View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

S

//IV~ak

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

/i

I

ARD OF GOVERNORB
Or THU

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Office Correspondence
TO
From

Date

Robert Solomon

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL

Attached for your

(FR)

information are the sum-up

remarks of the Fund Team in the U.S. Consultations, as
J. J. Polak yesterday.

This statement

is being held closely and is not being given to the
Executive Board of the Fund.

Cs
Attachment.

15, 1967.

December15,
19

IMFConsultations
Consultations with
with the U.S.
Subject: IMF

Board of Governors

presented by Mr.

December

Confidential
Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

Article VIII Consultation with the United States, 1967

Remarks by J. J. Polak for the Fund Team
December 14, 1967

We are indeed grateful for the cooperation you have given us in this
Article VIII consultation exercise.

Your responses to the many questions

we have raised, both written and oral, have provided the essential basis
for a very informative report to the Fund's Executive Board.

At this point,

I should like to sum up the way we see your economic situation and policies.
Although you may be sure that our report to the Board will attempt to give
a balanced picture of the

U.S. economic performance, I will focus

here mainly on problems and difficulties rather than on achievements.

We

consider this another working meeting, and are anticipating some further
active discussion.
On this same occasion a year ago, I reviewed the developmentof 1965
and 1966 that had led to accelerated price and cost increases, to the
emergence of distortions in the domestic economy, to a sharp deterioration
of the current account in the balance of payments, and to the creation of
various problems for national economic policy in 1967.

I then went on to

observe that there did not appear to be a set of policies that could get all
the variables back on track in the short run, and that economic management
for the next year or so might have to settle for a combination of results
that would fall short of optimum in at least some directions.
Unfortunately, the same general sitaution still prevails.

Little head-

way seems to have been made during 1967 in returning to a situation of
balanced progress toward multiple economic objectives--especially when such
progress is judged in terms of the Administration's hopes and projections at
the beginning of the year.

Clearly, some important problems remain:

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-2-

First, over-all prices have increased in 1967, once again, more than
was expected by U.S. officials and more than would be acceptable to the
authorities on a longer-run basis.
Second, the expansion of real output this year over 1966--at about 2 1/2
per cent--has been much below the economy's noninflationary potential growth
rate.

Within the year 1967, the problem facing the authorities has shifted

all the way from the avoidance of recession, which happily was successful, to
the restraint of aggregate demand and the restoration of balance in the economy-on which issues the jury is still out, primarily because of the difficulties
encountered in setting fiscal policy for the period ahead.

The year 1967 has

certainly posed some unusual problems for demand management, and in this
connection the Council is to be commended for having foreseen last January
the broad contour of cyclical developments.
Third, the improvement in the external current

account this year has

been substantially less than that projected in the Council's Report last
January.

As to the balance of payments as a whole, the deterioration from

1966 to 1967 has not conformed with the anticipation you expressed in last
year's consultation that further progress would be made over the near term
in reducing the payments deficit.
But let us now look ahead.

In an assessment of the economic outlook

for 1968 there are numerous questions relating to aggregate demand.

What

significance should be attached to the recent slowing down in various economic
indicators, including retail sales?
rates of saving?

Will consumers reduce their recent high

What is the probable course of outlays for residential

construction under differing assumptions about the tightness of monetary

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-3-

conditions?

How much further will the current effrts to curb federal spend-

ing be extended?

How strong will be the forces that seem likely to impart

a temporary thrust to aggregate spending during the first half of
year?

next

All in all, the economic outlook for 1968 seems somewhat less clear

than it did last August when the Administration presented its fiscal proposals,
featuring a 10 per cent tax surcharge.

But this aspect of the outlook, while

noteworthy, is not something on which I would put special emphasis.

I do

believe, however, that the outlook has undergone significant alteration because
of the recent cuts in federal spending.
may
How much additional fiscal restraint/be needed depends, of course, on
one's judgment about the increase in GNP that is appropriate in view of policy
considerations in several areas.

During the past year or so, prices have in-

creased more than might have been expected in the light of accepted judgments
about the relationship between price movements and the pressure of demand on
the economy.

While cyclical forces should bring some improvement in productivity,

the recent evidence of continuing wage and price pressures is disturbing.

And

though we were glad to hear that "incomes policy decisions for 1968 are under
intensive study by the Administration," we would not expect developments in
this field to have a decisive impact during the coming year.

It seems to us

that the balance of risks lying ahead for the U.S. economy--not only domestically
but in the balance of payments as well--calls for a cautious approach to demand
have indicated/
management, and we would go somewhat further than you/in holding

/

next year's
expansion

of GNP below what might be justified in terms of capacity considerations alone.
After many years of payments deficit and several years of disappointing price
performance, some corrective action in this direction seems necessary--bearing
ear ly
if
an/improvement
real
cost
larger
a
much
incurring
risk
of
in mind also the
with respect to
/ these policy aspects is not achieved.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-4-

Our judgment about the need to moderate the expansion of GNP implies
the application of some further restraint, and it would be unfortunate if
too much of the strain again fell on financial markets--in particular, on
the mortgage market.

Thus, we share your hope that an increase in income

taxes will be enacted in the very near future, although a somewhat smaller
increase than originally requested might now be appropriate in the light of
the cuts that have been made since August in planned federal expenditures.
Needless to say, we are aware that it may not prove possible to put
through a tax bill/at a very early date.

Neither we nor, we suspect, anyone

else is now in a position to judge the suitability of any particular tax
measure to be enacted several months hence.

This would depend, among other

things, on the revenues and expenditures projected in the federal budget for
the fiscal year 1969.
current
The experience of the past few months has pointed up the/difficulty of
making timely adjustments in fiscal policy.

This inevitably limits the relevance

of the near-term economic outlook in the consideration of a particular major
tax proposal.

On the one hand, the tax change may not be enacted for many

months, by which time the outlook may have altered considerably.

On the

other hand, the new tax rates, once in effect, may be difficult to increase
or decrease, whatever changes may have occurred in the economic outlook after
their enactment.
to search

These thoughts are not comforting.
for fiscal flexibility.

They underline the need

Without this, there is a risk of

serious departures from good economic performance, not only in an aggregate
sense but also with respect to the distortions that follow from the too
strenuous use of monetary policy that might be necessary in the circumstances.
The fundamental lesson seems clear--that ways must be found to bring more order
into the use of fiscal policy through an improvement of the procedures in this
area.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020
-5-

The fact is that monetary policy had to be modified significantly in the
course of 1967 (as in 1966) to meet the changing pressures in the economy and
in financial markets.

The expansionary policy followed by the Federal Reserve

System beginning late

in 1966 was well suited to the circumstances.

Given the

situation that had developed by the fall of the year, there can be no question
that the economy needed stimulus and that the financial system itself needed
respite from an intolerable degree of strain.

Since around the middle of

1967, there has been an appropriate change in the direction in which financial
conditions have moved.

The earlier pattern of easing--with the important cross-

current since early 1967 of rising long-term interest rates--has given way to a
broad, although gradual, move toward tighter conditions throughout financial
markets

as the economy has picked up.

It is admittedly difficult to judge whether this tightening has gone far
enough.

Important considerations have counseled against too rapid a tightening

of financial conditions.

In the early fall of 1967 scarcely a year had passed

since the financial system began to recover from the squeeze of 1966:

one would

not have lightly run the risk of plunging back into anything like that situation.
Moreover, the increasingly difficult position of the pound sterling would have
suffered from too sharp an upward adjustment in U.S. interest rates.

Hopes for

action on the tax bill also militated against vigorous action in the monetary field.
The changes which have occurred in the level and structure of interest rates
and in the position of financial institutions have in all likelihood not yet
reached the point of markedly affecting spending plans for early 1968.

From now

on, the monetary authorities may well face the difficult position where further
restraint will be needed--even though this restraint could have much of its effect
later in the year when the economy may well have entered into a stage of less
rapid expansion.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-6-

I turn now to the balance of payments and the question of gold.

We

are aware of the fact that we are dealing here with extremely sensitive
issues that require careful and delicate treatment.

However, we have had

the benefit of frankness on your side in describing the U.S. position on
these matters, and we feel that we would be less than forthcoming if we
did not give you our views with equal candor.

Needless to say, we invite--

and will doubtless receive--your frank reactions.
As I indicated last week, we have noted two broad stages of approach
by the United States to its balance of payments problem during the 1960's.
The first stage was characterized by a belief that achievement of payments
equilibrium was just around the corner, and that this would come about
through the operation of fundamental market forces supplemented by unilateral
actions on the part of the United States.

This stage, which featured

proclamations and promises at the highest level, culminated in late 1965
with the announcement of a target of balance of payments equilibrium

for 1966.
The current stage of balance of payments policy can be said to have
begun in the early part of 1966 with the first official indication that
elimination of the deficit probably would not be feasible so long as the
war in Viet-Nam continued.

This was followed by evolution of the

"structural" thesis that the U.S. payments deficit is a counterpart of
the EEC surplus and is dependent for its elimination over the longer run
on an approach that sees the adjustment process as a matter of common
responsibility.
Since the concept of the U.S. payments deficit as a "structural"
problem has been introduced into our discusions, I should like to make a
few comments on it--although this is not the time for a full consideration

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-7-

of this complex matter.

There is, of course, no disagreement on our part

with the general proposition that payments imbalances should be tackled by
surplus and deficit countries alike.

But is it not too narrow a view to

regard the current problem as involving simply a U.S.-EEC confrontation?
To mention one fact, for example, in the past several years the over-all
surplus of the EEC countries has amounted to less than half of the total
surpluses of all countries.

Even insofar as the EEC countries are con-

cerned, the United States does not need to be mesmerized by their over-all
surplus.

There is no evidence that these countries are intent on having

a surplus at all costs; and insofar as they were, this would not necessarily
involve a U.S. deficit as its counterpart:

the solution could lie in the

area of reserve creation, as U.S. officials have stressed in another context.
What particularly concerns us in this new U.S. "structural" approach
to the international payments problem is that it can easily be interpreted
to mean that the United States can relax, or has no option other than to
relax, unless there are corresponding efforts from the other side.

This

attitude seems indeed to be reflected in your description of the 1968
payments outlook, which conveyed to us the prospect of another year of
"drift" and "wait and see".

We did not find an evident real concern about

possible continuance of the deficit at the higher

1 96 7

once again, hopes for some improvement were expressed.

level even though,
And we were not

told that there is a U.S. policy intention to reduce the payments deficit
over the near term and to bring the balance of payments under firmer control.
If the United States has a strategy along these lines, it has not been made
public; nor has it been brought out in our consultation discussions.

We

cannot avoid the impression that the balance of payments has a lower priority

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-8-

in U.S. economic policy than it did some years ago.

Whether or not you

agree with this, I am sure that many others, both in this country and
abroad, have the same impression.
In our view, U.S. policy can hardly be based on the confident assumption that year after year two

or three billions of dollars can be injected

into the world economy by U.S. deficit
loss.

without an ever increasing gold

In the earlier years, conversion of dollars was limited to those

held officially.

A variety of understandings have now been evolved by

which many countries have been refraining from conversions of dollars into
gold which they might have wanted to make in other circumstances; and,
indeed, some countries have backed off further by turning liquid dollars
into somewhat longer assets for various reasons, including a desire to
help reduce the U.S. payments deficit on a "liquidity" basis.

The short-

run strategy that inspires such measures is obvious; at the same time,
U.S. officials are no doubt aware that these measures are not in the long
run conducive to enhancing the status of the dollar as a fully satisfactory
reserve asset.
While the question of official conversion has thus lost some of its
immediate importance, private dollar holdings have been given de facto
convertibility into gold via

the London gold market since November 1960.

I am not all that pessimistic about the long-run balance between supply
and demand in this market, as seems to have become the fashion.

Nonetheless,

it seems to me that two propositions with respect to the London gold market
are clearly true in present circumstances:
First, that the current supply flowing into it is not adequate to meet
total demand whenever speculative forces of some magnitude make themselves
felt on the demand side, and

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-n

d

..

Second, that speculative forces will continue

to appear as long as

a solution to the U.S. balance of payments problem is not reasonably in
sight.
The view that a continuing U.S. deficit willultimately lead to a
rise in the price of gold is rather widely held.
found encouragement

This view has no doubt

in statements made by private persons of importance

that cessation of gold sales by the United States might not necessarily be
a bad idea.

In this whole setting, it is not difficult to understand the

continued flow of some savings into gold on the part of such investors as
are allowed to take this action.
We have not the slightest doubt that the resources of gold at the
disposal of the gold pool members are large enough to weather any speculative bouts in the London market.

The financial measures to limit gold

speculation on credit that have been taken in Switzerland, and perhaps

elsewhere, can also be significant in this connection.

But given the

close balance, at best, that exists between the nonspeculative demand
for and the supply of gold, and in the absence of stronger evidence that
the United States is tackling its payments problem, it seems doubtful to
us that either the determination of the gold pool, or the legal measures

to control speculative demand in it, would prevent the steady drain of
gold that would convince speculators that they are on the winning side
in this battle.
At present, moreover, the availability of gold to the gold pool is
clouded by uncertainty as to the status of most of U.S. gold.

On December 6,

the President reaffirmed the U.S. pledge to keep the dollar strong and added
that "every ounce of our gold stock stands behind that pledge".

We have

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

- 10 -

noted, however, that this statement by the President seems to have been
ignored by newspapers here and abroad in the same way as they ignored an
equally strong statement made some years ago by the Chairman of the Federal
Reserve Board.

In the public mind only a small amount of gold is available

until the minimum "cover" is reached.

In the circumstances, legislation to

repeal the "cover" provision seems urgent, and if it were felt that such
legislation could not be passed promptly much wider knowledge

should be

given to the escape clauses that do, in fact, permit the use of all U.S.
gold even under present legislation.
I have ventured into this rather gloomy discussion of the gold situation not as an exercise in prediction, but to point up a matter that is
of real concern to us.

For our part, we see a contradiction between, on

the one hand, the present approach of the U.S. authorities to the balance
of payments and, on the other hand, their strong and unequivocal position
publicly taken with respect to the dollar price of gold.

In our view, the

way to resolve this contradiction in policy is the adoption of a much
more positive attitude on the part of the United States toward its balance
of payments problem.

We would not for a moment suggest that the United

States cease to stress the importance of the contribution that European
countries and surplus countries elsewhere can make to a smooth adjustment
process by suitable payments policies of their own.

Certainly, the Fund

itself will continue to stress these aspects of the adjustment process.

But

we would suggest that the United States redirect its policies--comprehensively-so as to make clear that it is determined to bring about a substantial
improvement in its payments position.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

-

ii -

As I indicated, I had the balance of payments in mind when I suggested
a few minutes ago that the general instruments of fiscal and monetary policy
should be directed toward a certain moderation of the expansion of GNP in
1968.

This should be helpful with respect to prices and costs and the current

account, especially on the import side.

In this connection, let me say that

we agree very much with the Secretary of the Treasury's statement of November
17 regarding the importance to the balance of payments of a return to relative
price stability and cost competitiveness in the domestic economy.

This is

surely the correct emphasis; even though the effects of rising unit labor costs
may not be discernible in short/run changes in export prices and export market

shares, the importance of these effects is not to be minimized.
It is not my intention to try to provide a detailed blueprint of the

more specific measures that might be adopted by the United States to improve
its balance of payments position.

Aside from the further restriction of govern-

ment expenditures abroad, such measures would need to be concentrated on the
capital account, and a thorough review of the voluntary restraint programs would
certainly be called for.

Here, my primary aim is to stress.the overriding

need for the U.S. authorities to make an early decision to give the balance of
payments a higher priority in the scheme of public policy, and to support this
decision with a combination of general and specific measures sufficient to bring
about a substantial reduction in the payments deficit.
There is a point that needs to be made in conclusion.

I have called attention

to the contradiction between the clearly stated U.S. objective with respect to

the dollar price of gold and the absence of firm action on the balance of payments,
and I have suggested that this contradiction be resolved by the adoption of a
broad policy addressed to a strengthening of the payments position.

Now, I would

not want to leave the impression with anyone in this audience that there is

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 5/27/2020

- 12 -

another choice--that the United States could opt for a soft payments policy

if only it were willing to abandon its attachment to the $35 an ounce price
for gold.

I do not believe there is such an option.

As far as we can see, the choice for the United States is not whether
to take a much more determined position on the balance of payments but when
to do so.

If such a position is taken promptly, it should be possible to

maintain the present gold price not only for official settlements but also
for private transactions against convertible currencies.

Delay i/such a

decision may bring the United States to a position where it still has to
adopt a payments policy in order to maintain the price of gold in official
settlements.

And one may envisage a third stage in which gold has been

"demonetized" and perhaps all countries are on a day-to-day basis on a
dollar standard.

Even for that world--which for reasons that I fail to

grasp seems to have a strong attraction to certain people--it would, I

think, be a complete illusion to believe that other countries would be
prepared to absorb a U.S. deficit in the form of a continuous addition
to their dollar holdings.

In other words, the United States would still

be faced with the need to remedy its payments position.
I am aware that I have been dealing with a series of rather grim
contingencies.

I am afraid that, in the circumstances, I have had no

choice but to put these stark truths on the table for your consideration
and discussion.