View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC BRIEFING - P.R. FISHER
JANUARY 31 - FEBRUARY 1, 1995

Mr. Chairman:
I will be referring to the three color charts on the single
page distributed this morning.

In describing domestic interest rate and foreign exchange
markets over the period, I will try to answer two questions:

First:

Why have expectations for interest rate increases
come down so much over the period, and

Second:

Why has the dollar weakened so much against the
German mark?

In response to the first question, I thinkthat expectations
for interest rate increases have unwound so much because they
were exaggerated -- at least, in part, because commonly-accepted
measures of those expectations were distorted by a number of
factors at the end of last year.

At the end of November and into early December,

the short-

end of the yield curve backed-up sharply as a number of bank
portfolios closed out positions in

two-

and three-year paper and

as Orange County's financing positions and portfolio were
liquidated.

At the same time,

market expectations for the

Committee's actions implied something of an extrapolation of what
was seen as the Committee's more aggressive approach in November.
Moreover,

these two phenomena

were mutually reinforcing.

Even

-

2

-

as market participants began to think that concerns about the
implications of Orange County might prevent an increase in rates
in December, market expectations for 150 basis points of
tightening by May appeared to justify 2-and 3-year yields over
seven and one half percent and, at the same time, short-end
yields at these levels were seen as confirming expectations for a
rapid increase in the Fed funds rate.

Over the course of January, there has been a gradual
unwinding both of expectations for Committee action and of the
"hump" in the yield curve.

For example, a major step in this process occurred following
the release on January 13th of the weaker-than-expected retail
sales.

In the first two panels of charts -- depicting the rates

implied by the monthly Fed Funds Futures contracts and the yield
curve -- the impact of this process can particularly be seen in
the shift from the green to the orange lines:

shaving

expectations for this meeting to a 50 basis point increase and,
more significantly, lowering the pace of expected increases in
the future.

While most people in the market remained skeptical about
either the accuracy or enduring significance of the retail sales
data, it did serve to remind market participants that they were
increasingly likely to face two-way risk in upcoming data

- 3

releases.

-

This, in turn, gave confidence to those wanting to

lock in the relatively high 2-to 5-year yields.

Thus, despite

much talk of "heavy supply," the market finally began to work
down the hump in the yield curve.

The release of fourth-quarter GDP last Friday, particularly
the inventory investment component, provided a similar occasion:
while the inventory estimate may be subject to revision, it
provided both a hint of a softening of demand and a reminder of
two-way risk in upcoming releases.
Turning to the dollar, in my opinion, it was precisely the
progressive unwinding of expectations for the Committee's
actions, and of short-end yields, that began to weigh on the
accumulated long-dollar positions in late December and triggered
the dollar's initial decline.

While the Mexican financial crisis

has recently begun to weigh on the dollar, this only became a
significant factor in mid-January, after the dollar's decline was
already well underway.

In December, I mentioned the surprising resilience of the
dollar in the face of events which, earlier in the year, would
have been expected to cause dollar weakness.

(These included the

resignation of Secretary Bentsen, the oscillations of the yield
curve surrounding Orange County and the Bankers Trust supervisory
announcement.)

The strong demand for dollars -- both corporate

and speculative -- was predicated on the numerous forecasts that

-

the dollar would rise in 1995.

4

-

To a great extent, these
the implications of the

forecasts themselves were based on:

rapidly flattening yield curve; the extrapolative projections of
the Committee's likely actions; and the absence of any data yet
indicating a slowing of the economy.

Having brought forward much of the demand for dollars into
early December, there were few firms seeking to buy dollars after
the Committee's December meeting.

In thin, holiday markets on

December 28th, after the European close, the dollar was subject
to an energetic effort to push it lower by triggering stop-loss
orders.

Given the lack of interested buyers, the dollar dropped

almost 3 pfennings in less than half an hour. However, it was
noted, and should be noted, that this initial drop merely
returned the dollar to the levels, around 1.55 marks, where
it had traded for several days after the Committee's November
75-basis point increase.

The dollar's second step lower occurred as a result of a
rush of demand for marks coming out of the politically- and
fiscally-weak European currencies.

It appears that several major

intermediaries, having taken long-dollar, short-mark positions
over the year-end, were caught wrong-footed by their customers'
demand for marks.

The quickest way to adjust their positions was

to sell dollar-mark and, on January 9th, again in New York

- 5 trading, the dollar fell nearly two pfennings in under

45

minutes.

With the dollar having demonstrated a surprising downward
momentum, and the yen eventually becoming subject to the
uncertainties of the Kobe earthquake, the mark quickly came to be
seen as the reserve currency of choice, rising to within a hair
of its all-time high on a trade-weighted basis on January 25th.
[199.40 vs. 200.40 on 10/5/92]

Thus, the dollar's first two steps lower were caused by the
unsustainability of the long-dollar positions, built-up in
December, in the face of the decreasing extent of expectations
for rate increases.

But by mid-January, as the expected duration

of the Mexican crisis shifted from temporary to indefinite, the
Mexican situation did begin to weigh on the dollar.

But there is

nothing especially "Mexican" about the specific mechanisms
through which the crisis has affected the dollar.

First, the Mexican crisis provided a further reason for the
unwinding of expectations for Committee actions -- on the
assumption that the Federal Reserve would not want to make
matters worse.

Indeed, because of the peso's weakness, and the

weakness of the Mexican financial system, foreign exchange market
participants became increasingly skeptical about the prospects

for the Committee to raise rates and about the prospects for the
dollar to rise even in the event of a Committee action.

Second, the Mexican crisis served as a catalyst for the
development of an alternative, negative forecast for the dollar
in 1995, which goes something like this:

If emerging market

economies, and Mexico in particular, are going to be a decreasing
source of demand for U.S. goods and services, while the U.S.
economy continues to grow strongly, then the U.S. current account
deficit is likely to increase.

If one combines a forecast for an

increasing current account deficit with a forecast for U.S.
interest rates to rise less, and less quickly, than previously
assumed, it is hard to see why one would expect the dollar to
move higher.

Finally, last week and on Monday, the foreign exchange
market has had something of a knee-jerk, negative reaction to the
political back-and-forth over the Mexican aid package.
Yesterday, the dollar got an initial bounce-back in early
European trading on rumors of concerted central bank dollar
support, indicating the nervousness of those who had taken shortdollar positions.

Apparently, just as the market was getting

comfortable with the idea that we were unlikely to be
intervening, and short-positions were being reestablished,
President Clinton's announcement hit the wires that "executive
authority" would be used for the Mexican package.

The scramble

-

7

-

to cover short positions again was made more urgent by the rumors
that the ESF would be selling its marks and yen to fund the
package.

Looking back over the month, it seems to me that by dint of
repetition, Mexico has become a bigger part of the accepted
But

explanation of why the dollar moved lower than is deserved.

now that the dollar is lower, and the perception of Mexico as a
contributing cause is widespread, the unresolved nature of the
peso crisis is one of the factors holding the dollar down.

In addition to the peso's weakness, the Canadian dollar has
been under pressure during the past month.

The markets exacted a

high price from the Bank of Canada for its failure to raise rates
in November in step with the Committee's 75 basis points.

Their

lagging rate increases, combined with market anxieties about the
Canadian government's fiscal policy and the Quebec separatist
referendum, brought the Canadian dollar to a 9-year low against
the U.S. dollar [1.4269 1/20] and pushed 30-year Canadian
interest rates up by over 50 basis points from early December.
By last week, however,through repeated rate increases, the Bank
of Canada seems to have persuaded the market that it will
maintain the higher, short-term rates to defend the currency,
stabilizing their dollar and bringing long-term rates back down.
If the Committee were to raise rates, I would expect the Bank of
Canada to match it with a 50 basis point increase of their own.

-

8

-

Turning to the Desks' operations, throughout the period,
domestic operations were aimed at maintaining the existing degree
of reserve pressure, with Fed funds expected to trade around

5 and one half percent, as directed by the Committee.

Year-end

pressures in the funds market only reached 7 percent, and by the
time traders left their desks for the New Year weekend, the funds
rate had touched a low of one-quarter percent.

The first part of the current maintenance period required a
draining of reserves as the seasonal increase in required
reserves and in currency rapidly reversed themselves.

Because of

the expected need to return to adding reserves in upcoming
maintenance periods, we met our draining needs with temporary
transactions and by the redemption of 600 million dollars in
7-year Treasury notes which matured without replacement.

Over

the past few days, we have returned to adding reserves as a rise
in the Treasury balance has introduced a temporary need, while
security market settlement pressures and expectations for a
policy move at the conclusion of this meeting have worked to
elevate rates in the money market.

Over the three maintenance periods since your last meeting,
the effective Fed funds rate has averaged 5.42, 5.49, and, as of
last night, 5.55 percent.

-9

-

Mr. Chairman, other than the 1.5 billion dollars in swap
drawings by the Bank of Mexico, during the period we had no
foreign exchange operations on behalf of the System's account.

I would be happy to answer any questions.

Monthly Effective Rates Implied by Federal Funds
Futures Contracts

Jan95
Feb95
Source: Bloomberg News Service

U.S. Treasury Yield Curve
8.00

8.00

7.80

7.80

7.60

7.60

7.40

7.40

7.20

7.20

7.00

7.00

6.80

6.80

1 yr

2 yr

3 yr

5 yr

10 yr

30 yr

Source: Bloomberg News Service

U.S. Dollar - German Mark
1.60
1.58
1.56
1.54

Nov

Source: Foreign Exchange Function
Markets Group: FRBNY

Dec

28

Jan

9

19

3

UpdatedJanuary 30, 1995

Michael J. Prell
February 1, 1995

FOMC BRIEFING

Anticipating that time would be short today, we
sure that we hit all the crucial points
Greenbook.

On the

to 1995.

in the two parts of the

assumption that we succeeded, I'll

underscore the highlights

tried to make

just quickly

of our forecast, particularly as they

Peter Hooper will then comment on the external

relate

sector.

And

I'll wrap up with a summary of the forecasts you submitted for use
the Humphrey-Hawkins
First,
assumption

in

report.

as you know, we've changed the monetary policy

for our

projection, to one of a stable federal funds rate.

I think we made this clear, but
not reflect an abandonment

let me emphasize that this change

did

of our basic view that further tightening

is needed if you wish to avoid a deterioration in the trend of
Rather, we

inflation.

at recent meetings

shifted our assumption partly because

suggested that some of you preferred to

comments

approach

the policy decision by thinking about what would occur if you left the
funds

rate at the prevailing level.

Indeed,

for some years now, it

has been our practice to base our forecast on a no-change assumption
except when it was

fairly clear that the Committee was

substantial policy moves,
funds

rate

or when it was

our judgment

anticipating
that such a

level would produce results that were obviously

unacceptable to you.
maximize the

Hopefully, by exploiting this flexibility, we

probability that our

projections will

provide a useful

reference point for your discussions.
One thing that made it a little easier to
funds

lower our baseline

rate path this time was the fact that we had decided to adopt a

FOMC Briefing--February 1, 1995

Michael J.

tighter fiscal policy assumption.

Prell

In a sense, the change we've made

could be characterized as conservative.
for granted that the Congress will

That

is, while we've taken it

pass a balanced budget amendment,

we've assumed that this will not cause a revolution in either
budgetary actions or market perceptions by the end of 1996.

Our

thinking is that it will be a while before ratification is assured,
and that--though lip-service will be paid to

implementation in the

coming months--the wrangling over the particulars will permit
enactment of only moderate budget cuts.

To be

sure, all of this is

highly conjectural, but we think it moves us closer than we were
before to the likely fiscal reality.
On balance, these
our

projection of real GDP

percent in 1996--about

revised assumptions have caused us to
growth to

raise

2-1/4 percent this year and 2-1/2

a half percentage point per year faster, on

average, than in the December Greenbook.

The drop-off in growth that

we are forecasting for this year from the 4 percent pace of 1994
obviously is substantial, and we feel kind of lonely when we look at
greater growth this year, with

outside forecasts--many of which have
rising interest

rates.

And we

hints at this point that
shaky early estimates for
anecdotes--sometimes

recognize that there are

any softening in demand is in train:
retail sales

late last year,

at least, that

our output forecast are reasonably balanced.

income;

of upbeat consumer sentiment

growing rapidly enough to generate
there also

and some

and houses.

But we've persuaded ourselves,

is still

some

supplied by industry advocates--regarding a

recent weakening in demand for autos

the indications

only a few

is a very strong tone to

manufacturing and nonresidential

The upside risks
and signs that
healthy gains

include

employment

in spendable

capital goods

construction.

- 2 -

the risks to

On the downside,

FOMC Briefing--February 1,

although we think most
quarter was

Michael J.

1995

of the inventory

investment

Prell

in the fourth

intended, the rate--which BEA guessed to be somewhat

higher than we did--does

not seem likely to persist

unless

expectations of higher prices become a much greater force than they
have been to date:
gearing down of the

in fact,

it

is not hard to

imagine a sharper

rate of accumulation than we have

could put a considerable dent in the momentum of the
might

also be argued that the risks

in the

attending the

international sphere have a downside bias

insofar as the prospects for our net exports
will be focusing on that
In any event,

issue in

economy.

It

recent developments
in the near term.

are concerned.

Peter

a few moments.

even with the

forecast, we believe that

forecast, which

rather tepid growth path we have

pressures on resources will

remain

in the underlying rate

appreciable and will result in an upward creep

projection is something of an act

of faith.

of inflation.

Again, this

There has been

no statistical evidence to date of a firming in the

underlying trend of retail
quarter

3.1

To the contrary, the fourth
in the core CPI.

saw a drop-off in the rate of increase
report

yesterday's
only

prices.

percent

on the

Employment Cost

Index showed an increase

than we

This

we can't

record understandably

rule out

realistically, given the

changed" with

change in the

regard

the

to

inflation.

recent good

news is

behavior of the economy.

noise in the data--and

having pierced the 6 percent
ago--it

has encouraged those who subscribe

the possibility that

signaling a fundamental

few months

in September, and two-

forecast.

to the view that "the world has
And

of

in private industry compensation over the past year--

two-tenths less than in the twelve months ended
tenths less

And.

But.

with unemployment

level we assumed to be the NAIRU only a

is just too

early to

expect

that

a change in the

FOMC Briefing--February 1,

Michael J.

1995

trend of inflation would be clearly

identifiable.

against rejection of our basic model at this

Prell

Also arguing

point is the anecdotal

evidence in the Beige Book and elsewhere that plainly suggests a
considerably more inflationary tone to labor and product markets over
the past few months.
Unfortunately, though it would be nice to think that the next
couple of CPI readings will settle the issue, experience--such as that
in the late 1980s--shows that the emergence of pickups in inflation
can be difficult to discern until the process is well advanced.

Thus,

we could well be in the position of having to make some difficult
judgment calls for a while, utilizing all of the statistical and
anecdotal information we can gather to assess the trends of wages and
prices.
At this point, let me turn the floor over to Peter.

- 4 -

February 1, 1995
Peter Hooper
FOMC Briefing

In recent weeks, developments in the international sphere have been more in the center
stage than usual. The peso crisis and, to a lesser extent, the earthquake in Japan not only have
rocked international financial markets but also affect the outlook for U.S. economic activity. I'll
briefly review these events and their implications and summarize our outlook for both the global
economy and the international sector of the U.S. economy.
Turning first to Mexico, our baseline forecast had assumed Congressional approval of the
$40 billion securities guarantee package. The multilateral support package announced yesterday
is of course intended to play the same role. Given this degree of support, we projected that the
peso would stabilize in the vicinity of 5.0 per dollar and that Mexican interest rates would recede
enough to keep the economy from dropping into recession. At the same time, we expect that
Mexico's macroeconomic stabilization program will reduce GDP growth to near zero this year,
down from 3 percent in 1994, and will yield enough wage and price restraint to ensure the peso
will have depreciated about 20 percent in real terms. Under these outcomes, Mexico's external
deficit would be cut roughly in half this year and somewhat more next year, from the $28 billion
deficit estimated for 1994. We expect most of this adjustment will fall on the United States, and
will reduce U.S. net export growth by an amount equal to nearly 1/4 percent of GDP, with much
of that effect coming in the first half of the year.

-5

Absent the multilateral support package,

-

we would see a much weaker peso, higher Mexican interest rates, a significant recession in
Mexico, and a greater decline in U.S. net exports--amounting to perhaps another 1/4 percent of
GDP.
While the United States stands to feel the largest direct effects of Mexico's impending
external adjustment, other countries have already felt negative repercussions from the peso crisis.
Argentina and Brazil, the two countries whose monetary systems come closest to Mexico's, have
suffered substantial declines in their stock markets and some increases in interest rates. As a
result, we have revised our projections of real growth in these two countries down somewhat.
Assuming the Mexican situation is contained, however, we do not expect these or other Latin
American economies to deteriorate further or enough to affect the United States significantly.
Canada has its own external and internal deficit problems, along with a good deal of
political uncertainty, and accordingly, has been vulnerable to shifts in investor confidence. In this
context, it has felt some of the fallout from Mexico, with a weakening of the Canadian dollar in
recent weeks that prompted the Bank of Canada to raise call money rates sharply. This monetary
tightening, along with what is likely to be an austere federal budget released later this month,
should take some steam out of Canada's rapid economic expansion.

Some monetary firming in

Canada probably would have been in order in any case, despite its continued favorable price
performance. While Canada is still somewhat behind the United States on the cyclical curve as
gauged by the magnitude of its potential output gap, resource utilization has tightened
considerably in the industrial sector and industrial materials prices have accelerated recently.
Turning next to Japan, the earthquake is expected to have disrupted transportation and
other infrastructure enough to reduce GDP growth in the first quarter by roughly 1 percentage

-6

-

point, although this is still at best only a rough guess. Rebuilding, which will be financed in part
by supplemental budgets and in part by reduced private savings, should result in a modest net
gain in GDP growth later this year and in 1996. The implications for U.S. net exports could
actually be a small positive in the near term, as the destruction of Kobe's port facilities will likely
reduce Japanese exports more than it does U.S. exports to Japan. The net effect on U.S. GDP
should be minimal however. Some transitory price pressures may arise in Japan as a result of
bottlenecks created by the earthquake, but given the substantial degree of economic slack in Japan,
and with GDP growth expected to be relatively moderate, underlying inflation should remain very
low for the next year or two at least.
In Europe, a strong cyclical recovery has been under way for over a year now. Growth of
industrial production appears to have slowed a bit in the fourth quarter from its very strong pace
earlier in 1994. Nevertheless, we expect GDP growth to remain strong this year as the
composition of the expansion shifts from exports and inventories to final domestic demand. This
shift should also stimulate demand for U.S. exports to Europe, which were surprisingly sluggish
last year.
With growth in the major developing countries generally expected to continue at near the
strong pace recorded in 1994, the world economy is undergoing virtually a global expansion. At
currently anticipated growth rates, other industrial countries are roughly one to three years behind
the United States in terms of potential output gaps, with Germany closest behind and Japan
furthest. Unemployment is still comfortably above estimated natural rates in most countries and
the risk of near-term wage acceleration is generally low. However, manufacturing capacity
utilization suggests a somewhat tighter picture. Most countries have surpassed their average

-7-

utilization rates of the past two decades. Last year's expansion of industrial production in Europe
in particular far exceeded earlier expectations. Price pressures in industrial materials and even
some final products have shown up in several countries. Absent further supply shocks, like the
1994 freeze in Brazil's coffee region, commodity price inflation should slow from last year's high,
but we expect demand pressures to keep those prices rising in real terms. Overall, our
expectation is that CPI inflation abroad will be slightly higher this year and next than last year, and
that U.S. import prices will continue to rise a bit faster than domestic prices, at least through
1995.
Abstracting from Mexico for the moment, we expect that a robust expansion of U.S.
exports over the next two years will be underpinned by continued strong growth abroad and the
recent and anticipated further weakening of the dollar. In our baseline forecast we have projected
that the exchange value of the dollar against the G-10 currencies would decline by several
percentage points over the next few months under the assumption of an unchanged federal funds
rate. Relative to our December forecast, this path of the dollar, in itself, stimulates real net
exports over the next two years by an amount equal to 1/2 percent of GDP.

Import growth

should slow from very high rates seen last year as the economy decelerates and the effects of the
lower dollar show through. Nevertheless, with U.S. output remaining near capacity, the
expansion of imports should just about keep pace with that of exports, yielding only a moderate
uptrend in net exports. When Mexico is added to the equation, we project total net exports will
decline this year but will pick up somewhat in 1996. This outlook is consistent with the U.S.
current account deficit widening to the neighborhood of $200 billion by the end of this year and
remaining there during 1996--an amount well in excess of 2-1/2 percent of GDP.

-8

-

Michael J. Prell
February 1, 1995
The economic

forecasts for 1995 that you submitted are
As usual, we have not

summarized in the handout.
funds

rate path for your projections.

specified a federal

We've only asked that,

pending

the outcome of this meeting, you assume that the Committee adopts what
in your own view would be the optimal monetary policy.
fact.

Given that

I can't say much about the causes of differences between your

forecasts and the

staff's.

For whatever reasons,

the vast majority of

you have predicted both stronger real growth and higher

inflation for

this year than we have.
As you can see,
percent,

the real GDP forecasts range from 2 to 3-1/4

with a central tendency--defined as

thirds--of 2 percent to 3 percent.

roughly the middle two-

Your inflation forecasts range

from 2-3/4 to 3-3/4 percent, with most between 3 and 3-1/2
The unemployment

rates

are for the most part

range from 5-1/4 percent to just

percent.

over 6, but

close to 5-1/2 percent.

The law requires

that the Board assess,

in the Humphrey-

Hawkins report, the consistency of the System's monetary policy plans
with the Administration's short-run economic
in the Economic Report of the
yet

President.

published its numbers, but

forecasts, as published

The Administration has not

judging from what we have heard, it

appears that their forecasts for both growth and inflation will be
within your central tendency ranges.
appreciably higher, however,

Their unemployment rate may be

owing to an artifact of their budget

preparation process, which forced them to lock in economic
before the

late-1994 decline

in joblessness had been revealed;

may find a way of revising their numbers for the Economic
but

if they don't, it

could raise some questions.

worth, though, the output-unemployment relationship
tendencies looks more

assumptions

conventional than theirs.

- 9 -

they

Report only,

For what it's
in your central

February 1,

1995

Long-run Ranges
Donald L. Kohn

Mr. Chairman, in the interest of time, I will
forego a discussion of the long-run scenarios in the blueI would, however, like to touch on one major uncer-

book.

tainty in the intermediate-term outlook--that for fiscal
policy.
A major shift in fiscal policy could greatly affect
the conduct of monetary policy, and in ways that may not
exactly follow the outlines of standard models.

In our

exercises, balancing the budget lowers equilibrium real
interest rates over time by 1-1/2 percentage points, as
compared to a current services baseline. In effect, this
would reverse the effects of the jump in structural deficits
that occurred in 1981. which evidently raised real interest
rates

in the 1980s.

As the Committee is aware, however, the

precise relationship of equilibrium rates to budget deficits
is not easy to pin down.

Other factors, such as financial

innovation, real estate booms, or enhanced returns from
capital investment, may have accounted for at least a portion of the higher real

rates since the early 1980s.

Even if we could be sure how much equilibrium real
rates would fall as a consequence of fiscal restraint, the
appropriate path for monetary policy will depend on the

-2-

dynamics of the responses of spenders and financial markets
to the fiscal policy changes.

We assumed that financial

markets would catch on only gradually as deficit reduction
is implemented.

But bond rates could fall more sharply to

new equilibrium levels once markets became convinced that
future deficit reduction will in fact be implemented.

If

there is little anticipatory behavior in the spending of
households and businesses, tighter fiscal policy can actually be stimulative for a time, as lower bond rates boost
spending before actual deficit reduction measures kick in-as perhaps we saw in 1993.

If the Federal Reserve were

worried about inflation risks, it wouldn't want to react to
falling real bond yields associated with deficit reduction
by immediately lowering the federal funds rate, and in
theory it might even want to run with a tighter policy than
otherwise for a period.
Of course, one can imagine some forward-looking
spending behavior as well.

Additional saving might come,

for example, from government workers anticipating layoffs or
social security recipients expecting their COLAs to be
trimmed.

The larger point is that the effects on the

economy of major deficit reduction will be difficult to
predict; they will depend importantly on the nature of the
cuts and their credibility, and forward-looking behavior

-3-

will not necessarily be confined to financial markets-though it's more likely to be stronger there.

In these

circumstances, relatively simple and straightforward formulations for compensating monetary policy responses are
likely to be wrong, and the Committee will need to assess
the ongoing effects of any substantial deficit reduction
carefully as they occur.
Of course, money growth targets were supposed to
be most useful for avoiding monetary policy mistakes in just
such situations of great uncertainty about aggregate spending.

Unfortunately, major doubts about the characteristics

of money demand have greatly reduced the utility of such
targets.

Nonetheless, the Committee is required to put

forward ranges for money and credit growth for the current
year, and this exercise still allows the Committee an opportunity to discuss broadly what types of financial conditions
it expects to be associated with its ultimate objectives for
the economy.
The table on page 13 of the bluebook gives the
staff's projections for money and debt for 1995 and 1996
under both the greenbook baseline forecast and the alternative simulation with rising interest rates.

As you can see,

we expect some pickup in growth of the broad money aggregates from 1994 to 1995, despite the slowing of growth in
nominal income.

In large measure this reflects the effects

on opportunity costs of the interest rate assumptions.
Under the staff baseline, opportunity costs would narrow as
deposit rates caught up with steady short-term market rates;
under the alternative, opportunity costs would widen, but
not as much as they did last year because a smaller rise in
market rates is assumed.

In addition, some special factors

holding down the growth of money last year--especially the
effects of declining mortgage repayments on demand depositswill not be a factor in 1995.

Helping M2 and M3, a drop in

FDIC insurance premiums should boost the attractiveness of
deposits relative to nondeposits as a source of funds.
Still, we are projecting a bit slower M2 growth than in
standard models because we are assuming that capital market
mutual funds will look a little better as long-term rates
stabilize, and we expect adjustment of deposit offering
rates by banks and thrifts to remain more sluggish than the
models have built in.
Debt should continue on its moderate growth path.
Reduced federal government borrowing is likely to be offset
by greater nonfederal debt issuance as business cash flow is
squeezed by declining profit margins and as retirements of
tax exempt bonds that had earlier been advance refunded
taper off.
Against this background, the table on page 17
presents

a couple of alternatives for money and debt ranges

for 1995.

Alternative I continues the ranges chosen on a

provisional basis last July.

These ranges do encompass

staff projections for money and debt under either the baseline or tighter scenario.

Committee members seem to be

anticipating appreciably faster growth of nominal GDP than
is the staff; nonetheless,

I suspect the alternative I

ranges would encompass money and debt growth consistent with
If there were a question, it

your projections

as well.

would be on M3.

This aggregate had a higher trend rate of

growth than M2 prior to the S&L debacle and bank problems of
the late 1980s.

Recent strength may suggest that with

depository troubles having been resolved, the tendency for
M3 to undershoot M2
close.

evident in recent years is drawing to a

Alternative IA includes what the bluebook charac-

terized as a technical adjustment to the M3 range.

That is,

such an adjustment would not have any implications for the
stance of monetary policy or the intentions of the Committee
going forward, but rather would simply recognize the shifting relationship between M3 and the other aggregates.
Another option would be to delay any adjustment until July,
when more data will be available to determine whether the
previous relationships are in fact
The 1 to 5 percent

reemerging.

range for M2 of alternative I

also can be thought of as a benchmark for growth in this
aggregate under conditions

of reasonable price stability.

if velocity again becomes trendless.

But it would not

necessarily provide much guidance on the Committee's expectations in any given year.

In the current year, if the

Committee were concerned about the potential for inflation
to accelerate, and it wanted to signal its intention to lean
against any such tendency, a lower range for M2 might be
chosen.

The 0 to 4 percent range of alternative II is

better centered on the staff's expectation of growth consistent with rising interest rates.

Presumably, the Committee

wishes to see some slowing of nominal income relative to the
last few years.

If that requires a significant further

increase in interest rates, M2 could well run close to,
even below, the 1 percent pace of 1994.

or

February 1, 1995

Short-run policy
Donald L. Kohn

Mr. Chairman, I will be brief.

The bluebook spelled out the

rationales for leaving policy unchanged or tightening by 50 basis
points.
Real interest rate are now close to or even slightly above
averages for the last 15 years--a period of relatively high real
rates--albeit well below the peaks of 1989.

At these levels, which

ought to be consistent over time with some restraint on spending, a
case can be made for waiting for more information about whether that
restraint is taking hold before tightening further.
strengthened by the straws in the wind that

The case is

final demand may in fact

be moderating, and by the possibility that the Mexican situation could
worsen and spread to other countries,

contributing to financial in-

stability and restraining our net exports.
cost data hold open the possibility that

Well-behaved price and

output will

slow and pres-

sures on resource utilization ease before much damage has been done in
terms of embedding higher inflation and inflation expectations in the
economy.

In these circumstances, the Federal Reserve may have

breathing room to see how some of the uncertainties

some

seem to be working

themselves out before it needs to move.
The question is whether slightly restrictive levels of real
interest rates are the most likely levels to accomplish the Committee's

objectives.

Intermediate-

and longer-term real rates do embody

market expectations of significant increases in short-term rates over
coming quarters, and the absence of tightening eventually would tend
to lower current real rates.

In the staff forecast, the current level

of the funds

rate is not high enough to keep inflation from rising.

Additional restraint--monetary or fiscal--is needed in part to offset
the effects of the momentum in spending by confident households and
businesses and the push later in 1995 from exports arising out of
The

expanding foreign demand and a lower dollar over the last year.

dollar has been weak again recently, even with the favorable price
data, suggesting the possibility of lingering concerns about the
factors bearing on policy here and the resultant inflation outlook.
Appreciable inflation risks and the need for moving policy
more clearly into restrictive territory to counter them may also be
seen as a result of the economy operating beyond its potential.

That

situation implies that economic expansion needs to slow substantially
from its recent pace to limit any pickup in inflation:

it may also

suggest relatively small risks of overshooting--of tightening so much
that the economy is pushed substantially below potential before
corrective action can be taken.
So far, there is little evidence from financial markets that
tighter policy is constraining borrowing or the availability of credit.
lems

Risk spreads are very narrow, implying markets don't see probfor borrowers even with the rate increases built into yield

curves.

And banks continue to ease terms and conditions for loans,

offsetting in part the effects of Federal Reserve tightening.

Even

the broader monetary aggregates have picked up in recent months,
though their long-term trends remain quite damped.

Growth of M2 and

M3 in January was the most rapid in several years.

We don't see this

sort of growth being sustained, though we do expect expansion of the
broad Ms to continue to exceed that of the last few years.

Faster

money growth, along with the strength in bank lending it has funded,
may be one more indication that higher rates have not yet begun to
bind significantly on borrowing and spending.