View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC NOTES

- PRF

July 1-2, 1997

Mr. Chairman:
I will be referring to the three pages of color charts.

Since your last meeting, there has been a further unwinding
of expectations for the Committee to raise rates.
As you can see
in the first panel, U.S. forward, three-month rates have shifted
downward in recent weeks -- particularly following the data
releases in early June.
Looking past all of the politics of European monetary union,
German interest rate expectations have shown a very modest,
decline. While there are some indications that the German
economy may pick up in the second half of the year, no one
expects this to press on resources, nor to improve the German
fiscal position appreciably, nor is there seen to be much -- if
any -- risk of an increase in rates by the Bundesbank.
In Japan, as shown in the third panel, interest rate
expectations have shifted up and down.
Japanese forward rates
were rising in May, significantly influenced by official
pronouncements that the Japanese economy was stronger than the
market thought and that the Bank of Japan would be raising rates
sooner rather than later.
But data releases in late May and
early June did not support the heightened expectations created by
the earlier open mouth operations and, once again, market
participants perceived a postponement of any action by the Bank
of Japan until closer to calendar-year end.
The market's first reaction to last week's release of the
Bank of Japan's "Tankan" survey was to shift back to the
stronger-sooner view. But looking past the headline index, and
the exporters' continued strength, the soggy state of the nonmanufacturing sectors suggested that the "self-sustaining forces
of recovery" remain elusive.

-

2

-

Looking at this page as a whole, the narrow spreads between
current and forward rates in all three markets are striking.
In
Germany the spread between current three-month deposit rates and
those expected nine months forward is only 27 basis points, here
in the United States it is 44 basis points, and in Japan: 62
Don and I frequently debate how to measure term
basis points.
premia in forward contracts: but, however measured, these are
very tight.
Turning to the second page, even as Japanese interest rates
declined a bit, shown in the top panel in the benchmark Japanese
government bond, the yen has generally maintained its recent
strength against a number of currencies, as you can see in the
bottom panel.
The yen's continued strength, I think, is a function of the
fears of the unhedged masses, resulting from the pain still
lingering from the yen's sharp move in May.
For example, the two-year appreciation of the dollar against
the yen induced Japanese exporters to lag their normal hedging of
dollar receivables. But now, with a greater sense of two-way
risk, the exporters are playing catch-up and, once again, their
hedging activities weigh on the exchange market's consciousness.
Perhaps more importantly, I think we in the United States
take too narrow a view of unhedged yen borrowings. By referring
to this type of exposure as the "yen carry trade" we
compartmentalize it as something limited to the sophisticated,
leveraged strategies of hedge funds.
However, in the Asia-pacific economies, borrowing from
Japanese banks is routine and unremarkable. While good data on
unhedged yen liabilities is hard to come by, anecdotally it seems
to be worthy of note.
One Asian central banker suggested a rather powerful analogy
to me, by observing that the Japanese banks were doing in reverse
sequence exactly what the U.S. banks did in the 1980s.
U.S.
banks first over-extended themselves lending to developing
economies and, followed this up in the mid- and late 80s by
overindulging in the U.S. real estate market.
Japanese banks
first over-extended themselves in Japanese real-estate lending in
the late 1980's and have spent the last several years
aggressively lending to (what we now call) emerging market
economies, such as Thailand. Ignoring the obvious supervisory
issues, this view helps me better understand why I am hearing as

much today about unhedged yen liabilities, with dollar-yen
trading around 114, as I did two years ago when dollar-yen was
trading below 100.
Turning
expectations
gave another
here are but

to the third page of charts, the unwinding of
for any near-term rate increase by the Committee
shot of adrenaline to the rally in financial assets:
a few examples.

In the first panel, you can again see the impact of the data
releases in early June, leading to the sharp narrowing of the
spread between the Committee's Fed Funds target and the yield on
Following the non-farm payroll and retail
the two-year note.
sales figures -- and reflecting, in part, the tight technical
conditions in the short-end of the yield curve which I will come
back to in a moment -- this spread was squeezed down to 50 basis
points, before widening out a bit in the last few days.
In the second panel, as a proxy for the general rally in
emerging market debt, spreads over comparable Treasuries of Latin
I think it is
American, stripped Brady bonds are shown.
significant, if understandable, that these spreads narrowed so
noticeably on the fact of the Committee's decision to leave rates
unchanged at your May meeting, suggesting the importance of risk
premia tied to the level of U.S. rates.
In the third panel, various equity indexes are graphed, reindexed to April 15th for comparison. You can see that the
spring rally got going after the release of the first quarter ECI
and then simmered down a bit. Looking back, I am a lot more
comfortable with the fact that the market rallied in late April
on muted price data than I am with the more recent leg of the
rally, which took off on the suggestion of weaker economic
activity, seen in the softer-than-feared employment report on
June 6th and retail sales release on June 12th.
U.S. equity markets pretty much peaked out the next day,
with the June 13th release of May PPI (which is not indicated on
the chart).
Yesterday's Wall Street Journal story about the "liquidity
premia" being paid for the bluest of the blue chip stocks,
because they will be "easier to sell", strikes me a potential
leading indicator of liquidity illusions.

-4-

Turning to domestic operations, required operating balances
fell to just under 15 and half billion, breaking the previous low
set in January of 15.75 billion, reflecting the continued growth
of sweep accounts. However, overall, the Fed Funds market has
behaved reasonably well -- with predictable exceptions, such as
yesterday when the funds rate traded above 6 percent for much of
the day with the conjunction of the quarter-end and the
settlement of the two- and five-year Treasury auctions.
In
general, it still appears to me that the funds market is
adjusting to the gradual decline in required reserve levels.
However, Don and I have circulated to the Committee a paper,
prepared by Board and Desk staff, on measures which could be
taken to address funds market volatility should it develop.
Just before your last meeting, we concluded a 5.1 billion
dollar par amount coupon pass and, in the last two weeks, we
completed a second consecutive coupon pass, in three legs,
for a
total of 4.7 billion par amount.
In maintaining the current 50-50 balance between Treasury
bills and coupon securities in the System Open Market Account, I
have been trying to follow a pattern of alternating bill and
coupon passes.
However, the bill market has become extremely
tight, as described in Section III.B. of the Desk's written
inter-meeting report, principally as a consequence of the
Instead of
Treasury's notable decrease in bill issuance.
purchasing bills, and further contracting the limited supply in
the secondary market, I elected to purchase coupon securities.
Treasury's decreased issuance of bills is noteworthy as an
example of external constraints on the management of the SOMA.
Last September when the Committee discussed the optimal structure
and management of the SOMA, some members expressed a preference
for increasing bill holdings. While we still owe the Committee
further work on the principles and alternative portfolio
structures which could guide SOMA's management, I did undertake
to increase the Desk's flexibility by arranging with the Treasury
for them to treat SOMA as an "add-on" in bill auctions, just as
they do in coupon auctions, so that amounts we roll over would
not be deducted from the Treasury's total offerings to the
public.
While formally the Treasury now treats our bill awards as an
add-on, as a de facto matter, it still appears to me that their
offerings to the public are affected by SOMA's rollovers and,
thus, we continue to have an impact on bill supply in the market.
I hope that, over time, the Treasury will become comfortable

treating our bill holdings more flexibly and we will continue our
dialogue.
But, at least in the short run, unless we want to
evaporate the bill market, I feel somewhat constrained from
purchasing bills.
In general, I prefer the transparency of making SOMA
purchase from the market and, thus, I have a preference not to
purchase securities directly from foreign central banks when
offered. More recently, I have also been conscious of the supply
conditions in the bill market.
However, on June 20th we did
purchase just under 600 million dollars worth of bills from the
Bank of Thailand, out of one billion they were seeking to sell.
I was inspired to do this, in part, to avoid being seen selling a
large quantity of bills in the market on the day the Thai finance
ministry was changing hands.
We also had a need to add reserves
that day, which initially we thought would be around one billion,
but we scaled back our purchase when our forecast need declined.
There were no foreign exchange intervention operations
during the period.
Mr. Chairman, I will need the Committee's ratification of
the Desk's domestic operations and I would be happy to answer any
questions.

Page 1

US Forward Rates

German Forward Rates

Japanese Forward Rates

Page 2

Yield on Benchmark Japanese Government Bond

Yen Appreciation Against Selected Currencies
(indexed to April 15 = 100)

Page 3

U.S. Yield Curve Spreads

Spread of Brady Debt over Long-Term Treasuries*

Equities Indices

Larry Slifman
FOMC Chart Show
July 1, 1997
As often seems to be the case, economic activity has been proceeding
at an uneven pace in recent quarters, creating uncertainty about the "true"
signal emanating from the data. Since the Greenbook was published we
received more monthly information about spending in the second quarter:
higher than expected consumption, but lower inventory investment and
construction outlays. On balance, we would be inclined at this point to
revise

up our estimate of second-quarter GDP growth by about a quarter

of a percentage point, to 2-1/2 percent. I should note that the charts show
the forecast as published in the Greenbook.
Averaging through the first-quarter zig and the second-quarter zag, we
think real GDP growth has been running in the neighborhood of a 4 percent
annual rate so far this year. This clearly is an unsustainable pace, and we
expect economic growth to slow gradually over the next year and a half.
The basic rationale for the slowing was laid out for you in the Greenbook,
and I won't go through the entire story. Suffice it to say that, in our view,
a combination of waning stock demands for business and household
investment goods and a moderate tightening of financial and credit
conditions should damp aggregate demand.
We expect the unemployment rate to edge down during the remainder
of this year. Next year, with output growing at around potential, the
unemployment rate holds just above 4-1/2 percent--a degree of labor market
resource utilization that we think is consistent with upward pressure on
labor costs and, eventually, on prices. Indeed, as you can see from the

-2middle column of the data panel in the lower right, the CPI excluding food
and energy is projected to accelerate three-tenths of a percentage point
between this year and next.
For what it's worth, the latest Blue Chip consensus forecast is telling a
story similar to the staffs for GDP over the next year and a half. However,
the average Blue Chip forecaster seems to have a higher estimate of
potential GDP growth--that is, the projected growth of GDP in the Blue
Chip consensus is not sufficient to keep the unemployment rate from rising.
The Greenbook and the Blue Chip consensus project essentially the same
inflation rate for the four quarters of 1998--suggesting that we are
considerably more optimistic about the likely near-term trade-off between
unemployment and inflation.
As shown in the upper panel of chart 2, our forecast is predicated on
the assumption that the federal funds rate will remain at its current level
through this year. But, as inflation pressures begin to mount and real rates
drop, we assume that the nominal fed funds rate will move up about 50
basis points. The expectation that monetary policy will hold steady in the
near term has helped fuel a rally in bond markets since the last FOMC
meeting. However, as labor market pressures continue to tighten and credit
demands grow, we think bond traders will lose some of their enthusiasm,
and yields will begin to rise later this year. Reflecting the assumed System
tightening, long-term rates are projected to rise a bit further next year-averaging about 7-1/4 percent in the second half of 1998.

-3We anticipate that the stock market will climb a little further in the
next few months. But we think corporate profits will prove disappointing
over time, and coupled with higher interest rates, this will lead to an
appreciable market correction in 1998--on the order of 15 to 20 percent.
On the fiscal policy front, the federal deficit is expected to widen a
touch next year as the growth of receipts slows--primarily because we don't
anticipate another outsized jump in revenues like the ones we saw in the
past two years. In addition, the budget resolution raised the caps on
discretionary spending and this should add about $8 billion to nondefense
outlays compared with the last Greenbook. But this is all pretty small stuff
in the greater scheme of things, and as suggested by our measure of
discretionary fiscal impetus, federal budget policy looks to be a virtually
neutral element in the outlook for aggregate demand.
Ted will now discuss the prospects for the external sector.

E. M. Truman
July 1, 1997

FOMC Chart Show Presentation - International Developments

The first international chart summarizes the outlook for the external sector of the U.S.
economy. The message depicted in the top panel has not changed fundamentally since January. We
are projecting a continued deterioration of the current account balance; it will exceed $200 billion and
2-1/2 percent of GDP in 1998. Our basic story has not changed either. Despite the positive influence
on our exports of faster growth abroad, a "dollar [to quote a prominent Washington personality] that
has been strong for some time now," U.S. growth that slows only gradually to around potential, and our
existing deficit position produce a widening gap between imports and exports of goods and services;
our deficit on net investment income expands as well.
As is shown in the middle left panel, the growth of real exports (black line) increased late last
year and early this year in response to the recovery of foreign activity and the lagged effects of the
weaker dollar in 1995. Export growth is expected to continue very strong through much of this year
but to drop back in 1998 as the effects of the recent strength of the dollar are felt with greater force.
Meanwhile, the growth of imports (red line) is expected to more than keep pace with that of exports;
imports are being boosted this year by the rapid expansion in domestic demand and by the stronger
dollar (which feeds through to imports more rapidly than to exports). Next year, import growth
should ease off somewhat as the expansion of the U.S. economy slows toward potential and the
influence of relative prices shifts toward neutral with the slight downward drift of the dollar. As is
shown in the box at the right, real net exports of goods and services are projected to make negative
contributions to the growth of real GDP throughout the projection period.
In the balance of my portion of our presentation I focus on the three issues listed at
the bottom of the chart: our thinking about exchange rates, the foreign outlook and implications for

-2U.S. exports, and developments affecting prices and quantities of U.S. imports.
The next chart addresses the first of these issues.

Based on the evidence of the past five

months, the foreign exchange value of the dollar in terms of other G-10 currencies appears to have
reached a high plateau.

As is shown in the top left panel, the rise in the dollar since its trough in

mid-1995 has been associated with a relative rise in U.S. real 10-year interest rates. Over the forecast
period, we are projecting a slight downward drift in the dollar reflecting the net effect of the four
influences on the dollar listed in the box at the right.
First, we think that our widening external deficit will put downward pressure on the dollar,
though we are far from confident about timing or magnitude.
Second, more rapid inflation in the United States than in other G-10 countries also will tend
to depress the dollar in nominal terms (the red line at the left), but it will translate into a smaller
depreciation on a price-adjusted basis (the black line) because of higher U.S. inflation than in other
G-10 countries; put another way, in the absence of the dollar's projected nominal depreciation, it
would appreciate in real terms and further weaken our external position.
Third, the differential in real long-term interest rates (the blue line) is expected to have a
neutral effect on the dollar. We have a very slight upward tilt in the path of real long-term interest
rates in foreign G-10 countries. The slight wiggles in the differential reflect primarily the projected
path of U.S. long-term interest rates.
The middle left panel illustrates, for three representative countries, how three-month rates are
expected to creep up in response to their strengthening expansions. In Canada, increases in interest
rates continue to keep pace with increases in U.S. interest rates. In Japan, as the expansion matures,
we are assuming that interest rates will begin a gradual rise from the abnormally low level that has
prevailed for almost two years. In Germany, we are assuming that short-term rates will rise about 75
basis points in the run-up to the start of EMU. However, under this scenario, German real and

-3nominal short-term interest rates still will be well below their average of the past several decades
when monetary policy is handed over by the Bundesbank to the European Central Bank -- a point to
which I will return in a moment.
This brings me to the fourth influence on the dollar, European Monetary Union. We are now
assuming that a broadly based EMU will start on January 1, 1999, with the initial participation of 11
of the current 15 members of the European Union. Italy, Spain and Portugal will be in; Denmark,
Greece, Sweden and the United Kingdom will be out, or stay out. The Maastricht treaty reference
values for 1997 fiscal deficits will be missed or fudged by most major participants. In the run-up to
EMU, at least, these factors plus an increase in general uncertainty will tend to continue placing
downward pressure on the EMU currencies relative to the dollar, everything else being equal.
Pulling all these influences together, we are projecting, as you can see in the middle-right
panel, that the dollar will remain essentially unchanged against the DM over the projection period -the negative influence on the dollar of our widening external deficits is outweighed by the positive
influence, so to speak, of EMU. The dollar depreciates substantially against the yen by the fourth
quarter of 1998; in this case, the influence of external balances -- including importantly the rising
Japanese surplus -- predominate. Finally, the U.S. dollar is projected to depreciate moderately against
the Canadian dollar.
To complete our exchange rate story, the bottom panels look at non-G-10 currencies.

The

black and blue lines show that in real terms the G-18 index tends to track movements in the G-10
index. For the eight non-G-10 currencies - two Latin American and six Asian - the trend of the
dollar has been one of gradual real depreciation, a trend that we expect to continue on balance. This
trend principally has been associated with the fact that inflation in these countries has been somewhat
more rapid than in the United States while most of their nominal exchange rates are closely tied to the
dollar. A partial exception to this generalization -- the Mexican peso - is shown at the right. Since

-4the dollar's substantial real appreciation against the peso in early 1995, it has retraced a good portion
of the rise because the large differential between Mexican and U.S. inflation has outweighed the
dollar's moderate further nominal appreciation against the peso. However, we are not projecting a
continuation of this pattern. As indicated, the real peso/dollar exchange rate is expected to remain
essentially unchanged over the next 18 months, as the dollar's nominal appreciation keeps pace with
the inflation differential.
Turning to the foreign outlook, the subject of Chart 5, the top left panel illustrates the
recovery since late 1995 in growth in both foreign G-7 countries and developing countries. As is
shown in the box at the right, we are projecting fairly strong growth in Japan and Canada this year
and next, while growth in the United Kingdom is projected to slow in 1998 under the influence of
tightening monetary policy.

Meanwhile, growth in our presumptive 11-country "Euro Area" is

projected to average about 2-3/4 percent, somewhat faster than our estimate of their potential growth
on average.
With respect to the developing countries, we expect a slowing of growth in Mexico and the
rest of Latin America following very strong performances last year; indeed, a slowdown in the first
part of this year already is evident. We also are projecting a modest slowing in growth (on average)
in developing countries in Other Asia. So far this year, lower growth has been recorded in Korea and
Taiwan. There is a larger than normal downside risk to our forecast for this region given the
uncertainties associated with the influence of the yen on their exports, weaknesses in some domestic
financial systems, potential spillovers from Thailand's problems, and the transfer earlier today (their
yesterday) of sovereignty over Hong Kong.
As shown in the middle left panel, consumer price inflation abroad is projected to be low, or
in Mexico's case declining.
The box at the right provides a perspective on output gaps in the foreign industrial economies.

-5As you can see, we estimate that the Japanese output gap will be reduced substantially by the end of
the forecast period; this reflects our assumption that growth of potential output in Japan is about 2
percent and our projection that actual Japanese growth will average about 2-1/2 percent over the
forecast period. Canada's output gap is projected to narrow more rapidly, but to remain somewhat
larger than Japan's at the end of the period.
In the case of the United Kingdom, our estimate of the level of potential output may well be
conservative in view of last Friday's substantial upward revision in the level of actual output. The
new data on actual output and our previous estimate of potential output suggest that the British output
gap already was more than eliminated by the end of 1996. However, our new estimates of potential
and the output gap, displayed in the box, imply that some slack remained at the end of last year; this
result at least makes the favorable recent U.K. price performance a bit more plausible.
The Euro Area presents an interesting case in the context of the start of EMU.

We estimate

that the output gap for the area as a whole still will be substantial -- more than a percentage point -when the European Central Bank opens its doors in early 1999. However, our judgment is that there
will be relatively little slack in Germany. At the same time there will be a larger amount in France,
and output in Italy and Spain (not shown) will be significantly below potential. Taking our estimates
at face value, one can speculate about two questions: Will the Bundesbank endeavor to put in place a
less accommodative stance of monetary policy than we have assumed before it hands over the reins of
monetary policy to the European Central Bank?

In setting policy during 1999, how much weight will

the ECB give to conditions in Germany versus other countries?

We will not fully confront the

implications of these issues for our forecast until we extend it into 1999, but they are some of the
uncertainties that will weigh on the euro in the period ahead.
Turning to our forecast for U.S.exports, the solid black bars in the bottom panel show that we
are projecting the continuation of a healthy expansion of total exports of goods and services both this

-6year and next. The other bars show the contributions of various categories of exports to the growth of
the total. In recent years, the major contributions have come from exports of computers and
semiconductors (the black, cross-hatched bars) and exports of other goods (the open red bars). In
1996 and so far in 1997, exports of other goods increased substantially more that our model's
prediction. This suggests a source of risk to our forecast; we chose a middle road and implicitly
assumed that the growth of these exports reverts to the historical rate. We have not assumed a
reversal in the positive surprise -- about half of which is attributable to a higher rate of aircraft
shipments than we expect to be sustained. In 1998, given the additional negative lagged effects of the
recent strength of the dollar, the contribution of other goods exports to the growth of the total shrinks
dramatically; exports of computers and semiconductors more than account for the overall growth we
are projecting.
The final international chart deals with U.S. imports, both prices and quantities.

With

respect to prices, the heavy red line in the top left panel shows that prices of total manufactured
imports have been on a declining trend since the second half of 1995, led by declines in prices of
imports from Japan and the NIEs as well as from Canada and, more recently, the European Union.
As indicated by the red line in the right panel, import prices have declined over the past year or so.
As shown by the bars, the estimated contribution of exchange rates to that decline has been
considerable. Declining import prices, in turn, have tended to hold down overall U.S. inflation by a
few tenths in recent quarters. This favorable influence of the dollar, through import prices, on U.S.
inflation is projected to be eliminated, if not reversed, over the period ahead.
The red lines in the middle panels depict actual and projected growth in quantities of goods
imports -- excluding oil, computers and semiconductors. The contribution of relative prices (on the
left) is to boost the growth of imports somewhat this year, but they become a neutral factor by the end
of next year. The predominant influence (shown at the right) is the pace of expansion of U.S. GDP.

-7The bottom panel presents another cut on recent and projected trends in the pattern of overall
growth of imports of goods and services. As in the case of exports, growth in the total (the solid
black bars) is dominated by computers and semiconductors (the black, cross-hatched bars) and by
other goods (the open red bars). The contributions to growth of the total from imports of services and
oil are relatively minor.

As U.S. GDP growth slows in 1998, the contribution of imports of

computers and semiconductors to the growth of the total will remain high in absolute terms and rise in
relative terms. The contribution of imports of other goods shrinks.
Larry Slifman will now continue our presentation.

Larry Slifman
FOMC Chart Show

July 1, 1997

As always, a key element in our GDP forecast is the consumer sector-the subject of chart 7. The upper left panel, presents the outlook for sales
of light motor vehicles. Our projection, as well as those of many industry
analysts, puts the "fundamental" demand for light vehicles--based on
demographic and scrappage trends--at about 14-1/2 to 14-3/4 million units
per year. Sales this year are likely to once again exceed the underlying
trend, reflecting, in part, the strength of income and consumer sentiment.
But sales are expected to move down toward the trend during 1998, and
motor vehicles, therefore, have a slightly negative influence on GDP growth
next year.
As noted in the Greenbook, we think that the current "pause" in
consumer spending outside of the motor vehicle sector is just that--a pause,
and not the beginning of a protracted slump. As I noted earlier, the
monthly PCE data for May that we received yesterday came in stronger
than expected and have led us to revise up our forecast of second-quarter
consumer spending by about three-fourths of a percentage point. Moreover,
as suggested by the forecast bar for 1997 in the upper right panel, consumer
spending for goods and services other than motor vehicles is expected to
continue rising at a fairly rapid clip during the next several months,
bringing the four-quarter growth rate to more than 3-1/2 percent.
Our bullish near-term PCE forecast relies, in part, on consumer
sentiment. As may be seen in the lower panels, both the overall Michigan
sentiment index and the question on unemployment expectations, which is

-2-

not part of the aggregate index, suggest that consumers are extremely
upbeat currently.
Returning to the upper right panel, consumer spending slows over the
course of 1998 as the pace of hiring moderates and income growth tapers
off. Spending may also be damped next year if lenders tighten credit terms
and standards, as they've already been doing on a limited basis--especially
for credit cards. Finally, there is the question of our stock market forecast
and how we see it affecting consumer spending. That is the subject of your
next chart.
Share prices have risen roughly 90 percent since the end of 1994,
producing a substantial increase in price-earnings ratios. The p-e chart
shown here updates the one Mike presented to you in February. After
adjusting for special charges for restructuring, shown by the red line in the
upper panel, the current p-e is at its highest level since the early seventies.
The vertical lines denote troughs in the earnings cycle for S&P 500 stocks.
You can see that peak p-e ratios typically have occurred near a trough in
earnings. Well we're far from that: profits have been soaring in recent
years. And yet, analysts expect even faster profit growth for the next three
to five years--the middle left panel.
If, instead, profits flatten out as we are projecting, the analysts and
other market participants will be disappointed. And, as I indicated earlier,
in our forecast this--along with the updrift in interest rates--leads to a
considerable price retreat next year.

-3In terms of our consumption forecast, the ups and downs of the stock
market are expected to have a muted effect. The lower panel compares the
wealth-income ratio (the blue line) with the consumption rate--that is, one
hundred minus the saving rate. The chart suggests that consumption growth
since early 1995 has been considerably less than would have been expected
on the basis of this simple wealth-spending relationship. Of course, the
opposite problem existed earlier in the nineties. Future revisions to the
national income accounts could possibly alter this picture, but for now it's
our assumption that in recent years other factors have been offsetting the
influence of the wealth effect. Previous Greenbooks have discussed some
of the possible explanations: strong income growth that has not yet been
fully incorporated into perceptions of permanent income; increased debtservice burdens, especially among households with below-average incomes;
and perhaps an increased desired to save for retirement, especially given the
attention in the media to the problems of the social security and Medicare
systems. In any event, our assumed stock market correction in 1998
reverses this year's sharp rise in the wealth-income ratio, which may begin
cutting into spending by year end.
Your next chart examines the other key source of deceleration in GDP
growth next year: a slowing of business spending for equipment. As may
be seen in the upper panel, investment in producers' durable equipment this
year is growing at an even more remarkable rate than the outsized pace
recorded in 1996--fuel by continued rapid spending for computers, a surge

-4-

in aircraft deliveries, and a revival of outlays for other capital goods after a
period of dormancy. However, all three components of PDE are expected
to grow more slowly in 1998.
The middle left panel presents actual and expected unit shipments of
PCs. The data are collected by the Information Technology Industry
Council, a trade association representing the leading US PC and
microprocessor manufacturers. As you can see, the industry expects
shipments to cool a bit this year and next. Nevertheless, they still are
forecasting gains of more than 15 percent per year. Recognizing the
performance improvements in these boxes, unit PC sales underestimate by
perhaps 10 percentage points or more the growth of real computer
investment as reported in the national income accounts. If anything, then,
our forecast of an 18-1/2 percent rise in real outlays next year may be on
the low side.
Meanwhile, Boeing continues to ramp up its production. By the end of
this year, Boeing expects to be completing 40 planes per month--about
twice the pace recorded late last year. Under current schedules, the
delivery rate levels off in 1998 and the impetus to GDP growth from this
sector slackens.
Orders for nondefense capital goods other than computers and
aircraft--the lower left panel--revived earlier this year and have remained
near their record levels. This suggests strong investment in the next several

-5-

months. But investment demand is projected to soften thereafter as output
decelerates and cash-flow flattens.
In contrast to the marked deceleration we are forecasting for
equipment, the growth in outlays for nonresidential structures is expected to
be maintained at close to the current rate. Contracts for private
nonresidential buildings are at high levels; vacancy rates for office space
have declined steadily; rents are rising; and REIT financing is readily
available.
As shown in the upper panel of exhibit 10, the strong investment in
computers has been associated with a pickup in the growth of the capital
stock for information processing equipment. In addition, the growth of the
stock of other kinds of business equipment--the middle panel--rose in the
mid-1990s and has remained elevated compared with the 1980s and early
nineties. Accordingly, the lower panel illustrates that the average growth of
aggregate capital input for equipment and structures relative to the growth
of labor--that is, capital deepening--has been running a bit faster in recent
years than in the preceding decade. But this relatively small stepup is not
enough, by itself, to significantly boost our assessment of trend productivity
growth. And, as Dave Stockton will now discuss, we still see no
compelling evidence that there has been an improvement in the growth of
potential GDP recently.

DStockton
Chart show
7/1//1997
As shown in the upper panel of your next chart, we' re projecting that the growth
in potential output over the next year and a half will remain at the 1.9 percent annual pace
that we estimate has prevailed since the cyclical peak in 1990. That projection is
composed of nearly equal contributions from the growth of labor input--line 2--and the
growth of productivity--line 3.
Taken at face value, the published figures for productivity in the nonfarm business
sector point to a sharper slowdown in productivity since 1990 than we have assumed-perhaps to about 3/4 percentage point per year. However, as we have noted previously in
the Greenbook, we are anticipating that real output and, hence productivity, will be revised
up in this summer's annual revisions to the national income accounts by enough to support
our 0.9 percent estimated trend--plotted in red in the middle panel. But in the absence of
any clear signs in the data of an increased pace of efficiency gains or a greater pick up in
capital deepening, we have been reluctant to project a still higher trend going forward.
The acceleration in economic activity over the past year likely has provided a
boost to output per hour. However, next year, we anticipate that productivity will rise a
bit more slowly--gradually approaching its longer-term trend--as activity decelerates and
firms reach deeper into the diminishing pool of qualified workers.
Abundant job opportunities have been drawing people into the labor force at a
rapid clip over the past year. The labor force participation rate--shown in the lower left
panel--moved above 67 percent in recent months, up about 1/2 percentage point from a

2
year ago. And in the context of our projection of some further tightening of labor
markets, we anticipate that the participation rate will continue to edge up over the next six
quarters.
As shown at the right, the resulting labor force growth is expected to remain above
its 1 percent trend over the projection period. Even so, the projected strength of economic
activity this year and smaller productivity gains in 1998 cause employment growth--the
second column--to outstrip the expansion of the labor force over the forecast period.
As a consequence, the unemployment rate--shown in the upper left panel of chart
12-- falls to close to 4-1/2 percent by early next year. Other indicators of labor market
conditions are showing similar signs of tautness. For example, in the Conference Board
survey--the upper right panel--the number of households reporting that jobs are plentiful
exceed by a wide margin those reporting that jobs are hard to get. In addition, the help
we've been getting from decelerating health insurance costs may be coming to an end.
The results of a Peat Marwick survey of large firms are presented in the middle left panel.
These firms report larger increases in health insurance premiums in 1997 than in 1996.
Although these increases are small and could be offset by lower wage gains, health care
costs are unlikely to be as favorable an influence going forward as they have been in the
recent past.
In our view, these factors already have left some imprint on compensation
inflation--plotted as the black line in the lower panel. And with the unemployment rate
projected to move still lower, a further mild acceleration is expected over the next year
and a half. That this process has not gained any perceptible momentum likely reflects the

3
fact that, while tightness in labor markets may be boosting hourly compensation costs a
bit more quickly, we have yet to witness any increase in inflation expectations--a
necessary ingredient of a conventional wage-price spiral. Indeed, the Michigan survey of
inflation expectations--shown in the middle right panel--has basically been moving
sideways for some time now.
To a large extent, developments in product markets appear, thus far, to have short
circuited this feedback mechanism. Two key factors, declining non-oil import prices and
ample manufacturing plant capacity, are highlighted in the upper panels of your next
exhibit. As shown in the left hand panel, non-oil import prices dropped 3 percent last
year and appear to have declined at a similar pace over the first half of this year. For the
reasons that Ted discussed earlier, we are expecting these declines to give way to
increases later this year and into the next, weakening one of the factors that has
suppressed price inflation over the past year and half.
Another favorable influence has been healthy growth of capacity, which has kept
the factory utilization rate close to its historical average, and by our assessment, a largely
neutral influence on price pressures in the goods sector. Moreover, we are anticipating
that utilization rates will edge down over the projection interval, as manufacturing
investment plans are only gradually scaled back in response to the weakening of sales,
profits, and cash flow that we have projected for this sector.

Owing to these restraining influences, the cyclically adjusted markup of prices over
unit labor costs in the nonfarm business sector--plotted in the middle panel--is expected to
drift down somewhat over the forecast period. As a consequence, we are projecting only

4
a very modest upturn in broad measures of price inflation--shown in the lower panels.
GDP prices--the black line--are projected to pick up from a 2 percent increase in 1996 to
a 2-1/4 percent increase this year and 2-1/2 percent increase next year. The sharp slowing
in food and energy prices under way this year, which receives a much larger weight in
PCE prices--the red line--results in lower consumption price inflation this year before

moving up to a 2-1/2 percent pace in 1998.
Obviously, there are considerable risks that lie on both sides of our inflation
projection. One risk is that current and prospective labor market tightness will leave a
clearer mark on the inflation process going forward than has been apparent over the past
year. And, if the price news turns less favorable, the feedback into inflation expectations
and labor costs could be more abrupt.
Another risk, which has received considerable attention, is the possibility that
fundamental changes are taking place in the economy that have raised underlying
productivity growth and restrained inflation. The implications of such an acceleration in
productivity are the subject of your next two charts. In the upper panel of chart 14, I
have plotted productivity in the nonfinancial corporate sector of the economy. This sector
covers a bit more than half of GDP and may be less susceptible to measurement error than
the financial and non-corporate sectors of the economy. Much like the broader nonfarm
business measure I showed in chart 11,

there are no clear-cut signs that the trend in

productivity of this sector has improved. But over the past two years--a period I have
highlighted in red on the chart--productivity has increased at nearly a 3 percent annual
rate, well above its 1-1/2 percent historical trend--the black dashed line.

5
If one wished to take an optimistic slant, such an upturn could be viewed as hinting at
an improving productivity performance.
You, of course, are quite familiar with the suspects in this story--rapid investment
in new technologies, the payoff from corporate restructurings, and the imperative to
innovate in response to an increasingly competitive world economy. I would note one
additional possibility--low and stable inflation. If some acceleration of productivity is
under way, the reduction in inflation and inflation uncertainty in recent years may have
played an important supporting role.
The lower panel of the exhibit outlines the effects that a step-up in the productivity
growth trend would have on both the supply and demand sides of the economy. On the
supply side, an increase in the pace of productivity growth will initially raise business
profitability by enabling firms to produce more with less. However, competitive pressures
soon would emerge that force down price inflation to better reflect the slower growth in
the costs of production. In labor markets, real wages rise more rapidly through some
combination of lower price inflation and larger nominal wage gains.
On the demand side of the economy, technological improvements boost business
investment, as firms seek to take advantage of profitable opportunities. Households also
raise spending as more rapid growth in both capital and labor income lead to upward
revisions in their estimate of trend--or so-called permanent--income. Needless to say,
there are similarities between these supply- and demand-side effects and some recent

economic developments.

6
In your next chart, I present simulations of our econometric model that lay out the
effects on some key economic variables of a permanent increase in productivity growth of
1/2 percentage point per year starting in 1997. For this exercise, I have considered two
alternative policy responses, which illustrate some of the tradeoffs you would face under
these circumstances. In one case, I assume that monetary policy stabilizes the
unemployment rate at its baseline path, thus allowing the effects of the higher productivity
growth to show through into permanently lower inflation. The second case assumes that
policy attempts to stabilize the long-run inflation rate and allows the unemployment rate to
fall temporarily. These alternatives are shown as deviations from baseline in the upper
four panels, with the inflation targeting case shown in red and the unemployment targeting
case shown in blue. In the lower table, I show the extended Greenbook forecast and the
consequences of more rapid productivity growth for inflation and unemployment under the
two alternative policy responses.
As you can see in the upper left hand panel, an unanticipated increase in the rate
of productivity growth of 1/2 percentage point per year initially results in a reduction in
price inflation under either policy. In the inflation-targeting case, the nominal funds rate-the red line in the middle left panel--is unchanged until 1999. During this period, both
inflation and the unemployment rate--the red lines in the upper two panels--move lower.
The boom in demand drives up output and reduces the unemployment rate. But, for a
while, productivity gains offset the cost pressures associated with larger wage gains and,
consequently, price inflation declines. In effect, the acceleration in productivity creates a
transitory drop in the NAIRU. By 1999, however, price inflation moves back up toward

7
baseline as labor costs are boosted, in part, by tight labor markets. In addition, the larger
real wage demands that follow the more rapidly rising productivity effectively reverse the
decline in the NAIRU and further boost labor cost increases. In fact, to prevent inflation
from moving above baseline, the nominal federal funds rate must be raised by about 3/4
percentage point between 1999 and 2001.
In the second case, to stabilize the unemployment rate--the blue line in the four
panels--the nominal federal funds rate is raised immediately to lean against the emerging
strength of aggregate demand. Taken together, the increase in nominal rates and the
decline in price inflation result in a more rapid rise in the real interest rate--the blue line
in the middle right panel--than occurs in the inflation-targeting case. Under these
circumstances, the improvement in productivity shows through to a permanently lower rate
of price inflation--the upper left panel--by about the 1/2 percentage point increase in the
growth of productivity.
In the end, the policy choice comes down to a tradeoff between, on the one hand,
permanently lower inflation and, on the other hand, unchanged inflation but an extended-if temporary--period of lower unemployment. Clearly, supply shocks--good ones as well
as bad ones--confront policymakers with some difficult decisions. However, if we are
fortunate enough to be facing this situation, your choices will be between some very
attractive outcomes.
The final chart in our presentation displays your forecasts for 1997 and 1998. As
shown in the upper panel, you have revised up your estimates of real GDP growth for this
year and, correspondingly, revised down your estimates of the level of the unemployment

8
rate in the fourth quarter of this year. At the same time, however, you have revised down
your CPI projections for 1997. As shown in the lower panel, for 1998, you anticipate a
considerable slowing in the growth of real GDP; the unemployment rate is expected to
hold steady; and CPI inflation is projected to edge up.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR) CLASS I-FOMC

Material for

Staff Presentation to the
Federal Open Market Committee
July 1, 1997

Chart 1

Forecast Summary

Chart 2

Background Factors in the Staff Forecast

Financial environment
Federal funds rate remains at current level this year and then moves up
moderately in 1998.
Long-term rates begin to firm later this year reflecting inflation concerns, and
rise a bit further next year as the System tightens.
Stock prices climb further in the next few months; but disappointing profits,
coupled with higher interest rates, lead to an appreciable correction next
year.

Fiscal policy
The deficit widens slightly.
Revenue growth slows in FY98, while outlays increase at about the pace of
recent years.
The macroeconomic consequences should be negligible.

Federal Fiscal Indicators
1995
Unified deficit ($billions, fiscal year)

Fiscal impetus (calendar year)*
*Percent of GDP; negative values indicate restraint.

1996

1997

1998

163.9

107.2

59.1

84.7

-. 4

-. 1

-. 2

-. 1

Chart 3

Forecast Summary: External Sector

Chart 4

Exchange Rates and Interest Rates

Chart 5

Foreign Outlook and U.S. Exports

Chart 6

U.S. Imports

Chart 7

Consumption

Chart 8

Price-Earnings Ratio - S&P 500

Chart 9

Business Investment

Chart 10

Real Net Capital Stock

Chart 11

The Supply Side

Chart 12

The Labor Market

Chart 13

Product Markets and Price Inflation

Chart 14

The Effects of Faster Productivity Growth

Chart 15

Alternative Scenarios with Faster Productivity Growth
(0.5 percentage point per year faster productivity growth;
deviations from baseline)

Chart 16

ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR 1997

ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR 1998

DStockton
7/1/1997
Price measurement for monetary policy
Over the past year, Committee members have raised a number of questions about the
conduct of monetary policy in a low-inflation environment. In a paper circulated recently to
the FOMC, my colleagues David Lebow, Deb Lindner, Dan Sichel, and Bob Tetlow focused
in depth on issues surrounding the choice of a price measure to guide monetary policy and on
defining zero inflation in terms of the available published price indexes.
We organized our project around four basic questions: First, what does economic
theory suggest is the measure of prices most appropriate for judging the performance of
monetary policy? Second, what are the statistical relationships among the major price
indexes that we monitor? Third, what are the measurement errors in these indexes and what
rate of change in these measures would correspond roughly to zero inflation? And finally,
what would be the consequences for the stability of real output and interest rates, of focusing
monetary policy on various measures of price inflation?
Let me start with the guidance provided by economic theory. Unfortunately, theory
does not point unambiguously to a specific price index to guide monetary policy. In
principle, to answer the question coherently requires a complete model of the economy that
incorporates all of the costs of inflation. Using such a model, one could trace monetary
policy actions through to their effects on different price measures and then define a price
objective to minimize the costs of inflation and inflation uncertainty. The problem is that no
such comprehensive model exists. As a consequence, our analysis--like the literature--is
somewhat compartmentalized and thus not entirely satisfying. That said, the authors note
some useful observations.

2
One observation is that some costs of inflation point toward the desirability of
stabilizing a broad measure of prices, with the choice determined by one's judgment about
how inflation distortions are related to movements in various measures of aggregate prices.
Households, businesses, and governments all participate in transactions that could be distorted
by inflation, impairing efficiency and ultimately reducing society's consumption possibilities.
Under these circumstances, stabilizing a broad collection of prices, such as the GDP price
measure, might be appropriate. If one viewed household decisions, particularly those related
to long-term saving and investment, as most susceptible to errors associated with inflation,
greater weight might be placed on stabilizing a consumption price measure, such as PCE
prices. But, we see little justification for considering, as a long-run objective, any narrower
measure of prices.
A second observation is that the measure of prices implicitly embedded in nominal
interest rates might be the appropriate objective of policy, especially if one were concerned
about minimizing tax distortions and limiting the effect of the inflation risk premium on the
cost of capital. What is this measure? We don't know. It would seem likely that interest
rates are determined by the interaction of borrowers and lenders who must be considering a
very broad range of prices in making their decisions. This is an issue that deserves some
careful empirical attention.
Finally, we noted that there are some arguments in favor of including assets in the
price index to guide monetary policy. Frankly, we didn't make much progress evaluating
these arguments. And, in the end, we largely punted on the issue for three pretty good
reasons: no theory, no data, and no empirical models. With respect to the theory, there is

3
surprisingly little work that addresses this issue. On the data side, constructing an index that
included a reasonably comprehensive coverage of asset prices would be a monumental
undertaking. Finally, targeting such an index, even if it were available, would be such a
radical departure from your past behavior, econometric models estimated on historical data
would not provide much guidance for policymaking. I'm afraid that this is an issue that
remains on the research agenda.
In the second section of the paper, the authors address the question of whether, in
practice, the choice of an inflation measure matters. If all the major measures move closely
together over time, the choice of which index to focus on will not be very consequential. We
employed a battery of statistical tests to determine whether most broad measures of inflation
move together over long periods or drift apart; in the jargon of econometricians, we tested
whether measures of inflation are cointegrated. We concluded that the most broad measures
are cointegrated; that is, PCE, GDP, and CPI inflation do not drift apart over long periods of
time.
However, that does not mean that these measures will always be giving the same
signal about inflation. The paper presents spreads between the four-quarter changes of the
major indexes. Over the past ten years, the GDP chain-weighted price index has increased,
on average, about 0.3 percentage point per year less than the PCE price measure, and 0.5
percentage point per year less than the CPI. But year by year, these differences fluctuate
considerably and can give conflicting signals about the magnitude and direction of inflation
movements. For example, PCE inflation has run about 0.2 percentage point less per year than
CPI inflation over the past ten years. But for a time last year, PCE prices were rising 3/4

4
percentage point less than the CPI, largely reflecting a smaller measured increase in medical
care costs, which also receive a bigger weight in PCE prices. Given their different
construction and data sources, it's not surprising that different indexes will, at times, provide
conflicting signals about the movement of inflation.
In the third section of the paper, the authors review our current thinking about
measurement bias in the CPI, and extend that analysis to GDP and PCE prices. Clearly, in
assessing the performance of inflation relative to the objective of zero inflation, it is
necessary to take account of the measurement bias in the relevant price indexes. As we have
noted previously, our current best estimate of the annual bias in the CPI is about 1 percentage
point. By 1999, we estimate that the bias will be about 0.8 percentage point per year. The
smaller estimated bias largely reflects our assumption that BLS will implement geometric
weighting for some item strata in the CPI next year, further reducing low-level substitution
bias.
Because PCE prices, to a large extent, use CPI components in their construction, this
index is subject to most of the same sources of measurement bias. The principal exception is
that chain-weighting of the PCE price measure avoids the upper-level substitution bias that
plagues the fixed-weighted CPI. We estimate that the overall bias in the PCE chain price
index will be 0.6 percent per year in 1999--two-tenths less than the CPI. A little more guess
work was involved in deriving a measure of the bias in the GDP price index. But using the
available research and a dose of judgment, we estimate a bias of 0.7 percent per year.
There isn't much evidence on whether these biases might have changed over time. It's
possible that the rapid pace of technical change that we perceive in recent years has led to an

5
intensification of measurement problems. But, the Stigler Commission established to study
the CPI in the early 1960s reported with similar intensity many of the same quality
adjustment and new goods bias problems that we discuss today.
In the final section of the paper, we explored how stabilization of various inflation
measures might affect the behavior of real output and interest rates. Because certain price
indexes are more sensitive to certain types of shocks, stabilizing different price measures
could have different consequences for the variability of real output and interest rates. For
example, because we consume more petroleum products than we produce, fluctuations in oil
prices have larger effects on PCE prices than GDP prices. Consequently, if these were the
chief source of inflation disturbances, limiting fluctuations in PCE prices could result in
larger fluctuations in real output than would a similar stabilization of GDP prices. Of course,
the opposite could be true as well; domestic productivity shocks would have larger effects on
production prices than consumption prices.
In the event, stochastic simulations of the staffs econometric model using shocks that
have typified the past thirty years suggested macroeconomic performance would not be much
affected by the inflation measure that is stabilized. Stabilizing either PCE or GDP price
inflation results in about equal volatility of real output around potential. Roughly the same
result held when we used shocks drawn from the events of the past ten years--PCE and GDP
prices perform about equally well.
Finally, we compared targeting PCE prices to targeting core PCE prices. We found
that we could achieve lower combinations of inflation and output variability when policy
responded to the total PCE inflation measure rather than just the core measure. Within the

6
context of our model, this result occurs because food and energy shocks have effects that feed
back onto real output and inflation. If policymakers ignore the potential propagation of these
shocks when they occur, they will have to push harder on real output later on to reverse these
effects.
Two caveats are in order with respect to this finding. First, the result may be specific
to our model. For example, if households and businesses largely ignore the effects of food
and energy shocks in forming inflation expectations, the adverse feedbacks that are
incorporated in our model might be smaller in reality. The second caveat is that
policymakers may be able to sort out permanent from transitory shocks. Obviously, if we
were confident in our abilities to make accurately that distinction, you could respond to the
permanent shocks and largely ignore the temporary shocks. Nevertheless, the model results
are useful in pointing out the danger of focusing on too narrow a price measure in making
policy.
In conclusion, I think the authors covered a great deal of useful ground and made
substantial progress in clarifying some of the issues that confront monetary policy in a lowinflation environment. However, we recognize that we still have a long way to go and that
there are some significant gaps in our knowledge. In that regard, I should note that
considerable work--both theoretical and empirical--is under way around the System to address
the policy issues growing out of the U.S. economy's approach to price stability.

MONEY AND DEBT RANGES
FOMC BRIEFING
Thomas D. Simpson
July 2, 1997
The choice regarding annual ranges for broad money and debt
The staff is again projecting that

conjures up a sense of deja vu.

growth in M2 will be near and M3 a little above the upper ends of
their respective ranges for this year.

Moreover, the picture does not

change greatly for next year, measured against the current ranges
which were first selected in mid-1995.

In contrast, debt of domestic

nonfinancial sectors continues to expand around the midpoint of the
3 to 7 percent range that was first adopted at the beginning of 1995.
Perhaps the best way to examine these projections is to begin
with debt.

The top panel of your first exhibit shows that we expect

debt this year and next to continue growing in the 4-1/2 to 5-1/2
percent shaded area that has characterized the period since 1990.
This is close to projected growth in nominal GDP this year and a
little faster than GDP next year.

The composition of total debt

growth, however, is shifting a little from federal, the thin line, to
private borrowing.

Within the private sector, borrowing by businesses

is expected to be boosted by healthy gains in capital outlays, in the
context of little further improvement in internally generated funds,
while household debt decelerates further but continues to outpace
income.

In the period ahead, we see private sector borrowing

restrained only fractionally by a shift by creditors away from
accommodation toward snugging.

With banks and thrifts healthy and

lending continuing to be profitable, even as credit quality erodes a
bit, we foresee depository credit growing in line with or a touch
faster than debt over these two years, as shown by the thin line in
the lower panel.

The top panel of your next exhibit illustrates the staff's
projected funding by banks and thrifts of those depository credit
flows.

The M3 funding of depository credit, the shaded portion of the

bars, picked up in 1995 around the time that depository credit moved
higher.

In particular, issuance of large time deposits, shown in the

center panel for commercial banks, reversed course and has risen
smartly ever since.

Last year, M3 was lifted by some substitution of

CDs for liabilities to foreign offices, the broken line, although that
runoff may be drawing to an end, perhaps owing to the pickup in credit
this year that needs to be financed.

We expect recent funding

patterns, with a considerable emphasis on M3 sources, to persist
through next year.
We also expect that money market mutual funds in M3,

shown in

the memo line of the lower panel, will continue to grow very rapidly
reflecting to their popularity for liquidity management, imparting
some upward thrust to M3.

As a consequence, the staff projects that

M3 will grow 6-1/2 percent this year and 6 percent next year, also
shown in the lower panel, extending to four the number of consecutive
years of M3 growth in the 6 to 6-3/4 percent area.
Probably of more importance to the Committee is M2 and the
issue of whether its recent behavior has been in line with a more
traditional velocity relationship.

Exhibit 3 plots the now-familiar

relationship between M2 velocity, the vertical axis, and a measure of
opportunity costs, the horizontal axis, and is the same as chart 6 in
the bluebook.

As illustrated in the upper panel, along the top line,

recent observations remain in the cluster that has characterized the
period since mid-1994, which is amplified in the lower panel.

The

implied velocity relationship--as embodied in the slope of the line-has properties that are quite similar to the one that characterized

the three-decade period ending in the late 1980s, the lower line in
the upper panel.
The incoming evidence on the M2 relationship has, indeed,
been encouraging.

Staff analysis suggests that, in addition to a

similar relationship with opportunity costs as before, recent
experience has been consistent with less noise in the V2-opportunity
cost relationship and a prompter response of M2 to movements in
interest rates and income than before.
Nonetheless, the period of closer fit still is quite short in
terms of statistical reliability, and one that has been on the
tranquil side of longer historical experience.

Moreover, the

financial environment has changed in some important ways since the
late 1980s,

such as the much greater availability and lower

transactions costs of long-term mutual funds, which as an analytical
matter might suggest changes in velocity behavior.

These

considerations would seem to argue for continued caution in viewing M2
as a serious guide to policy or a key indicator of economic
developments, although continued stability and predictability might
suggest that unexpected movements in this aggregate deserve some
weight in the constellation of indicators that you rely on in
assessing economic

and price trends.

Our forecast of growth in M2 for this year, 4-1/2 percent,
falls a little shy of that of income and thus our expected Q4 velocity
in the lower panel, shown by a red X, stands a little above that of
Q4:1996.

Next year, we are projecting that M2 growth, at 4 percent,

will again fall short of income, implying a value of V2 for Q4:1998
shown by the other red X.

The rise in V2 next year owes to some

assumed monetary tightening over the second half of the year.

In view of these various considerations, the staff has
suggested two alternative sets of ranges, shown on exhibit 4, which
also appear on page 20 of the bluebook.

Alternative I ranges are

those adopted for 1997 by the Committee in February, and alternative
II ranges are higher by 1 percentage point for M2 and 2 percentage
points for M3, better centering them on staff projections both for
this year and next.
both alternatives.

The suggested range for debt is the same under
I would note that your central tendency for growth

in nominal GDP, shown as a memo line, brackets the staff forecast for
this year but is a little higher for next year.

This implies that if

your financial assumptions are similar to those of the staff, your
expectations for money and debt growth, based on normal velocity
behavior, are similar to those of the staff for this year but perhaps
a bit stronger for 1998.
Should the Committee believe that velocity relationships are
still rather uncertain and that the most effective role for the ranges
continues to be as benchmarks of monetary growth under price stability
and historically normal velocity behavior, then alternative I would
again seem to be favored, both for 1997 and 1998.

The midpoint of

alternative I for M2 is 3 percent, close to staff's expectation of
nominal GDP growth under price stability.

Because we would also

expect debt growth to average around 3 percent in these
circumstances--the bottom of the current debt range--the Committee
might want to consider lowering the range for debt to that of M2, were
the debt range, too, to be viewed as a benchmark under price
stability.

However, changing any of the ranges could run the risk of

being construed by the public as suggesting that the Committee would
be placing greater emphasis on the money or debt aggregates in its
conduct of policy than it has in recent years.

Should the Committee instead wish to announce ranges
consistent with its expectations for money and debt growth, it still
could choose between alternatives I and II.

Alternative I ranges

might be favored in this context if the Committee thought that
velocity relationships had become reasonably predictable again and it
wanted the ranges to convey expectations of money growth under a
relatively tight policy stance designed to lean against upward
inflationary pressures.

Were there concerns that a boom economy might

be in the offing, M2 in that event would likely breach the upper end
of the alternative I range, providing a further rationale for
imposing more monetary restraint.
Alternative II ranges are better centered on staff
projections, given the Greenbook forecast and its financial
assumptions.

Moreover, they might be viewed as more consistent with

the Committee's expectations for 1998,
nominal GDP growth.

given your central tendency for

Furthermore, alternative II ranges provide

greater scope for real output to expand in line with favorable supply
shocks to the economy as well as a little more headroom if the
Committee foresaw turbulence in equity markets as a distinct
possibility and the monetary aggregates becoming a likely refuge for
shell-shocked investors.

Strictly Confidential (FR) Class I FOMC

MATERIAL FOR STAFF PRESENTATION ON
MONEY AND DEBT RANGES

July 1-2, 1997

Exhibit 1

Domestic Nonfinancial Debt

Exhibit 2

Flows of Depository Credit and M3 and Non-M3 Sources of Funding
(Billions of dollars)

Exhibit 3

M2 Velocity and Opportunity Cost
1959:Q1-1997:Q1

1994:Q3-1997:Q2; 1997:Q4, 1998:Q4

Exhibit 4
GROWTH OF MONEY AND DEBT AND ALTERNATIVE RANGES
(Percent)

July 2,

1997

FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn
I'll begin with some thoughts on the longer-term strategies
section of the bluebook, talk a bit about how the results of
those exercises might--or might not--relate to the current
situation and finish with proposed changes in the wording of the
operational paragraph of the directive.
My take on the modeling exercises will start with chart 2
following page 6 of the bluebook.

These simulations are built

from the Greenbook forecast and illustrate the basic risk
embodied in that forecast.

Specifically, that the economy most

likely is operating beyond its sustainable potential, and unless
the Committee tightens sufficiently at some point, inflation will
be on an upward trajectory.
This imbalance has opened up despite a real federal funds
rate, shown in the upper right panel, that is at or even above
its historical averages.

Those historical averages do not factor

in the extraordinary contribution of recent financial conditions
in supporting spending.

In effect, the rise in stock prices and

unusually generous provision of credit to many private borrowers,
through their effects on wealth and on the cost of funds, are
seen as having substantially increased the equilibrium rate.

In

the staff forecast, narrowing profit margins take their toll on
equity prices and credit availability, and fiscal policy continues to be modestly restrictive, reducing the equilibrium

2
rates.

Eventually, a real funds rate around its current level

becomes high enough to bring aggregate demand in line with longrun supply.

But this happens over a period of years.

In the

interim, inflation picks up, so that merely avoiding a decline in
the real funds rate will require raising the nominal rate--a
process the Greenbook assumes gets started in the second half of
next year.
If the staff has correctly identified the risks, the question is not whether the funds rate will have to be raised, but
only when, by how much, for how long, and what will be the
eventual inflation rate.

Once an output gap has opened, infla-

tion pressures begin to build, and the sooner action is taken,
the less disruptive will be the needed adjustment.

At this

point, according to the model, holding inflation near its recent
levels without incurring a recession--the "stable inflation"
strategy--can be accomplished with fairly prompt action and a
moderate rise in the nominal funds rate over the next year.
These simulations were done by taking the extended Greenbook
forecast and manipulating the federal funds rate to achieve
particular outcomes.

A more general question concerns the Com-

mittee's strategy in responding to actual or expected deviations
of output from potential and inflation from its objectives as the
economy is subjected to unexpected developments.

In particular,

we were interested in comparing the consequences of a so-called
opportunistic strategy--one that waits for favorable surprises
to reduce inflation from moderate levels--to strategies that

3
deliberately seek lower inflation.

To make this comparison, we

needed to move away from the Greenbook projections and subject
the staff's econometric model to a set of surprises that
approximates those that have hit the economy over the last
several decades.

These are the stochastic simulations in the

second part of this bluebook section.

We tried to look at two

potential issues--getting to price stability, and what happens
once you're there.
As to the first issue, the results shown on chart 4 after
page 12 address the transition from one steady state with inflation at 2-1/2 percent to another with inflation at 1 percent.
The asymmetric responses of an opportunistic policymaker to inflationary and deflationary surprises under these circumstances
do guarantee that the long-run inflation goal is eventually
achieved.

Not surprisingly, it takes considerably longer on

average if a policymaker waits for favorable shocks rather than
deliberately seeking price stability.

In fact, the time to get

to price stability under the opportunistic strategy depends on
the nature of the shocks hitting the economy--the smaller the
shocks, the longer the time.

All policies ultimately entail

about the same cumulative output loss, but the deliberate
policymaker takes that loss earlier, for a shorter time, and in
the form of larger output gaps than does the opportunistic
policymaker.

The model, as we used it, does not differentiate

between deliberate and opportunistic policies in terms of the
public's understanding of the System's objectives and hence the

4
credibility of policy.

Moreover, it makes no provision for

reduced distortions and enhanced efficiencies as inflation falls;
presumably the choice between these approaches would rest, in
part, on an evaluation of the benefits of achieving price
stability sooner under a deliberate strategy relative to the
costs of the sharper output losses likely to be involved.
Within the set of deliberate strategies, it is instructive
to compare the Henderson-McKibben or target zone policy rules to
the Taylor rule.

Not only is attention to output gaps entirely

consistent with achieving inflation objectives, but placing more
weight on such gaps than on the deviations of inflation from its
objective, as in the Henderson-McKibben rule, may involve
achieving this goal on average with less wrenching adjustments.
Comparing chart 4 with chart 5, which is after page 15,
raises the question as to whether strategies need to be adapted
once the inflation objective has been reached.

This is an

important topic--and a full treatment would deal with the
potential problems of the zero interest rate constraint, among
many other issues. As you can see, given shocks of the nature of
those of the last 30 years, there is a substantial probability of
measured inflation falling below zero when one is your objective.
In this limited exercise, opportunism, which to be sure is
usually presented as a transition strategy, fares poorly in the
steady state in terms of damping variations in inflation around a

5
goal.

Henderson-McKibben seems to do very well, with its strong

responses to inflation and especially output gaps.
But, I should caution, a number of caveats apply to this
result, raising questions about whether vigorous policy responses
are always advisable in the real world--especially the world you
are facing now.

First, the parameters of the Henderson-McKibben

rule were derived to work well in a model not too dissimilar from
the one actually used to generate these simulations.

In addi-

tion, in using a model--and in particular its steady state--we
are assuming that the underlying structure of the economy is
known and does not change over time; in the exercises, all the
surprises that the economy faces involve the positions of the
various functions, not the slopes.

The size of the coefficients

that govern how the economy responds to monetary policy are known
with certainty.

As you discussed at your last meeting, some

kinds of uncertainty--especially about the response of the
economy to policy--do argue for a cautious approach.
Moreover, forceful policy is most appropriate when surprises
are in aggregate demand.

In such circumstances, output and in-

flation are moving in the same direction; with no short-run
tradeoffs, vigorous policy is stabilizing in every respect.

In

effect, the staff forecast embodies such a shock, in which unanticipated strength in aggregate demand has pushed the economy
past its sustainable potential.

Recent favorable inflation out-

comes are seen, in part, as the consequence of temporary factors
that are likely to dissipate, as Dave Stockton discussed.

This

6
is what gives the payoff we saw in the first set of simulations
from prompt policy actions, and would be the rationale for an
immediate tightening, as in alternative C.
Such a response might not be appropriate if the surprises
are more on the supply side of the economy.

Supply shocks do

entail tradeoffs, in which policymakers might well choose more
restrained actions that take some of the surprise in prices and
some in output.

Dave's briefing modelled a favorable producti-

vity surprise in which the Committee could realize some combination of lower inflation and higher production.

The bluebook

showed an exercise in which NAIRU was 4-3/4 percent, and holding
the funds rate locked in the current unemployment and inflation
rates.
Thus, in formulating policy, differentiating among various
types of shocks is essential, but this can be quite difficult as
events unfold.

Key uncertainties at this time surround the

relationship of output to prices--whether or to what extent there
has been a favorable shift in the economy's aggregate supply.
The combination of an upside surprise to output and shortfall in
inflation in the first half of this year does suggest the
possibility of a favorable supply shock, rather than a shift in
demand.
In these circumstances, the Committee may view recent data
as at least justifying maintaining the "wait and see" posture of
alternative B to assess the current situation.

It may view data

on actual prices and the absence of most early signs of pressures

7
on margins and prices, as increasing the possibility that the
economy is not producing appreciably beyond its potential.
Moreover, slowing final demand may suggest that the expansion is
moderating enough to hold the economy at its present level of
resource utilization, limiting any buildup of inflation pressures
that may be occurring.

Finally, with inflation already quite

low, the Committee may see the gains from further disinflation as
sufficiently small to take a bit of a chance on the economy being
able to sustain the current high operating level.
But, as I noted, identifying the type of shock is
problematic in real time.

Prices usually lag output, and move-

ments or surprises in prices and economic activity over a relatively short interval--such as the first half of this year--may
not be unambiguous indicators of the underlying situation.

The

size of the decline in the unemployment rate and the degree of
strength in output may suggest that at least some of the firsthalf performance reflected a positive demand surprise that
threatens to outpace any lasting upward shift in sustainable
supply.

Any such increases in long-term supply are likely to

occur relatively slowly if they are the result of a pick up in
productivity trends that are just becoming visible in the data,
or of more flexible product and labor markets.
Consequently, even if the Committee believes the staff has
not fully taken into account the implications of the recent good
price performance, it may see the risks still as tilted toward
higher inflation.

If so, at some point it may wish to consider

8
further tightening, even before it sees convincing evidence of
accelerating prices.

If demand has overshot potential, as the

simulations showed, the longer corrective action is delayed, the
more difficult the adjustment is likely to be.

So long as the

Committee saw this to be a distinct possibility, and the incoming
data weren't contradicting this hypothesis, a gradual, occasional
firming might be one possible approach, which ensured against
cumulating inflation pressures.

A view that higher inflation

remained the major risk to the economy, and one that was serious
enough to potentially warrant Committee action before too long,
could be reflected by retaining the asymmetrical language of the
directive.
And that brings me to my final subject.

The bluebook sug-

gests Committee consideration of the changes in the wording of
two sentences in the operational paragraph of the directive,
which are shown on page 31.

In the first sentence, the alter-

native would make explicit your expectations for the funds rate-something you now do in public announcements of policy changes.
We propose retaining the language that indicates that you work
through reserve markets to the federal funds rate, rather than
simply giving a funds rate target.

This is an accurate

description of the process, and avoiding the implication that the
Federal Reserve controls the federal funds rate absolutely and
directly might be especially helpful if that rate becomes more
variable with the drop in reserve balances.

9
The second suggestion involves the sentence dealing with
intermeeting changes in the reserve conditions and the funds
rate.

No changes are proposed for the preamble of the sentence,

which describes the background against which any such decision
should be made.

But we do give possible alternative wording for

the part of the sentence that establishes symmetry or asymmetry.
The alternative drops the would/ might and slightly/somewhat
distinctions, which the Committee has been making less use of in
recent years.

In addition, in framing the symmetry/asymmetry

language we tried to give a sense of what this might mean in the
context of considering an intermeeting policy adjustment.
Specifically, it seems to imply something about how
information is weighed.

incoming

For example, an unexpected pickup in

consumer prices might be more likely to trigger consideration of
action if the Committee were already concerned about the risks
that inflation would rise.

We recognize that various members

interpret this part of the directive differently, that no
intermeeting adjustment has been made for some time, and that we
may feel a certain kinship with Pandora before the discussion
proceeds very far.

Indeed, the Committee has lived for some time

with the "constructive ambiguity" of the current wording of this
sentence, and may prefer to continue in this mode.