View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
Has the Phillip Curve Died?
New Evidence from Cross-Geographical Data
By Daniel J. Wilson
Summary
•

Low wage and price inflation during the current recovery has caused many observers to ask
whether the wage and/or price Phillips Curves have flattened in recent years.

•

I offer new evidence on this question using cross-geographical Phillips Curve (PC) estimations,
based on MSA-level panel data from 1991 to 2015.
o I investigate both the price and wage PCs.

•

The evidence points to a flattening of the cross-geographical price and wage PCs over time,
especially during the current recovery.
o The evidence for flattening is especially strong for the wage PC.
o The cross-MSA evidence suggests that flattening of the price PC during the current
recovery has lowered price inflation pressures by about one-tenth of a percentage point,
while the flattening of the wage PC during the current recovery has lowered wage
inflation pressures by about two-tenths.

•

I discuss the implications of this cross-geographical PC flattening for the aggregate PC.
o While these slopes can differ due to cross-geographical labor mobility and tradability,
these factors together have trended over recent years in such a way as to suggest the
aggregate slope has flattened at least as much as the cross-geographical slope.

Page 1 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
I. Has the Phillips Curve flattened in recent years?
A. The price Phillips Curve
•

As in Leduc & Wilson (2015), I estimate the cross-geographical price Phillips Curve using the
following specification:

π it = α t + α i + ρπ i ,t −1 + β ( uit − uit ) + ε i ,t ,

(1)

where π it denotes the inflation rate in MSA i in year t, αt represents time fixed effects, αi
represents MSA fixed effects, uit denotes MSA i’s actual rate of unemployment and uit denotes
MSA i’s natural rate of unemployment. The natural rate is allowed to be MSA- and time-varying.
o I measure MSA-level inflation using the annual percentage change in the CPI price
index.
o I measure the natural rate by a 10-year trailing average of the area’s unemployment rate.
o The year fixed effects will capture aggregate movements in inflation expectations,
national or global supply shocks, and other macroeconomic factors (including monetary
policy).
•

I first update the results of Leduc & Wilson, extending their sample through 2015. 1 The estimated
slope – the coefficient on the unemployment gap – for the full 1991-2015 sample period is shown
in the first row of column (1) of Table 1.

•

The estimated full-sample PC slope is -0.23, which is statistically significant at below the 1%
level. This slope implies that a one percentage point (p.p.) decline in a MSA’s unemployment gap
is associated with an increase in its inflation rate of 0.23 p.p.

1

State-level price inflation data is only available from 2008 onward, so I do not use them here for
investigating how the price PC slope has changed over time. Nonetheless, I have also estimated the crossstate price PC for the period 2009 – 2015, finding a precisely estimated slope of -0.06, consistent with the
hypothesis that the cross-geographical PC is close to flat over this period.

Page 2 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.

•

This full sample slope, however, masks consider variation across subperiods, as shown in the
second and third rows of Table 1. Over 1991 – 2008, the estimated price PC slope in the crossMSA data is -0.28. Yet, for the current recovery period (2009 – 2015), the slope is significantly
flatter, at -0.16. The difference in slopes is statistically significant at the 10% level.
o To put this flattening in context, note that the national unemployment gap fell by five p.p.
between 2009Q4 and 2016Q4, or about 0.7 p.p. per year. A PC slope of -0.28 implies that
a drop in a city’s unemployment gap of that magnitude should increase its annual inflation
rate by 0.20 p.p. By contrast, a slope of -0.16 implies an increase in annual inflation of
0.11 p.p. Hence, this flattening amounts to about one-tenth lower inflation pressure during
the current recovery.
o This relative flattening of the cross-MSA Phillips Curve is robust to alternative measures
of slack. 2
o The flattening is also broad-based across subcategories of inflation. 3

2

Appendix Table A1 shows results where slack is measured by the current unemployment rate, the lagged
unemployment rate, or the lagged unemployment gap. In each case, the price PC slope is flatter over 20092015 than over the full sample.
3
Appendix Table A2 shows analogous results where inflation is split into subcategories. Five of the six
subcategories have a flatter PC slope during the current recovery compared with the full 1991-2015 sample
period. The other category, nondurable goods, shows essentially no change in its PC slope.

Page 3 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
•

To investigate whether the cross-geographical price PC slope has changed over time more
generally, I estimate equation (1) using 7-year rolling samples for 1991 – 1997, 1992 – 1998, and
so on, through 2009 – 2015.

•

The PC slope coefficients ( ) and their 90% confidence intervals are shown in Figure 1. The
evidence on flattening is mixed. The slope was generally stable over time, hovering around -0.2
to -0.3, until recent years. A clear increase in the slope did not occur until very recently, with
sample periods ending in 2014 or 2015.

•

Figure 2 shows analogous results using the unemployment rate, instead of the gap, as the measure
of slack. Note that this graph starts a few years earlier because the unemployment rate data is
available earlier than the gap data.
o Using the unemployment rate, the evidence of a flattening of the slope in recent years is
much stronger.

Page 4 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.

Page 5 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
B. The wage Phillips Curve
•

Next I turn to the cross-geographical wage Phillips Curve, estimating a standard wage PC
specification:

π itw = α t + α i + ρπ i ,t −1 + β ( uit − uit ) + ε it ,

(2)

where π itw denotes the wage inflation rate in MSA i in year t, and other variables are as defined
earlier.
o My primary measure of annual "wages" for a given area is total wage and salary income
divided by total employment (wage income per job). The data come from the BEA
Regional Economic Accounts.
•

As I did for the price PC, I estimate the wage PC (equation (2)) using MSA panel data over the
full sample period 1991-2015 and over the subperiods 1991-2008 and 2009-2015. The results
are shown in column (2) of Table 1.

•

For the full sample period, the estimated cross-MSA wage PC slope is -0.35, which is
statistically significant at below the 1% level. This slope implies that a one percentage point
decrease in a MSA's unemployment gap is associated with an increase in its wage inflation rate
of 0.35 percentage point.

•

However, as was the case for the price PC results, these full sample results mask consider
variation across subperiods. The estimated cross-MSA PC slope over 1991-2008 is -0.45. Over
2009-2015, the slope is just -0.14 and statistically insignificant.
o To put this in context, a 0.7 p.p. per year drop in the unemployment gap – such as that
observed at the national level during the current recovery – implies an increase in annual
wage inflation of 0.32 p.p. if the wage PC slope is -0.45 but just 0.10 p.p. if the slope is 0.14. Hence, this flattening amounts to about two-tenths lower wage inflation pressure
during the current recovery.

•

This evidence of flattening is robust to using alternative measures of slack.
o Appendix Table A3 shows results using the current unemployment rate, the lagged
unemployment rate, or the lagged unemployment gap. In each case, the slope of the
wage PC is statistically significantly negative over the full sample period but it is closer
to zero and statistically insignificant over the 2009 - 2015 period.

Page 6 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
•

As I did for price inflation, I also investigate whether the cross-geographical wage PC slope has
changed over time more generally using 7-year rolling-sample regressions of equation (2).

•

The wage PC slope coefficients ( ) and their 90% confidence intervals, based on MSA data, are
shown in Figure 3. The analogous figure using the unemployment rate instead of the gap is
shown in Figure 4. 4 Both figures point to a flattening of the cross-MSA wage PC slope starting
around the 2002 - 2008 sample and continuing through the latest (2009 - 2015) sample period.
o This flattening is quite robust. It is insensitive to omitting time fixed effects, replacing
lagged price inflation as a regressor with lagged wage inflation (in the MSA
regressions), measuring slack with the unemployment rate instead of the gap (as shown),
and down-weighting outliers (via quantile/median regression).

•

Evidence of flattening in the wage PC also holds in cross-state regressions.
o Analogous BEA wage inflation data is available back to 1991 for states. Appendix
Figure A1 (based on the unemployment gap) and A2 (based on the unemployment rate)
show the estimated wage PC slope using the state data. One sees a clear flattening of the
slope in recent sample periods.
o At the state level, I also have constructed wages using average hourly earnings (AHE)
directly from the CPS micro data. Rolling-sample wage PC slope results based on AHE
are shown in Appendix Figures A3-A4. Again, one sees strong evidence of flattening in
recent periods.

4

Note that this graph starts a few years earlier because the unemployment rate data is available earlier than
the gap data.

Page 7 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.

Page 8 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
II. Implications for the aggregate price and wage Phillips Curves
A. Does Cross-Geographic PC flattening imply aggregate PC flattening?
•

At any given point in time, the cross-geographical Phillips Curve slope need not be equal to the
aggregate Phillips Curve slope. There are two key reasons why they might differ: 5,6
o Labor mobility: Blanchard and Katz (1992) document that interstate migration in the U.S. is
a key mechanism by which state economies return to equilibrium after regional booms and
busts. In effect, in-migration of job seekers in response to a local boom represents a labor
supply shock that helps offset the wage pressures stemming from the initial increase in labor
demand. This will tend to mute the effect of labor market tightness on wage inflation relative
the effect at the national level, where in-migration of labor from abroad is very limited.
o Tradability: A local “aggregate demand” shock will bid up prices of local non-tradables such
as housing, but have little effect on the prices of locally produced tradable goods, the prices
of which are set by national and international demand and supply. Thus, the greater the share
of local final consumption that is produced non-locally (i.e., the higher is tradability), the
lower is the effect of local demand on local inflation. Of course, the same logic applies at the
national level in an international context, but international tradability is far lower than intranational tradability.

•

A priori, it is possible that increases over recent years in cross-geographical labor mobility or
output tradability could have caused a flattening in the cross-geographical price PC without a
corresponding flattening in the aggregate price PC. However, available evidence on these two
factors suggests the opposite has occurred.

5

Another issue is monetary policy. In cross-geographical comparisons, either with a single cross-section or
pooled cross-sections with time fixed effects, monetary policy is held fixed. By contrast, in national time
series PC regressions, monetary policy must be explicitly controlled for or it becomes an omitted variable. If
it is omitted, estimates of the national PC slope will be downward biased estimates of the true causal effect of
demand shocks on inflation because monetary policy generally “leans against the wind” – offsetting the
inflationary pressures from aggregate demand shocks by raising interest rates in response to reductions in
resource slack. Thus, national time-series estimates of the PC slope that do not explicitly account for
monetary policy could be lower than estimates of the cross-geographical PC slope.
6
For similar reasons, these same factors are key sources of difference between a cross-geographic fiscal
multiplier and an aggregate multiplier, as shown in Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) and Leduc and Wilson
(2013). Blanchard and Katz (1999) discuss how internal labor mobility can cause cross-geographic PC
estimates to be biased estimates of the aggregate PC: “This source of bias is likely to be especially important
for the United States, where labor mobility is a major source of adjustment to state labor-market shocks.”

Page 9 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
o First, cross-state labor mobility in the U.S. has fallen over time (Kaplan and Schulhofer-Wohl
2017), which should have steepened the cross-geographical PC slope over time.
o Second, there is no evidence suggesting that the tradable-good share of local economies’ final
consumption has changed over recent years. Also, note that the tradability factor only affects
the price PC slope, so changes in tradability could not explain the observed flattening of the
cross-geographical wage PC.
•

Thus, changes in these two factors together cannot explain the flattening of the cross-geographical
PC slope, implying that the aggregate PC slope – holding monetary policy fixed – has flattened
at least as much.

B. Why might the PC have flattened?
•

The cross-geographical PC estimates can be useful in discriminating between alternative theories
of why the aggregate PC slope may have flattened during the current recovery.
o One theory is that inflation expectations have become unanchored. This explanation is
hard to square with the cross-geographical evidence presented in this briefing because
inflation expectations are generally thought to be tied to the monetary policy inflation
objective, which is common across all states and cities.
o Another theory is that the economy has been hit by a string of negative inflation shocks,
involving several different idiosyncratic factors (see other briefing in current binder).
However, the factors to which analysts have pointed, such as factors involving the dollar,
oil, pharmaceutical products, cellular services, etc., tend to be global and national in nature
and hence they are unlikely to explain the cross-geographical PC flattening.
o Similarly, disinflation due to technological and structural changes in the retail sector
cannot explain this cross-geographical flattening.
o In addition, these idiosyncratic factors relate to price inflation and offer no explanation of
the observed flattening of the cross-geographical wage PC.

•

Theories that could potentially explain both a cross-geographic PC flattening and an aggregate
PC flattening generally involve changes in structural parameters characterizing the wage and
price setting processes (e.g., in a New Keynesian model).
o For example, a decline in worker bargaining power (combined with unchanged passthrough of unit labor costs to final prices) – consistent with reduced unionization, the

Page 10 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
decline in the labor share, and increased industry concentration ratios – is a potential
explanation. However, these trends generally pre-date the start of the flattening of the
cross-geographical PC.
o Another possibility is downward nominal wage rigidities. Daly and Hobijn (2014) show
that downward nominal wage rigidities are more likely to bind in recessions, and
particularly in the Great Recession. They show theoretically that such rigidities can mute
the downward pressure on wage growth during these periods when labor market slack is
especially high, thus flattening the wage Phillips Curve. Moreover, pent-up demand for
real wage cuts by firms can linger into the recovery period and delay the normalization
of the Phillips Curve even as slack returns to normal.
•

The explanation for the flattening, of course, is crucial for predicting whether the PC slope will
soon return to prior levels or remain flat in coming years.
o Explanations involving secular declines in worker bargaining power suggest the flat
slope will persist, while explanations such as downward nominal wage rigidities suggest
the PC slope should steepen going forward.

•

Monitoring how the cross-geographical PC evolves in the years ahead should help reveal the
underlying causes of the recent flattening.

Page 11 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
References
Blanchard, Olivier, and Lawrence F. Katz, “Wage Dynamics: Reconciling Theory and Evidence,”
American Economic Review, May 1999, 89(2), pp.69-74.
Daly, Mary, and Bart Hobijn (2014), “Downward Nominal Wage Rigidities Bend the Phillips
Curve,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 46(S2), pp.51-93.
Kaplan, Greg, and Sam Schulhofer-Wohl (2017). “Understanding the Long-Run Decline in
Interstate Migration,” International Economic Review, 58(1), pp.57-94.
Leduc, Sylvain, and Daniel J. Wilson (2015), “Regional Phillips Curves,” FRBSF pre-FOMC
Briefing, June 2015.
Leduc, Sylvain and Daniel Wilson, “Roads to Prosperity or Bridges to Nowhere? Theory and
Evidence on the Impact of Public Infrastructure Investment.” In NBER Macroeconomics
Annual 2012, Acemoglu, et al., editors (2013) pp. 89-142.
Nakamura, Emi and Jon Steinsson, “Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union: Evidence from US
Regions,” American Economic Review, 2014, 104 (3), 753-92.

Page 12 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.
Appendix. Supplementary Results

Page 13 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.

Page 14 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.

Page 15 of 16

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/12/2024
PART 1-X
9/13/2017
Internal F.R.

Page 16 of 16