View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
ISSN 1936-5330

Does Communicating a
Numerical Inflation Target
Anchor Inflation Expectations?
Evidence & Bond Market
Implications
Brent Bundick and A. Lee Smith
January 2018
RWP 18-01

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Does Communicating a Numerical Inflation
Target Anchor Inflation Expectations?
Evidence & Bond Market Implications∗
Brent Bundick†

A. Lee Smith‡

January 2018

Abstract
High-frequency empirical evidence suggests that inflation expectations in the United
States became better anchored after the Federal Reserve began communicating a numerical inflation target. Using an event-study approach, we find that forward measures
of inflation compensation became unresponsive to news about current inflation after
the adoption of an explicit inflation target. In contrast, we find that forward measures
of nominal compensation in Japan continue to drift with news about current inflation,
even after the Bank of Japan adopted a numerical inflation target. These empirical
findings have implications for the term structure of interest rates in the United States.
In a calibrated macro-finance model, we show that the apparent anchoring of inflation
expectations implies lower term premium in longer-term bond yields and decreases the
slope of the yield curve.

JEL Classification: E32, E52
Keywords: Monetary Policy, Inflation, Structural Breaks, Term Structure of Interest Rates
∗

We thank Andrew Foerster, Esther George, Craig Hakkio, Nick Sly, and Jon Willis for helpful discussions.
Trenton Herriford provided excellent research assistance and we thank CADRE for computational support.
The views expressed herein are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City or the Federal Reserve System.
†

Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.

Email: brent.bundick@kc.frb.org

‡

Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.

Email: andrew.smith@kc.frb.org

1

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

1

Introduction

In January 2012, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) adopted a numerical target
of two percent inflation over the longer-run, which it believed was most consistent with its
statutory mandates. Economic theory, such as Woodford (2003), predicts that such a policy
change should lead to better economic outcomes. Anchoring long-run inflation expectations
allows a central bank to respond aggressively to cyclical swings in the real economy without
sacrificing its price stability mandate. Indeed, the FOMC alluded to such benefits when it
adopted its long-run inflation objective:
“Communicating this inflation goal clearly to the public helps keep longer-term inflation expectations firmly anchored, thereby fostering price stability and moderate long-term interest
rates and enhancing the Committee’s ability to promote maximum employment in the face
of significant economic disturbances.” – Statement on Longer-Run Goals & Policy Strategy
One year after the Federal Reserve had adopted its inflation target, the Bank of Japan (BOJ)
adopted a similar two percent inflation objective in January 2013. Merely publishing a numerical objective for inflation, however, does not necessarily cement inflation expectations
at the central bank’s target. For example, the announcement could lack credibility if the
central bank failed to deliver on previous commitments. Instead, the degree to which inflation expectations are anchored remains an empirical question.
In this paper, we use data from bond markets to test whether the adoption of an explicit
longer-run inflation objective better anchored inflation expectations in the United States
(U.S.) and Japan. The anchored inflation expectations hypothesis implies a strong testable
prediction, which we can evaluate statistically. In particular, if a central bank adopts a credible long-run inflation target, then expectations about inflation far in the future shouldn’t
respond to news about current inflation. In contrast, if inflation expectations are not well
anchored, then recent inflation developments can sway longer-term inflation expectations.
Using a high-frequency approach, we measure the responses of market-based measures of
inflation compensation to data surprises contained in monthly Consumer Price Index (CPI)
reports published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics in the U.S. and the Statistics Bureau in
Japan.
Prior to the adoption of a numerical inflation target in the United States, we find that
measures of far forward inflation compensation drift following inflation surprises. How2

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

ever, after the FOMC started communicating numerical objectives for longer-run inflation,
a battery of econometric tests suggest that inflation compensation no longer comoves with
inflation surprises. These results are consistent with an anchoring of inflation expectations
as the FOMC moved towards adopting a numerical inflation target.
Structural break tests suggest a change in the relationship between inflation compensation and core inflation surprises shortly after FOMC participants began regularly publishing
“longer-run” values for inflation in the quarterly Summary of Economic Projections (SEP).
Moreover, narrative evidence also supports this timing of our estimated breakdate. For example, dialogue contained in the 2010 FOMC transcripts suggests that Committee members
believed inflation expectations were anchored well before the formal adoption of the two
percent inflation objective. Thus, by January 2012, we are able to statistically distinguish
between the drifting inflation expectations regime of the late-1990’s/2000’s and the more
recent anchored inflation expectations regime.
In contrast, we find no evidence of a similar anchoring in Japan. Our analysis suggests
that inflation expectations continue to drift with inflation surprises in that country despite
numerous changes in their monetary policy regime over the past two decades. However, the
estimated response of nominal forward rates to Japanese inflation surprises appears to have
diminished, albeit insignificantly, since 2013. Based on our findings from the U.S. experience,
these recent results could signal the early stages of inflation expectations becoming better
anchored in Japan. While we see some tentative signs of anchoring since the 2013 adoption
of an inflation target, past inconsistencies between the Bank of Japan’s communication and
its policy actions has likely slowed the process of anchoring in Japan. This interpretation
is consistent with the conclusions of De Michelis and Iacoviello (2016), which use structural
models to argue that a lack of credibility has kept inflation expectations in Japan from moving closer to the Bank of Japan’s target.
Finally, we show that these empirical findings have implications for the term structure
of interest rates in the United States. Previous work by Rudebusch and Wu (2008) and
Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) argues that drifting inflation expectations, a form of long-run
nominal risk, is a key mechanism that helps macro-finance models match historical features
of the U.S. yield curve. Using the Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) model, we examine the
general-equilibrium implications of the anchoring of U.S. inflation expectations for Treasury
yields. The model implies that anchoring inflation expectations reduces the average term
premium on 10-year Treasury bonds by 5–16 basis points and flattens the yield curve.
3

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

2

Testing the Anchored Inflation Hypothesis

In this section, we present a simple model of longer-term inflation expectations that guides
our intuition and our empirical specifications. Specifically, we model the evolution of longterm inflation expectations as follows:
LT
LT
πtLT = πt−1
+ β(πt − πt−1
),

(1)

where πtLT is the long-term inflation expectation in period t and πt is the inflation rate in
period t. We often associate πtLT with far forward measures of inflation expectations. This
model builds upon the macro-finance literature of Gürkaynak, Sack and Swanson (2005),
Rudebusch and Wu (2008), and Rudebusch and Swanson (2012), which finds that drifting
long-term inflation expectations help explain characteristics of the U.S. Treasury yield curve.
The coefficient β determines the degree to which long-term inflation expectations are
anchored. In one extreme, if β = 1 then long-term inflation expectation are completely
unanchored and they move in lockstep with current inflation. On the other extreme, if
β = 0, then long-term inflation expectations are anchored, in the sense that they are invariant realized inflation. For the intermediate cases that 0 < β < 1, then inflation expectations
drift with current inflation.
To test the degree to which inflation expectations are anchored, we must estimate the
value of β. However, a simple regression of measures of long-term inflation expectations on
current inflation is likely to yield biased estimates of β. Equation (1) is typically thought to
be part of a larger macroeconomic model which contains an expectations-augmented Phillips
curve, in which current inflation also depends on long-term inflation expectations. Therefore,
the simultaneity between long-term inflation expectations when β > 0 and actual inflation
makes the estimation of Equation (1) problematic.
However, a slight algebraic manipulation of Equation (1) allows us to easily estimate β
directly using an event-study approach. If we take the expectations of Equation (1) at time
t − 1 and subtract it from Equation (1) above, we arrive at the following equation:
πtLT − Et−1 πtLT = β(πt − Et−1 πt ),

(2)

where the right-hand side captures the news about current inflation that was revealed between time t − 1 and t, and the coefficient β captures how that news about inflation affects
long-term inflation expectations.

4

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

To measure β, we estimate Equation (2) using the one-day change in far forward yields
around the release of CPI reports. Our preferred measure of πtLT is five-year, five-year forward inflation compensation implied by the spread between nominal Treasury yields and
yields on Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities (TIPS). For the United States, we obtain
daily data on this measure from the Federal Reserve Board. By focusing on forward measures of inflation compensation, we cleanse any direct effect that current inflation has on
average expected inflation over the next decade. As an alternative, we also use the nominal
one-year forward rate maturing in ten years (nominal one-year rate beginning in nine years)
as a measure of forward nominal compensation. In U.S. data, for the samples that the two
measures overlap, we find similar results. For Japan, where data on inflation-protected bond
yields are unavailable, we use the nominal one year forward rate maturing in ten years as
our measure of long-term inflation compensation.1
For our measure of πt − Et−1 πt in Equation (2), we use data surprises emanating from
the release of monthly CPI reports.2 For the U.S. and Japan, we measure Et−1 πt using the
median forecast from the surveys of professional forecasters compiled by Bloomberg prior to
each data release. Furthermore, Bloomberg maintains data on the actual reported value of
πt in the report (i.e. not the revised value). For the U.S., we have forecasts and the actual
release for the month-over-month percent change in CPI for both headline and core inflation.
Using these two forecasts, along with the weight of core components in the CPI basket, we
construct an implied food and energy surprise component. As we will show, however, our
results are robust to using the percent change in an index of energy and agricultural prices
as an alternative control for changes in non-core prices on the day of the CPI release.3 Our
sample periods are generally limited by the availability of data on inflation surprises, which
starts in 1997 for the United States and in 2001 for Japan.
1

For both the U.S. and Japan, we calculate nominal forward rates from the yield on constant maturity
zero coupon bond yields as described in Gürkaynak, Levin and Swanson (2010).
2
Our regression model is therefore very similar to the model in Gürkaynak, Levin and Swanson (2010)
except we focus exclusively on CPI reports (i.e. news about inflation) as prescribed from Equation (2).
3
For Japan, using this additional control variable is essential since we are unable to infer the weights on
the core component (which is prices excluding fresh food). Also, for Japan, our inflation surprises are for
the year-over-year percent change in the core CPI inflation as opposed to the month-over-month percent
change. Although this may have implications for interpreting the magnitude of β, the scaling in no way
affects hypothesis tests against the null hypothesis of β = 0.

5

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

3

Inflation News & Inflation Compensation in the U.S.

Did the relationship between market-implied inflation compensation and unexpected news
about inflation change around the time that the FOMC adopted an explicit inflation objective? We apply several different statistical methods to detect such a possible change. First,
we look for a structural break using split-sample regressions, which impose a break in the
regression model after the policy change. Using this approach, we find evidence consistent
with an anchoring of inflation expectations after 2012. To get a more precise sense of when
inflation expectations became anchored, we then apply tests for a structural break at an unknown date. These break tests suggest that the relationship between inflation compensation
and inflation news changed in the first half of 2010. Although this candidate break date is
about two years prior to the FOMC’s adoption of a numerical inflation objective, it follows
shortly after the Committee began publishing numerical ranges for “longer-run” inflation
in the quarterly Summary of Economic Projections. Finally, we show that both narrative
evidence as well as rolling window regressions further support these conclusions.

3.1

Did a Numerical Target Better Anchor Expectations?

Using our core CPI surprise and the surprise associated with the food and energy components,
we estimate the following event-study regression to measure β, the response of long-term
inflation compensation to news about inflation,
∆πtLT = α + βπtcore + γπtf e + εt ,

(3)

where ∆πtLT is the one-day change in the 5-year, 5-year forward measure of inflation compensation on the day of a CPI release, π core is the core CPI surprise, and π f e is the surprise
associated with the food and energy component.4 We will refer to this specification as
the “inflation compensation model.” We estimate Equation 3 using ordinary least squares
where each observation corresponds to a given CPI release. We split our data into two distinct sample periods to determine if the underlying relationship between inflation surprises
and inflation compensation changed after the FOMC’s adoption of an explicit inflation target. First, we examine the January 1999 – December 2011 sample period, which is prior to
the inflation target adoption. Then, we examine the January 2012 – October 2017 period
following the policy change.
4

We scale the core CPI surprises by the weight of core items in the CPI basket. Our results are insensitive
to this scaling.

6

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

We find statistically significant evidence that inflation compensation responds less to
economic news about inflation following the adoption of the inflation target. The first two
columns of Table 1 show the estimated coefficients from Equation 3 across sample periods.
Prior to January 2012, a positive core CPI surprise leads to a statistically significant increase
in inflation compensation. A ten-basis point core CPI surprise typically raises five-year, fiveyear forward inflation compensation by one and half basis points. After the FOMC formally
adopting its inflation target, however, the coefficient on core CPI falls and is statistically indistinguishable from zero. In the third column of Table 1, we formally conduct a Chow (1960)
test, which suggests the presence of a structural break in β in 2012. The post-January 2012
dummy variable that interacts with the core inflation surprise is negative and statistically
significant, which suggests a change in the relationship between news about core inflation
and longer-term inflation compensation after the FOMC adopted its formal inflation target.
The break in the estimate of β appears to reflect a change in the reaction of inflation
expectations to CPI surprises after 2012, rather than a change in the nature of CPI surprises. Table 2 shows the summary statistics for CPI surprises both before and after 2012.
The standard deviation of the Bloomberg core inflation surprises is equal to 0.072 prior to
2012 and 0.066 thereafter. Furthermore, the surprises in both periods are not significantly
skewed nor is there evidence that they are non-normal as the Jarque-Bera statistic falls below
its critical value in both samples. The most notable difference between the two samples is
the presence of an average downside inflation surprise after 2012. The negative mean surprise largely reflects the very most recent string of downside core CPI surprises beginning in
March of 2017. From the viewpoint of our regression model, this change in the distribution
of inflation surprises, all else equal, has the potential to impact the intercept α, but not the
slope coefficient β. However, Table 1 shows that we find no statistically significant evidence
of a change in the regression intercept across the two sample periods.
We consistently find that CPI surprises associated with the food and energy components
of the consumption basket don’t significantly affect longer-term inflation compensation. Two
intuitive reasons support this empirical finding. First, to the extent that food and energy
price fluctuations are short-lived and often reverse, we would expect them not to have a big
effect on longer-term inflation expectations. Second, thanks to vibrant spot and derivatives
markets based on food and energy commodities, bond investors already have some information about the food and energy components ahead of the CPI release. Both prior to and
after the adoption of the inflation target, we find that the coefficients on the food and energy
surprises remain near zero and this relationship appears stable over time.
7

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

3.2

Testing for a Structural Break at an Unknown Date

Rather than imposing a break after 2012 in the relationship between far forward inflation
compensation and inflation surprises, we now estimate the most likely timing of the break.
In particular, we test for a structural break at an unknown date. The estimated breakdate
allows us to provide some further interpretation of the source of the break in the β coefficient. If a change in β reflected a better anchoring of inflation expectations, we would
expect the estimated break date to lag or coincide with a change in U.S. monetary policy.
If instead the estimated break date is not supported with corroborating narrative evidence,
it could reflect general instability in the regression model rather than deep structural change.
Tests for a structural break at an unknown date reveal evidence of a break in β, but not
any of the other parameters in the regression model. Table 3 shows the results of Andrews
(1993) and Quandt (1960) test and the Andrews and Ploberger (1994) test for a structural
break in the inflation compensation regression model in Equation 3. Both tests suggests that
the relationship between inflation compensation and inflation news changed in May 2010.
The candidate break date is significant at the 5% level for both tests, indicating strong
statistical evidence of a change in β. There is no evidence of a break in any of the other
regression parameters, including the variance of the regression residual. Since our regression
model has a relatively low R2 , instability due to changes in the liquidity of the TIPS market
over time would likely appear as a break in the residual variance. Importantly, we find no
evidence of such a break.
The solid black line in the top panel of Figure 1 plots the time series of Chow test statistics for a break in β. The breaktest sequence has a fairly well-defined maximum at the
estimated break date with no other clear peaks. This pattern suggests a one-time structural
break in the sensitivity of long-term inflation expectations to core CPI surprises occurring
around 2010.5
The estimated break date occurs before the Federal Reserve formally adopted a two
percent inflation target in January of 2012, but shortly after FOMC participants began to
publish quarterly projections for “longer-run” inflation. In April of 2009, the Summary of
5

More formally, if we split the sample into two subsamples 1999-2010 and 2010-2017, the Andrews-Quandt
test indicates no other breaks while the Andrews-Ploberger test indicates weak evidence (significant at the
10% level) of a second break in November of 2012. The 2010 break is again found with a high level of
statistical significance from both the Andrews-Quandt and Andrews-Ploberger test when we perform the
refinement proposed in Bai (1997), which tests for a break at an unknown date from 1999-2012.

8

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Economic Projections (SEP) added longer-run inflation which, according to the language
summarizing these economic projections, “[...] represent each participant’s assessment of
the rate to which each variable would be expected to converge under appropriate monetary
policy and in the absence of further shocks to the economy.” According to most economic
theories, monetary policy solely determines inflation in the longer run. Therefore, one interpretation of this estimated break date is that public expectations began to fixate on these
projections as an initial numerical range for the FOMC’s longer-term inflation objective.
This interpretation of the timing and the source of the break in β aligns with the thinking
of the FOMC at the time. In an October 2010 conference call, the Committee discussed
making changes to the FOMC’s policy and communication framework. As the Committee
debated specific language to describe its inflation objective, then recently appointed ViceChair Janet Yellen asserted that the FOMC’s SEP was serving to provide numerical guidance
around the FOMC’s inflation objective: “I don’t think we need to seek Committee agreement
on a single specific inflation target at this point. To say it is ‘about two percent,’ or ‘two
percent or a bit less,’ strikes me as an accurate characterization of our SEP responses.”
Vice-Chair Yellen went on to say that while she supported the Committee’s adoption of a
numerical inflation target, “The Committee’s objectives are already pretty well understood
by markets, so they’ll probably get the message without the numbers.”

3.3

Robustness to Alternative Data, Samples, & Specifications

Our baseline model shows that market-based measures of inflation expectations became less
sensitive to news about inflation after the FOMC began to communicate a numerical inflation
objective. We now show that this finding is robust to a number of alternative specifications.
Specifically, we illustrate this robustness using: (i) alternative measures of nominal compensation and food and energy price controls, (ii) data samples that exclude the global financial
crisis, and (iii) specifications that allow for more gradual parametric change. Under all these
alternatives, we find that nominal compensation responds less to inflation news after the
adoption of the explicit inflation objective.
In our baseline inflation compensation model, we proxy forward inflation expectations
by using inflation compensation measured from inflation-indexed bonds. However, TIPS
yields may contain a non-trivial, time-varying liquidity premium which could distort our
measure of inflation expectations.6 Our baseline model also uses the weight of core goods
6

As long as this premium is uncorrelated with core inflation surprises, our baseline results remain unbiased.

9

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

and services in the overall CPI basket, along with the headline and core CPI surprises,
to infer the information content emanating from food and energy components. While this
weight varies little month to month, its value is not exactly known in real time. To address
both of these concerns, we instead estimate the following alternative regression model:
∆ytLT = α + βπtcore + γ f πtf ood + γ e πtenergy + εt ,

(4)

where ∆ytLT is the one-day change in the one-year, nine-year forward rate around CPI announcements and πtf ood and πtenergy are the one-day percent changes in the Goldman Sachs
agricultural and energy price indexes, respectively. We will refer to this specification as the
“forward rate model.”
Rather than using inflation compensation measured from inflation-indexed bonds, this
alternative model uses far forward measures of nominal compensation as a proxy for longterm inflation expectations. Although real factors could influence this measure of forward
compensation, Gürkaynak, Sack and Swanson (2005) argue that most macroeconomic models
would predict that real variables return to their steady state values following a disturbance
before nine years. In addition, this specification uses the change in spot prices for food
and energy inputs instead of the implied surprise from the CPI measure of food and energy
prices. Given that timely information on the previous month’s food and energy prices already available to bond investors at the time of the CPI release, the change in spot prices
for food and energy inputs might be a more appropriate control for these non-core items on
the day of the CPI release.
Table 4 reports our regression estimates for the United States using the forward rate
model, which continues to show a statistically significant decline in the response of inflation compensation to inflation news following the adoption of the inflation target.7 The
robustness of our findings using the forward rate model is important as we move to our
cross-country analysis. In Section 4, we repeat a similar exercise for Japan. For that country, however, we lack data on real (inflation-indexed) bonds and the knowledge about the
weight of core components in the CPI basket. Thus, we cannot estimate our preferred inflation compensation model specified in Equation 3. However, we can estimate the forward
rate model.
Using this alternative model, tests for a structural break at an unknown date also suggest
a break in the coefficient on the core inflation surprise around 2010. The solid black line
7

We no longer scale the core CPI surprises by the weight of core components in the CPI basket.

10

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

in the second panel of Figure 1 plots the Chow test sequence for β using the forward rate
regression model over time. Once again, we see a clear peak in the time series of the test
statistic in the first half of 2010. However, there is also a sharp spike in the sequence of
Chow tests in late 2008. Table 5 shows that the test statistic at the December 2008 break
date exceeds the 10% critical value of the Andrews-Quandt test. However, the local maximum in 2010 also exceeds this critical value. The presence of two local maxima could signal
either two breaks or, based on the timing, instability during the financial crisis. This latter
possibility of instability in the regression model due to the global financial crisis leads us to
further examine the robustness of our candidate break dates.
If we drop the precipice of the global financial crisis, we find evidence indicating the presence of a single structural break in 2010. For the inflation compensation model, Table 6 shows
that if we drop the fourth quarter of 2008 and first quarter of 2009 from the estimation, we
estimate the exact same break date of May of 2010 for the core inflation coefficient. The blue
dotted lines in Figure 1 plot the time series of the Chow statistics for samples that exclude
the financial crisis. For both regression models, the presence of a peak in the time series of
the break statistics in 2010 is insensitive to the inclusion or exclusion of the financial crisis.
After excluding the precipice of the financial crisis, Table 7 shows that the estimated breakdate for the forward rate model is February of 2010, which also matches the maximum of the
sequence of Chow test statistics. This finding suggests that the source of instability in the
response of forward bond yields to inflation surprises occurring around 2010 is not simply a
reflection of financial market volatility but, instead, is likely due to deeper structural change.
Rolling-window regressions also suggest a similar decline in β over time. This alternative
approach to measuring the time variation in the sensitivity of long-term inflation expectations
to inflation surprises is well suited to capture a more gradual changes in the coefficients
over time. The top panel of Figure 2 illustrates the time variation in β from the inflation
compensation regression model specified in Equation (3) using 10-year rolling samples. We
observe the same pattern of structural change as our previous findings. Early in the sample,
prior to 2012, β is estimated to be statistically significant and positive. However, by 2010,
the point estimate of β begins to decline and falls to values not different from zero by 2012.
The second panel of Figure 2 shows similar time variation in β as estimated from the forward
rate regression model in Equation 4. The point estimate of β from the forward rate model
is positive and close to being significant in 2010, before beginning a steady descent.

11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

4

Inflation News & Inflation Compensation in Japan

About one year after the FOMC formally adopted its longer-run inflation target of two percent, the Bank of Japan (BOJ) followed suit. After years of deflation and slow growth,
Shinzo Abe campaigned on a platform of reflation through an official inflation target and
aggressive quantitative easing. After taking office in December of 2012, Prime Minister Abe
appointed Haruhiko Kuroda as the Governor of the Bank of Japan. Shortly after taking office, Governor Kuroda implemented a more aggressive quantitative easing campaign, which
was further expanded in October 2014. In January 2016, the BOJ implemented a negative
interest rate on reserves policy. Later that year, the Bank pursued a policy of yield curve
control, which buys and sells bonds as necessary to achieve a 0% yield on 10-year Japanese
government bonds.
Given this narrative evidence of several regimes changes in Japanese monetary policy,
we empirically evaluate whether the adoption of these policies has better anchored inflation
expectations in Japan. To this end, we look for evidence of parameter instability in the
following statistical model for Japan:
∆ytLT = α + βπtcore + γ f πtf ood + εt .

(5)

where ∆ytLT is the one-day change in a 1-year, 9-year forward rate around Japanese CPI
announcements, π core is the core Japanese CPI surprise (which excludes the price of fresh
food), and πtf ood is the one-day percent change in the Goldman Sachs agricultural price index.
We find no evidence of a change in the response of nominal forward rates to core inflation
surprises in Japan. Following the same strategy as we did for the U.S., we initially impose
a break in the regression relationship in January of 2013, after the election of Shinzo Abe.
Table 8 shows the split-sample regression estimates over the 2001-2012 sample period and
2013-2017 sample periods. In both subsamples, the estimate of β, the coefficient on the core
inflation surprise, is positive and statistically significant. However, the point estimate of β
in the more recent sample is about half the size compared to its pre-Abe/Kuroda estimate.
This finding may suggest some initial signs of anchoring in Japan. However, a more formal
Chow (1960) test yields no statistically significant evidence of a break in β.
Using structural break tests for an unknown date, we can more generally test for a break
in the relationship between nominal forward yields and core inflation surprises. However,
unlike our findings for the United States, these tests indicate stability in the regression model
12

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

in Equation (5) over time. The Andrews-Quandt and Andrews-Ploberger tests indicate no
evidence of significant time variation in β. The bottom panel of Figure 1 shows the Chow
test sequence over candidate breakdates. The time series of Chow tests has no well defined
peaks that exceed the 10% critical value for a structural break. Rolling-window regressions
also support these findings of a lack of structural change. The bottom panel of Figure 2
illustrates estimates of the sensitivity of nominal forward rates to core inflation surprises
over 10-year rolling windows advanced by one month at a time. As with the split-sample
estimates and the break tests, the time series of estimated β coefficients suggests a positive
and stable relationship between inflation news and inflation compensation in Japan. This
evidence indicates that despite the host of policy changes implemented by the BOJ, inflation
expectations – as perceived by bond market investors – remain unanchored.

5

Implications for U.S. Bond Markets

To this point, we have used data on inflation compensation to analyze how bond markets perceive the inflation objectives of central banks. In this section, we now explore the
general-equilibrium effects of the apparent anchoring of U.S. inflation expectations for the
term structure of U.S. interest rates. Drifting inflation expectations embody a long-run
risk for holders of nominal debt. As a result, Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) and others
show that this mechanism helps dynamic, general-equilibrium models simultaneously match
macroeconomic and financial market moments. Specifically, they find that that drifting inflation expectations help these models generate a significantly positive average term premium
on long-term nominal bonds and an upward sloping yield curve. By reducing long-run nominal risk, these models predict that anchoring inflation expectations should reduce the term
premium and flatten the yield curve.8
Using the calibrated model of Rudebusch and Swanson (2012), we now quantitatively
assess the implications of anchored inflation expectations for the average term premium and
slope of the yield curve. Similar to our Equation (1), Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) assume
that long-term inflation expectations drift according to the following process:


LT
πtLT = ρπ πt−1
+ ϑπ π̄t − πtLT ,

(6)

where π̄t is an infinite sum of past inflation with geometrically declining weights on more
8

Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) show that price-level targeting, which completely eliminates inflation
risk to nominal bond holders, implies that the term premium and the slope of the yield curve are essentially
zero in their model.

13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

distant inflation.9 Using a moment matching exercise, Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) find
that a value of ϑπ = 0.003 helps the model jointly match macroeconomic and yield curve
moments. They also consider a calibrated model, in which they set ϑπ = 0.01, which is much
more inline with our high-frequency empirical evidence.10
On average, the anchoring of inflation expectations causes a modest decline in the term
premium and flattens the yield curve. The second two columns of Table 9 illustrate the
average term premium and slope of the yield curve under the two different calibrations in
Rudebusch and Swanson (2012). In the final column, we solve the model setting ϑπ = 0,
which is consistent with our high-frequency evidence that inflation expectations became
better anchored over the past few years. Depending on the calibration, the average term
premium on a 10-year Treasury bond declines by 5–16 basis points. Moreover, we see that
the yield curve is a bit flatter when inflation expectations do not respond to current inflation
developments. These results highlight that small changes in agents’ views about the central
bank’s inflation objective can have significant general-equilibrium implications for the term
structure of interest rates.

6

Conclusions

Almost ten years ago, Gürkaynak, Levin and Swanson (2010) conducted a detailed, crosscountry analysis on the effects that numerical inflation targeting has on long-run inflation
expectations. They concluded that inflation expectations were generally better anchored in
the UK and Sweden than in the United States because, at that time, the United States had
not yet adopted an explicit long-term inflation objective. Our paper provides two key results
which further their influential work. First, our results highlight an out-of-sample test of their
findings. Indeed, we find that inflation expectations became better anchored as the FOMC
began communicating a numerical value for its longer-term inflation objective. Specifically,
9

In their model, Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) also incorporate exogenous shocks to long-term inflation
expectations, which are unrelated to current inflation outcomes. Numerically, these shocks have only very
small implications for the average term premium and slope of the yield curve. Therefore, we set the volatility
of these shocks to zero in our analysis and focus on the endogenous drifting of inflation expectations due to
realized inflation outcomes.
10
Rudebusch and Swanson (2012) calibrate their model at a quarterly frequency, while our high-frequency
estimation of Equation 2 relates monthly inflation to changes in annualized inflation compensation. After
accounting for the difference in data frequencies, as well as the calibration of the lag polynominal used to
calculate π̄t in their model, our high-frequency baseline model would imply a value of ϑπ = 0.04 over the
1999–2011 sample period.

14

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

we find a reduction in the sensitivity of far forward measures of nominal compensation to
current inflation surprises in the United States after 2012. Thus, we find evidence that
further validates their analysis and conclusion; a credible, numerical inflation objective can
better anchor inflation expectations.
However, our second key result provides an caveat to the applicability of this result. Using
data from Japan, we find that simply communicating an inflation target may be insufficient
to anchor inflation expectations. Although the BOJ adopted an explicit numerical inflation
objective about one year after the Federal Reserve, we find no statistically significant evidence that, as of yet, far forward nominal bond prices are less responsive to CPI surprises.
However, the point estimate of the degree of sensitivity has fallen since the adoption of the
BOJ’s inflation target and aggressive monetary easing. These results for Japan suggest that
words must be accompanied by either expected or actual actions to achieve credibility around
an inflation target. Even if the central bank announces a numerical inflation objective, poor
credibility and past policy actions may slow or prevent inflation expectations from becoming
anchored.
Our results also suggest that monitoring the sensitivity of far forward nominal compensation to the flow of inflation data is a valuable tool for understanding how bond markets
perceive monetary policy. Given the changes in the response of inflation compensation to
inflation news that we document in this paper, further modeling the time variation in this
relationship could be fruitful. In particular, maintaining more general time-varying parameter models could enhance real-time surveillance of inflation expectations for central banks.
Finally, we show that anchoring inflation expectations has implications for the shape of
the yield curve. All else equal, a more credible commitment to a numerical inflation target
reduces long-run nominal risk to bond holders. Therefore, anchoring inflation expectations
reduces the extra compensation investors require for bearing inflation risk over the life of
the bond (the term premium) and flattens the yield curve. We show, through the lens of a
standard macro-finance model, that this effect may be quantitatively meaningful.

15

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

References
Andrews, Donald WK. 1993. “Tests for parameter instability and structural change with
unknown change point.” Econometrica, 821–856.
Andrews, Donald WK, and Werner Ploberger. 1994. “Optimal tests when a nuisance
parameter is present only under the alternative.” Econometrica, 1383–1414.
Bai, Jushan. 1997. “Estimation of a change point in multiple regression models.” The
Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(4): 551–563.
Chow, Gregory C. 1960. “Tests of equality between sets of coefficients in two linear regressions.” Econometrica, 591–605.
De Michelis, Andrea, and Matteo Iacoviello. 2016. “Raising an inflation target: The
Japanese experience with Abenomics.” European Economic Review, 88: 67–87.
Gürkaynak, Refet S., Andrew Levin, and Eric Swanson. 2010. “Does Inflation Targeting Anchor Long-Run Inflation Expectations? Evidence from the U.S., U.K, and Sweden.”
Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(6): 1208–1242.
Gürkaynak, Refet S, Brian Sack, and Eric Swanson. 2005. “The sensitivity of longterm interest rates to economic news: evidence and implications for macroeconomic models.” The American economic review, 95(1): 425–436.
Hansen, Bruce E. 1997. “Approximate asymptotic p values for structural-change tests.”
Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 15(1): 60–67.
Quandt, Richard E. 1960. “Tests of the hypothesis that a linear regression system obeys
two separate regimes.” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 55(290): 324–330.
Rudebusch, Glenn D., and Eric T. Swanson. 2012. “The Bond Premium in a DSGE
Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(1): 105–143.
Rudebusch, Glenn D, and Tao Wu. 2008. “A Macro-Finance Model of the Term Structure, Monetary Policy and the Economy.” The Economic Journal, 118(530): 906–926.
Woodford, Michael. 2003. Interest and Prices. Princeton University Press.

16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 1: U.S. Inflation Compensation Model
5-Year, 5-Year Forward Inflation
Constant

1999-2011

2012-2017

1999-2017

0.00

0.00

0.00

(0.00)

(0.00)

(0.00)

0.15∗∗

Core CPI surprise

(0.07)
−0.02

Food & Energy CPI surprise

(0.04)

−0.07
(0.08)
−0.02
(0.06)

Constant ×It≥2012

0.15∗∗
(0.07)
−0.02
(0.04)
0.00
(0.01)
−0.22∗∗

Core CPI surprise ×It≥2012

(0.10)
Food & Energy CPI surprise ×It≥2012

0.00
(0.07)

Observations
R

2

155

68

223

0.04

0.01

0.03

Note: Eicker-White standard errors in parenthesis. ∗ p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05

17

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 2: Summary Statistics of U.S. Core CPI Inflation Surprises
1997-2011

2012-2017

0.00

−0.02

Mean

(0.63)

(0.01)

Standard Deviation

0.07

0.07

Skewness

0.16

−0.33

(0.39)
Kutroisis

−0.33

Jarque-Bera

Observations

0.41

(0.37)

(0.51)

1.58

1.72

(0.45)

(0.42)

179

70

Note: p-values in parenthesis.

18

(0.28)

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 3: U.S. Inflation Compensation Model: Structural Break Tests at an Unknown Date
5-Year, 5-Year Forward Inflation

Constant

Core CPI surprise

Food & Energy CPI surprise

All Coefficients

Residual Variance

Andrews-Quandt

Andrews-Ploberger

Date

Test Statistic

Test Statistic

2002:08

1.78

0.24

(0.84)

(0.73)

9.76∗∗

2010:05

2010:07

2010:05

2013:03

(0.03)

(0.05)

1.14

0.13

(0.98)

(0.95)

11.37

2.78

(0.13)

(0.20)

2.38

0.50

(0.69)

(0.44)

Note: Approximate asymptotic p-values from Hansen (1997) in parenthesis.
Observations: 223
∗
p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05

19

2.07∗∗

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 4: U.S. Forward Rate Model
1-Year, 9-Year Forward Rate
Constant

1997-2011

2012-2017

1997-2017

0.00

0.00

0.00

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

0.11∗

Core CPI surprise

GS Agriculture Price Index

GS Energy Price Index

−0.08

0.11∗

(0.06)

(0.07)

(0.06)

0.00

0.02

0.00

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

0.00
(0.00)

0.01∗∗
(0.00)

Constant ×It≥2012

0.00
(0.00)
0.00
(0.01)
−0.18∗

Core CPI surprise ×It≥2012

(0.09)
GS Agriculture Price Index ×It≥2012

0.01
(0.01)

GS Energy Price Index ×It≥2012

0.00
(0.00)

Observations
2

R

179

69

248

0.04

0.13

0.06

Note: Eicker-White standard errors in parenthesis. ∗ p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05

20

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 5: U.S. Forward Rate Model: Structural Break Tests
1-Year, 9-Year Forward Rate

Constant

Core CPI surprise

GS Agriculture Price Index

GS Energy Price Index

All Coefficients

Residual Variance

Andrews-Quandt

Andrews-Ploberger

Date

Test Statistic

Test Statistic

2003:09

2.94

0.40

(0.57)

(0.53)

7.72∗

2008:12

2003:09

2008:10

2008:12

2013:11

2.06∗∗

(0.08)

(0.05)

5.10

1.24

(0.24)

(0.14)

4.25

0.75

(0.34)

(0.29)

10.22

3.23

(0.36)

(0.26)

1.85

0.19

(0.82)

(0.81)

Note: Approximate asymptotic p-values from Hansen (1997) in parenthesis.
Observations: 248
∗
p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05

21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 6: U.S. Inflation Compensation Model: Structural Break Tests Excluding Financial
Crisis
5-Year, 5-Year Forward Inflation

Constant

Core CPI surprise

Food & Energy CPI surprise

All Coefficients

Residual Variance

Andrews-Quandt

Andrews-Ploberger

Date

Test Statistic

Test Statistic

2002:08

2.13

0.27

(0.75)

(0.70)

9.91∗∗

2010:05

2010:07

2010:05

2001:09

(0.03)

(0.05)

1.20

0.13

(0.97)

(0.93)

10.90

2.57

(0.15)

(0.24)

2.55

0.60

(0.65)

(0.37)

Note: Approximate asymptotic p-values from Hansen (1997) in parenthesis.
Observations: 218
∗
p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05

22

2.13∗∗

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 7: U.S. Forward Rate Model: Structural Break Tests Excluding Financial Crisis
1-Year, 9-Year Forward Rate

Constant

Core CPI surprise

GS Agriculture Price Index

GS Energy Price Index

All Coefficients

Residual Variance

Andrews-Quandt

Andrews-Ploberger

Date

Test Statistic

Test Statistic

2003:09

1.99

0.24

(0.79)

(0.71)

10.29∗∗

2010:02

2003:09

2011:05

2003:09

2013:11

2.72∗∗

(0.02)

(0.02)

5.04

1.23

(0.24)

(0.14)

5.20

0.88

(0.23)

(0.24)

14.08

4.42∗

(0.11)

(0.10)

2.06

0.37

(0.77)

(0.56)

Note: Approximate asymptotic p-values from Hansen (1997) in parenthesis.
Observations: 242
∗
p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05

23

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 8: Japan Forward Rate Model
1-Year, 9-Year Forward Rate
Constant

2001-2012

2013-2017

2001-2017

0.00

0.00

0.00

(0.01)

(0.00)

(0.01)

0.13∗∗

Core CPI surprise

GS Agricultural Price Index

0.07∗

0.13∗∗

(0.06)

(0.04)

(0.06)

0.00

0.00

0.00

(0.00)

(0.00)

(0.00)

Constant ×It≥2013

0.00
(0.01)

Core CPI surprise ×It≥2013

−0.06
(0.08)

GS Agricultural Price Index ×It≥2013

0.00
(0.00)

Observations
R

2

136

57

193

0.02

0.04

0.02

Note: Eicker-White standard errors in paranthesis. ∗ p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05

24

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Table 9: Model-Implied Implications of Anchored Inflation Expectations
Model

Model

Drifting Expectations

Anchored Expectations

Data

ϑπ = 0.003

ϑπ = 0.01

ϑπ = 0.0

Average 10-Year Term Premium

1.06

1.00

1.11

0.95

Average Slope of Yield Curve

1.43

0.88

0.96

0.85

Note: We compute the model-implied moments using the model in Section III.B of Rudebusch and Swanson
(2012). With the exception of ϑπ , all other model parameters are calibrated to match their best-fit values
reported in the paper. The empirical moments are from Table 3 of their paper.

25

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Figure 1: Chow Test Sequence for Core Inflation Coefficient as a Function of Breakdate
US Inflation Compensation Model

12

Longer-run inflation
added to SEP

Chow Test Sequence
Excluding Crisis
Andrews Critical Value

9

2% inflation
target adopted

6

3

0
2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

US Forward Rate Model

12

Longer-run inflation
added to SEP

2% inflation
target adopted

9

6

3

0
2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Japan Forward Rate Model

12

2% inflation
target adopted

QQE

9

6

3

0
2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

2015

Note: Each panel shows the sequence of Chow test statistics as a function of candidate break dates. For each
model, 15% of the observations on the ends of the sample are not examined as break points. 10% critical
values are obtained from Andrews (1993) for π0 = 0.15 and p = 1.

26

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024

Figure 2: Rolling Window Estimates of Core Inflation Coefficient
US Inflation Compensation Model

0.5
Longer-run inflation
added to SEP

90% Conf Interval
Point Estimate

2% inflation
target adopted

0.25

0

-0.25
2007

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

2015

2017

US Forward Rate Model

0.5
Longer-run inflation
added to SEP

2% inflation
target adopted

0.25

0

-0.25
2007

2009

2011

2013

Japan Forward Rate Model

0.5
2% inflation
target adopted

QQE

Yield Curve
Control

0.25

0

-0.25
2011

2013

2015

2017

Note: Each panel shows the sequence of estimates of β as a function of time. The date on the x-axis denotes
the end point of the 10-year rolling sample. The 90% confidence intervals are computed as the point estimate
plus or minus 1.645 times the robust standard error.

27