basis, without
such prior arrangement, would seem to make no difference in principle;
in both instances the objective of the special adjustment is to avoid
a deficiency at a particular Reserve Bank. The practical difference,
of course, is that the earlier procedure did not guarantee avoidance
of a deficiency.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

Actually, the principle underlying adjustments between
statement dates in both the present procedure and that of
September 10, 1963, is essentially the same as the principle inherent
in earlier allocation procedures. For many years, with changes in
details, the procedures have provided for special adjustments (in
addition to periodic allocations) to prevent the reserve ratio of any
Bank from falling below a specified percentage above the statutory
minimum. At one time (May 1936) the specified "floor" was set at
50 per cent; it was gradually lowered to 40, 35, 30, and eventually

28 per cent. The purpose was to avoid unusually low reserve ratios
at individual Banks. Under the present procedure, the purpose is to
avoid an actual deficiency, since the present "floor" is the statutory
minimum. However, in both cases, the general objective was to equalize
reserve ratios of the various Banks.

Going further, it is difficult to see any distinction in
principle between special "as of" adjustments between statement dates
and "as of" allocations on statement dates or at other specified
periodic intervals as provided in earlier procedures. The objective
of "allocations", like that of "special adjustments", has always been
to equalize the reserve positions of the Reserve Banks. Stated
differently, if special adjustments between statement dates in order
to avoid reserve deficiencies are vulnerable to legal objection, the
same is true in principle of periodic allocations based on equalization
of the average combined reserve ratios of the twelve Reserve Banks.
Accordingly, it is assumed that the broad question presented
is whether "allocations" and "adjustments" of Reserve Bank participations in Government securities held in the System Account, as determined by the Open Market Committee, for the purpose of avoiding a
reserve deficiency on the part of any Reserve Bank is inconsistent
with statutory requirements.
It is understood that the principal argument that has been
advanced against the legality of the allocation procedure is that it
constitutes a device to conceal reserve deficiencies through bookkeeping adjustments and, in effect, amounts to consideration of Reserve
Bank reserve requirements on a System basis rather than an individual
Bank basis as contemplated by the Federal Reserve Act.
It should be emphasized that this memorandum deals only with

the legal question just stated. It is not concerned with the policy
question whether deficiencies in reserves at individual Reserve Banks
should be allowed to occur between statement dates (with payment of the
statutory tax), without any effort to avoid such deficiencies through

special adjustments in the System Account, or whether a more fundamental
change should be made to discontinue periodic allocations based on
equalization of the reserve ratios of the twelve Reserve Banks.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

OPINION

For the reasons hereafter stated, it is my opinion that:
(1) The law does not expressly prohibit transfers
of particular assets between Federal Reserve Banks,
as provided by the present allocation procedure, in
order to avoid reserve deficiencies; on the contrary,
such transfers of assets may be regarded as a legitimate
means of achieving compliance with Reserve Bank reserve
requirements;
(2) The Federal Open Market Committee has statutory

authority to determine the basis upon which securities
in the System Account shall be allocated, and the basis
provided in the present allocation procedure is therefore
to be regarded as valid unless clearly contrary to some
provision of law; and
(3) Transfers of assets among the Reserve Banks,
including allocations of Government securities in the
System Account, have been regarded since the earliest
years of the System as an appropriate means of equalizing the reserve positions of the Reserve Banks and
avoiding reserve deficiencies; and Congress has been
aware of, and has not objected to, the System's longestablished practice in this respect.
I conclude, therefore, that the present allocation procedure
does not violate either the letter or the spirit of the relevant provisions of law.

DISCUSSION

1.

Statutory Provisions

Paragraph 3 of section 16 of the Federal Reserve Act
(12 U.S.C. 413) requires every Reserve Bank to maintain "reserves in
gold certificates of not less than 25 per centum against its deposits
and reserves in gold certificates of not less than 25 per centum against
its Federal Reserve notes in actual circulation". These are separate
requirements; the fact that a Reserve Bank has gold certificates equal
to 25 per cent of its combined notes and deposits is not sufficient.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

In computing its reserves against Federal Reserve notes,
a Reserve Bank (1) must include gold certificates pledged as collateral
for such notes under paragraph 2 of section 16 (12 U.S.C. 412), which
requires such notes to be secured 100 per cent by eligible paper, direct
obligations of the United States, or gold certificates; (2) must include
gold certificates held with the Treasury Department in the "redemption
fund" pursuant to paragraph 4 of section 16 (12 U.S.C. 414); and

(3) may include all or any part of gold certificates to its credit in
the "Interdistrict Settlement Fund" provided for by paragraph 16 of
section 16 (12 U.S.C. 467).
In computing its reserves against deposits, a Reserve Bank
may include gold certificates in the Interdistrict Settlement Fund, but
not gold certificates pledged as collateral for Federal Reserve notes
or gold certificates in the redemption fund.
Under section 11(c) of the Federal Reserve Act (12 U.S.C. 248(c)),
the Board is authorized to suspend any reserve requirements prescribed
by the Act for a period of not more than 30 days and to renew such suspension for periods not exceeding 15 days, provided that the Board must
prescribe a graduated tax on reserve deficiencies. In the case of
reserves against Federal Reserve notes, the Board must establish a
graduated tax on deficiencies in accordance with the formula set forth
in that section. Any tax required to be paid on a reserve deficiency
against notes must be added to the discount rate charged by the
deficient Reserve Bank.
Clearly, these provisions of the law require reserves against
both notes and deposits to be computed separately for each Reserve
Bank. In other words, it is not enough that the aggregate amount of
gold certificates held by all Reserve Banks and "allocated" to note
backing equals 25 per cent of all Federal Reserve notes in circulation.
However, the question at issue appears to be whether, assuming the
necessity for computations on an individual Bank basis, it is permissible
to make allocations and adjustments in the System Account in order to
avoid deficiencies at individual Banks.

2. Mechanics of Adjustments

Banking transactions throughout the country result in debits
and credits among Federal Reserve Banks, resulting from the collection
of checks, transfers of funds, and so on. In the very early days of
the System, such transactions were settled through reciprocal balances
between the Reserve Banks. In 1915, the Board established a "gold
settlement fund" to provide for weekly settlements of interdistrict

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

debits and credits. In 1917, in order to simplify such settlements,
Congress amended the Federal Reserve Act (paragraph 16 of section 16)
to provide for deposits of gold or gold certificates with the Treasury,
subject to orders of the Board - the "Gold Settlement Fund". Since
the Gold Reserve Act of 1934, this Fund has been known as the
"Interdistrict Settlement Fund".
To the extent that gold certificate credits in the Interdistrict
Settlement Fund are used to settle balances owing by one Reserve Bank
to another, the result is obviously a reduction of the debtor Bank's
reserves. That Bank, however, has a participation in the System Account's
holdings of Government securities; and it is able to restore its reserves
by "selling" a part of such participation to another Reserve Bank in
exchange for gold certificates.
In a memorandum from the Division of Bank Operations, dated
April 10, 1964, it was suggested that balances might be settled by
transfers of holdings of Government securities rather than by transfers
of gold certificates in the Interdistrict Settlement Fund. The adoption
of such a proposal clearly would not give rise to the legal question
discussed in this memorandum, since it would not involve any adjustments
in Reserve Bank holdings of gold certificates in the Interdistrict
Settlement Fund. Nor would such a plan give rise to any legal question
as to the non-use of the Interdistrict Settlement Fund for "settlement"
purposes, since, as pointed out in the memorandum above mentioned,
there is no legal requirement that clearings be settled through that
Fund. However, these considerations are irrelevant to the present
question, which relates only to transfers of participations in Government securities in the System Account in exchange for gold certificates
in order to avoid individual Reserve Bank reserve deficiencies.

3.

Compliance with the "Letter of the Law"

Clearly, allocations of Government securities in the System
Account do not violate the letter of the provisions of law heretofore
mentioned. Those provisions require only that each Reserve Bank shall
maintain specified reserves in gold certificates and that, in the
event of a deficiency, the Bank shall pay a graduated tax at a rate
fixed (within statutory limits) by the Board of Governors. The use of
legitimate means to avoid a deficiency would not violate the statute.
Actually, the transactions in question may reasonably be
regarded as an appropriate method of complying with the statutory
reserve requirements. A member bank is required by law to carry
reserves in the form of particular types of assets - a balance with

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

-6-

its Reserve Bank or cash in vault; but it is recognized that a member
bank may properly augment its reserves by rediscounting customers'
paper with its Reserve Bank or by borrowing Federal funds from other
member banks. Similarly, it may be argued, a Reserve Bank may properly
sell Government securities in exchange for gold certificates in order
to augment the type of assets in which its reserves are required to be
carried.
The difference, one might argue, is that a member bank must
deal at arm's length with other banking institutions in seeking to
avoid reserve deficiencies, whereas a Reserve Bank is able to avoid
deficiencies by more or less automatic transactions in the System Account
in a manner that in effect ignores the responsibility of each Reserve
Bank to maintain its own reserves and that results, to some degree, in
treating all the Reserve Banks as a single institution.
The answer to such an argument is to be found in (1) statutory
provisions in effect authorizing the Federal Open Market Committee to
treat Reserve Bank holdings of Government securities on a System basis,
and (2) long-established sanction of the practice of transferring
assets among the Reserve Banks in order to avoid reserve deficiencies.
4. Federal Open Market Committee's Authority to Determine Basis for
Allocating Securities

Section 12A(b) of the Federal Reserve Act (12 U.S.C. 263)
provides that no Reserve Bank shall engage or decline to engage in
open market operations except in accordance with the direction and
regulations of the Federal Open Market Committee. The Committee's
regulation (sec. 4(b)) provides that the Committee shall from time to

time "determine the principles which shall govern the allocation among
the several Federal Reserve Banks of Government securities and other
obligations held in the System Open Market Account, with a view to
meeting the changing needs of the Federal Reserve Banks". This is the
legal basis for the present allocation procedure.
The propriety of allocating participations in a common

investment account to meet the "changing needs" of individual Reserve
Banks has been recognized since 1923 when a "System account" was first
established by the nonstatutory "Open Market Investment Committee" of
the "Governors' Conference".
It is interesting to note that the first allocation formula
adopted by that Committee was based on the reserve ratios of the
Reserve Banks. For a number of years thereafter the formula was

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

designed principally as a means of distributing earnings in a manner
that would meet the estimated expense and dividend requirements of
the respective Banks. At the same time, equalization of the reserve
positions of the Banks continued to be an important consideration;
and the formula adopted by the Executive Committee of the Open Market
Policy Conference in May 1933 was based solely on reserve positions.
Both objectives - distribution of earnings and equalization
of reserve positions - were recognized in the open market regulation
(Regulation M) issued by the Board on August 10, 1933, pursuant to the
Banking Act of 1933, which gave statutory status to the Open Market
Committee but placed regulatory authority in the Board. The Board's
regulation gave first place, however, to equalization of reserve positions. It provided that allocations of Government securities and other
obligations should be made
". . . with the view primarily of (a) enabling each
Federal Reserve Bank to maintain a suitable reserve
position, and (b) equalizing as far as practicable
the net earning position of the Federal Reserve Banks."
The Banking Act of 1935 transferred regulation of open market
operations from the Board to the Open Market Committee. In regulations
adopted effective March 19, 1936, the Committee provided merely that
allocations should be made with a view to meeting the "changing needs"
of the Reserve Banks; but the specific procedure prescribed by the
Committee followed generally the procedures that had been in effect for
many years. Until 1953 the formula was based mainly on anticipated
expense and dividend requirements; from 1953 until 1962 it was based on
total assets; but at all times the procedure included provisions designed
to maintain a specified level of reserves at all Reserve Banks. On
March 6, 1962, the formula was changed to a basis that required periodic
reallocations to maintain the reserve positions of the individual Banks;
and, with changes in January, September, and December 1963, the procedure
has continued on this basis.
The legal authority of the Federal Open Market Committee
to determine the basis for allocations among the Reserve Banks was
strengthened by the Banking Act of 1935, which prohibited the Reserve
Banks not only from engaging, but from "declining" to engage, in open
market operations except pursuant to directions and regulations of the
Committee. Because of this change in the law, the Committee ordered
the consolidation of all Reserve Bank holdings of Government securities
in the System Account effective June 30, 1936. As a reasonable incident
to the Committee's plenary authority to determine when and in what
amounts Government securities should be purchased and sold in the System
Account, the Committee clearly was vested with authority to prescribe

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

-8-

the basis on which participations should be allocated among the Reserve
Banks. It was on this ground that the Board's General Counsel,
Mr. Wyatt, in an opinion of November 26, 1937, concluded that the
Committee had legal authority to continue to require allocations of
securities on the basis of book value instead of current market price.
For similar reasons, the Committee must be regarded as having
authority to prescribe a procedure designed to avoid reserve deficiencies
at individual Reserve Banks, unless such a procedure would be inconsistent with other provisions of law. As has been noted, such a procedure does not violate the letter of provisions of law regarding the
maintenance of reserves by the Reserve Banks. It remains to be considered whether the procedure in any way contravenes the spirit or
intent of the reserve requirement provisions.

5.

Distribution of Assets to Avoid Reserve Deficiencies as Consistent
with Spirit ofthe Law

Since the very beginning of the Federal Reserve System, it
has been recognized - expressly and frequently - that distribution of
assets among the Reserve Banks to avoid reserve deficiencies is a
legitimate and appropriate practice.
One provision of the original Federal Reserve Act, which
remains unchanged in the law today, was expressly designed - and has
been used - for the purpose of shifting available resources among the
Federal Reserve Banks in order to avoid reserve deficiencies at
particular banks. This is the provision contained in section 11(b) of
the Act which authorizes the Board
"To permit, or, on the affirmative vote of at least
five members of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System to require Federal Reserve Banks to
rediscount the discounted paper of other Federal
reserve banks at rates to be fixed by the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System."
In describing this authority for "interdistrict rediscounting"
during the debates on the original Act, Representative Phelan said:
". .. Herein is provided a means whereby funds in one
part of the country for which there is no demand may
be applied to that part of ourcountry which is in need. ..

"

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors
During 1915, it appeared that such interdistrict rediscounting
might become necessary; and, in its Annual Report for that year, the
Board expressly stated that it had been prepared, if necessary, to

set this provision of law in operation "in order to make available for
Federal Reserve Banks requiring larger resources the available funds
of other reserve banks, the collective strength of the reserve system

as a whole being far in excess of any demands that might reasonably

be expected to be brought to bear upon it at that time."
Report, page 8)

(1915 Annual

The first inter-Reserve Bank rediscounting occurred late in
1917, and from that time until the end of 1921 such transactions took
place in considerable volume. At one time or another all of the Reserve
Banks were both borrowers and lenders, depending upon the credit needs
of member banks in the respective districts and the resulting reserve
ratios of the individual Reserve Banks.
Although section 11(b) gave the Board authority to compel
interdistrict rediscounting, this never became necessary because of
"a spontaneous spirit of cooperation between the Federal Reserve Banks"
as a result of which all transactions suggested by the Board were made
voluntarily. (1919 Annual Report, page 5)
It was clearly recognized that such interdistrict rediscounts
were directly related to the reserve ratios of individual Reserve Banks.
Thus, in its 1918 Annual Report (page 3), the Board stated:
"The Board's policy has been to utilize, in an
appropriate degree, the reserves of the 12 Federal
Reserve Banks with the purpose of avoiding undue
variations in their reserve position. Discount
transactions between the banks have not, as a rule,
been negotiated between banks themselves, but through
the medium of the Federal Reserve Board, instructions
being given by telegraph and transfers incident to the
operations were effected in the same way."
Again, in its 1921 Annual Report (page 42), the Board stated:
"Reserve ratios of Federal Reserve Banks,
considered separately, are closely related to the

rediscount transactions between Federal Reserve Banks.
A Federal Reserve Bank will seek rediscount accommodations from other reserve banks at times when its own
reserve is insufficient, without declining to a point
below the legal minimum, to supply the credit demands
of its member banks. ..

"

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

-10-

After 1921, the only interdistrict rediscounting
transaction occurred in March 1933 when, because of an unusual flow
of bank reserves away from New York, the New York Federal Reserve
Bank was required to borrow from other Reserve Banks in order to avoid
a reserve deficiency. (1933 Federal Reserve Bulletin 211)
During the early years of the System, the rediscounting of

eligible paper among the Reserve Banks was the most logical method of
distributing resources in order to avoid reserve deficiencies.

Sales

of Government securities between the Reserve Banks for this purpose did
not occur, it is presumed, for the reason that the volume of Government
securities held by the Reserve Banks was minimal during those years.
After the enactment of the Banking Act of 1933, which gave
statutory status to the Federal Open Market Committee, and the great
increase in holdings of Government securities by the Reserve Banks,
the shifting of resources to avoid reserve deficiencies gradually came
to be accomplished through allocations of participations in the System
Open Market Account. This development was brought to the attention
of Congress on a number of occasions.
For example, when Governor Eccles testified before the
Banking and Currency Committees of Congress in 1945, in support of
legislation to reduce the gold reserve requirements, he stated:
I do not know what the ratios would be if we did
"..
not shift back and forth between the Reserve Banks to
keep the reserves balanced out. . . ."

(Hearings before

House Banking and Currency Committee on H. R. 2124,
February 27, 1945, p. 9)
". ..

As a matter of fact today we are adjusting the

holdings of Government securities between the various
Reserve Banks almost daily to try to keep their reserve
ratios as nearly equal as possible. . . ."

(Hearings

before Senate Banking and Currency Committee on S. 510,
February 20, 1945, p. 31)
In 1949, in a statement submitted by the Board to the Joint
Committee on the Economic Report, the Board stated:
". .. Adjustments may be made in the allocations of
securities in the System Open Market Account from time
to time if the reserve position of a particular Federal
Reserve Bank indicates that an adjustment is desirable."
(Hearings before the Subcommittee on Monetary, Credit,
and Fiscal Policies of the Joint Committee on the
Economic Report, November 16, 1949, p. 38)

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 4/17/2020

Board of Governors

-11-

From the foregoing, it is clear that the practice of
distributing assets among the Reserve Banks, whether by interdistrict
rediscounting or by the allocation or adjustment of Government securities in the Open Market Account in order to avoid reserve deficiencies
at individual Reserve Banks, has been considered legitimate and appropriate throughout the existence of the Federal Reserve System and that
this practice has been made known to Congress on numerous occasions.
Despite amendments to provisions of the Act regarding reserve requirements and open market operations, neither Congress nor its Committees
have ever questioned the legality of the practice. Under traditional
rules of statutory construction, such long-established administrative
practice, known to, and not disapproved by, the legislature, provides
additional strong support, if it were needed, for the conclusion that
such allocations of participations in the Open Market Account to avoid
reserve deficiencies in individual Reserve Banks is consistent not only
with the letter but with the spirit of the relevant provisions of law.