View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
July 2, 1991
Sam Y. Cross

When you met here in mid-May the dollar had entered a period of
temporary stability.

The exuberance of the dollar's recovery in

February and March had faded in light of uncertainties about the
timing and strength of the anticipated U. S. economic recovery and the
dollar was fluctuating with no clear trend.

Since then, however, the

dollar ratcheted up another notch, and rose by about 5 to 6 percent on
average in the intermeeting period, though the rise was nearly 8 percent against the mark and less than 1 percent against the yen.
Sentiment toward the dollar remains positive; July has started out
with further upward movement and there is a widespread view in the
market that the dollar still has upside potential.
The latest boost in sentiment began in late May.

A series of

economic data, starting with housing and personal income, persuaded
many market participants that the U. S. recovery was, in fact, underway and might also be more robust than previously foreseen.

Soon

thereafter, the dollar received further reinforcement from political
and economic uncertainty in Germany, particularly following a state
election victory by the opposition Social Democrats in early June.
Although market participants were wary how the monetary authorities
might respond to the dollar's renewed rise, they bid the dollar up,
especially against the mark, during the first half of June.
As the dollar rose, market participants recognized that the rally
might be causing problems for Germany and to a lesser degree Japan.

Throughout the spring, German officials had pointed to the need for a
strong mark to assist the financing of unification.

It was feared

that, in both Germany and Japan, currency weakness might force the
central banks to maintain tighter monetary conditions than were appropriate for purely domestic considerations.

The market was watching

for evidence that the authorities in those countries might try to
forestall such moves by intervening to contain the dollar's rise and
by seeking cooperation from the United States and others in those intervention efforts.
In fact, the Bundesbank did initiate a round of coordinated intervention with most other European central banks and the Bank of Japan
on June 10.

Although the United States did not join, these operations

and expectations of similar ones later on served to dampen the dollar's upward momentum at times.

By mid-June talk had begun to spread

that the G-7 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors would meet
prior to the July summit to arrange a major effort to cap the dollar's
rise.

So when such a meeting was announced for June 23, the dollar

retreated sharply before steadying.
Nevertheless, underlying sentiment towards the dollar continued to
be bolstered by prospects of near-term recovery in the U.S. economy.
As a result, when the initial market interpretation of the G-7 communique was that it offered no new initiative to the dollar, at first
the dollar rose.

But, almost immediately, interpretive comments by a

number of officials--from France, Japan, and Britain--caused the
market to reevaluate its skepticism about the likelihood of coordinated G-7 intervention.

Also, reports began to circulate that the

Bundesbank was selling U.S. Treasury securities.

Market gurus specu-

lated that the German central bank was either building its war chest
for a major intervention or, alternatively, that it was preparing to
buy back accumulated mark reserves from the Federal Reserve and the
Treasury so that the United States would then be in a position to conduct large-scale intervention.

In these circumstances, the dollar

gave back most of its gains in the past week or so since the G-7 meeting.
Other developments last week also tended to weigh on other currencies and thereby helped add to the dollar's attractiveness.

With

respect to the German mark, uncertainty that a controversial withholding tax might be reimposed resurfaced last Thursday when the German
High Court set a deadline for more effective taxation of investment
income.

This led to a sharp sell-off in all mark assets and a broad

decline of the mark against other currencies.

Also, the reemergence

of turmoil in Yugoslavia supported the dollar and weighed on the mark,
reflecting Germany's economic exposure to that nation.
The yen has generally been somewhat less weak than the mark.
Nevertheless, the latest securities scandals have at times made market
participants uneasy about foreign investors' reaction, and have led to
some sapping of the yen's strength in the exchange markets as well as
to renewed weakness in Japan's equity market.

Yesterday, the Bank of

Japan lowered its official discount rate one-half percentage point, to
5-1/2 percent.

Although the timing of the move had not been widely

expected, talk of a lowering of Japanese interest rates had been
around for months and the stock market decline of recent days was seen
by many as likely to argue for an earlier monetary policy action.

The U.S. monetary authorities intervened on only one occasion
during the period; that was in late May when Sweden announced its
decision to link the krona to the ECU.

The change in Sweden's ex-

change rate regime had balance sheet implications for a lot of Swedish
institutions that had borrowed dollars.

With the announcement coming

out late in Europe on a Friday, the dollar/mark market was the only
one still open to absorb the hedging operations these institutions
needed to do, and the rush to hedge prompted a temporary but sharp
rise in the dollar against the mark.

These pressures were met by sub-

stantial intervention by the Bundesbank and the Swedish Riksbank.

The

Desk sold $50 million in cooperation with that effort.
The only other operation during the period is one we have already
reported--the off-market currency exchange with the Bundesbank.

As

you know, we agreed to exchange, at market rates, DM 10 billion for
approximately $5.5 billion, with the Federal Reserve exchanging DM 6
billion and the Treasury DM 4 billion.

These exchanges are to occur

in installments, the first of which was for DM 4 billion, which
settled on June 27, and the remaining six are each for DM 1 billion
and will occur on agreed dates over the next six months.

Entering

this arrangement immediately reduced the Federal Reserve's exposure,
or net open position, by the full DM 6 billion.

The exchange produced

for the Federal Reserve a realized profit of $103.4 million on the
first transaction and an estimated $139 million more on the remaining
six transactions.
Mr. Chairman, I would like to request the Committee's approval of
the operations of the period.

July 1,

1991

FOMC MEETING NOTES
JULY 2 - 3, 1991

JOAN E. LOVETT
Desk operations during the intermeeting period were
geared to maintaining unchanged reserve conditions, expected to
be associated with Federal funds trading in the area of
5 3/4 percent.

The borrowing allowance was raised for technical

reasons in light of normal springtime increases in seasonal use.
The allowance was raised in four steps by a total of $125 million, bringing it to $325 million.

Actual borrowing ran a bit

above the allowance over the first three periods, reflecting
occasional use of the adjustment facility by larger banks.

For

the period in progress, it is running considerably higher in the
early days in part because of reserve shortages at quarter-end.
The funds rate was reasonably steady throughout the intermeeting
period, averaging pretty close to the 5 3/4 percent central
point.

The quarter-end saw relatively mild rate pressure, but

skimpy reserve balances led to a firming by the close which has
carried into the early days of this week.
Reserve management was pretty uneventful during the
first two maintenance periods.

Rising reserve needs were

anticipated and were met through a combination of outright
purchases and RPs, mostly of the customer variety.

The purchases

came to $3.6 billion, including about $1.1 billion of bills and
notes purchased from foreign accounts and $2.5 billion of bills

-2-

purchased in the market on May 29.

The market generally expected

a stable Fed policy stance but, near the outset of the period, a
soft funds rate in conjunction with a weaker durable goods report
generated some market discussion which the Desk dampened with a
round of MSPs.
Reserve needs were much more uncertain in the third
period, which was characterized by large revisions to the outlook
moving through the period.

Uncertainty about the timing and

magnitude of June tax payments to the Treasury was the key
difficulty.

Many market analysts appeared to be having similar

difficulty and, consequently, anticipated Desk operations on
either side of the market depending on these flows.

In fact, we

drained reserves twice and added on three occasions, acting when
the weight of the estimates and reserve market conditions
suggested the need.

The operations added on balance.

The period in progress showed a fairly sizable reserve
need, and our early actions were designed to start meeting it as
well as to assure sufficient clearing balances over the quarterend weekend.

However, market demand for these reserves was not

there at the time as most participants apparently felt adequately
positioned.

Thus, dealers terminated early the bulk of the 4-day

RPs we had arranged and gave us only meager propositions when we
tried to replace them.

As a result, clearing balances over the

quarter-end weekend were skimpy, and we got $1.5 billion of

-3-

borrowing.

Given current and prospective needs, we again began

supplementing our RPs with outright purchases from foreign
accounts over recent days, buying a total of about $300 million
in the period underway.
Following your last meeting, market interest rates
were, on the whole, generally steady over the remainder of May.
Data at month's end soon gave rise to rumblings about an earlierthan-expected recovery, and the surprise increase in May NFP
announced in early June put a focus on both an earlier and
potentially stronger rebound.

Market rates rose a solid 20 to

35 basis points by mid-June as the new outlook was factored in
and, except for very short maturities, the increases came pretty
much across the yield curve.

Following the employment report, a

fairly steady stream of data added to the notion that the economy
had begun up the path to recovery, as did remarks by Federal
Reserve officials.
Having discounted the recovery early on, differing
views about its strength and sustainability caused some trimming
in rates on Treasury issues over the balance of June.
Market views on this score are divided.

Some see a healthy

though not vigorous rebound, and others still look for anemic
growth or downside risks.

Supporting arguments for each case

have left participants in a guarded mode.

The "standard"

consensus probably calls for real growth around 3 percent over

articles on the health of the banking system and periodic drops
in equity prices here and abroad acted at times to suppress the
rate rise.

The Treasury issued a net of $24 billion in bills

during the period.

The auction held yesterday--for a record

$20.8 billion--brought average issuing rates of 5.59 and
5.71 percent, respectively, on new 3- and 6-month issues,
compared with rates of 5.50 and 5.63 percent just prior to your
last meeting.
Private short-term rates also rose by about 10 to
25 basis points.
only a little.

For most of the period, quality spreads widened
The default by Columbia Gas System on some

maturing CP elicited a fairly muted response in the paper of
other issuers, apparently because its particular financial
difficulties were deemed specific to the company.

Despite the

focus on the banking system, quality spreads there were also
fairly quiescent--in fact modestly narrower--until late in the
period.

The ease with which this market slipped the other way

suggests that the recent stability was tentative.

The Wells

Fargo announcement on June 25 caught the market off-guard and
aroused fresh concerns about asset quality more broadly.

Rumors

of various banking problems surfaced over the remainder of the
week.

The so-called "TED" spread widened out by 9 basis points

on the last week, with downward pressure on longer-term BHC debt
and equity prices resuming.

After adjusting higher through mid-June, intermediate
and longer Treasury maturities settled into a trading range.

The

long bond approached 8 5/8 percent briefly but receded back to
around 8 1/2 percent thereafter.

The Treasury raised some

$18 billion of new cash in this sector during the period.

It

appears that Treasury net marketable borrowing came in pretty
close to the $40 billion second quarter estimate provided by the
Treasury at the time of the May refunding.

Associated cash

balances look to have finished the quarter about $9 billion
higher.
The Treasury's May 2-year note auction commanded a fair
amount of market attention early on and again more recently.

In

that auction, as you recall, a few bidders stepped ahead of the
market talk, spurring reports of concentrated holdings and fears
of shortages.

When the issue subsequently began to rise in price

in both the cash and financing markets, cries of "foul ball" were
heard from some participants.

Others at the time seemed to feel

that this was the byproduct of trading strategies that the market
should be able to take in stride, so long as it did not pose a
threat to the process going forward.
Market discussion of the matter seemed to fade when the
issue began to move back toward more normal alignment on the
yield curve, though it remained relatively expensive in financing
markets.

However, concern resurfaced later in June as the market

approached another auction of 2-year notes.

Most participants

were fearful of setting up pre-auction short positions given the
prior experience.

The normal spread between the outstanding and

when-issued security widened out going into the auction and it
has moved even further over recent days.

Given the caution, the

auction came a little behind immediate pre-auction when-issued
trading.

Meanwhile, the Treasury has been reviewing its auction

procedures with a view to probable change amid signs of
discomfort with the auction process.
On the whole, rates on intermediate and longer Treasury
coupon issues ended the period about 15 to 20 basis points
higher.

In the 2-year area, rates were roughly 10 basis points

lower to 10 basis points higher though there was a flare-up in
volatility there today for reasons that are not entirely clear.
Finally, in other markets, corporate spreads remained
quite tight despite sizable new issuance throughout the period.
There is currently some debate in the market about whether such
narrow spreads can be maintained.

The municipal calendar was

also large, in part reflecting heavy issuance of short-term notes
going into the June 30 fiscal year-end of many states.

A number

of these entities are struggling with severe budget problems
which placed some upward pressure on their yields.

The

Bridgeport bankruptcy filing generated little fallout.

Michael J. Prell
July 2, 1991

CHART SHOW PRESENTATION -- DOMESTIC ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

As you know, recent data have been almost uniformly positive,
providing strong evidence of a turn in the economy.

Chart 1 displays

the Commerce Department's composite indexes of economic indicators.
The leading indicators, in the top panel, have risen every month since
January, and according to our LEI-based probability model, we can be
highly confident now that a recovery is in train.
The coincident indicators, in the bottom panel, have begun to
confirm the upturn, flattening out in April and edging up in May.
This suggests that the trough month probably will be March or April,
and I've used April and the second quarter in these and subsequent
charts.
Of course, all this leaves some important questions
unanswered--notably, what the character of the ensuing expansion will
be and what it will bring in terms of inflation and the U.S. external
position.

Chart 2 begins the examination of these questions.

The top panel shows four-quarter percent changes in real GNP.
It is apparent that the expansion we've projected for the next year
and a half is more subdued than most of the prior upswings plotted.
It is tempting to say, simply, that mild recessions, such as that we
just experienced, naturally beget mild upturns.

In fact, the

correlation is quite good, but, given that it is based on a small
sample, one might not want to depend on it.

In any event, I know that

you would feel deprived if you did not have the benefit of our
insightful--or at least lengthy--analysis of the forecast.
We see three major factors underlying the turnaround in the
economy.

The first two of these are basically the reversal of the

negative forces unleashed by the Gulf crisis last summer:

namely, the

jump in oil prices and the sudden plunge in consumer and business
confidence regarding economic prospects.

The third factor is the

interest rate decline fostered by the System and the easing in
financial market conditions more generally, reflected in narrowing
risk premia and improved access to the capital markets for many
financial and nonfinancial firms.
Of these three influences, the monetary stimulus is perhaps
the most difficult to assess, for the indicators in this area are
rather ambiguous.

For example, although interest rates have come down

in recent quarters, they've not declined as much as in some other
recessions, especially at the long end of the maturity spectrum.

This

could mean that the monetary impulse has been less, or perhaps that
the expected returns on capital have held up better.

Looking at the

monetary aggregates, M2 hasn't accelerated the way it did in past
recessions, but, of course, we no longer have the deposit rate
ceilings that played such a big part in the past and there have been
notable changes in patterns of intermediation that may be
accommodating the flow of funds to investors with little adverse
effect on aggregate demand.

And then there is the rise in the dollar

this year, which might suggest a restrained monetary policy, but may
reflect, importantly, an elevation of expectations regarding U.S.

economic performance.

Sifting through all of this, we conclude that

the economy currently is benefitting from an expansionary monetary
impulse, but probably one of lesser magnitude than those in some other
cycles.
There are, to be sure, some other, sectoral considerations
that distinguish this upturn from earlier ones, and these are
reflected in the table at the bottom of the page.

The table shows the

contributions of various expenditure categories to the projected
increase in real GNP, comparing the current upswing to those that
began in 1961, 1970, 1975, and 1982.

In light of the uncertainty

about which quarter the NBER eventually will select as the latest
trough, I've shown calculations based on both the first and second
quarters of this year.

As it turns out, it doesn't matter much which

of those two quarters is used--the picture is fundamentally the same.
I'd offer the following observations on these data:
(1) The first-year GNP increase we've projected is smaller
than the 5-1/2 percent average of the prior upturns; only the upturn
after 1970, at 3.2 percent, fell short of the 6 percent mark.
(2) Inventory investment, the next-to-last line, is likely to
provide its usual boost to production; aggressive destocking has laid
the groundwork for a sizable swing in inventory investment, even while
businesses maintain a tight hold on ratios of stocks to sales.
(3) As the memo item indicates, it is final sales that
account for the smaller gain in GNP this time.
(4) Consumption, construction and government purchases all
look to be areas of subpar contribution, while we think that exports

will make a relatively healthy contribution to GNP over the coming
year.
I'll be exploring those relatively weak components of
domestic demand in the next few charts, and Ted will be addressing the
outlook for the external sector.
Turning to chart 3, a basic premise of our forecast is that
the personal saving rate is so low now that it would be unreasonable
to anticipate that consumer spending will outstrip the growth of
disposable income.

The saving rate was 3.6 percent in May, according

to last week's release, and it edges up to just 4 percent in our
projection.
One is given at least slight pause in this cautious
assessment when one looks back at late 1982.

Then, too, the saving

rate was low by the standards of prior years and household debt
burdens were historically high.

Indeed, as you can see in the middle

panels, at the end of the '82 recession, consumers themselves were
reporting an unwillingness to use savings or to borrow for major
purchases rather similar to what they are saying today.

Yet spending

proceeded to vastly outstrip income growth in the ensuing expansion.
In contrast to 1982, however, we are starting at a lower saving rate
and, as shown in the bottom panel, we are coming off a period of
extraordinary accumulation of durable goods, rather than a deep
recession in which an appreciable pent-up demand developed.
Our judgment is that the current concerns about financial
stress in the household sector probably are, once again, overdone, but

that, unless there is a surge in household wealth like that in the
1980s, consumption is unlikely to outpace income growth.
In search of that income growth, then, let me turn to the
construction sector--which is treated in your next chart.

In past

expansions, private construction activity--in particular,
homebuilding--provided substantial impetus to job and income growth in
the first year.

The thrust probably will be considerably less

impressive this time.

Housing starts and sales have picked up in

recent months and should increase further.

But we see a couple of

limiting factors on the supply side of the market.

The first of these

is illustrated in the top panel, which shows the remarkable rise in
the number of vacant housing units during the past decade.

A

testament to the potency of builder optimism and lender profligacy,
the existing overhang of unoccupied units is likely to damp prices and
new construction in a good many markets.

The other negative supply

factor is the marked shift in credit availability for land acquisition
and development, even in the single-family sector; we continue to
think the problem here is often overstated, but we don't think it is
non-existent.

Many smaller, less well capitalized builders

undoubtedly are encountering some difficulty in finding financing even
for sound projects.
There is, of course, a similar problem in the nonresidential
construction sector.

As the middle panel shows, contracts for private

nonresidential building--the solid line--have been trending downward
for a while and construction activity has a considerable way to go to
catch up.

In past expansions, nonresidential construction has lagged

the general business upturn by a few quarters, but in this instance we
expect that it may be at least a couple of years before construction
turns around.

Justifiably, in terms of the damage it has been doing

to financial institutions, the commercial real estate bust has been
the focus of much attention.

The bottom left panel indicates that

office vacancy rates remain very high, and with prices and rents
remaining soft, lenders are likely to be preoccupied for some time

with managing their losses and with avoiding new exposures.

Other

commercial properties also appear to be in ample supply; although the
imbalance probably is less serious than that for offices, a
significant upturn in building probably will be slow in coming.

All

that said, though, the panel at the right is intended to provide a
reminder that these sectors represent rather small parts of the
economy:

investment in office and other commercial structures is less

than a percent of GNP.

In sum, as far as construction activity is

concerned, it is residential--not nonresidential--building that is
likely to be the important story in terms of subpar impetus to
economic expansion over the coming year.
I've mentioned financial concerns with respect to both the
household and business sector.

While there clearly are some strains

in the financial markets that will linger for a while, we don't
believe that they represent a serious impediment to expansion--at
least not to the kind of moderate upswing we're projecting.

The top

panel of chart 5 shows our projection of borrowing, scaled by nominal
GNP.

As you can see, we believe that the projected level of spending

can be financed with still low rates of credit growth.

The middle

panel reveals one reason why we don't anticipate heavy borrowing by
businesses:

namely, we believe that firms will not be engaging in the

kind of leveraging that produced massive net share retirements--the
red line--in the 1980s.

Similarly, in the household sector, with real

after-tax interest rates high on consumer loans, with asset values not
providing the same support for expanded borrowing, and with the
pressure less intense to buy new big-ticket durables, we expect
borrowing to pick up only a bit in the period ahead.

We believe that

these private credit needs and those of the government sector can be
met without undue strain on financial intermediaries.
Speaking of the government sector, chart 6 focuses on the
federal component.

The top panel compares federal purchases in this

cycle versus other recent cycles.

Notably, purchases are expected to

be weaker in the coming year--the solid red line--than in any other
expansion with the exception of that following the 1970 recession--the
dashed red line.

Interestingly, that too was a period of military

retrenchment and, as I noted earlier, of relatively weak economic
recovery.
The middle panel shows our measure of the impetus being
delivered to aggregate demand by discretionary fiscal policy action.
The budget agreement reached last year implies significant restraint
during this recovery.

This is a considerable departure from the

experience in some earlier cycles, when there were tax cuts, social
security benefit hikes, or other stimulative actions as the economy
pulled out of the recession.

-8-

This difference is visible in the unified budget figures,
shown below.

When one strips out the foreign contributions to the

Defense Cooperation Account and the effects of deposit insurance, the
widening of the unified deficit this fiscal year is fairly mild--and
in significant part explained by Desert Storm outlays.
Like the federal government, states and localities are facing
significant budgetary constraints at present.

The top panel of chart

7 shows that the operating and capital account deficit of the state
and local sector has become very deep over the past few years.

This

gap has developed in a different way than did those in the past.

The

persistent gaps of the 1960s reflected heavy infrastructure
investment, largely financed by federal grants or borrowing rather
than by taxation; as you can see in the bottom panel, structures
outlays have been trending upward once again in the past decade, but
they don't loom as large relative to the overall size of the sector's
expenditures as they did in the '60s.

The deficits in the mid-'70s

and early '80s were basically transitory phenomena related to cyclical
shortfalls in revenues.

But the recent deficit emerged during a

period of economic expansion, and reflects in large measure a
structural problem of tax limitations and growing demands for
services.

The pressures have been exacerbated by the imposition on

states and localities of burdens mandated by federal initiatives-without commensurate grants.
In any event, these units are now responding in a variety of
ways to the fiscal imbalance.

We are seeing both higher taxes--some

of which are adding directly to measured inflation--and spending

-9-

cutbacks.

In many cases, those spending cutbacks are from very

ambitious plans, and so they don't imply large absolute declines.

And

they often are in transfer payments or in compensation rates--neither
of which is directly reflected in the GNP component, real purchases of
goods and services.

Nonetheless, we anticipate enough layoffs and

construction postponements to produce a relatively weak contribution
to economic expansion from state and local purchases.
Chart 8 summarizes the inflation outlook associated with our
projection of a moderate expansion.

The top panel shows our forecast

that, as usual, much of the initial increase in output will be
achieved through increases in labor productivity.

Thus, as indicated

in the middle panel, unemployment will be slow to drop off and is
expected to remain well above 6 percent through next year.
The red shaded areas in the middle and bottom panels
highlight periods when the actual unemployment rate has been above the
nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment, or NAIRU.

Not

surprisingly, given that this estimate of the NAIRU is derived from
the observed relation of unemployment and inflation, you can see that
these periods have generally witnessed decelerations of consumer
prices.

Because we anticipate that the slack in the labor market will

remain significant, and pressures on plant capacity modest, we expect
to see inflation trending downward through 1992.
Ted will now continue the briefing.
**************

E. M. Truman
July 2, 1991

Chart Show Presentation --

International Developments

Chart 9 summarizes the staff's outlook for the U.S.
external accounts.

The major factors affecting that outlook are

presented in the box at the top of the chart.
The principal factor is the recovery of U.S. domestic
demand which will stimulate demand for imports.

At the same

time, we expect a moderate pickup in growth on average in the
major foreign industrial countries.

This will help to support

U.S. recovery.
On the negative side for domestic growth, we are
projecting that most of the recent strength of the dollar will
persist over the forecast period.

On our weighted-average basis,

with the rise today, the dollar has risen close to 6 percent
since the May Committee meeting.

We continue to think that some

of the influences tending to push the dollar up are temporary,
and that the dollar will drift off a bit from its recent highs.
However, we are now projecting that the dollar will average about
5 percent higher over the forecast period than in the May
Greenbook.

This tends to restrain the domestic expansion as well

as inflation.
A neutral element in our outlook is the assumption
that oil prices will remain near current levels.

This is based

on our belief that Saudi Arabia will adjust its production to

-

2 -

avoid any substantial price fluctuations, especially as Iraq and
Kuwait resume exporting.
The lower panel summarizes the effects of these various
factors on our projection of U.S. external balances.

As the red

line indicates, real net exports of goods and services will make
a small negative net contribution to U.S. real GNP over the
forecast period -- about 20 billion 1982 dollars over the seven
quarters from the first quarter of this year through the end of
next year.

Meanwhile, the current account is projected to settle

down to a deficit of about $45 billion by the fourth quarter of
this year after the contributions to the Defense Cooperation
Account are no longer coming in.

Next year, the deficit should

widen to somewhat more than $50 billion.

However, compared with

several years ago, deficits of this size would be a substantial
improvement both in absolute terms and as a percentage of GNP.

The next chart summarizes recent developments with
respect to exchange rates and interest rates.

As is shown by the

red line in the top panel, the dollar through June on average had
appreciated about 15 percent in real, or price-adjusted, terms
since its low of February [July 2 about 2 percent above June
average].

On this basis, the dollar was only about 3 percent

above its average value since February 1987, the post-Louvre
period.

Roughly the same relationship holds for the Deutschemark

and the yen; however, in nominal terms against the DM, the rate
today is essentially the same as at the Louvre meeting [183.05
compared with 153.65 for the yen].

-

3 -

The dollar's rise over the first half of 1991 appears to
have been fueled by the quick and successful end of the Gulf War
and, more recently, by prospects of a stronger U.S. recovery than
earlier anticipated.

At the same time, special factors have

affected some of the other currencies.

Political factors within

Germany and in the Soviet Union and, more recently, Yugoslavia
have weighed on the DM along with a growing sense that the
Bundesbank is constrained not to move aggressively against
incipient inflation forces in that country.

Thus, as is shown in

the box at the left in the middle panel, so far this year through
the end of June, the dollar appreciated 21 percent against the
DM, but only 3 percent against the yen, and it depreciated
slightly against the Canadian dollar.
The black line in the upper panel indicates that U.S.
real long-term interest rates have risen relative to rates abroad
this year.

It is clear from the box at the right in the middle

panel and the charts in the lower panel that, while U.S. shortterm interest rates have fallen more than rates abroad, U.S.
long-term rates have risen somewhat at the same time that rates
abroad have tended to decline.

Developments since last Friday

have tended to reinforce these trends in long-term rates.

Such a

shift in the structure of interest rates is consistent with the
expectation of a recovery in the U.S. economy, the likelihood
that U.S. interest rates will be higher at some point in the
future (particularly relative to foreign rates), and, therefore,
the strengthening of the dollar that we have seen.

-

4 -

Cyclical patterns abroad vary considerably from country
to country.

The top panels of Chart 11 illustrate the very

different patterns of industrial production in the major
industrial economies.

Production in Japan and Germany is still

expanding at quite rapid rates on a year-over-year basis.
As is suggested by the data on consumer prices presented in the
middle panels, these countries still face what for them is high
inflation.
Meanwhile, Canada and the United Kingdom remain in
recession, though we think that the Canadian economy may be
pulling out of its decline.

Data on consumer price inflation in

these two countries are distorted by a number of special factors:
In Canada, by the introduction of the Goods and Services Tax and,
in the United Kingdom, by the removal of the influence of rising
mortgage interest rates and the poll tax.

Nevertheless, enough

slack has opened up in both economies that inflation pressures
are receding.

Production is weak in France and Italy, pressures

on capacity have been reduced, and unemployment is rising.

As a

consequence, there has been a further narrowing of the gap
between inflation in these countries and inflation in Germany.
Indeed, the inflation gap between France and Germany essentially
has been eliminated.
As is summarized in the box at the bottom of the page,
we anticipate that growth will be slowing in Germany and Japan
over the balance of this year following very strong first
quarters.

Inflation remains a concern for the authorities in

these countries.

-

5 -

Meanwhile, we think we can detect tentative signs of
pickup in some of the weaker economies.
Against this background, we expect that monetary
policies will remain cautious, but interest rates may decline
further in some countries as inflation eases.

We expect that

fiscal policy in Germany will become somewhat tighter after the
expansion this year, assuming policy is not paralyzed by the
political process.

Fiscal policies are likely to be on the

contractionary side on average in the other countries.
The next chart summarizes our projection for growth and
inflation abroad.

The upper left panel shows that foreign

growth, weighted by shares in U.S. nonagricultural exports,
slowed during 1990.

Growth in the first half of this year

remained at about the same weak rate as in the second half of
last year.

We are projecting a recovery toward 3 percent over

the second half of this year -- a bit less pronounced than the
projected recovery of the U.S. economy -- and a further rise to
near 3-1/2 percent next year -- somewhat stronger than U.S.

growth.

As can be seen in the box at the right, the major

foreign industrial countries -- the G-6 countries -- account for

most of the pickup in foreign growth on average.
The middle panel provides greater detail on our
forecasts for the G-6 countries.

While economic activity in

Germany and Japan has held up well on balance through the first
half of this year, we expect that reported real GNP actually
declined in the second quarter.

After this pause, growth is

projected to be moderate in the second half, followed by somewhat

-

6 -

more rapid expansion next year.

Growth slowed in France and

Italy at the end of last year and in the first half of this year
partly under the influence of higher oil prices and a decline in
confidence.

Both factors have now turned around, and we are

expecting a modest pickup in the second half of the year and in
1992.
From the standpoint of our non-agricultural exports,
Canada and the United Kingdom are important markets; Canada is
our largest market, and the United Kingdom is our fourth largest
after Japan and Mexico.

We anticipate that the recessions in

Canada and the United Kingdom will come to end in the second half
of the year, if they have not already, and this should provide a
boost to demand for U.S. exports.

In Canada, in particular,

orders, retail sales, and housing starts are pointing to a
pickup.

In the United Kingdom, the story is more of a bottoming

out and a recovery of confidence.

Growth in these countries next

year should be respectable but not buoyant, that is, a bit less
than the estimated growth of potential output.
Partly as a consequence of the projected moderate
recovery and expansion in the G-6 countries other than Germany
and Japan, inflation is expected to decline substantially in
these countries, as is shown in the lower left panel of the
chart.

However, some of this improvement is a statistical

artifact associated with special one-time factors, such as the
Goods and Services Tax in Canada, that will not be present in
1992.

Nevertheless, the gap between underlying inflation in

these countries and the average rate in Japan and Germany is

-

7 -

projected to narrow substantially.

As is shown in the box at the

right, the gap between U.S. inflation and the average for all of
the G-6 should be fairly small.
Chart 13 summarizes various influences on two important
components of the outlook for our external accounts:
nonagricultural exports and non-oil imports.

Using our

econometric model, we have tried to decompose the sources of
expansion and contraction affecting these broad categories of
merchandise trade.

In the case of nonagricultural exports, the

top panel, the striped bars show that these exports have been
expanding, and are expected to continue to expand, at annual
rates of 30 to 40 billion 1982 dollars.

As is shown by the red

bars, foreign growth over the second half of 1990 and the first
half of 1991 has made a very modest contribution to that growth,
but in the forecast period, the contribution will increase
substantially.

Meanwhile, relative price effects, which include

not only the dollar's performance but the also behavior of prices
and costs here and abroad, have been and will be important in
1991, but will decline in significance next year.
Turning to non-oil imports, the lower panel, the turn in
U.S. growth, the red bars, is the dominant factor producing the
swing in non-oil imports.

While relative prices were less of a

positive factor boosting imports in the first half of this year,
compared with 1990, they do not have a major influence in our
outlook for non-oil imports.
My last chart considers the external sector as the
transmission mechanism from the rest of the world to the U.S.

-

economy.

8 -

In particular, it addresses the influence of the

dollar's rise since February, and the possible consequences of
continued weak growth on average abroad.

To construct the

alternative scenarios presented in the chart, we employed the
staff's econometric models and used as a baseline the Greenbook
forecast extended through 1993, with M2 growth at 5-1/2 percent
and U.S. real GNP growth at 2-1/2 percent.
In the first alternative, we assumed the dollar remained
at its February level, almost 15 percent lower than what is built
into the current Greenbook forecast.

However, the federal funds

rate is unchanged from the assumption underlying the baseline.
By itself, the February Dollar scenario would imply somewhat
higher growth of real GNP this year and substantially higher
growth in 1992 and 1993.

In contrast with the baseline, the

lower level of the dollar is sustained, and its effects tend to
cumulate.

By the end of 1992, the unemployment rate would be

back at 5-1/2 percent, and it drops below 4-1/2 percent by the
end of 1993.

Not surprisingly, the inflation of GNP prices picks

up noticeably by 1993.
One curious feature of this scenario is that foreign
growth is higher on average in 1993 than in the baseline.

The

reason is that relative to our baseline forecast, the Canadian
dollar appreciates only slightly against the U.S. dollar but
depreciates against the non-dollar currencies; this tends to
stimulate the Canadian economy as does the faster U.S. growth.
Moreover, we have assumed that interest rates in Canada track
interest rates in the United States; as a consequence, they

-

9 -

decline in real terms along with U.S. rates, which also
stimulates the Canadian economy.

Higher growth in Canada

outweighs lower growth in Japan, Germany and the rest of European
countries compared with the baseline forecast.
Overall, the U.S. current account deficit at the end of
1993 is somewhat more than half its size in the baseline.
In assessing this alternative scenario, it is
interesting to recall that the interest rate assumption that went
along with the lower dollar exchange rates in the staff's
judgmental forecast back in February was higher than what we now
are assuming -- the federal funds rate was about 100 basis points
higher.

The level of U.S. economic activity projected in

February for the fourth quarter of 1992 was almost exactly the
same as we are now projecting.
We tried a modification of the February Dollar scenario
in our econometric models.

In it, the dollar remained at its

February level, but the federal funds rate was adjusted to leave
the path of U.S. real GNP essentially the same as in the baseline
forecast.

Our models suggest that to achieve this result, the

federal funds rate today would have to be about 130 basis points
higher now and increase about another 20 basis points or so over
the course of 1992.

Given all the factors that can affect our

forecasts, this correspondence of judgmental and model-based
results is remarkably close.

In essence, it can be said that the

decline in the funds rate has offset the unexpected strength of
the dollar.

-

10 -

The second alternative scenario hypothesizes continued
weak foreign growth.

We manipulated the demand side of the

models to ensure that foreign growth, weighted by U.S.
nonagricultural exports, remains at about 1-1/2 percent -roughly the rate that prevailed over the second half of 1990 and
the first half of 1991.

Again, the federal funds rate was

unchanged from the baseline.
Such a scenario of weak foreign growth has little effect
on the growth of U.S. real GNP this year, but it would chop off
about 3/4 of a percentage point next year, and almost twice that
much in 1993.

As a consequence, the performance of GNP prices is

considerably better than in the baseline.

However, the current

balance deteriorates substantially.
To compensate for the lower foreign growth, the models
suggested that the funds rate would have to be about 50 basis
points lower over the second half of this year and roughly 100
basis points lower by the end of next year.
I would caution the Committee that this second scenario
is rather extreme.

While we do not have perfect foresight about

the foreign outlook, and it certainly could be somewhat weaker in
the short term, we believe the chances are very small of
sustained weakness on the scale assumed for purposes of
constructing this alternative.
On that reassuring note, I'll turn our presentation back
to Mike Prell.

Michael J. Prell
July 2, 1991

CHART SHOW PRESENTATION -- CONCLUSION

The final exhibit summarizes the forecasts you provided last
week.

There doesn't appear to be vast disagreement among you:

all of

you project a moderate upturn in activity, declining unemployment, and
inflation moving below the recent trend by next year.

Whether there

was as much consistency in the assumptions you made regarding policy
will, of course, become clearer in the discussion ahead.
Because the law requires that we report on how our objectives
relate to the Administration's economic forecast, I've shown their
current numbers--which are those from February.

The Mid-session

budget review is due later this month, and it will include new
numbers.

My sense is that the changes will be small, perhaps mainly a

reduction in the forecast of inflation, bringing it closer to your
central tendency.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR) CLASS I-FOMC

Materialfor

Staff Presentationto the
FederalOpen Market Committee
July 2, 1991

Chart 1

COMPOSITE INDEX OF LEADING ECONOMIC INDICATORS

Index, 1967=100
180

-

-

1977

1983

1986

1974

1977

1980

1983

90

1989

PROBABILITY OF EXPANSION, BASED ON LEADING INDICATORS *

1971

120

-

1974

150

Percent

1986

1989

*Each observation represents the probability that an expansion has begun or will begin during the next three months.

INDEX OF COINCIDENT INDICATORS

Index, 1967=100

-

1971

1974

1977

1980

1983

1986

1989

150

Chart 2

REAL GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT

1960

1964

1968

4-quarter percent change

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

Contributions to Real GNP Growth in the First Year of Expansion

(percentage points)
Current Cycle
91:Q1 Trough
91:Q2 Trough
GNP
Personal consumption
Producers' durable equipment
Construction
Government purchases (ex. CCC)
Exports of goods and services
Imports of goods and services
Inventories (incl. CCC)
MEMO: Final sales (ex. CCC)
*1961, 1970, 1975 and 1982.

Average of Four
Earlier Cycles*

3.2

3.7

5.5

1.8
.4
.1
-. 1
.7
-1.0
1.3

1.7
.6
.2
-. 2
1.1
-1.1
1.5

3.2
.6
1.1
.4
.2
-1.2
1.4

1.9

2.2

4.2

Chart 3

PERSONAL SAVINGS RATE

Percen
12

9

6

3

0
1950

1956

1968

1962

WILLINGNESS TO USE SAVINGS

Percent

1974

1980

1986

WILLINGNESS TO BORROW

1992

Percent
40

FMichigan Survey
30

20

10

I
1982

1985

1988

1991

I

1982

I

I

I

1985

1988

PER HOUSEHOLD EXPENDITURE ON DURABLES

1991

0

Ratio scale
5000

1982 dollars
4000
3000

h-

2000

1950

1956

1000
1962

1968

1974

1980

1986

1992

Chart 4

VACANT HOUSING UNITS

1960

Millions

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

NONRESIDENTIAL BUILDING

Ratio Scale

Index, December 1982 - 100

Contracts

-May

Construction
May

I

I

I

I

I

1982

1980

I
1984

OFFICE VACANCY RATES

Percent

I

I

I

1986

I
1988

I
1990

NONRESIDENTIAL STRUCTURES--1990

Coldwell Banker
Metropolitan area

1982 dollars

Total

121

Office
Other commercial

1988

1990

17

Utilities and other
1986

20

Drilling and mining

1984

17

Institutional

1982

22

Industrial

1980

19

26

170

Chart 5

NET BORROWING BY NONFINANCIAL SECTORS

Percent of GNP

Total
Households and Businesses

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

NONFINANCIAL BUSINESSES - FUNDS RAISED

1992

Percent of GNP
15

Net Borrowing
Net Equity Issuance
10

Net Borrowing

5

0

1968

1972

HOUSEHOLDS-

1976

1980

1984

1988

FUNDS RAISED

1992

Percent of GNP
9

Consumer Credit
Home Mortgages

V
I

I

1968
1968

I

I

I

I

1972
1972

I

I

I
I
1976
1976

I

II
1980
1980

Consumer Credit

1984
1984

1988

1992

1988

1992

Chart 6

REAL FEDERAL PURCHASES (EXCLUDING CCC)

Trough=1.0
1.1

1970:4 Cycle

1.050

1

0.95

0.9

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

Quarters before/after trough

FISCAL IMPETUS

Percent of GNP
1.5

Calendar Years
Stimulus

0.75

Restraint

1960

1965

1970

FEDERAL BUDGET DEFICIT-

1980

1975

1985

UNIFIED BASIS

0.75

1990

Percent of GNP
9

Fiscal Years
Total
Ex DCA* and Deposit Insurance

7

Total

1981
*Defense Cooperation Account

1983

1985

1987

1989

Chart 7

STATE AND LOCAL SURPLUS/DEFICIT

Percent of GNP
1.5

Operating and Capital Accounts
0.75

0

0.75

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1.5

1985

STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT REAL PURCHASES

1990

Billions of 1982 dollars
520

Total

390

260

130

Structures

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

Chart 8

LABOR PRODUCTIVITY

Index, 1982=100
120

Nonfarm Business

110

100

90

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

CIVILIAN UNEMPLOYMENT RATE*

1992

Percent

12

9

6

3

0
1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

PRICES FOR PCE EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY*

1988

1992

4-quarter percent change
12

Fixed-Weight Index
9

6

3

1968

1972

1976

1980

*Shading Indicates periods when unemployment rate exceeds NAIRU.

1984

1988

1992

Chart 9

U.S. External Accounts

MAJOR FACTORS AFFECTING THE EXTERNAL SECTOR

*

Recovery of U.S. domestic demand.

*

Moderate pickup in growth on average in the major foreign
industrial countries.

*

Recent strength of the dollar persists.

*

Oil prices remain near current levels.

EXTERNAL BALANCES
Billions of 1982 dollars, SAAR

Billions of dollars, SAAR

50

50

Billions of dollars

Current Account

annual rate, 04
+

+

0

0

Real Net Exports

1990 1991 1992

Merchandise

50

50

100
Merchandise Trade

1989

1990

1992

-111

-73

-84

Current
Account
100

Trade

-94

-45

-52

-4

-14

Real Net
Exports

- 9

Chart 10

THE DOLLAR AND THE INTEREST DIFFERENTIAL
Percent

Ratio scale, March 1973 = 100

Real long-term
interest differential*

Price-adjusted
Dollar

dollar**

1986

1988

1987

1989

1990

1991

*Difference between rates on long-term U.S. government bonds and a weighted average of foreign G-10 long-term government or public
authority bond rates, adjusted for expected inflation.
" Weighted average against foreign G-10 countries, adjusted by relative consumer prices.

Nominal Interest Rates
Percent

Nominal Dollar Exchange Rates
Percent change
12/90 to 6/28/91

Change

Level

12/90 to 6/28/91

6/28/91

Deutschemark
Pound Sterling
Yen
Canadian Dollar

Three-month
Germany
Japan
U.S.

-0.17
-0.35
-1.76

9.00
7.92
6.06

S. Korean Won
Taiwan Dollar

Long-term
Germany
Japan
U.S.

-0.28
0.04
0.16

8.50
6.78
8.24

SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES

1989

1990

Percent

1991

1 Multilateral trade-weighted average for foreign G 10 countries

LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

1989

1990

Percent

1991

Chart 11

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION*
12-month percent change

1988

1989

CONSUMER PRICES*

1990

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION*
12-month percent change

1991

1988

1989

CONSUMER PRICES*

12-month percent change

1990

1991

12-month percent change

Canada and U.K.
6

France and Italy
4

Germany

2

1988

1990

1991

1988

1990

ECONOMIC POLICY ABROAD
* Growth slowing in Japan and Germany following very strong first
quarters, but inflation concerns remain.
* Tentative signs of pickup in some weaker economies.
* Monetary policy cautious, but interest rates may decline further in
some countries as inflation eases.
* Fiscal policy in Germany tighter following expansion this year;
policies slightly contractionary on average in other countries.

* Averages weighted

by bilateral shares in U S non-agricultural exports

1991

Chart 12

REAL GNP: U.S. AND FOREIGN

Percent change, SAAR

Foreign GNP*
Percent change

ates
United States

G-6

Other

1990 H1

2.0

3.8

1990 H2

-0.6

2.7

1991 H1

0.1

3.1

1991 H2

2.0

3.6

1992

2.8

3.8

Foreign* (right bar)

REAL GNP: G-6 COUNTRIES**

Percent change, SAAR

Germany
Japan

1990

1991

1992

CONSUMER PRICES: U.S. AND G-6 COUNTRIES***
4-quarter percent change

U.S.

Other G-6 countries

Consumer Prices**
Percent change
Q4 to Q4
6

G-6

U.S.

1989

4.2

4.6

1990

4.5

6.3

1991

4.1

3.4

1992

3.3

3.7

5

United States

U.S.

4

3

Japan and Germany
2

1989

1990

* Average of 22 industrial and 8 developing countnes weighted by bilateral shares in U.S. non-agricultural exports
** Averages weighted by bilateral shares in U S non-agricultural exports
** Average using U.S. bilateral non-oil import weights

Chart 13

FACTORS AFFECTING NONAGRICULTURAL EXPORTS

Change, billions of 1982 dollars, SAAR

Total

Relative prices
Foreign growth (right bar)

1990

1991

FACTORS AFFECTING NON-OIL IMPORTS

1992

Change, billions of 1982 dollars, SAAR

Total
Relative prices
U.S. growth (right bar)

1990

1991

1992

Chart 14

Alternative Scenarios
Baseline:

Greenbook forecast extended through 1993; M2 growth at 5-1/2
percent in 1992 and 1993.

February Dollar:

Dollar at the level projected in February, almost 15 percent
below level now projected; federal funds rate unchanged from
baseline.

Weak Foreign Growth:

Foreign growth remains at about 1-1/2 percent; federal funds rate
unchanged from baseline.

1991

1992

1993

Percent change, Q4 to Q4
Real GNP, U.S.
Baseline
February Dollar
Weak Foreign Growth

1-1/2
2-1/2
1-1/2

2-3/4
4-1/4
2

2-1/2
5
1

GNP Prices
Baseline
February Dollar
Weak Foreign Growth

4
4-1/2
4

3-1/2
4-1/2
3-1/4

3-1/4
5
2-1/2

Real GNP, Foreign *
Baseline
February Dollar
Weak Foreign Growth

2-1/4
2-1/4
1-1/2

3-1/2
3-1/4
1-1/2

3-1/2
4
1-1/2

Q4 Level, $ billions
Current Account
Baseline
February Dollar
Weak Foreign Growth

-45
-37
-48

-52
-20
-73

-56
-32
-95

*

Average of 22 industrial and 8 developing countries weighted by bilateral shares in U.S. nonagricultural exports.

Chart 15

ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR 1991
FOMC
Central
Tendency

Range
----------------Nominal GNP

Administration

Staff

Percent change, Q4 to Q4------------

Real GNP
previous estimate

CPI
previous estimate

3-3/4 to 5-3/4

4-1/2 to 5-1/4

5.3

5.3

3-1/2 to 5-1/2

3-3/4 to 5-1/4

5.3

5.9

1/2 to 1-1/2

3/4 to 1

0.9

1.5

-1/2 to 1-1/2

3/4 to 1-1/2

0.9

1.9

3 to 4-1/2

previous estimate

3-1/4 to 3-3/4

4.3

3.4

3 to 4-1/2

3-1/4 to 4

4.3

3.9

----------------- Average level, Q4, percent-----------------Unemployment rate
previous estimate

6-1/2 to 7

6-3/4 to 7

6.7

6.6

6-1/2 to 7-1/2

6-1/2 to 7

6.7

6.1

ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR 1992
FOMC
Range

Central
Tendency

Administration

Staff

----------------- -Percent change, Q4 to Q4-----------Nominal GNP

4 to 6-3/4

5-1/2 to 6-1/2

7.5

6.1

Real GNP

2 to 3-1/2

2-1/4 to 3-1/4

3.6

2.8

2-1/2 to 4-1/4

3 to 4

3.9

3.7

CPI

----------------- Average level, Q4, percent-----------------Unemployment rate

6 to 6-3/4

6-1/4 to 6-1/2

6.6

6.3

July 2,

1991

LONG-RUN RANGES
Donald L. Kohn

At this meeting the Committee is called on to review its long-run
ranges for money and debt for this year and to set ranges on a provisional
basis for 1992.
The choice of ranges can be thought of as conditional on three
basic considerations: the objectives of policy, the underlying forces and
risks in the economy as they bear on reaching these objectives, and the
relationship of money growth to a given path of spending and income.
The first set of considerations is addressed in the simulations
of alternative strategies in the bluebook, whose results are given on page
9.

The strategies represent three fundamental approaches to policy in the

next few years:

one that emphasizes increases in output and declines in

unemployment (Strategy III),

one that puts stress on consolidating recent

gains on inflation and moving close to price stability in 5 years (Strategy II) and one that takes something of a middle road by making gradual
progress on both inflation and unemployment (the baseline strategy I);
Strategy IV is a variant of the baseline, which emphasizes output early on
and prices somewhat later.
The possible outcomes that different strategies can produce depend importantly on the starting point for the economy, including any
developments already built in for the near term, more or less independent
of the monetary policy path followed in the months immediately ahead.

In

that regard, we are starting from a condition of slack in the economy, and
consequently can expect a near-term deceleration of inflation under any

approach.

The degree of slack is not especially large compared to past

recessions, however, and could be reduced by the near-term bounceback in
activity.
This situation has several consequences illustrated in the simulations.

First, if policy attempts to push unemployment down rapidly and

significantly, as in Strategy III, progress in reducing inflation will be
very limited, and could be reversed in a few years unless the additional
ease were offset after only a few quarters, as in Strategy IV.

Second,

because the existing degree of slack is modest, any drop in unemployment
will allow only fairly modest progress on inflation.

Strategy II, aimed

at approaching price stability over 5 years, entails very small declines
in unemployment now and an increase later; of course, these latter results
do not embody credibility effects, which might allow significant declines
in both inflation and unemployment after this strategy had been in place
for a time.
The tendency for inflation to persist also implies the need for
policy to accommodate some pickup in nominal GNP growth in 1992 relative
to the last few years if unemployment is to be reduced.

Indeed, one could

characterize the tighter strategy as one that holds down money growth to
resist any such near-term pickup, and enforces decelerating nominal GNP
growth from 1993 on.

The easier strategy is accomplished by raising

nominal GNP growth to about 7 percent in 1992 and keeping it there; the
baseline increases nominal GNP growth to 6 percent in 1992, then gradually
reduces it thereafter.
The path for money that can accommodate the Committee's objectives for prices and output depends on an assessment of the second and

third sets of considerations--the underlying forces working on spending
and prices, and the underlying relationships of money to spending.

With

regard to the former, as Mike and Ted detailed, the staff forecast sees
essentially flat nominal short-term interest rates producing gradually
declining unemployment and inflation rates.

The continued improvement in

price performance occurs because the level of real rates implied by the
nominal rates is sufficiently high, given all the damping forces Mike
discussed, to keep the economy from rebounding all the way to its potential; that configuration has been extended in the baseline forecast.
Obviously, a weaker economy would imply the need for lower interest rates
to meet any set of objectives, and a stronger economy higher interest
rates.

Changing interest rates, in turn, by influencing opportunity costs

and velocity, would affect the money growth needed to achieve the Committee's objectives.

In this regard, the money ranges should give sufficient

scope to deal with potential deviations from expectations; the choice of
ranges itself can convey some sense of how the Committee sees the risks,
as well as how, in the context of its objectives, it would react to particular types of unexpected developments.
What money goes with a particular path for spending depends not
only on the associated movements of interest rates, but also any changes
in underlying relationships of money to income.

While unexpectedly slug-

gish money growth has presaged shortfalls in nominal spending over the
past year, the full extent of the weakness in money has not been reflected
in nominal GNP, at least based on historical patterns.

Velocity has de-

clined over the last three quarters, but not by as much as would be expected when effects of the drop in interest rates are taken into account.

The reasons for this remain something of a mystery.

They probably involve

the declining importance of depositories in the intermediation process--a
secular trend, arising from technological change and fuller pricing of the
safety net, that has been accentuated and compressed in time by the current travails of both banks and thrifts.

These developments have affected

the supply side of the market for M2 by damping depositories appetites for
funds and the demand side through concern over the safety and liquidity of
deposits and through the availability of other saving vehicles.
In projecting money growth relative to nominal income and interest rates, the staff has assumed that the unusual strength in velocity
will not be reversed, and indeed that there will be further shortfalls in
M2 growth relative to growth in income, but the size of these additional
shortfalls and associated increases in velocity will gradually decrease.
Depositories are expected to become more willing and better able to supply
credit as the expansion helps to reduce anticipated loan losses, bolstering their access to capital markets and improving the appetite both of
depositories and of depositors for deposits.
This analysis leads us to project 5-1/2 percent growth of M2 for
the remainder of 1991 and for 1992, consistent with the greenbook forecast
of nominal income and interest rates.

Such growth would represent an

acceleration from the pace of recent years.

As noted above, in the ab-

sence of an unexpectedly sharp slowing of inflation, somewhat greater
nominal GNP expansion would seem to be needed to reduce the unemployment
rate.

Even with the more rapid money growth, this projection still im-

plies an increase in velocity, especially in the second half of this year,
but to a lesser extent in 1992 as well.

Several outside commentators have

noted that such an increase in the first part of an expansion would be
unusual.

In the staff forecast this behavior of velocity has its origin

in several aspects of the current situation that differentiate it from
past cycles.

First is the assumed further downward shift in money demand,

or upward shift in velocity.

Second is relatively damped downward trajec-

tory of rates in the months leading up to this trough, giving less impetus
to money demand--and depressing velocity less--early in this recovery.
Third is the decontrol of deposit rates; this is the first recovery we
have experienced without any vestige of Regulation Q holding deposit rates
below equilibriums or effects of its staged lifting.

In fact, the staff

expects some, small, further reductions in deposit offering rates in coming months that will raise M2 opportunity costs and contribute to higher
velocity.
Against this background, there seems little reason to revise the
ranges for 1991 now in place.

M2 and M3 are now in the middle portions of

their ranges, and under the staff forecast are expected to stay there.

In

these circumstances, even if the Committee desired a different outcome
than the staff forecast, or had questions about the assessment of the
economy, prices or money demand underlying that forecast, the resultant
adjustments to policy most likely could be accommodated within the current
money ranges.

Your own forecasts of nominal GNP for the year fall a

little short of those of the staff, but, assuming your forecasts were not
built on appreciable changes in interest rates, are likely also to involve
money growth in the middle portion of the range, considering that the
staff projection was for M2 a bit above its midpoint.

Moreover, given the

factors expected to be boosting M2 velocity in coming quarters, growth

around the midpoint in 1991 would seem to be compatible with a policy that
was on track to produce the 6 percent nominal GNP growth both you and the
staff have projected for 1992.

In these circumstances, growth of money--

at least M2--approaching the outer edges of the existing ranges this year
likely would signal the need to take a hard look at the thrust of policy
relative to the Committee's objectives.
The growth of debt so far this year is at the lower end of its
range, but is expected to move higher over the second half with the pick
up in the economy.

A failure of debt to strengthen might signal a pro-

blem, such as intensifying restraints on credit supplies, that could affect the performance of the economy.

Reducing the debt range at this time

could be read as connoting complacency about these kinds of developments
in credit markets.

On the demand side, desired debt-to-income ratios may

well be shifting down as a consequence of wider interest spreads at intermediaries and problems encountered by borrowers over the past year in
servicing high debt levels, but such shifts are of uncertain size and
duration and should be encompassed within the range.
Alternative ranges for money and debt growth for 1992 are given

on page 18 of the bluebook.

Alternative I, which would raise the ranges

from those in effect this year, would be most consistent with the staff forecast for M2.

Raising the ranges would seem to signal that priority was

being placed on assuring a fairly robust recovery.

The higher upper end

of the range would give sufficient room to move against any weakness in
the economy should it re-emerge, for example, once the surge from the
inventory adjustment is completed.

If further reductions in interest

rates were needed, the increase in velocity envisioned in the staff forecast would be far less likely.

Scope for greater M2 growth would also

prove necessary if the recent downward shifts in M2 demand stopped, or
especially if they began to reverse.

At the same time, the higher range,

by potentially accommodating very strong GNP growth, also could be read as
connoting less concern about maintaining the downward tilt to inflation in
1992 and beyond.
Alternative II would carry over the current ranges on a provisional basis.

Although M3 and debt are projected to grow in the middle of

the alternative II ranges in the staff forecast, M2 growth at 5-1/2 percent would be in the upper half of its alternative II range, implying
greater scope to run a tighter than an easier policy and higher probability that increases rather than decreases in rates might be needed to hit
the ranges.

The Committee might want such a bias toward tightening if it

were concerned about the potential for inadvertently building in undesired
inflation pressures by delaying a needed tightening as the expansion moved
out of its initial stages and resource utilization rose.

The failure to

ratchet down the range as in a number of recent years could be justified
by a desire for stronger nominal GNP growth than in the recession and
immediate pre-recession years, recognizing that such growth is still likely to be compatible with lower inflation.

The central tendency of your

own projections is for 6 percent nominal GNP in 1992, the strongest since
1988, with inflation generally below 4 percent and probably headed lower
given a 6-1/4 to 6-1/2 percent unemployment rate projected for the end of
1992; if there were little or no increase in velocity, such an outcome

-8-

would require M2 very close to the top of the alternative II range.

Sim-

ply carrying over the ranges might also make sense and be explainable in
the context of uncertainty about the evolution of the financial system,
and its implications for the relationship between money and GNP growth,
accentuated at this time not only by the fragile state of many banks and
thrifts but also by a pending bill that could affect attitudes toward
deposits in ways that are difficult to predict.
Finally, the Committee could reduce the ranges further, as in
Alternative III.

Such a step would emphasize the Committee's commitment

to price stability.

The lower ranges imply that the Committee envisions

a prompt reaction to any tendency for nominal GNP to exceed its projections, and would tend to constrain and delay any easings undertaken if the
economy falls short.

Such a course might be seen as potentially com-

promising the possibilities for a significant recovery over the next year
or so, but it would also consolidate recent gains in inflation and keep
policy on track to make substantial further progress toward price stability, with attendant longer-run benefits.

July 3,

1991

SHORT-RUN POLICY BRIEFING
Donald L. Kohn
With the trough of the cycle now tentatively marked as April, the
next meeting of the FOMC will occur in the fourth month after the trough.
On occasion in the past, the initial rise in the federal funds rate has
occurred by that time in the cycle--though, to be sure, easing also occurred past this point, and past cycles may not provide the ideal model
for current policy.

The staff forecast, of course, does not envision such

an increase this time around, given the other restraining influences discussed yesterday, including the milder degree of policy easing put in
place during the recession.
Markets clearly expect some upward movement of interest rates-perhaps not over the next month or so, but probably by yearend.

Looking

at the entire yield curve, the slope is as steep as in the initial stages
of any expansion, even those following more aggressive policy easings.
This tilt, and its steepening over recent months, likely does not reflect
concerns about a flare-up of inflation, judging from the the appreciating
dollar and subdued behavior of commodity prices.

But the persistence of

high long-term rates in the face of an appreciating dollar and substantial
declines in short-term rates could be read as indicating an enduring skepticism about whether lasting progress on inflation can be sustained
through an expansion.

By implication, markets must be seeing the rise in

short-term rates built into the yield curve as an upward movement of real
rates necessary to keep inflation from accelerating.
While these expectations might argue for the Committee to be
especially alert to the possibility of needing to raise rates over coming

months, certain financial flow variables, especially those associated with
depositories, continue to flash warning signals about the possibilities of
weak expansion.

To date, bank credit has been anemic--weaker in fact over

the past few months than it was in the first quarter.

Growth in total

bank credit is usually a leading indicator of business cycle expansions,
though business loans often lag the cycle trough.

Partial data for June

suggest another month of flat bank credit, after allowing for the effects
of banks buying thrifts, and further decreases in business loans.

While

the behavior of loans appears to be mostly a question of declining demand
for short-term credit, supply conditions remain tight.

Often, the spread

of the prime rate over the federal funds rate has begun to narrow appreciably by this point; some times this narrowing has resulted from an initial
upward movement of the federal funds rate, but on occasion it has also
reflected decreases in the prime in the early stages of expansion.

While

some banks are reported to be seeking lending outlets a bit more aggressively, that lending seems to be targetted only at the highest quality
borrowers.

Renewed skittishness in markets for bank debt and equity in

the last week may impart a continuing element of caution to bank behavior,
even as the economy rebounds.
The fall-off in bank credit in the second quarter has been accompanied by a marked slowdown in M2 growth as well.

The moderation in M2

growth in the last few months has appeared to represent not weakness in
contemporaneous income or spending, but rather a continuation of the
velocity shifts of the past year.

Those shifts in turn seem to have their

origin in the rerouting of credit flows around depository institutions
and, to an extent some portfolio shifts by money holders into capital

market instruments, in response to declining yields on M2 assets and the
steeper yield curve.

The implications of the slowdown in money for future

spending depends in large measure on the interpretation of these two
phenomena.

The portfolio shifts, themselves, seem innocuous, since they

do not directly affect spending or wealth.

But if they indicate a high

level of real long-term rates, weak money may be telling us something
about incentives to spend.

Similarly, damped credit growth at depositor-

ies may simply be a measure of the ready availability of other sources of
funds.

But if it also connotes banks and thrifts continuing to hold cre-

dit conditions quite tight, effective real rates to borrowers may remain
high, with implications for spending and growth.
Even with the unchanged funds rates of alternative B, the staff
does have a pickup in M2 growth forecast over coming months in association
with the strengthening economy, as we discussed earlier in the meeting.
Uncertainties about the relationship of M2 to spending over one or two
quarters suggest the need to react to any deviations from expectations
with care.

Nonetheless, continued sluggish money growth, with M2 becoming

entrenched in the lower part of its range, might indicate that policy was
not fostering the financial conditions needed to sustain moderate recovery, and at least would provide an important counterweight to the expectations of tightening built into the yield curve.