View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in
the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
in Washington, D. C.,
PRESENT:

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

on Tuesday, January 10, 1967, at 9:30 a.m.

Martin, Chairman
Brimmer

Clay
Daane
Hickman
Irons
Maisel
Mitchell
Robertson
Shepardson
Treiber, Alternate for Mr. Hayes
Wayne, Alternate for Mr. Bopp

Messrs. Scanlon, Francis, and Swan, Alternate
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Ellis, Patterson, and Galusha, Presidents
of the Federal Reserve Banks of Boston, Atlanta,
and Minneapolis, respectively
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Sherman, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Kenyon, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Broida, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Molony, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Brill, Economist
Messrs. Eastburn, Green, Koch, Mann, Partee,
Solomon, Tow, and Young, Associate Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market Account
Mr. Coombs, Special Manager, System Open Market
Account
Mr. Fauver, Assistant to the Board of Governors
Mr. Williams, Adviser, Division of Research and
Statistics, Board of Governors
Messrs. Hersey and Reynolds, Advisers, Division
of International Finance, Board of Governors

1/10/67

-2
Mr. Axilrod, Associate Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Miss Eaton, General Assistant, Office of the
Secretary, Board of Governors
Mr. Hilkert, First Vice President, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Messrs. Eisenmenger, Link, Taylor, Baughman,
Jones, Andersen, and Craven, Vice Presidents
of the Federal Reserve Banks of Boston,
New York, Atlanta, Chicago, St. Louis,
St. Louis, and San Francisco, respectively
Messrs. Meek and Monhollon, Assistant Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of New York and Richmond, respectively
Mr. Kareken, Consultant, Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis
Chairman Martin said that at this, the first Committee meeting

of the new year, it might be well once again to offer a word of
caution to those in attendance in reminder that the discussions and
decisions of the Committee were confidential until officially made
public.
Upon motion duly made and seconded,
and by unanimous vote, the minutes of the
meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee
held on December 13, 1966, were approved.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the members
of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of the System
Open Market Account on foreign exchange market conditions and on
Open Market Account and Treasury operations in foreign currencies
for the period December 13, 1966, through January 4, 1967, and a
supplemental report for January 5 through 9, 1967.

Copies of these

reports have been placed in the files of the Committee.

1/10/67
In comments supplementing the written reports, Mr. Coombs
said that the Treasury gold stock would remain unchanged this week.
Holdings of the Stabilization Fund were about $50 million, and at
the moment there were no sizable central bank orders in sight.
On the London gold market, however, serious trouble appeared to
be shaping up.

During 1966 the gold pool lost $300 million, leaving

resources at the end of the year of only $60 million.

In addition,

and this was not generally appreciated, during 1966 the U.S. sold
$150 million for domestic uses.

Thus, over the year the total drain

into market uses from official stocks was $450 million--a very large
figure and, as he had indicated at previous meetings, one that
threatened to grow in future years.
Toward the year-end, Mr. Coombs continued, a good deal of
gold had been bought for window-dressing purposes, some of which
might flow back; indeed, in the first few days of the year the gold
pool picked up about $11
events recently.

million.

But there had been two disturbing

One was the First National City Bank letter which

pointed up the deterioration in the supply-demand situation for gold
and concluded that all new production in 1966 had gone into private
hands, with none left for official stocks.

The true situation was

worse than that, but the publication of the National City Bank's
analysis had had a highly unsettling effect on the market, which
now was beginning to realize the underlying situation.

A second,

-4

1/10/67

and more disturbing, development was the French campaign 1/

which was now directed at raising doubts about the

official price of gold.

Of course, the French were well aware of

the nature of the supply-demand situation through their participation
in the London gold pool.

Their campaign moved into higher gear

last weekend with the French Finance Minister, Mr. Debre, calling
for multilateral consideration of the official price of gold.

His

statement was taken by the market as an official suggestion that the
price of gold should be increased.

Mr. Debre would meet with the

other Common Market Finance Ministers on January 16 and if past
experience was a guide the communique issued after that meeting
might well stir up still further speculation.

There had been very

heavy buying of gold in London today, and thus far the pool had
lost $9 million.

That situation could get worse.

There had been quite a bit of discussion of Mr. Debre's
press conference at the Basle meeting this past weekend, Mr. Coombs
continued,

2/

He hoped, however, that it would
be possible to get the cooperation of other central banks in devising
some sort of contingency plan for dealing with a possible breakout
1/ Part of a sentence has been deleted at this point for one of the
reasons cited in the preface. The deleted material was descriptive of
the "campaign" under discussion.
2/ Two sentences and part of a third have been deleted at this point

for one of the reasons cited in the preface. The deleted material
related to views expressed at the Basle meeting.

-5

1/10/67
of the London gold price.

As he had said many times before, he

thought that was the single most serious threat facing the U.S.
in the area of international finance, and it was more dangerous
today than it had been earlier.
On the exchange markets, Mr. Coombs reported, sterling
continued to be depressed by uncertainties with respect to both
short- and long-run prospects.

For each of the past three months

the British had managed to squeeze out some small reserve gainson the order of $40 or $50 million--but those gains were highly
inadequate in relation to the volume of their debts falling due
this year.

They owed well over $1 billion in short-term (6 - 9 month)

debt that had been on the books since last summer.

In addition,

they owed about $900 million to the International Monetary Fund,
on which the payment date was the end of November.

Thus, they had

over $2 billion to be paid off within about ten months.

Unless

they got a major swing in their favor they were not going to make
it, and their failure to do so could have very serious consequences
for the international payments system.

He hoped that in such an

eventuality the System would be able to protect itself, but much
of the answer lay in what the British themselves could do in the
way of policy to bring about a significant turnaround in the situation.

1/10/67
There was some hope for sterling

in a general easing of

international credit conditions, Mr. Coombs said.

The discount

rate reduction by the German Federal Bank had been helpful, and
it was quite possible that the Bank might cut the rate again during
the next few weeks.

More importantly, the Germans might reduce

their reserve requirements and thus bring about some easing in
their credit markets.
difficulties of last

The British took the position that their
summer were attributable largely to general

monetary tightness, and that argument undoubtedly had some merit.
If they now were to recoup the losses they incurred beginning last
fall they probably would have to maintain some competitive advantage
in interest rates and credit availability, in order to attract some
part of the funds from the U.S. and other countries flowing back
into the Euro-dollar market.

On balance, he thought it would be

to the advantage of the U.S. to have those

funds flow to Britain-

not only in permitting the British to pay off their loans on time,
but also because the safest place for the money to go that was being
returned to the Euro-dollar market by U.S. banks was to the U.K.
Regarding System swap operations, Mr. Coombs reported that
at present the System owed $85 million to the Bundesbank, $35 million
to the Netherlands Bank, and a total of $90 million to the Bank for
International

Settlements and the National Bank of Switzerland.

hoped that the debt in marks could be cleaned up in the next

few

He

-7

1/10/67

weeks; it had been incurred in connection with year-end pressures
which had already moderated.

Repayment of the Swiss franc debt

might be delayed somewhat because the Swiss took in a large volume
of dollars over the year-end both outright and in one-month swaps,
and the reversal of those reserve accruals had priority over
System acquisitions of francs as Switzerland moved into its seasonal
deficit.

There was a chance that repayment of the System drawings

would not begin until near the end of February, but he hoped for
some repayments in February and full liquidation by the end of
March.

That would mean that the System's Swiss franc borrowings

would be extended beyond the 6-month period usually thought of as
a limit, perhaps to 7-1/2 or 8 months, but he did not see much
possibility of accelerating repayment.

The Treasury might be asked

to issue a franc-denominated bond to the Swiss to permit more rapid
repayment, but in his judgment it would be better to save that
device for possible future needs.
to clean up the guilder debt.

It might prove more difficult

In part, the problem resulted from

the fact that the Dutch had no means of increasing their money
supply except by running a balance of payments surplus or by main
taining domestic money market conditions that pulled money in from
abroad.

This primitive monetary policy was an important factor in

the frequency of Federal Reserve drawings of Dutch guilders and
similarly tended to obstruct the repayment process.

To repay the

$35 million now outstanding, it might be well either for the U.S.

1/10/67

-8

to make a drawing on the IMF or for the Treasury to issue a
guilder bond to the Dutch.

Both possibilities were now under

consideration.
On the other side of the accounts, Mr. Coombs continued,
the BIS still owed the System $49 million of the $200 million they
had borrowed to deal with year-end window-dressing, and he thought
they would be able to liquidate that remaining debt within the next
week or two.

The Bank of England had paid off $100 million of its

drawings under the swap line with the System and he thought that
in using any reserve accruals they would give priority to repaying
their remaining debt.

The System swap line was the most important

source of credit the British had, and thus far they had been scrupu
lous in paying off their borrowings.

Unless some severe problems

arose over the next month or two--and that was conceivable, given
the pressures in the gold market--there was a reasonable chance
that their debt to the System would be liquidated within roughly
six months from the time it was incurred.
Mr. Brimmer noted that Mr. Coombs had said it might be
helpful to the U.S. if Britain maintained some differential in
interest rates.

Did that imply that the U.S. should not encourage

the Bank of England to lower their Bank rate?
Mr. Coombs replied that he thought the British would have
a difficult problem in working out the precise means for taking

-9

1/10/67

advantage of an easing of credit in international markets.

He

felt that it would be appropriate to offer a very general comment
to the effect that it might be desirable for them to maintain some
differential.

But it probably would be undesirable to suggest any

specific ways of doing so, since some delicate political questions
might well be involved.
Thereupon, upon motion duly made
and seconded, and by unanimous vote,
the System open market transactions in
foreign currencies during the period
December 13, 1966, through January 9,
1967, were approved, ratified, and
confirmed.
Mr. Coombs reported that the two swap arrangements with
the German Federal Bank--the original $250 million, six-month
arrangement and the $150 million, five-month arrangement negotiated
on a temporary basis in September--matured on February 9, 1967.
At the last Basle meeting President Blessing of the Bundesbank
indicated that they would be prepared to renew the temporary arrange
ment and to consolidate it with the original arrangement.

Mr. Coombs

recommended renewal of the combined arrangement with the German
Federal Bank, totaling $400 million, for a period of six months.
Renewal of the $400 million swap
arrangement with the German Federal
Bank for a period of six months was
approved.
Mr. Coombs then reported that the $100 million arrangement
with the Bank of France would come to the end of its three-month

1/10/67

-10

term on February 10, 1967.

That arrangement was inoperative, and

it was becoming somewhat anomalous in view of the French Government's
attitude, but he thought there was some advantage in continuing to
maintain it as a bridge to the future when the French might be
somewhat more amenable to international cooperation than they were
at the moment.

Accordingly, he recommended renewal of the arrange

ment.
Renewal of the $100 million swap
arrangement with the Bank of France
for a period of three months was
approved.
Mr. Coombs noted that several drawings under the swap lines
would reach maturity soon.

On January 25, 1967 two Swiss franc

drawings would mature--one for $25 million with the BIS and one for
$15

million with the Swiss National Bank.

If renewed, both would

be second renewals, thus extending their terms beyond the usual
six-month period.

As he had indicated earlier, he hoped that the

seasonal weakening of the franc in the spring months would enable
the System to clean up those drawings in February and March.
Mr. Shepardson expressed continuing reservations with regard
to the extension of swap drawings beyond a six-month period.
Chairman Martin observed that Mr. Shepardson's reservations
were well taken.

He thought, however, that the Committee could

approve second renewals since it was still operating on an experi
mental basis in this area.

-11

1/10/67

Renewal of the two Swiss franc
drawings was noted without objection.
Finally, Mr. Coombs noted that two drawings on the Netherlands
Bank would mature soon--a $10 million drawing on January 23, and a
$25 million drawing on February 7, 1967.

Both of those drawings

also had already been renewed once, but as he had mentioned earlier
the possibilities of cleaning them up either by going to the IMF
or by issuing a guilder bond to the Dutch were under consideration.
In his view the guilder bond might be the more satisfactory method
since the flows of funds to the Netherlands resulted from their
tight credit policies, and did not reflect a basic balance of payments
surplus.

But whatever the method used, he thought he could assure

the Committee that the System's guilder debt would be repaid within
a month or six weeks.
Mr. Shepardson expressed reservations about second renewals
of these drawings also.
Renewal of the two drawings
on the Netherlands Bank was noted
without objection.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the members
of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System Open Market
Account covering open market operations in U.S. Government securities
and bankers' acceptances for the period December 13, 1966, through
January 4, 1967, and a supplemental report covering the period

1/10/67

-12-

January 5 through 9, 1967.

Copies of both reports have been

placed in the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Holmes
commented as

follows:

Since the Committee last met the capital markets
have turned in a strong performance in a buoyant
atmosphere, bank credit has showed renewed strength,
and the money market has weathered the stresses and
strains of the tax and year-end statement dates with
out undue problems. In general, bank credit expansion
moved ahead more rapidly and market interest rates
declined further than had been anticipated at the time
of the last meeting without a need to push net borrowed
reserves to zero or the Federal funds rate to 5 per
cent or below. And with market rates moving lower,
banks were able to add to their outstanding CD's in
December in contrast to the $700 million-$l billion
decline anticipated a month ago.
Market expectations--shaped by additional evidence
of less restraint in monetary policy, by weakness in
some economic indicators, and to some extent, by develop
ments in Vietnam--in effect succeeded in changing the
relationships among the short-run monetary variables
with which we are most concerned in our day-to-day
operations. As the various written reports to the
Committee have indicated, much of the rise in bank credit
can be traced to increased borrowing by dealers to finance
their substantial inventories of securities and to in
creases in bank portfolios of Government and municipal
securities, Dealer financing needs have exerted pressure
on the money market, but with the major New York City
banks maintaining their dealer loan rates at high levels,
there has been some restraint recently on dealers'
willingness to add to their holdings. I would not now
characterize dealer positions as being dangerously
over-extended, but they could become a source of market
pressure if the anticipated flow of corporate and public
fund money to the market and continued bank demand fail
to materialize at a time when there is little seasonal
need for the System to supply reserves.
Open market operations, as the written reports to
the Committee have detailed, were frequent and large, as

1/10/67

-13-

they usually are in December, and were complicated more
than usually by the tendency for reserves to fall short
of expectations, by the shift in market expectations,
and by year-end developments involving international
money flows. Outright purchases of Government securities
approached $1 billion, and very heavy use was made of
repurchase agreements against Government and agency
securities over the period. Over $4 billion in repurchase
agreements were made, with the average daily balance
amounting to $575 million.
Repurchase agreements were a particularly useful
tool during this period in view of the many uncertainties
in the reserve picture. They enabled the System to make
heavy injections of reserves in order to head off money
market tightness on individual days, when it seemed
likely that the operation would have to be shortly
reversed. With dealer financing needs a source of
recurrent pressure in the money markets, the repurchase
agreement was a natural instrument for injecting reserves
at the point of greatest need. A comparable volume of
outright purchases and sales of securities would
undoubtedly have subjected the markets to a series of
unnecessary shocks and could have had unpredictable
effects on interest rates during a difficult period.
Moreover, we learned early in the period that very sizable
sales of Treasury bills by foreign monetary authorities
would be involved at the year-end in regular and special
debt repayments to the United States. Although the
precise amounts and the timing were not clear at that
early date, it appeared advisable to conduct operations
in such a way as to leave open an option for the System
to acquire at least part of these bills, rather than be
forced to sell as much as $1/2 billion or more Treasury
bills in the market at the very end of the year. Quite
obviously the nonbank Government securities dealers
welcomed the opportunity to sell securities to the System
under repurchase agreements made at the discount rate,
but we did not consider it wise to give out a signal that
could easily have been misinterpreted in the market by
raising the rate at this particular time.
Rates on three- and six-month Treasury bills declined
about 1/4 per cent over the interval, with some tendency
for rates to level off at the end of the period. In
yesterday's regular weekly Treasury bill auction, average
rates of 4.82 and 4.89 per cent, respectively, were set

1/10/67
on the three- and six-month bills. Rates on bankers'
acceptances, commercial paper, and FNMA discount notes
also moved lower over the period. Yields on intermediate
and long-term Treasury obligations declined by 20 to 50
basis points, and by the close of the period yields in
the 3- to 5-year area were 1 - 1-1/2 percentage points
below their August peaks, while long-term bond yields
were about back to where they were at the time of the
December 1965 discount rate change. Despite the build-up
of the calendar of new issues, the corporate and municipal
markets have maintained a confident tone.
The $250
million A.T. & T. issue, which is up for bidding this
morning, was expected last night to be reoffered at
about 5-3/8 - 5-1/2 per cent, compared with a 5.83 yield
in the last Aaa telephone issue brought to market on
December 6. The new FNMA 5, 10, and 15-year participation
certificates--brought to market at a uniform 5.20 per
cent--received an excellent reception. The 15-year
issue rose to a premium of as much as 20/32 bid, until
late yesterday when the price dropped 1/2 point reflecting
market rumors of an early Export-Import Bank participation
certificate announcement.
The next few weeks are apt to be a testing period
in the market for the pattern of interest rate relation
ships and financial flows that have been emerging since
monetary policy entered a phase of less restraint. It
will also be a period in which the markets will be
assessing the implications of the various Presidential
messages for the monetary-fiscal policy mix in 1967, and
will be reassessing the economic outlook as each new
bit of information becomes available. As the blue book1/
indicates, monetary expansion is expected to be vigorous
in January, but there are at least the usual number of
uncertainties in the picture. The Treasury will be
announcing in about two weeks the terms of its February
refunding, and the usual "even keel" considerations will
come into play in the latter part of the interval before
the Committee meets again.
In response to a question by Mr. Mitchell, Mr. Holmes said
that he thought that dealers' positions were not dangerously
1/ The report, "Money Market and Reserve Relationships,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

1/10/67

-15

overextended partly because they were not unusually large relative
to other recent years; for example, dealer financing needs
currently were only about 10 per cent larger than they had been
two years ago.

Dealers with whom the Desk had talked appeared

confident of the market.

They were concerned about the high level

of marginal borrowing costs at New York banks, but were willing
to incur some negative carry in the expectation that they would
make out quite well.

Their holdings of coupon issues had not

expanded substantially, which was rather surprising in view of
the change in expectations.

Dealer financing needs had been a

source of money market pressure recently, as he had noted, and
they could pose a problem if the flows anticipated this month did
not take place.
In reply to another question by Mr. Mitchell, Mr. Holmes
said that the volume of System repurchase agreements with dealers
had been quite high recently, but it usually was high in December.
In December 1966 the System had financed about 12 per cent of
dealer positions in Governments, compared to 7 per cent in
December 1965 and 10 per cent in December 1964.

Thus, the Desk

had been doing a bit more through RP's recently than in earlier
years, but not markedly more.
Mr. Mitchell then referred to Mr. Holmes' comment that it
had been considered unwise to raise the rate charged on RP's in

1/10/67

-16

the recent period on the ground that such a signal could be easily
misconstrued in the market.

He asked whether the same situation

would hold in the coming period.
Mr. Holmes replied that RP's were not likely to be made in
large volume in the coming weeks of January, when the Desk probably
would not be supplying reserves.

He thought that a higher rate on

RP's could be adequately explained to dealers.
Mr. Brimmer asked whether debt management activity was
likely to interfere with achievement of Committee objectives over
the next month or two, apart from sales of participation certificates
and agency issues.

There had been reports to the effect that as

monetary conditions eased the Treasury would tend increasingly to
step into the market with the objective of achieving some lengthening
of the debt.

In particular, did the Manager expect that the February

refunding would impose a greater burden on the market than had been
anticipated?
Mr. Holmes replied that it was obvious, given the 4-1/4
per cent interest rate ceiling on new bond issues, that the Treasury
would not be offering a maturity beyond 5 years in the February
refunding.

Thinking had not yet focused on the terms of the refund

ing, and probably would not until the end of January approached.
It was possible that the Treasury might make a split offering,

1/10/67

-17

involving a short-term security and one with a maturity in the
neighborhood of 4 or 5 years, but no decision had been reached.
Mr. Hickman asked whether the Committee was not relatively
free of an even keel restraint, at least for the first part of the
coming period, in view of the facts that the refunding involved
less than $4 billion in publicly-held maturing issues and that
its terms were not to be announced until near the end of January.
Mr. Holmes replied that he thought the refunding would
not be an especially difficult one, and accordingly that it should
not constrain the Committee from changing policy today if it was
inclined to do so.
In reply to a question by Mr. Swan, Mr. Holmes said that
the next Treasury financing after the forthcoming refunding was
likely to be a cash offering for payment in the second half of
February.
Thereupon, upon motion duly made
and seconded, and by unanimous vote,
the open market transactions in Govern
ment securities and bankers' acceptances
during the period December 13, 1966,
through January 9, 1967, were approved,
ratified, and confirmed.
Chairman Martin then called for the staff economic and
financial reports, supplementing the written reports that had been
distributed prior to the meeting, copies of which have been placed
in the files of the Committee.

Mr. Koch made the following statement on economic conditions:
The new information on domestic nonfinancial develop
ments that has become available since our last meeting
confirms the deceleration in the pace of the economic
expansion. The staff now estimates an increase of only
$7 billion in the GNP in the current quarter, despite
the fact that the fourth-quarter 1966 increase has been
raised to over $14 billion.
The most disturbing aspect of recent economic
developments is the sharply increased extent to which
production is going into inventories. Business inventory
accumulation has apparently been even greater than assumed
earlier and final takings smaller. Christmas sales were
generally disappointing to retailers and the rise of
consumer expenditures in the fourth quarter as a whole
was relatively small. To lagging sales of autos and
construction materials has been added less strength in
furniture, appliances, textiles, and other goods.
As for prices, recent developments have been mixed,
as indicated in the green book,1/ but the net result has
been a slowdown in the rate of rise of the broad price
indices. In the new year, prospects are for further
advances, but at a slower pace.
The future course of consumption and of the whole
economy for that matter will depend importantly on
developments in the three main areas of more or less
exogenous spending, namely, business outlays on plant
and equipment and on inventories and defense spending.
This is particularly true since consumption has been high
relative to income for several quarters.
We have no additional direct information today on
business fixed expenditures, but the data on new orders
for durable goods support the finding of the November
Commerce-SEC survey, namely, that the rise is decelerating.
New orders were down in both October and November, in part
due to lower defense orders. The level of new orders in
November was the lowest in a year and the backlog of
outstanding orders declined for the first time in three
years. The National Association of Purchasing Agents

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

1/10/67

-19-

also states that the number of its members reporting
improved new orders and higher production in December
was the smallest since the 1960-61 recession.
Definitive information on the Federal budget and
defense spending is still not available, but the informa
tion from the Daily Treasury Statement on recent months'
spending confirms staff projections of a tapering off
in the rate of increase of defense outlays beginning
last quarter. But, despite a tapering off in the rate
of defense spending and even if a tax increase is enacted,
the Federal budget deficit for both this fiscal year
and next is likely to be large. Of particular relevance
to economic developments, though, is the fact that part
of the deficit for the next few quarters at least is
likely to be a passive reflection of a reduced rate of
growth in tax revenues resulting from the projected
slowdown in the economic expansion rather than of increased
spending. We shall learn more about the fiscal picture
shortly in the State of the Union and Budget messages.
Since business inventory developments are a key
factor in the likely course of the economy in the near
term future, let me turn back to them for a second and
closer look.
I mentioned earlier that recent inventory accumulation
had been larger than anticipated earlier. Despite better
accounting controls and higher financing costs, stock-sales
ratios have been on a sharp rise since early 1966,
particularly in the durable goods manufacturing industries.
The rise in stocks has been largest in work-in-process
in the areas of consumer durable goods, defense goods,
and machinery and equipment.
What does this mean for the likely future course of
inventories in particular and of the total economy in
general? As for consumer durable goods, the recent rise
in stocks has been in household durables as well as in
autos. Production has already been cut back in many of
these lines, in autos to approximately the 8-million-car
current annual rate of sales. In the defense area, the
rise in new orders dropped off rather sharply in October
and November, and, with output of defense equipment now
rising much less rapidly than earlier in 1966, defense
work-in-process stocks may also be rising less rapidly
from now on, particularly if some production bottlenecks
are broken. Finally, in the area of machinery and
equipment, the tapering off of the plant and equipment

1/10/67

-20-

investment boom should mean a pronounced deceleration
in the rise of stocks in these industries in coming
months, even though the order backlog in this area is
still large.
All this tends to confirm the staff estimate of a
sharp fall-off in business inventory building in the
current quarter, perhaps by $5 billion or more. Even
such a drop is not likely to lower stock-sales ratios
and as a result pressure for further curtailment of
additions to inventories is apt to continue.
A sharp decline in inventory accumulation would in
and of itself create another pause in the economic expan
sion similar to those we have experienced several times
since World War II.
This is a common economic forecast
for the first half of 1967.
It is shared by some
Administration economists and by most of our staff.
The inventory deceleration will reduce market
demands and put to a test the underlying strength of
business capital spending programs, that is, the extent
to which such programs are supported by longer-run as
contrasted with short-run market prospects. The rate
of increase in business capital spending is already
decelerating, and if such spending actually begins to
decline we shall have a situation calling for major
policy alterations.
In the meantime, though, even the
near-term prospects for moderately reduced economic
growth call for a continuation of the gradual process
of overt monetary easing on which the Committee embarked
two meetings ago.
Mr. Axilrod made the following statement concerning financial
developments:
The policy of reduced monetary restraint initiated
by this Committee in the fall appears to be gradually
taking hold in financial markets.
This is evidenced
mainly by the increased flow of time deposit funds to
banks, including negotiable CD money to large banks,
and also by the more comfortable position of nonbank
savings institutions. It is also seen in the further
declines of market interest rates, both short- and
long-term, during the past several weeks.
But in many ways the impact of the new policy on
markets and the economy is not yet fully secure.

1/10/67

-21-

For one, the substantial rise in the money supply
its recent mid-November low point appears to have
in large part a short-run response to a decline in
Government deposits. We have not yet had evidence
at current levels of interest rates the privately
money stock is capable of sustained moderate growthat a rate much above the 2 per cent of 1966.
For a second, the lending policies of banks and
other financial institutions do not yet appear to have
altered definitively toward less restraint.
Some probing
in that direction is probably in train, but our contacts
with banks in recent weeks suggest that a wait-and-see
attitude still predominates.
And for a third, the recent interest rate declines
were in part based on expectations--expectations not
only that monetary policy was easing but that domestic
business expansion was weakening and that fiscal policy
would in one way or another not be a very massive
expansionary force in the period ahead. I would not rule
out the possibility that interest rates could rise, at
least temporarily, over the weeks ahead. On the other
hand, if expectations of business weakening prove correct,
even current interest rate levels may turn out to be too
high to provide the needed encouragement to economic
demand.
While one's view as to the likely strength of demands
for goods and services is fundamental to one's appraisal
of the appropriateness of current interest rate levels,
the condition of lending institutions is also a highly
relevant factor. The stringency that developed in these
institutions along with the 40-year record market interest
rates of last year resulted in a marked further erosion
of their liquidity positions. For commercial banks this
is most dramatically illustrated by the rise last year
in loan-deposit ratios (with dealer loans excluded) at
New York City banks from around 70 per cent to 80 per
cent. The adverse experience of such banks, savings
and loan associations, and life insurance companies
suggests that a significant relaxation of lending policies
depends in good part on at least a partial restoration of
their liquidity positions. And for both of those
developments to proximate each other in time might require
not only clearer signals as to prospective economic and
fiscal events but also clearer signals from the monetary
authority as might be indicated by some further reduction

from
been
U.S.
that
held
say,

1/10/67

-22-

in interest rates--or, at a minimum, efforts to forestall
any reversal of the recent interest rate declines.
The need to encourage a relatively prompt relaxation
of lending standards at financial institutions is based
in part on the nature of the economic imbalances that at
the moment appear to be developing. A principal danger
to the economy, as Mr. Koch has pointed out, seems to
come from a probable relatively sharp decrease in inven
tory accumulation over the period ahead. While some
inventory readjustment appears to be unavoidable, its
speed and scope might be modified somewhat if banks
were more accommodative of business loans. The inventory
adjustment might also be tempered if consumer spending
on goods, both durable and nondurable, could be relatively
well maintained; and given the University of Michigan
consumer survey evaluation that consumers are gloomy,
but not outright pessimists, an easing of bank lending
terms on loans directly to consumers and indirectly
through finance companies might just make additional
spending attractive or possible for some of the less
dour consumers.
Construction and home-building is, of course, the
area which might be encouraged to provide most of the
offset to any developing weakness in other economic
sectors; and it is an area which has traditionally--and
very recently--been quite responsive to changes in the
financial environment. Recent monetary policy actions
appear to have stopped the deterioration in mortgage
markets, and set in motion forces--such as the renewed
flow of savings funds to nonbank institutions--which
should eventually yield an actual easing of conditions.
This will depend on a continued good experience for
savings and loan associations. But, if a prompter
reversal of present market tightness is desired, it
will depend on further declines in long-term market
interest rates so as to increase the relative attrac
tiveness of mortgages to other financial institutions
such as banks and insurance companies.
It would appear that the easing of lending terms and
conditions that major financial institutions seem to be
approaching could be made more secure, and probably
usefully hastened, if open market operations were conducted
in such a way as to sustain continued bank reserve growth
and to risk a temporarily rather rapid expansion. In
this context, it may be desirable to attain a somewhat

1/10/67

-23-

lower Federal funds rate and a lower level of member
bank borrowings than has prevailed on average in recent
weeks--perhaps even a level of borrowings that would
bring the net reserve position of banks close to zero
and the Federal funds rate to around 5 per cent. If
that were done, it is possible, but by no means certain,
that the resulting expansion of reserves would be
fairly rapid on average. But such an expansion would
be desirable during the turn-around phase of monetary
policy in the degree that it permits a decline of
interest rates, a restoration of bank liquidity, and
some relaxation of bank lending standards ahead of,
rather than merely in reaction to, a reduction in loan
demands.
It is, however, particularly difficult to anticipate
and quantify the interrelations among aggregate reserves,
marginal reserve measures, and interest rates in the
period ahead--given the diversity of economic forecasts
and pressures and the unknown credit market reaction to
tonight's State of the Union message and the forthcoming
Federal budget. It is not difficult to conceive, for
example, of upward bill rate pressures if dealers were
to run from their current extended bill positions. On
the other hand, it is also not difficult to envision
circumstances--such as worsening business news--which
might even make it desirable for open market operations
at some stage to be conducted so as to give more direct
encouragement to the flow of funds in long-term markets
by including significant purchases of intermediate- or
The slackening of the invest
longer-term coupon issues.
ment boom appears to indicate that this winter's burst
of corporate security issues is likely to fade in the
spring; as a result, investor funds might be relatively
quickly channeled to the mortgage market once it became
clear that interest rates on other long-term securities
would be substantially reduced. I put forth the suggestion
for System purchases of coupon issues with some tentative
ness, but as indicative of the kind of flexibility in
approach that monetary policy might wish to keep in
reserve as some of the current uncertainties are resolved.
Mr. Mitchell asked which, if any, of the alternative draft
directives submitted by the staff 1 / Mr. Axilrod thought was
consistent with the policy course he was recommending.
1/

Appended to these minutes as Attachment A.

1/10/67

-24
Mr. Axilrod replied that alternative B could be consistent

with the course he recommended, depending on the interpretation the
Committee placed on the phrase, "somewhat easier conditions in the
money market."
Mr. Brimmer commented that by adopting alternative B the
Committee would not necessarily be implying that it wanted to go
as far as Mr. Axilrod recommended, and the latter agreed.
Mr. Daane referred to Mr. Axilrod's comments about possible
System purchases of coupon issues, and asked whether he thought
that present conditions were parallel to those in the latter part
of 1961 when "operation twist" was begun.
Mr. Axilrod replied that he had not had such a parallel in
mind.

In the 1961 period the U.S. balance of payments was an

important factor in the decision to begin purchases of coupon issues.
While balance of payments considerations might again be relevant
to the question, he had been addressing himself to the fact that
it might be desirable to get a more rapid reversal of conditions
in the mortgage market, and he had thought of open market operations
in coupon issues as a possible means of reducing the typically
long leads and lags in that area.
Mr. Wayne commented that the policy course Mr. Axilrod had
recommended seemed to him to be more closely represented by
alternative C of the draft directives than by alternative B.

-25

1/10/67

Mr. Axilrod remarked that such a policy could be consistent
with either of those alternatives, depending on what interpretations
the Committee placed on their language.

The problem he had seen

with alternative C was that it called for "expansion in bank credit
at a moderate rate," and under the course he recommended the expan
sion rate in the short run probably would be quite rapid.

But

that alternative might be taken as consistent with his policy
recommendation if the Committee interpreted the word "moderate" as
applying to the longer run, and was prepared to tolerate a rapid
short-run expansion as banks acted to improve their liquidity
positions.
Mr. Swan observed that, as he had interpreted the analysis
in the blue book, a shift to somewhat greater ease might well mean
more rapid bank credit expansion over the longer run but at the
same time it might have little effect on the January growth rate.
Mr. Axilrod said his interpretation of the blue book
discussion was that a move toward further ease at this meeting
might result in bank credit expansion on average in January at an
annual rate higher than the 7 - 9 per cent projected under unchanged
money market conditions, as banks seized the opportunity to capture
CD money and to restore their liquidity positions, but that the
growth rate in the following months of the winter would be lower.

-26

1/10/67

Mr. Maisel asked whether the matter might not be clarified
by concentrating on expected future developments rather than on
what had already happened.

As he understood it, much of the expan

sion included in the projection of a 7 - 9 per cent growth rate
on average in January reflected strength in the latter part of
December, rather than expected strength in the weeks ahead.
Mr. Axilrod agreed.

He noted that the blue book projected

a 4 - 6 per cent growth rate between the end of December and the
end of January, and that it implied no strengthening in February.
Mr. Maisel asked whether it was not also expected that
over the period from this meeting to the next bank credit would
grow at a rather low rate.
In reply, Mr. Axilrod said that that would be his guess.
Mr. Reynolds then presented the following statement on the
balance of payments and related matters:
In the fourth quarter of 1966, two new tendencies
appeared in U.S. international transactions. The trade
surplus began to improve. And the capital accounts
began to deteriorate. Both tendencies had been expected,
though perhaps not so soon.
In anticipating these tendencies, all of us have
felt concern about the possibility that the trade im
provement might come more slowly than the capital account
deterioration, so that the over-all position would get
worse before it got better. We have also felt concern
that even over the longer span of a year or more, the
payments position might not show any significant
improvement.
Recent events offer no comfort on either score, but
neither do they add to the gloom. The fact that the

1/10/67
capital account deterioration outweighed the trade
improvement between the third and fourth quarters seems
to have resulted so much from special and erratic
influences that it tells us little that is new about
future prospects.
The only recent changes in capital flows that we
can yet identify relate to U.S. bank credit and to U.S.
liabilities to the Euro-dollar market. The renewed
moderate outflow of bank credit in October-November
probably did not reflect much change in the lending
attitudes of U.S. banks. Instead, it seems likely to
have resulted from more active foreign use of existing
lines of credit, perhaps because of year-end stringencies,
and some bunching of term-loan disbursements without
significant change in the rate of new commitments. One
would expect that large U.S. banks, as their reserve and
liquidity positions ease, would begin to make foreign
loans more readily at about the same time that they ease
their domestic lending. But the October-November out
flows seem to have come too soon to be related to any
such general change.
The leveling off and subsequent decline of U.S.
banks' liabilities to their foreign branches since mid
November is more likely to have reflected the first
effects of reduced tightness in domestic financial markets
But year-end influences play such
and in bank positions.
a large role in these flows that we cannot yet judge
whether the repayments to the Euro-dollar market came
mainly at U.S. initiative or instead reflected mainly
year-end difficulties in attracting wanted funds. Hence
in this case, too, the recent experience provides little
It does seem
guide to the magnitude of future flows.
likely, however, that given the large banks' preoccupation
with their liquidity positions, they will want to make
further repayments to the Euro-dollar market before giving
the green light to their loan officers.
These available data on fourth-quarter capital flows
by no means explain what happened in that quarter. There
must also have been a substantial deterioration on other
items. One can only guess at the possibilities. Direct
investment outflows, having fallen below the expected
yearly average in the third quarter, may have increased in
There may well have been a reversal in the
the fourth.
errors and omissions item, which had turned unusually
favorable in the third quarter, presumably reflecting
unrecorded capital inflows generated by the sterling crisis

1/10/67
and by the extreme tightness of credit here during the

summer. There could also have been some further
deterioration in military and service transactions, but
these transactions as a group do not often show large
quarterly changes.
The improvement in the trade balance from the third
quarter to October-November is a good deal easier to
interpret than the changes on capital account; it probably
represented the beginning of a new trend that will continue
through at least several calendar quarters. Merchandise
imports in October-November were little higher than in the
third quarter. Imports of materials, which account for
about two-fifths of the total, actually declined, even
though within that category steel imports remained at
record highs. Imports of materials tend to fluctuate like
domestic production of materials, but with wider cyclical
amplitude. If GNP develops as projected in the first
half of 1967, with a sharp reduction in the rate of
inventory accumulation and some decline in production of
materials, there is likely to be a substantial decline in
imports of materials.
Imports of capital equipment increased further in
October-November, but they should level off soon if the
domestic projections of a leveling off in business spending
and an easing of capacity pressures are fulfilled. Thus,
even if imports of some consumer goods continue buoyant,
I would not expect total merchandise imports to increase
appreciably in the months ahead.
Exports, meanwhile, should continue to advance. The
pace will probably slow down from the 13 per cent annual
rate registered from the third quarter to October-November.
There were temporary elements in that advance, and there
may be some weakening in Canadian demand for U.S. products.
Demand has also been weakening in Britain and Germany, but
our exports to those countries have already declined and
may not fall much further.
With shipments still rising to most other countries,
the rate of growth in total U.S. exports ought not to fall
below, say, an 8 per cent annual rate over the months
ahead. This rate, with imports level, would raise the
annual rate of trade surplus from about $3-1/2 billion in
the low second half of 1966 to perhaps $5 billion or so
in the first half of 1967.
Since net outflows of capital (excluding foreign
liquid funds) may increase by a roughly offsetting amount

1/10/67

-29-

between these two half-years, the liquidity balance seems
likely to remain above a $2 billion annual rate. In
addition, there will probably be outflows of foreign
liquid funds. So the official settlements deficit also
will probably exceed a $2 billion rate, in marked contrast
to the exceptional surplus registered during the half-year
just ended.
These guesses, as I suggested earlier, are not signifi
cantly different from those of a month ago. What, if
anything, do they imply for monetary policy, when taken
together with domestic prospects?
My answer is the same one that Mr. Hersey gave you
at the last meeting. I can see no way in which monetary
policy actions can improve the near-term payments outlookgloomy though it is--without jeopardizing the longer-term
outlook. If for balance of payments reasons, monetary
policy should seek to minimize capital outflows by denying
an easing that domestic conditions seemed to require,
the resultant further weakening of the domestic economy
would be likely eventually to have adverse repercussions
on activity abroad and hence on U.S. exports. In
particular, if we should hesitate to ease as economic
activity slackens, Britain would have to hesitate also,
and the German authorities too might move more slowly
than seems desirable. These three countries together have
a decisive influence on the world economic climate.
It remains essential, of course, to minimize domestic
inflation of prices and costs, since these are the
touchstone of the longer-run payments adjustment. But
within that constraint, the objective of working toward
long-run equilibrium in international payments is probably
best served at this time by policies aimed at the domestic
objective of sustaining growth.
Chairman Martin then called for the go-around of comments
and views on economic conditions and monetary policy, beginning with
Mr. Treiber, who made the following statement:
As we enter a new year it should be helpful to look
back over the old year and see how successful we have
been as a nation in attaining our broad national economic
goals of: (1) maximum sustainable growth, (2) reasonable
price stability, (3) maximum practicable employment, and
(4) equilibrium in international payments.

1/10/67

-30-

We have done best on the employment goal. Indeed,
there have been many shortages of skilled labor, and even
of unskilled labor in a number of places. Economic growth
was high in 1966 but the high rate was not sustainable.
After several years of relative price stability, 1966 was
marked by upward price pressures, and as the year ended,
further price increases appeared in prospect. A severe
balance-of-payments problem has become even more acute.
The combination of strong private demand and an
additional stimulus from Federal fiscal policy put heavy,
indeed excessive, pressure on our resources of men and
equipment. Not only did the boom bring price increases
at home, but it also contributed to a deterioration of
our international trade surplus. Monetary policy was left
with too much of the burden of fighting inflation. Money
was tighter than it had been in decades.
As the year-end approached, the hectic pace of busi
ness and credit expansion subsided, interest rates declined
from their peaks, and there was some relaxation in the
severe credit pressures of the summer.
How about 1967? Some forecasters see a business slow
down or recession in 1967. Housing is in a slump, the
capital boom is moderating, and consumers appear more
hesitant. But the question is basically whether we are
in a pause, or about to take a definite and cumulative
turn downward. The growth in business spending for fixed
investment and for inventories will doubtless be slower
in 1967. On the other hand, we may expect a revival in
residential construction. In any analysis of the economic
outlook defense spending is a vital factor; indeed it is
now a major factor. Although we will have to wait a week
or so before we see the President's budget message it i,
reasonable to assume that in the coming year there wil1
be a substantial increase in such expenditures over last
year. With continued over-all investment demand and high
Government spending, a continued uptrend in consumer
spending seems likely. It seems to us, on balance, that
in 1967 as a whole an excessive expansion in demand is
a greater danger than recession. In this connection, I
note that the staff's analysis concentrated on the early
part of the year.

Although food prices have declined recently, the
consumer has seen a persistent rise in the prices of
nonfood commodities and especially of services. Labor cost
per unit of output has been rising, and despite the relative
stability of wholesale prices during the last couple of

1/10/67
months, a cost-price push seems likely. The demands of
organized labor are likely to be high, and there are
likely to be greater pressures on corporate profits.
Our balance-of-payments record for 1966 is again
discouraging. The deficit on a liquidity basis is likely
to be well over $1-1/2 billion, compared with $1.3 billion
in 1965.
Had it not been for special transactions which
were more than twice as great in 1966 as in 1965, the 1966
deficit would have exceeded $3 billion. Every effort
should be made to improve our trade balance. A determined
effort to check inflation at home is essential to keep
our exports competitive and to dampen the high demand for
imports. It is difficult to see an improvement in our
international balance of payments in 1967.
Indeed, without
a large amount of special transactions, the deficit on a
liquidity basis is likely to be worse, and it is hard to
foresee such a large amount of special transactions.
The problem of financing the deficit is likely to
become more acute in 1967. On an official settlements
basis we had a surplus of perhaps $1/2 billion in 1966.
But this good showing depended essentially on high
interest rates in the United States which provided foreign
private holders of dollars with an incentive to hold on
to, and to increase, their dollar holdings because of the
good return on them. Thus Euro-dollar lending to American
banks through their foreign branches increased by $2-1/2
billion last year and helped finance the deficit. It is
inconceivable that additional lending of this magnitude
could occur this year. Any substantial decline in interest
rates in the United States relative to rates abroad could
well bring a reversal of these flows. In any case the
implications for our gold stock are ominous.
The resumed advance in bank credit in December and
the projections suggesting a further rise in January are
encouraging. A persistence of the earlier declines in
bank credit would have been incompatible with our goals.
It is worth emphasizing, however, that the loan-deposit
ratios of banks are still very high--much higher than they
were at the beginning of 1966. Many bankers tell us that
they want to improve their liquidity position before they
seek a substantial expansion in loans.
Over the coming months the mix of monetary policy
and fiscal policy will be of particular importance. We
may have to wait, however, for the President's budget
message to learn of the Government's proposed expenditures

1/10/67

-32-

and the way in which the Administration expects them
to be financed. In the meantime, it seems to us, there
should be no change in credit policy. We believe that,
until the next meeting of the Committee, open market
operations should be conducted with a view to maintain
ing about the currently prevailing conditions in the
money market. Under such a policy one might expect the
Federal funds rate to fluctuate above the 5 per cent
level, with rates on three-month Treasury bills near
their present levels.
The range of net borrowed reserves
could be wide, but free reserves should be avoided,
because their appearance would be likely to bolster
market expectations of further monetary ease; these
expectations are already strong, in part because the
rescinding of the System's statement of September 1 on
business loans and discount administration has been
widely interpreted as an overt act emphasizing a System
intent to continue easing pressure on bank reserves.
Since I think that the proper policy prescription
is "no change," I favor alternative A of the draft
directives prepared by the staff. I have difficulty in
trying to comprehend alternative C and its implications
for the conduct of operations. It originally seemed to
me that it raised more issues than it settled, and the
discussion following Mr. Axilrod's remarks confirmed that
view. Even if it means no change, I would prefer to use
language similar to that used in the past to indicate no
change. I think that the meaning of alternative A is
clear. I endorse it.
Mr. Francis observed that growth in total demand for goods
and services had slowed somewhat.

In view of that moderation and

of a restrictive trend in most aggregate measures of monetary
action, the Committee at its last two meetings adopted a less
restrictive course.

Beginning in November the Manager of the

Account had been asked to attain somewhat easier conditions in the
money market with an objective of fostering moderate growth in
money and credit.

Subsequently, lower interest rates, lower net

-33

1/10/67

borrowed reserves, and other indications of ease developed in
the money market.

However, it was not certain that the aggregate

monetary measures had evidenced less restriction.
In the last few weeks, Mr. Francis continued, commercial
banks had obtained more funds and were probably lending or investing
more.

Both time deposits and demand deposits had gone up, and it

appeared that total bank credit had expanded.

However, one hesi

tated to conclude at this point that expansion in those magnitudes
and the evidence of ease resulted primarily from System actions
or that they were having an expansionary effect on economic activity.
The rise in time deposits might merely reflect the facts that, with
declining market interest rates, banks were now able to compete for
CD funds, and that the disintermediation of last fall was now being
reversed without any net gain of funds to borrowers.
The rise in demand deposits and bank reserves in the last
several weeks might also be misleading, Mr. Francis said.

Around

the middle of the final month of each of the last ten quarters, there
had been a marked increase in demand deposits.

Hence, the current

rise might reflect in large measure a problem of seasonal adjustment.
Mr. Francis recalled that Mr. Partee, in his review of recent
financial developments at the last meeting of the Committee, had
noted that despite some easing of money market conditions banking
aggregates had consistently shown shortfalls from projected levels

1/10/67

-34

for some months.

Although increases in reserves and money had been

recorded since mid-December, there was no reason to believe that
the problem of obtaining a moderate amount of monetary growth, which
had been the desire of the Committee, had been solved.
Mr. Francis noted that the staff projected a marked rise in
total reserves from December to January, but those reserves were
expected to be utilized in supporting Government demand deposits
and time deposits, as the reversal of the disintermediation was
expected to continue.

Private demand deposits, according to projec

tions, would decline and money would remain about unchanged.

With

those projections, and with the experience since last summer of
shortfalls in final data from projected levels, special effort
might be required in order to move toward a less restrictive course
including expansion of the money supply.
If the prospects for total demand were as weak as the staff
indicated, Mr. Francis concluded, it behooved the monetary authority
to do all it could to alter that situation.

The Committee should

not be satisfied with "a gradual reduction in the degree of monetary
restraint" mentioned on page 6 of the blue book.

Assuming the

relation among variables which was outlined on page 6 of the blue
book, he suggested the Committee should aim for positive free
reserves, a Federal funds rate below 5 per cent, and a bill rate

1/10/67

-35

about at the discount rate.

It should strive for an upward trend

of the money supply at about a 3 per cent rate.
Mr. Francis thought that alternative B of the staff drafts,
with some alteration, would fit his approach to the situation.
would alter its language to read ". .

He

. System open market operations

until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a
view to attaining such conditions in the money market and such an
increase in total reserves as are necessary to assure a moderate
rise in the money supply. .

."

Mr. Patterson remarked that most of the bankers in the Sixth
District with whom he talked had told him that requests for loans
from their good customers were still greater than they could satisfy
and that they saw no signs of a general letdown in the pressures for
credit.

However, the statistics they reported told a somewhat

different story.
Loans at all member banks had been practically unchanged
for three months after account was taken of seasonal influences,
Mr. Patterson noted.
actually lower.

In some areas of the District loans were

Average interest rates on new business loans charged

by the banks in Atlanta and New Orleans were unchanged between
September and December, after a 38-basis point gain between June and
December and a 30-basis point gain during the spring quarter.

In

December Sixth District member bank borrowing was the lowest since

-36

1/10/67

July 1966, and much less reliance was placed by District banks on
the Federal funds market.

Of the banks included in the Quarterly

Survey of Bank Lending Practices, as of December 15 only a minority
reported loan demand as moderately stronger.

The rest reported

loan demand as essentially unchanged or moderately weaker.
District bankers were inclined to attribute those develop
ments to their having adopted firmer lending practices, Mr. Patterson
said.

They inferred that any slight reduction in requests for loans

at their banks resulted partly from the realization by potential
borrowers that it would be fruitless to apply for a loan.

Some

bankers stressed their desire to get into a more liquid position.
Indeed, there actually was some shifting in the security portfolios
of the large banks in December, and loan-deposit ratios at all
member banks had declined since September.

Moreover, some restriction

in their lending and investment volume had resulted from a less-than
seasonal increase in demand and time deposits at the larger banks
and a downtrend in deposits, on a seasonally adjusted basis, in the
last three months in some areas of the Sixth District.

Some change

in deposit trends, however, was suggested by the statistics for the
large District banks in late December, when time deposits rose
slightly.
On the other hand, Mr. Patterson continued, the behavior
of the latest available economic indicators continued to confirm

-37

1/10/67

the slowing in the District's economic activity that was reported
at previous meetings.

Employment apparently picked up a little

toward the end of the year in contrast to the slackness during the
months of mid-1966, and the unemployment rate in November fell to
3.5 per cent, the lowest since May.

However, the District was

sharing in the slower pace of auto sales and in the auto production
cutbacks.

Weakness persisted in some types of construction, and

the tabulation of announcements of proposed new or expanded manufac
turing plants for the fourth quarter promised a slower rate of
capital expenditures in the future.
Mr. Patterson thought a reasonable conclusion that could
be drawn from that mixed collection of information seemed to be
something like the following:

There was a strong demand for loans,

although some potential borrowers were being excluded because of
high interest rates and bank lending policies.

The slackening in

loan expansion resulted from both a slowdown in demand, reflecting
a slower rate of economic expansion, and the efforts of banks to
get into more liquid positions.

Since many bankers were uneasy

about their declining liquidity, they seemed to be welcoming any
respite, no matter how small.
So far as he could determine, Mr. Patterson said, much the
same conclusion could be reached in respect to the national scene.
That meant that member banks now were likely to be less responsive

1/10/67

-38

to increased availability of reserves in expanding their loans and
investments than they would have been early last year.

Thus,

insofar as net borrowed reserves or free reserves reflected reserve
availability, a net borrowed reserve figure of, say, $100 million
was much less stimulative now than it would have been at this time
last year or during a considerable part of 1966.

That might explain

why, despite the turn toward greater ease initiated several meetings
ago by the Committee, the declining trend in the bank credit proxy
had not been reversed until very recently.
In order to be sure that the recent rise in the bank credit
proxy did not prove to be temporary, therefore, Mr. Patterson
favored continuing to move gently toward greater ease.

Currently,

the net borrowed reserve figure was especially suspect as a guide
to reserve availability.

But if that figure was to be used, he would

favor moving toward a zero position.

With that understanding, he

would favor alternative C of the draft directives.
Mr. Hilkert remarked that indicators for the real sector of
the economy seemed to him increasingly to be pointing to a lessening
of demand pressures.

Conditions in the Third District continued to

be generally good, as they were in the nation.
of softening were appearing in the District.

However, indications

Manufacturing employ

ment was off a little, and steel production had been declining, as
had construction contract awards and auto registrations.

1/10/67

-39
On the national scene, Mr. Hilkert found it difficult to

discover any new sources of significant strength.
and attitudes seemed relatively lethargic.

Consumer demands

Although there might be

some point to the fact that construction could hardly go much lower,
that did not stir hope for new strength.

But most of all, he was

disturbed--as apparently was the Board's staff--by the recent move
ment of new orders, backlogs, and inventories.

The latter pointed

quite clearly to involuntary accumulation.
To Mr. Hilkert, the resulting projection by the staff of a
substantial cutback in the rate of gain in GNP during the first
quarter was significant.

Forecasts appearing daily in the press

did not now generally support the view that a recession was ahead.
But if the staff's projection for the first quarter proved correct,
forecasts might soon become much more bearish.
Other things being equal, facts like those argued for another
move toward ease, Mr. Hilkert said.
about the increase
this year.

He was, of course, concerned

in wages now taking place and likely to continue

Credit ease should not proceed so fast and so far as

to aggravate that development.

Yet, it seemed to him there was

little that monetary policy could do now to halt the trend, let
alone roll it back.
In the financial sector of the economy, Mr. Hilkert noted,
substantial and rapid easing in money market conditions had taken

-40

1/10/67
place.

As pointed out in the blue book, bank credit and the money

supply now seemed to be responding.
not been overdone.

In his view, that

Information coming

Bank from the larger banks

easing had

to the Philadelphia Reserve

in the District indicated that they were

not yet anxious to seek more customers, had not changed
ing policies, and were concerned about

their liquidity.

their lend
Rescinding

the September 1 letter had had relatively little effect on their
attitudes.
Another signal of the Federal Reserve's

intent to ease,

therefore, seemed to Mr. Hilkert to be called for if those attitudes
were to be changed.

On balance, he believed alternative B would be

appropriate in accomplishing the desired purposes.

Although he

would think of the implementation of the directive as being accom
plished somewhat gradually, the changes contemplated by alternative B
should be sufficient to impress

the market and banks that a further

change was being made.
The balance of payments

implications of further ease did,

of course, concern him, Mr. Hilkert said.

However, he looked for

further improvement in the trade account as domestic expansion
slackened.

And, hopefully, easier credit conditions abroad might

make it possible for the Committee to proceed toward easier
conditions domestically without adverse effect.

1/10/67

-41
Mr. Hickman commented that recent economic news revealed

further moderation in some sectors and increased weakness in
others.

Notable developments in December were the increase in

insured unemployment (reflecting mainly the cutbacks in autos and
steel), the disappointing performance of retail sales, and the
further (probably involuntary) buildup in business inventories.
The industrial production index, on the basis of very preliminary
estimates made at his Bank, showed little, if any, increase in
December.
At the last quarterly meeting of Fourth District business
economists in mid-December, Mr. Hickman continued, the general
theme was one of increased anxiety about the economic outlook,
which was reflected in a lowering of the group's forecasts--the
third successive time that that had occurred.

The group was con

cerned about the hazy outlook for defense spending, the tapering
of capital spending, the profit squeeze, the erosion of new orders
and backlogs, and general imbalances among major economic sectors.
Their median forecast for GNP in 1967 in current dollars was $783
billion, a year-to-year gain of 6 per cent, with moderate and
diminishing quarterly increases.

That implied a modest increase

in real GNP, something on the order of 3 per cent.

Median forecasts

for industrial production showed fractional quarterly increases,
with the annual gain in 1967 amounting only to 3 per cent.

1/10/67

-42
Mr. Hickman noted that the Fourth District business

economists expected appreciable increases in unit labor costs
in manufacturing in each quarter of 1967, with the average of
the medians for the year up 2.5 per cent.

The group expected

corporate profits after taxes to remain level in the first half
and to decline in the second half, with a year-to-year decline
of about 1-1/2 per cent.

Only about one-fourth of the group

expected that taxes would be increased in 1967, and almost all
thought that a tax increase was undesirable.

Since he was no

longer a dues-paying member in the union of business economists,
he was not allowed to vote.

If he could have voted, he would

have been one of those voting against a tax increase at this time,
largely for domestic economic reasons, but partly also because of
glimmerings of hope that tensions were easing in Vietnam.
In regard to monetary policy, Mr. Hickman was pleased to
note the substantial increase in both the money supply and the
bank credit proxy that occurred in December.

He would like to

think that that reflected the economy's prompt response to the
Committee's recent modest shift in policy, although the usual
seasonal churning in December made it quite difficult to determine
if that actually was the case.

The staff's projection of no change

in the money supply for January suggested to him some further eas
ing was still needed.

1/10/67

-43
Mr. Hickman's prescription for policy until the next meeting

was to provide whatever reserves were needed to produce an increase
in the money supply in the range of 3 to 6 per cent (seasonally
adjusted annual rate), as well as to bring about some further modest
reduction in interest rates.

To achieve those objectives, he thought

the Committee should not be constrained by the public's reaction to
the published figures on the net reserve position of banks, and
should permit positive free reserves to develop, if necessary.

In

view of the imminence of the Treasury refunding, he would prefer to
move promptly in the direction of further ease.

The recent reduction

in the German bank rate from 5 to 4-1/2 per cent provided some basis
for hope that a further modest reduction in interest rates in the
U.S. would not trigger a flight of hot money from this country.

He

favored alternative B of the draft directives, and would be receptive
to System purchase of intermediate- and long-term issues.
Mr. Brimmer said that the direction in which the Committee
should move in the next few weeks seemed reasonably clear to him.
He agreed with Mr. Reynolds' conclusion that the objective of long
run improvement in the balance of payments would be served best by
policies that sustained domestic growth, and he thought the Committee
was fortunate in having so smooth a meshing of policy requirements
for the balance of payments and the domestic economy.

-44

1/10/67

As he looked back at financial developments in the past few
weeks, Mr. Brimmer continued, he was impressed with the strength of
the markets and the magnitude of the change in expectations follow
ing the Committee's shift toward less restraint.

He thought it was

now incumbent upon the Committee to validate the present expectations.
As some observers had noted, there had been a large reaction to a
relatively moderate change in open market policy and the rescission
of the September 1 letter.

He thought the Committee should now do

much more to insure that the money supply and bank credit would
expand at rates approaching those that members had suggested were
desirable at recent meetings.

He was impressed by the degree of

inertia existing in the banking system but he was not surprised by
it, given the desire of banks to restore their liquidity positions.
Nevertheless, low bank liquidity did impede the Committee's efforts
to affect the economy through changes in money market conditions.

It

was important that bank loan expansion not rest simply on increases
in loans to security dealers; it should also reflect rising loans to
business.
Mr. Brimmer said he had been particularly impressed with the
policy course Mr. Axilrod had suggested, and he thought that by the
time of its next meeting the Committee might want to give serious
consideration to that proposal for a more overt change.

For the

time being, however, in view of the uncertainties regarding the

1/10/67

-45

Administration's tax and expenditure recommendations, he thought
the proper course for the Committee was to proceed along the path
it had been following recently.

of the draft directives.

That led him to favor alternative B

At the same time, he would not want to have

the level of interest rates taken as the sole key to the operations
of the Desk.

He would not be disturbed if the three-month bill rate

declined to the neighborhood of 4-1/2 per cent.

Nor would he be

disturbed very much if net borrowed reserves approached the zero
level or even if free reserves emerged.

But it should not be the

main objective of the Manager to produce those results; the main
objective should be to achieve increases in bank credit and the
money supply.
In the preceding discussion, Mr. Brimmer continued, a
question had been implied as to whether the period with which the
Committee was most properly concerned was the first half of 1967
or the whole year.

He thought it was appropriate for the Committee

to do all that it could to insure that economic conditions in the
first half did not deteriorate to the point that the second-half
conditions would be much weaker.

In his judgment, unless there was

sufficient easing of terms in mortgage markets, the economy was not
likely to display strength in the second half.
In sum, Mr. Brimmer concluded, he favored alternative B
today, and he hoped that by the time of the next meeting the

1/10/67

-46

Committee would be in a better position to decide whether the course
suggested by Mr. Axilroad was appropriate.

Mr. Maisel agreed with the staff analysis of the current
situation.

It seemed to him, therefore, that the Committee had to

make clear its current goal--namely, a monetary policy that over
the course of this year would help in increasing, rather than decreas
ing, total demand in the economy.
Given that ultimate goal, Mr. Maisel said, what influence
could monetary policy have?

Either through increased credit avail

ability or through lower interest rates, monetary policy might
influence those making spending decisions to add somewhat to their
expenditures.

More specifically, liquidity could be rebuilt, credit

availability might rise so that easier mortgage terms might aid
housing and that, plus some direct impact through instalment credit,
might add an incremental amount to expenditures on consumer durables.
There might also be marginal credit users who had been forced to run
with lower inventories than they desired and with less investment
in plant and equipment, but the impacts in those areas would probably
not be great.
Given that basic role for monetary policy, Mr. Maisel asked,
what sort of intermediate policy index could the Committee use in
directing its action for the next two or three months?

The

Committee's main indexes could, as indicated in the alternative

1/10/67

-47

draft directives, be concerned primarily with either quantities
or rates.

The Committee could use the total increase in the amount

of credit flows, or, since it had only slight current knowledge
of total credit flows, it could use as a proxy either bank credit
expansion or reserves furnished by the Federal Reserve--adjusting
the amount aimed at for either proxy with time, if the proxy seemed
to vary from the total credit movement desired.

On the other hand,

obviously the Committee could also set an interest rate goal on
the assumption that it would require particular changes in the
interest rate to bring about the desired over-all goal for spending
in the economy.
It seemed to Mr. Maisel that, at the moment, the Committee
would be better off if it chose as its major policy variable changes
in credit and reserves, using interest rates as a subsidiary guide.
In the first place, Mr. Maisel feared that by adopting
interest rates or money market conditions alone, the Committee was
likely to pay too much attention to most recent events.

As the

green book showed, in many money market areas rates still were
running 100 basis points or more over November 1965.

Even while

others had come down sharply, a large gap still remained.

At the

same time, the Committee was uncertain as to whether it was the
level of rates or their change that would make the critical differ
ences in reaching any desired spending goal.

1/10/67

-48
During a period of rapid change, Mr. Maisel also feared

the Committee was too likely to be bemused by the rate of change
rather than by the actual level of interest rates.

That was partic

ularly true since the real demand for credit during this period was
uncertain and little was known as to how much it could be expected
to affect spending.

There might be strong pressures to accommodate

some of the backlog which had been postponed from recent periods
in order simply to improve liquidity without any spending impact.
In addition, if a major inventory run-off actually occurred, demand
for funds might fall far below normal.

In either case interest

rates would not be an adequate guide of the Federal Reserve's
actions or influence.

They would represent a mixture of special

supply and demand factors and would not mirror the total impact.
Clearly, Mr. Maisel continued, the same argument might be
made against using the amount of credit as an index, but here the
problems were likely to be less strong.

The Committee knew that

the economy had been through a period in which credit had expanded
far less than normal.

It should be simpler to get agreement for

credit expansion to return to a normal rate.

When such an expansion

was achieved, it could then be determined whether that normal
expansion was sufficient in terms of related interest rates, credit
expansion, and liquidity to achieve the Committee's ultimate goal.

1/10/67

-49
With respect to the draft directives, Mr. Maisel said,

obviously he preferred the third alternative--C.

He assumed that

by "moderate" the Committee would, following the dictionary defini
tion, mean avoiding extremes.

Therefore, the directive should mean

that the Committee was aiming at a normal or adequate movement in
total deposits to achieve its goal.

It seemed clear the Committee's

goal should be a bank credit proxy that grew at about a 7 per cent
annual rate.

The blue book projection for the next four weeks showed

required reserves expanding at far less than a normal rate and one
not sufficient to achieve a desirable rate of expansion in total
credit.

Thus, to achieve the moderate expansion in bank credit

called for in the directive, conditions would be needed under which
required reserves would expand at a more rapid rate than that pro
jected in the blue book.

That should be the index for action used

during the next four weeks.

Reserves should be added unless or

until required reserves were showing a far smaller run-off than
indicated in the blue book.

Positive free reserves might well be

needed to achieve that aim and, as indicated by Mr. Axilrod, a
considerably lower Federal funds rate.

If the Committee was getting

that expansion it should, as indicated in alternative C's proviso
clause, be less concerned with rates.
Mr. Daane said that the course of System policy in recent
weeks seemed to him to have been clearly appropriate as to direction.

1/10/67

-50

His position at the last two meetings had reflected reservations
regarding the overtness of the change and the degree of ease the
Committee sought as it moved down the road toward greater ease.
Those reservations, in turn, reflected confidence in the underlying
strength of the economy, his skepticism as to whether public spend
ing might not exceed current estimates in a period of war, and his
concern about the balance of payments.

Those considerations had

led him to feel more cautious than the majority regarding the
aggressiveness with which the Committee should move toward ease.
Today, Mr. Daane continued, he still felt concern about the
balance of payments--he shared Mr. Treiber's views on possible
deterioration on capital account--and he was no more assured than
he had been earlier as to the course of public spending.

He was

impressed, however, by the increasing signs of deceleration in the
private economy, and he thought it was necessary for the Committee
to continue to move--and to demonstrate that it was moving--toward
somewhat greater ease.

Accordingly, he favored alternative B, in

the moderate sense in which he would interpret it.

He had some

sympathy with the view that later in 1967 the Committee might again
be confronted with a need to restrain the economy, but it seemed
to him that the immediate problem was the reverse.
Mr. Daane added that he was not so sanguine as the staff,
or Mr. Brimmer, that longer-run strength in the domestic economy

1/10/67

-51

and in the world economy would insure against a rather rapid
deterioration in the balance of payments in 1967, whether on the
liquidity basis or the official settlements basis.

That was why he

would interpret alternative B as calling for a gradual and moderate
movement.

Operationally, he thought there was some parallel between

the current situation and that of early 1961 and thus he would favor
some System purchases in the coupon area.

Such purchases seemed

desirable not only on the domestic grounds that Mr. Axilrod had
mentioned but also for balance of payments reasons.

He did not think

the Committee could take great comfort in the 1/2 per cent reduction
in the German discount rate in terms of the totality of international
flows.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that while several people had talked
about the longer-run problem for monetary policy he thought the
basic problem lay in the short run, because the lags in transmitting
the effects of policy changes through commercial banks to the economy
at large were rather substantial.

The Committee's task was to

satisfy the banks' desire to rebuild liquidity so that they would
reverse the loan policies they had been following--and to do so on
a cautious basis, so that if there were a bounce-back in loan growth
it would not get out of hand.

The economic analysis presented

today suggested that there would not be such a bounce-back.

From

-52

1/10/67

his conversations with bankers, however, he gathered that they
thought underlying loan demands remained strong, and that if they
turned their loan officers loose the volume would build up fast.
He did not think that the bankers were completely confident in
their view, and he personally did not know the answer.

But he

thought that any policy the Committee adopted for the next four
weeks should have an element of caution in it.
As to the directive, Mr. Mitchell said, he had some sympathy
with the modification Mr. Francis had proposed in alternative B,
which introduced a reference to the money supply.

He noted that

Mr. Axilrod had said that the money supply was not likely to show
sustained growth, although he (Mr. Mitchell) was not persuaded that
that was the case.
Mr. Axilrod commented that the money supply projection was
based on an assumption of no change in money market conditions.
Mr. Mitchell went on to say that while he could accept
alternative B as written, he would prefer to delete the word "some
what," and to replace the words "significantly faster" with "very much
faster," so that the paragraph would read, ". . . with a view to
attaining easier conditions in the money market, unless bank credit
appears to be expanding very much faster than currently anticipated."
He also could accept alternative C if the final clause was deleted.
Whatever the language, however, he favored continuing the trend of

1/10/67

-53

deliberate and steady easing, but with a readiness to pull back
if and when the liquidity barrier was broken and bank credit
growth became excessive.
Mr. Shepardson said there was no need to elaborate on the
reports of economic conditions that had been made.

He thought

the main consideration influencing the Committee's decision on
monetary policy for the period until the next meeting was the contin
uing uncertainty regarding fiscal policy.

There had been some

expansion in bank credit recently and the projections made on the
assumption of no change in money market conditions--as contemplated
in alternative A of the draft directives--were for further bank
credit expansion on average in January at a 7 to 9 per cent annual
rate.

That seemed to him to be an appropriate growth rate at this

time.

In his judgment the Committee had to be concerned about the

more serious implications presently evident for balance of payments
developments.

That fact, together with the uncertainty about

fiscal policy, clearly called for the type of action contemplated
under alternative A.

The projections indicated that there might

be no change in the money supply if that alternative was adopted.
It seemed to him, however, that experience indicated that the money
supply tended to fluctuate widely in the short run regardless of
the Committee's policy objectives.

Accordingly, he felt that the

Committee should not be overly concerned about the expected lack

1/10/67

-54

of money supply growth at the moment, as long as there was reason
able growth in bank credit.
Mr. Wayne reported that business activity showed more signs
of slowing and that expectations were definitely less optimistic
in the Fifth District.

In November both nonfarm employment and

man-hours in manufacturing scored gains, but more recent information
was quite uniformly on the weak side.

On balance, manufacturers

in all categories reported for December lower levels of shipments,
new orders, and backlogs, and significantly higher inventories of
finished goods.

The insured unemployment rate rose throughout the

District but remained below the level of a year ago.

It appeared

that a slump in demand might have caused a postponement or cancel
lation of price increases which had been expected in the furniture
industry.
In the country as a whole, Mr. Wayne said, a gradual slowing
of economic activity was becoming increasingly apparent.

He had to

confess that he was impressed with the pervasive downward movement
of the statistical indicators.

The rise in housing starts in

November was about the only increase which had been reported in
recent weeks.

Even if that should signal a bottoming out of the

housing cycle, it would still be several months before housing became
a source of strength.

Sales of United States automobiles in both

domestic and foreign markets continued weak and production schedules

-55

1/10/67

were being cut back to trim new car inventories, which totaled
well over 1.4 million units.

Inventory accumulation by manufac

turers accelerated in November, inventory-sales ratios continued
to rise, and increases in finished stocks suggested that some of
the recent accumulation might have been involuntary.

Easing of

materials prices and slower growth of order backlogs in recent
months would probably reduce voluntary accumulation.
To Mr. Wayne, those widespread signs of moderation in the
pace of economic advance were hopefully the signs of adjustment
toward a noninflationary rate of economic growth and not the signs
of emerging recession.

Much depended on the degree of fiscal stimu

lation which the economy received in the weeks and months ahead.
But the level of expenditures associated with the war effort and
the question of a tax increase remained the principal uncertainties
on the economic scene.

While recent figures indicated a leveling

off in military contract awards and defense orders, those series
might provide only a hazy indication of future expenditures.
Despite the uncertainties surrounding the degree of fiscal
stimulation in coming months, it seemed to Mr. Wayne that in view
of increasing signs of weakness in the private sector and absence
of growth in important financial variables in the second half of
last year, monetary policy should continue to promote the moderate
growth in the money supply, bank credit, and time deposits indicated
by the preliminary figures for December.

He would not like to see

-56

1/10/67

a rapid acceleration in the growth of those variables, but neither
would he like to see the plus signs of December washed out by
negative signs in January.

Encouraged by the behavior of interest

rates and marginal reserve measures and by the rescission of the
September 1 letter, banks were perhaps becoming somewhat more willing
lenders, a welcome response in view of recent slow growth in bank
credit.

While recognizing that in conducting day-to-day operations

the Desk found it difficult to focus on aggregative measures, he
believed the objective should be to encourage growth in required
reserves and the bank credit proxy at something close to the
December rate.
Alternative B of the staff draft directives, as defined by
Mr. Axilrod, seemed to Mr. Wayne appropriate.
Mr. Clay commented that in recent weeks monetary policy
implementation generally had attained the financial variables goals
sought by the Committee.

In view of the economic information that

had become available, those monetary policy goals and attainments
had been appropriate to the prevailing economic situation.
Mr. Clay said that the timing of this morning's meeting relative
to the President's message and other Administration messages to follow
placed the Committee under a handicap in formulating monetary policy
for the next four weeks.

Nevertheless, the information available

concerning the prospective economic situation appeared to justify a
continuation of the policy currently prevailing.

More specifically,

1/10/67

-57

it appeared desirable that sufficient reserves be provided so that
bank credit could continue to expand.
mean that loan volume would expand.

That would not necessarily
Conversations with bankers

confirmed that current loan behavior was only partially explained
by lessened loan demand and limited availability of funds.

Bankers

were reluctant to relax their own credit restraints in a desire to
improve their banks' liquidity positions.
Mr. Clay thought it was by no means clear what targets should
be set in endeavoring to continue the recent improvement in the
financial aggregates.

One could begin by accepting the projections

of financial aggregates in the blue book, as developed from page 3
to the middle of page 6,1/ and the money market conditions specified

1/ This section of the blue book read in part as follows:
"Bank credit expansion is likely to continue in January, but at
a slower pace than indicated by the large recent week-to-week
increases. The increase in the January average of outstanding
bank credit over the December average may be in a 7 - 9 per cent
(annual rate) range, but this includes the carry-over effect on
the monthly averages of the strength in the latter part of
December. From the end of December through the end of January,
a growth rate in the 4 - 6 per cent range appears likely . . . .
The interest rate and credit demand assumptions appear consistent
with expansion of time and savings deposits at all commercial banks
by about 12 per cent in January on a monthly average basis . .
Money supply in January is expected to show little or no net change
on average. Private demand deposits may decline somewhat, partly
because of a projected rise of almost $1 billion in U.S. Government
deposits. But private demand deposits are not assumed to decline
by as much as Government deposits rise

. .

. .

These deposit pro

jections imply a sizable expansion in aggregate reserves in January
on average--in the order of 10 - 12 per cent for nonborrowed and
total reserves. For December-January together, nonborrowed
reserves may show an increase around the 5 - 7 per cent range."

1/10/67

-58-

at the top of page 4 1/ of the blue book.

If those projections

of financial aggregates did not generally materialize, it should
be understood that instructions to the Manager would call for a
modification of the money market targets such as those suggested
on page 6 of the blue book.

2/

Alternative A of the draft economic policy directive, as
defined in the accompanying staff notes,3/ appeared to Mr. Clay
to be appropriate for the period ahead.
Mr. Scanlon commented that economic developments in the
Seventh Federal Reserve District in recent weeks had presented no
surprises.

There were indications that excessive pressures on

productive resources had eased further.

Unemployment compensation

1/ This material read as follows: "These projections
assume that the 3-month bill rate stays roughly within the
recent 4.75 - 4.85 per cent range over the period ahead,
that net borrowed reserves fluctuate around $100 million,
and that Federal funds and dealer loan rates back down some
what from recent high levels of around year-end."
"If the Committee
2/
This material read as follows:
wishes to continue a gradual reduction in the degree of
monetary restraint, it might call for open market operations
to achieve a set of money market conditions that might include
a net borrowed reserve position averaging close to zero and
Federal funds averaging near 5 per cent. This would, in all
likelihood, bring the 3-month bill rate down to a 4.60 - 4.75
per cent range."
3/ The staff notes suggested using the complex of money
market conditions cited in note 1/ as a description of the
general kinds of conditions to be maintained if alternative A
were to be adopted by the Committee.

1/10/67

-59

claims in December were somewhat higher in each of the District
States than in December 1965, but were still at very low levels.
The increases had been particularly evident in automobile manufac
turing centers.

Also, the rise in help-wanted advertisements in

major newspapers, while increasing somewhat further, had not
maintained the spectacularly large increases of earlier months.
Price increases continued to be announced in a variety of
goods and services, Mr. Scanlon noted, notwithstanding the evidence
of better balance in the over-all supply-demand situation.

The

demand for construction equipment had weakened further and major
firms in that industry did not see an early end to that development.
In conversations with businessmen, Mr. Scanlon said, he
detected a greater sensitivity to the possibility of their finding
themselves with excessively large inventories.
had reported plans to reduce inventories.

A number of firms

That had been noted

especially in steel-using firms, even though there had been some
evidence recently of strengthening demand for steel.

But thus far,

the transition to a more balanced supply-demand situation had been
orderly and had not engendered excessive pessimism.
On the banking scene, Mr. Scanlon remarked, District banks
shared in the rather sharp increase in credit during December.
Loan expansion reflected mainly the temporary needs of securities
dealers and finance companies.

Increases in business and consumer

-60

1/10/67

loans were relatively small compared with other recent Decembers.
The recent growth in deposits which had accompanied the easier
money market had made it possible for the large banks to acquire
some Governments as well as to make additional money market loans,
and the largest banks had shown a significant reduction in their
loan ratios since early December.

Some rebuilding of liquidity

was to be expected, and banks as well as dealers might find many
Governments and municipals attractively priced, given the expecta
tion of further declines in interest rates in the period ahead.
Mr. Scanlon reported that large District banks had acquired
more than $150 million through net sales of negotiable CD's since
mid-December, and had shown substantial gains through savings-type
certificates following their recent boost in rates offered on
those instruments.

While they had attracted some new money, large

banks in Chicago estimated that about three-fourths of the gain
in CD's under $100,000 denomination resulted from the transfer of
other deposits in the bank.

Current rate relationships appeared

conducive to continued growth in deposits and credit.
As to policy, while Mr. Scanlon would not be satisfied with
the large magnitude of the increase in bank credit and reserves pro
jected for January if there were reason to expect it to continue,
he was happy to see them both on the plus side again.

Even after

the sizable increase projected for January, total reserves would

1/10/67

-61

still be below the levels of last September.

In view of the signs

of hesitancy in the private sector of the economy, he thought it
desirable to continue the upward momentum in total reserves,
possibly over the longer range at a somewhat slower rate than pro

jected for January, but hopefully at a sustained rate.
Mr. Scanlon said that his views on policy closely paralleled
those of Mr. Mitchell.

While he could accept alternative B of the

draft directives in light of Mr. Axilrod's explanation, he favored
alternative C since it provided for a wider range of fluctuation
in money market conditions if that proved to be a necessary conse
quence of operations directed at maintaining the desired rates of
growth in monetary aggregates.

He believed that the Committee

could stabilize either aggregate reserve measures or money market
conditions, but that it probably could not stabilize both concurrently.
Mr. Galusha reported that the indices of economic activity
in the Ninth District confirmed the District's historic lagging
role, for most of those measures reflected a considerable momentum.
Recent personal interviews indicated a developing pessimism, however.
In the Ninth District, no less than in the nation, the
situation of banks eased appreciably during December, Mr. Galusha
said.

Total deposits of District banks increased more than

seasonally; for weekly reporting banks, the rise in total loans and

-62

1/10/67

investments was double the usual seasonal increase.

The December

drop in the average loan-deposit ratio was very sharp at weekly
reporting banks, and those banks ended 1966 with a lower average
ratio than they had at the end of 1965.

The largest Ninth District

banks were able to increase the average maturity of their CD's
somewhat.

And, finally, he might mention that among Twin Cities

bankers speculation had turned to when a reduction in the prime rate
would come.
In a way, Mr. Galusha observed, all that was gratifying.
Banking developments, both in his District and in the nation, could
be interpreted as showing that Committee policy was having the
desired effect.

But the Committee was perhaps some way still from

getting the supply-side loan response that appeared to be needed.
That suggested that pressing further--continuing the trend to lower
market interest rates--would be appropriate.

In that regard, it was

of considerable importance that the Bundesbank had been so obliging.
Possibly now the Bank of England would follow the Bundesbank's lead.
For himself, then, Mr. Galusha favored a slight--and he
would emphasize the word slight--further reduction in market interest
rates at this time.

He recognized, though, that there was something

to be said for pausing now--for holding to the status quo at least
briefly--although with a Treasury financing to be announced late in
January, that hold could be too lengthy.

-63

1/10/67

But one thing was clear, Mr. Galusha said.

The Committee

could not afford a return of market rates to previous, higher levels.
According to the blue book, the recent welcome decline in the bill
rate was in considerable measure the result of expectations.

But

from tonight on, and for the next few weeks, expectations could
prove quite volatile.

And the Committee should not, he believed,

allow any change in expectations to result in higher interest rates.
It could be that, to maintain the present structure of rates, the
level of net borrowed reserves would have to be reduced somewhatpossibly to between zero and $100 million.
Without knowing what the President was going to say tonight
and in messages to come, Mr. Galusha continued, it was not easy to
talk of policy targets.

But perhaps it was enough for the Committee

to agree that, at the very least, the Manager should be given all
the latitude possible to resist fully any trend to higher interest
rates stemming possibly from disappointments about announced fiscal
policies.

Either alternative B or C of the draft directives appeared

appropriate.
In concluding, Mr. Galusha said he might replow an old furrow
and urge again that further thought be given to structural reform of
reserve requirements and, more particularly, to lower requirements
for small banks.

At the moment he was at least as concerned with the

1/10/67

-64

System's image in Sleepy Eye as in Zurich.

Lest that appear exces

sively parochial, it might have further usefulness for the System
because--depending upon what the Administration decided about taxesthe Committee might want some way of dramatizing a switch to still
greater monetary ease and, unfortunately, a reduction in discount
rates would seem out of the question at present.
Mr. Swan said that in December business loans of Twelfth
District weekly reporting banks again rose considerably more than
in the rest of the country, as they had in November, although the
increase was somewhat less than in the same month last year.

Also

continuing in December was a greater than national increase in total
time and savings deposits at commercial banks, as large negotiable
CD's outstanding increased somewhat more than elsewhere.

Some

indications were appearing that the larger banks were reluctant to
go beyond six months' maturity in their large CD's.

Although most

banks still indicated that the matter was subject to negotiation,
one bank had adopted a definite policy of not going beyond six months.
Also, one bank had announced a reduction in maximum rate, from 5-1/2
to 5-1/4 per cent, on long maturity CD's.
There were strong indications in the latest survey, Mr. Swan
continued, that in both the District and the nation the lending
practices of most banks were unchanged from three months earlier.
Four of the 17 reporting banks in the District indicated that loan

-65

1/10/67

demands had weakened in the past three months, but none reported
that they expected demands to be weaker in the first quarter of
1967.

Similarly, their willingness to make loans remained essen

tially unchanged.

The only cases of increased willingness to lend

involved two banks, which expressed that attitude with respect to
consumer instalment loans.

At the other extreme, eight of the 17

District banks indicated reduced willingness to make mortgage loans
on multifamily structures.

Those findings suggested to him there

was still some question of the availability of supply to be worked
out before much reaction could be expected in the lending policies
of banks.

Like Mr. Mitchell, he was somewhat concerned about

banks' attitudes regarding the strength of underlying loan demands.
As to monetary policy, Mr. Swan said, it seemed to him that
the relatively gloomy cast of both the green book analysis and the
discussion today suggested that the Committee perhaps should move
somewhat further in the direction of ease.

However, he did not

believe that the evidence was sufficiently clear to justify a marked
move at this juncture.

In view of the balance of payments situation,

the still relatively tight labor market, the fact that the Adminis
tration would be announcing its current economic policy views before
the Committee's next meeting, and the fact that a Treasury financing,
even though not a major one, lay ahead, he would prefer to see a
rather gradual change over the next two weeks, rather than a more

1/10/67

-66

abrupt move that might lead to various kinds of undesired market
interpretations.

He would certainly like to see some increase in

bank credit, and also in the money supply.

He favored alternative

B, but because he would interpret "somewhat easier conditions"
rather conservatively, he was not sure that he advocated the same
specific targets as others who also favored that alternative.

He

would hope to see the bill rate around 4-3/4 per cent, the Federal
funds rate around 5 per cent, and marginal reserves ranging from
$100 million net borrowed reserves to zero, but not becoming positive.
He agreed with Mr. Brimmer that if much easier money market conditions
developed and interest rates moved down further the Desk should not
try to offset those changes, but that such conditions should not be
actively sought.

He also saw no objections to operations in the

longer term area on a fairly small scale.
Mr. Swan noted that some sentiment had been expressed in
favor of adopting alternative C, which called for fostering moderate
bank credit expansion, for the second paragraph of the directive.
The second paragraph specified the Committee's immediate goal, and
he thought that it should be formulated in terms of conditions in
the money market, as in alternative B.

However, he would suggest

including a reference to the objective of accommodating bank credit
expansion since it had been the Committee's practice during most of
last year to refer to bank credit in the concluding "policy" sentence

1/10/67

-67

of the first paragraph.

The third sentence of the staff's draft

of the first paragraph noted that "bank credit expansion has resumed";
the last sentence of that paragraph might be revised to say that
it was the Committee's policy to foster money and credit conditions,
"including bank credit expansion", conducive to noninflationary
economic expansion.
In a final comment on the first paragraph, Mr. Swan said
he appreciated the staff's suggestion that the language of the
balance of payments reference should be changed even though no
change in

substance was proposed,

in order--as the notes attached

to the draft said--to indicate that the payments balance was receiv
ing the continuing attention of the Committee.

But the new language

the staff proposed, by referring to "trends in international trans
actions", seemed to imply a more basic change in the situation than
in fact there had been.

Accordingly, he would suggest continuing

the reference used in the previous directive.
Mr. Irons reported that economic conditions were generally
strong in the Eleventh District.

At the same time there were the

cross-currents and the indications of slowing rates of growth that
were evident in the national economy.

Slackening in autos,

construction, and other areas was partially offset by the generally
high level of activity prevailing.

Employment was up in virtually

1/10/67

-68

all categories, and the unemployment rate was low--about 2 per
cent.

There were signs that labor market pressures might have

lessened somewhat, but not significantly.
District also was up.

Production in the

On the other hand, department store sales

had not been as favorable as had been hoped.

Construction activ

ity was a little lower than might have been expected, but the
difference was not of large magnitude.

Sales of automobiles had

been relatively favorable; in December they were within 1 per cent
of the year-ago volume.
As to District financial conditions, Mr. Irons continued,
there were increases in the past month in commercial and industrial
loans, demand deposits, and both total time deposits and CD's.
The reserve positions of District banks were somewhat less strained
than earlier.

Banks still were borrowing through the Federal funds

market but in smaller volume.

Borrowings from the Reserve Bank for

window-dressing purposes normally were expected over the year-end,
but this year there had been virtually no activity at the discount
window in that period.
The national picture had already been well described,
Mr. Irons said.

He recognized that most indicators showed a

tendency towards slower growth, but here again the differences were
small.

The major uncertainty continued to be the nature of the

1/10/67

-69

actions that would be taken in the public sector.

Some of the

answers on that subject would be obtained from the President's
State of the Union message this evening, and more would be forth
coming in messages to be delivered over the next few weeks.

The

markets seemed to have adjusted to the considerable shift toward
ease that had been made by the System.

It was the general feeling

in his District that credit policy had become easier; the question

was how much easier policy would be.
Mr. Irons commented that he was disturbed by the deteriora
tion in the balance of payments and the possibility of worsening
in the gold situation.

The problems in those areas were serious,

and they probably deserved an increasing amount of thought and
attention on the part of the Committee.
Today, Mr. Irons said, he would favor maintaining an even
keel, continuing the present conditions in the money market.

The

figures that a number of other members had indicated they would
like to see emerge seemed appropriate to him.

He was not sure that

it would matter a great deal which of the three alternative
directives the Committee adopted.

He thought the staff had done

an excellent drafting job, formulating each alternative to
incorporate a concluding phrase that appropriately modified the
earlier language.

On balance, however, in view of various

considerations--including the Treasury financing, the basic economic

-70

1/10/67

situation and outlook as he saw it, the uncertainties with regard
to the public sector, and the balance of payments situation--he
favored alternative A.
Mr. Ellis said that the New England economy, measured in
real terms, appeared to have slowed its rate of advance.

Manufac

turing workweeks shortened slightly in November, and the man hour
index declined a fraction.

The index of factory output likewise

leveled in November from its October peak.

Manufacturers' shipments

in the fourth quarter declined from the previous quarter, as they
had projected, but were scheduled to rise sharply in the current
quarter.
Bankers continued to report strong loan demand, Mr. Ellis
noted, but they were taking moves to restore liquidity before
expanding lending.

Liquidity ratios had risen more than seasonally

and loan-deposit ratios had dropped noticeably since late November.
At least one bank had cut its interest rate on large short-term
business loans by 53 basis points, and the average for the large
Boston banks had been a cut of 43 basis points in their lending
rates between the September and December surveys.

Meanwhile, they

had become more selective in the rates they would pay for long-term
CD money.
Mr. Ellis reported having listened to some very direct
language about the inequity of the revised voluntary foreign credit

1/10/67

-71

restraint program.

The thrust of one protest was against the 10

per cent limit on loans to developed countries since they were the
countries most likely to be able to qualify for non-export related
loans.

The thrust of another protest was directed to the inequity

of delaying access to the 109 per cent quota.

Those "less cooper

ative" banks who by last fall had reached their ceilings seemed free
to disburse repayments without regard to the 10 per cent limit.
Insofar as the banks felt they had been penalized for not having
used their quotas, and insofar as they might be expected to have
more lendable funds during 1967, it seemed only logical to expect
them to move to and hold at their ceilings for fear of losing their
quotas permanently.

If that course was followed, it would naturally

have a substantial negative impact on the U.S. balance of payments.
He thought that was important if the Committee had any inclination
to view the VFCR program as a shelter against an outflow of the
funds it was putting into the economy.
Turning to monetary policy, Mr. Ellis said that the weight
of evidence emerging since the Committee's last meeting had served
to confirm the short-run forecasts of the staff that the temperature
of the economic climate had been slowly cooling, which had been a
clear objective of the Committee's policy only six months ago.

The

evidence also revealed that the shift in monetary policy commenced

1/10/67

-72

in mid-November had introduced a changed--and more optimisticoutlook for credit availability and effective market performance
in the months immediately ahead.

The paramount issue of policy

was whether the easing trend should be accelerated or the present
posture maintained.

As Mr. Axilrod had noted, fundamental to one's

judgment on that score was his evaluation of the underlying strength
of the economy.

His (Mr. Ellis') own resolution of that issue was

that the economy was unlikely to experience anything more than a
temporary "inventory" pause--a helpful consolidation period--if
the country was committed to support a continuing war effort in
Vietnam and continued expansion of other Government services at
Federal, State, and local levels.

He was inclined to view consumers

as ready to utilize their enlarged incomes to expand spending when
credit was available and uncertainties were reduced--conditions that
seemed likely to prevail increasingly in the next several months,
especially when the outlines of the Federal budget became clear.
Mr. Ellis confessed to a considerable difficulty in persist
ing in such an optimistic viewpoint while studying the well-presented
analysis of the green book.

By the same token, he found no difficulty

in believing that the Committee had already obtained perhaps 80 per
cent of the impact associated with public recognition of its change
in policy.
20 per cent?

How hard should the Committee push to obtain the other
Should it flood the reservoir to insure leakage to the

1/10/67

-73

economy?

To postpone any further moves toward easing while awaiting

the fiscal counterpart to the Committee's monetary actions seemed
almost costless in terms of monetary effect to be achieved in the
interim, and yet it would preserve a greater range of policy alter
natives for selection when better information was available.

In

common with Mr. Mitchell he did not rule out the possibility of a
bounce-back in bank lending.
His premise that a "wait and see" posture would be virtually
costless in a policy sense rested, Mr. Ellis observed, on the blue
book evaluation of the manner in which bank credit expansion had
resumed.

The bank credit proxy had expanded at an annual rate of

7 per cent since the Committee's policy shift of mid-November and
it was projected to expand at 7-9 per cent average rate in January
without a further change in policy.

Time deposit growth had resumed

since mid-November at an annual rate of 10.3 per cent, which was
equal to the growth rate in the first half of last year--and was
a rate that the Committee used to think of as excessive.

Without

further policy change, growth in time deposits was projected to
accelerate to 12 per cent in January.

The staff opened its blue

book discussion of prospective developments, absent further policy
actions, by indicating that "Bank credit expansion is likely to
continue in January, but at a slower pace than indicated by the

1/10/67

-74

large recent week-to-week increases."

From the end of December

to the end of January the staff expectation was for bank credit
expansion at a rate in the 4 to 6 per cent range, with net borrowed
reserves averaging around recent levels.

Total reserves were

projected to rise at a 10 - 12 per cent annual rate on average in
January.

In his judgment those projections were an entirely accept

able prospect and they encouraged him to specify as "targets"

the

underlying assumptions of a 90-day bill rate in the 4.75 - 4.85
per cent range, net borrowed reserves fluctuating around $100 million,
and Federal funds and dealer loan rates somewhat below their high
year-end levels.
As he considered the three alternative directives, Mr. Ellis
said, he had somewhat the same feeling as Mr. Irons had expressedtheir implications were rather similar.

That led him to wonder why

the Committee should accept any alternative other than A, which
provided for modification of operations if bank credit growth deviated
significantly from expectations.

Adoption of either of the other

alternatives would logically mean that the Committee sought expansion
in bank credit at a rate in excess of 7 - 9 per cent, in reserves at
a rate in excess of 10 - 12 per cent, and in time deposits at a rate
in excess of 12 per cent.

To seek such growth rates would seem to

him to go beyond what might be called a "gradual" change.
he favored alternative A.

Accordingly,

1/10/67

-75Mr. Robertson then made the following statement:

It is obvious that the effects of our easing of
monetary policy are gradually spreading through the
financial system, even though responses have been
exaggerated in some markets by expectational influences,
while being restrained in others by overhangs of caution,
uncertainty, and institutional inertia.
As yet, there have been few signs of any effects
of such credit easing on actual spending decisions--they
could hardly have been expected so quickly, given what
we know about monetary lags. The business statistics
flowing in seem to be indicating greater and greater
moderation of underlying expansive forces, leaving
us with a present rate of deceleration of growth that
we would not want to see continued for very long. None
theless, the economy still possesses significant elements
of strength, to which some added buoyancy will be given
as the easier credit climate begins to affect business
decisions. I see no need, therefore, for aggressive
further monetary easing today (particularly with the
Government's fiscal program for calendar 1967 still up
in the air). Furthermore, I am not sufficiently complacent
about future price increases to be willing to push hard
on the monetary accelerator at the first signs that the
economy might slow down more than we contemplated when
restrictive policies were formulated last year.
I do think it is essential, however, for us to
continue the gradual relaxation of monetary restraint
that we launched a few weeks ago. We should be trying
to create an environment in which we foster an orderly
and moderate bank credit expansion, with some moderate
recovery in large CD outstandings, a continued reasonable
growth in consumer-type time and savings deposits (but
not so vigorous as to pull funds away again from other
savings intermediaries), and a money supply expansion
that is neither so large nor so small as to have import
for a significant change from the current flow of spending.
To foster these intermediate objectives, we should
seek some further easing of net reserve availability
and related money market conditions in the interval
between now and late January when "even keel" consider
ations come to the fore. This means that I would like
to see net borrowed reserves running regularly below
$100 million (and perhaps occasionally positive), and

1/10/67
that I would dislike to see the Federal funds rate
hanging up around 5-1/2 per cent or higher, or the
bill rate running up appreciably and giving off confus
ing signals to the market. But I want to emphasize,
as I have in the past, that these money market factors
should not be looked at as ends in themselves, and we
should be quick to take moderating action as suggested
by the "proviso" clause in the directive if our aggre
gate credit objectives are not being fostered.
As a practical matter, I know the Manager cannot
reasonably expect to hit all the targets I have cited.
Deviations in individual measures will inevitably occur,
and they can even be positively helpful, so long as
they are not disruptively large, because they will serve
to keep both us and the market from settling into ruts.
If, therefore, the Manager can manage to achieve some
kind of average of the results I have been describing,
I will be satisfied.
With these views in mind, I would be prepared to
vote for alternative B for the directive, as drafted
by the staff.
Chairman Martin commented that the Committee members seemed
for the most part to be in agreement today.

He personally was quite

well satisfied with the way policy had gone since the decision to
change; the Committee had been pursuing an easier, but not an easy,
policy--a distinction he thought was significant--and he would want
to continue on that course.

Adoption of alternative B today would

seem to him to be quite clearly consistent with such a policy.

He

thought some rather disturbing operational problems could be
encountered if the Committee adopted alternative C.

At its next

meeting the Committee would have more information on prospective
fiscal policy that could be taken into consideration, but for the
time being he would propose adoption of alternative B as drafted.

1/10/67

-77The Chairman then suggested that the Committee vote on a

directive consisting of the staff's draft for the first paragraph
and alternative B for the second paragraph.
Thereupon, upon motion duly made
and seconded, and with Messrs. Irons,
Shepardson, and Treiber dissenting, the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York was
authorized and directed, until otherwise
directed by the Committee, to execute
transactions in the System Account in
accordance with the following current
economic policy directive:
The economic and financial developments reviewed
at this meeting indicate further moderation in various
expansionary forces and sharply increased inventory
accumulation. The pace of advance of broad price
measures has slowed, although upward price and cost
pressures persist for many finished goods and services.
Partly reflecting the recent modification of monetary
policy, financial market conditions have become less
taut than earlier and bank credit expansion has resumed.
With respect to the balance of payments, trends in
international transactions indicate a continuing serious
problem. In this situation, it is the Federal Open
Market Committee's policy to foster money and credit
conditions conducive to noninflationary economic expansion
and progress toward reasonable equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.
To implement this policy, and taking account of
forthcoming Treasury financing, System open market opera
tions until the next meeting of the Committee shall be
conducted with a view to attaining somewhat easier
conditions in the money market, unless bank credit appears
to be expanding significantly faster than currently
anticipated.

1/10/67

-78
It was agreed that the next meeting of the Committee would

be held on Tuesday, February 7, 1967, at 9:30 a.m.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

ATTACHMENT A
CONFIDENTIAL (FR)

January 9, 1967

Drafts of Current Economic Policy Directive for Consideration by the
Federal Open Market Committee at its Meeting on January 10, 1967
FIRST PARAGRAPH
The economic and financial developments reviewed at this
meeting indicate further moderation in various expansionary forces
and sharply increased inventory accumulation. The pace of advance
of broad price measures has slowed, although upward price and cost
pressures persist for many finished goods and services. Partly
reflecting the recent modification of monetary policy, financial
market conditions have become less taut than earlier and bank credit
expansion has resumed. With respect to the balance of payments, trends
in international transactions indicate a continuing serious problem.
In this situation, it is the Federal Open Market Committee's policy to
foster money and credit conditions conducive to noninflationary economic
expansion and progress toward reasonable equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.
SECOND PARAGRAPH
Alternative A:
To implement this policy, and taking account of forthcoming
Treasury financing, System open market operations until the next
meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a view to maintaining
about the currently prevailing conditions in the money market, but
operations shall be modified as necessary to moderate any apparently
significant deviation of bank credit from current expectations.
Alternative B:
To implement this policy, and taking account of forthcoming
Treasury financing, System open market operations until the next
meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a view to attaining
somewhat easier conditions in the money market, unless bank credit
appears to be expanding significantly faster than currently antic
ipated.
Alternative C:
To implement this policy, and taking account of forthcoming
Treasury financing, System open market operations until the next

-2
meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a view to fostering
expansion in bank credit at a moderate rate, but operations shall be
modified as necessary to limit any sharp easing or firming of money
market conditions.