View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

Notes For FOMC Meeting

February 5, 1991
Sam Y. Cross

The Gulf conflict dominated foreign exchange trading during
much of the period since you last met.

Nervousness over the conflict,

about whether it would result in war and if so how long and broad the
conflict might be, provided waves of support for the dollar through
December and most of January.

It was not until last week, when

changes in Bundesbank and Federal Reserve discount rates underscored
the divergent trends in interest rates in the two countries that
market attention turned back to economic conditions here and abroad.
When that occurred, the dollar fell to reach a new historic low
against the mark yesterday morning.
The dollar is now 1 to 2 percent below the levels prevailing
at the time of your mid-December meeting.

In the interim, however,

there was considerable volatility, and the dollar came under two
periods of strong upward pressure, both associated with political
developments abroad.

In the second of these episodes, the dollar

moved up to Y138 and DM 1.55 as the first reports of war in the Gulf
reached the market.

From these levels, the dollar then reversed

course and within hours tumbled a full 4 to 5 percent back down to its
mid-December levels.
Recognizing the potential for great volatility in financial
markets, we had begun before January 15 to consult informally with the
Bundesbank and the Bank of Japan about how we might work together to
deal with any shocks or unusual pressures in the exchange markets.
explored various possibilities.

We

In the event, neither the Bundesbank

nor the Bank of Japan wanted to agree to any precise program in
advance, although both professed a willingness to cooperate if

conditions warranted.

The Japanese were more reluctant to consider

operations in their currency than the Germans, reflecting the fact
that the dollar was not nearly as close to its all-time low against
the yen as it was against the mark and that the Japanese have been
under considerable pressure from the Europeans to let their currency
appreciate further.
As it turned out, the dollar moved up with the increasing
prospect of war in mid-January and the outbreak of allied bombing on
January 16.

However, the possibility of war had been well anticipated

so that market operators were quick to take advantage of the run-up of
rates to take profits on long dollar positions.

Some of the longer-

term position takers actually moved to establish short-dollar
positions, believing that a quick and decisive war would allow the
market to return its attention to underlying economic and interest
rate trends.

As a result, the dollar turned around abruptly as I have

already mentioned and has tended to move irregularly lower since then.
The G.7, at its meeting on January 21,

said merely that they were

"prepared to respond as appropriate to maintain stability in
international markets" and had little market impact.

In informal

discussions, Treasury tested sentiment about a concept of more
specific trading ranges but found both the Germans and the Japanese
skeptical about any formal undertakings.
Last week, sentiment toward the dollar weakened further as
divergent economic trends in the United States, on the one hand, and
Germany and Japan, on the other, became increasingly apparent and took
their toll.
the Gulf war.

A number of developments drew market attention away from
Most notably there were the German interest rate hikes

on Thursday, followed on Friday by the release of U.S. employment data
and the subsequent reduction in our discount and federal funds rates.

Also, there were comments on the need for lower interest rates by the
President, Secretary Brady and others, which reinforced expectations
of continuing interest rate reductions.

All of this tended to

overwhelm the factors supporting the dollar and the dealing
community's reluctance to go short dollars.
In that environment, we contacted the Bundesbank and agreed
that we would jointly act to resist further significant dollar
declines.

As events unfolded, the dollar broke through its previous

historic low of DM 1.4625 yesterday, and hit a new low of about DM
1.4560 by 8:00 a.m.

The Desk initiated two rounds of concerted

intervention around the 9:00 a.m. opening in New York.

We purchased a

total of $100 million against marks, and were joined by 14 other
central banks which together bought a total of $325 million, nearly
all against marks.
On the basis of the market reaction and the commentary we
subsequently received from the other central banks, these operations
were successful, at least initially.

However, there have been further

pressures today, and there are further operations.

Market

participants were impressed with the evidence of G-7 cohesion in the
exchange area.

But, it is clear that the current interest rate

differentials against the dollar and the presumption of further
declines in dollar interest rates weigh

heavily against the dollar.

On another matter, we have continued to sell, as customer
operations, currencies received by Treasury from German and Japanese
contributions to Desert Shield.

During January, we sold

under this arrangement.
Mr. Chairman, I request the Committee's approval for the
Federal Reserve's purchase of $50 million against marks yesterday, our
only operation on behalf of the System during the period.

This

-4-

represents the Federal Reserve's half of the $100 million intervention
yesterday.

Notes for FOMC Meeting
Peter D. Sternlight
February 5-6, 1991
The past intermeeting period was marked by
unprecedented turbulence in the market for bank reserves--the
Federal funds market--as bank reserve managers and the System's
Trading Desk coped with year-end pressures, the phase-down of
reserve requirements that brought required reserve balances down
to levels insufficient at times to meet clearing needs, and some
large day-to-day projection errors.

Amazingly, notwithstanding

the turbulence, market participants were never in much doubt as
to the thrust of policy and the Desk was able to communicate
policy moves quite clearly to the market.
The first such move was undertaken shortly after the
Committee's December 18 meeting.

The afternoon of that meeting,

the Board approved a 1/2 percentage point reduction in the
discount rate to 6 1/2 percent.

Beginning the next day, the Desk

aimed for reserve conditions associated with Federal funds
trading around 7 percent--down 1/4 percentage point from the
previously expected rate.

The market got the message fairly

readily, although actual funds rates showed considerable
variation going into the year-end period and the phase-down of
reserve requirements.

The second move was made around January 9,

in particular response to soft money growth, and also against the

broad background of weakness in the economy and slackening
inflation.

The funds rate was now expected to vary around

6 3/4 percent.

Once again, the market got the point quickly even

though variations in the funds rate were so wide as to render the
idea of a central tendency rather abstract.

While year-end

pressures, as such, had passed, we were still living with the
aftermath of the huge provisions of reserves to cope with yearend, and at the same time with the constraints introduced by
lower reserve requirements.

Those reductions brought the need

for balances at the Fed for reserve requirement purposes down to
the point where the more critical factor was often the need to
maintain sufficient balances for clearing purposes.

The third

move came near the end of the period, following the Board's
further reduction of the discount rate by another 1/2 percentage
point to 6 percent.

This time, as noted at the Committee

conference call last Friday morning, just before the discount
rate move was announced, the decision was to have the full
50 basis point cut show through to the funds rate, reducing the
expected rate to around 6 1/4 percent.

Once again, even though

funds were rather volatile over the day last Friday, the new
6 1/4 percent level was communicated fairly clearly.
On average over reserve maintenance periods, funds were
not vastly different from the expected central points, but the
averages concealed some very wide variations, not just on
settlement days--to which markets have been accustomed--but also
on many other days.

Funds averaged about 7 1/4 percent in the

reserve period ended December 26, reflecting pre-year-end

firmness--but with actual rates as low as 1/16 percent on
December 24 and as high as 100 percent on December 26.

In the

January 9 period, when the objective was 7 percent until the
final day, the average turned out around 6.80 percent, with some
trading as low as zero on the year-end date and as high as 12 or
13 percent at other times.

For a few days near the start of the

January 23 period it appeared that greater stability had
returned, with funds holding close to the 6 3/4 percent
objective, but greater volatility soon returned and we saw rates
as high as 30 and 90 percent on the last two days of that period.
The period average was again around 6.80 percent, with benefit of
luck.
The current period has again seen much variability,
averaging around 7 1/8 percent through yesterday with a range of
roughly 1/4 to 15 percent.

The particular reason for

volatility in this current period seems to be that balances
maintained at the Fed to meet reserve requirements are
exceptionally low, as vault cash is seasonably high and
requirements seasonally low (as well as having been reduced by
the December action).

This apparently meant that the binding

constraint on balances was the need for balances for clearing
purposes--a highly variable quantity that we are still learning
to track.

Projection misses added to the problem, and the

effects of misses tended to be magnified as the smaller volume of
maintained reserves provided less cushion to absorb day-to-day
flows.

In addition, my impression is that the funds market has

"thinned out" in the sense that participants are more name

conscious about counterparties.

There are some institutions that

don't want to sell, or would sell only limited amounts to certain
others.

This has led to reported situations, especially in late-

day activity, of trades going through at widely different rates
at about the same time.
While the path level of borrowing remained in the
$100-125 million range, actual borrowing often exceeded this
level, especially on tight funds days.

For full reserve periods,

average borrowing ranged from about $275 million to $850 million,
though this current period is coming out somewhat under
$200 million.

Part of the borrowing reflected the needs of Bank

of New England, but on average this was a small factor as they
were able to leave the window once Treasury tax and loan account
balances built up in mid-January.

The highest daily borrowing

came at the ends of the December 26 and January 23 periods, in
each case about $5 billion.

On both occasions there was a

deceptively comfortable money market on the morning of those
settlement days that precluded aggressive Desk action to provide
for projected needs, lest the market be misled about policy; and
then there were large projection misses to boot, though we would
have been reluctant to add more reserves on those occasions even
if our projections had been accurate!
Demands for excess reserves were highly variable, as
noted, reflecting year-end and the complications introduced by
the reserve requirement cut along with the emerging need for
clearing balances.

Excess normally had ranged within a few

hundred million of $1 billion.

In the December 26 period, which

saw the first part of the reserve requirement phase-down, excess
bulged to about $2 billion.

In the next period, which saw the

rest of the reserve requirement cut as well as year-end, excess
soared to around $3 1/2 billion--though this was evidently more
than was really wanted and led to large carry-overs into the next
period.

In that interval, ended January 23, excess dropped to a

currently estimated $900 million--and was probably less than was
desired given the very tight close.

In the current period, now

drawing to an end, demands have bulged again, apparently to
something around $3 billion.
At the start of the intermeeting period, it appeared
that there would be some reserve needs up through about year-end,
but then huge needs to absorb reserves as the year-end factors
faded, revealing the excess reserves released by the reserve
requirement reduction and augmented by seasonal movements in
currency and required reserves.

The Desk's initial strategy was

to meet reserve needs with repurchase agreements while at the
same time gradually lightening outright holdings through run-offs
of bills and sales to foreign accounts.

As the Committee will

recall, the need to absorb reserves by end of the period looked
so large that we requested a substantial increase in the standard
intermeeting leeway.

Part way through the period, the reserve

outlook changed dramatically as prospectively high Treasury
balances after the mid-January tax date and large currency
outflows apparently related to the Middle East substantially
reduced the projected need to drain reserves.

Thus after running

off just $2 billion of bill holdings and selling $1.6 billion of

-6-

bills to foreign accounts we discontinued the shrinkage of our
outright portfolio--thereby not even using the normal leeway
never mind the expanded amount.
Meantime, heavy use was made of temporary transactions,
especially repurchase agreements, with unusually large volumes
employed just before year-end.

Specifically to deal with year-

end pressures, a new technique was used a few days before the
year-end, in which we arranged forward RP's in heavy volume, to
take effect on the year-end date.
helpful in

This seemed to be particularly

relieving the somewhat paranoid market fears about

getting financed on that day.

On a few occasions,

after our

exceptionally heavy provisions of reserves had flooded the market
and rates were very soft, we arranged matched sale-purchase
transactions in the market to extract seemingly over-abundant
reserves.

The volatility and uncertainty were such, though, that

on at least one occasion after extracting reserves with matched
sales--a move that we felt virtually obliged to undertake lest
the market falsely conclude we were easing--the funds market
subsequently became excessively tight.
The gyrating funds rate seemed to have little effect on
other market interest rates.

Rather, those rates responded to a

variety of influences over the period, including news on the
economy, prices, money growth, perceived policy moves, and of
course Middle East developments.

On net, the Treasury yield

curve steepened appreciably as short term rates came down under
the impact of policy easings.

Key bill rates fell about

70-80 basis points--not far from matching the full percentage

point decline in the System's expected funds rate.

In last

Monday's 3- and 6-month bill auctions the average rates were
5.97 and 5.94 percent, down from 6.78 and 6.77 percent just
before the last meeting date.

Net bill issuance was about

unchanged over the period as increases in the regular weekly
cycles were about offset by a December paydown of cash management
bills.

Meantime, increasing amounts of bills were absorbed by

noncompetitive tenders, probably reflecting to some extent
anxieties about the financial system.
Rates on commercial paper and bank CDs dropped by
roughly 100 to 175 basis points, with the larger declines in the
shorter maturities where the passage of year-end was a prominent
factor.

Banks cut their prime rate a full percentage point, in

two stages, to 9 percent.

The first cut followed the mid-

December discount rate reduction rather sluggishly as most banks
waited for the passage of year-end before acting.

The second

came with greater alacrity in response to the latest discount
rate cut and perceived reduction in the Fed's funds rate goal.
For intermediate and longer maturities the rate
declines were much less--about 20-50 basis points for Treasury
issues due in 2 to 7 years and about 15-20 basis points for the
longer term issues.

Indeed, over much of the period, the yield

on long Treasuries was higher than in mid-December, reflecting
worries about the Middle East, and at times a view that the
economy might not be as soft or inflation as subdued as it
appeared at other times.

Continuing additions to supply, actual

or prospective, were also a factor in the intermediate and longer

area.

Counting the current quarterly financing, for which

auctions are now being held, the Treasury will have raised nearly
$38 billion in the coupon market since the December meeting,
while Refcorp raised another $7 billion in January using up its
authorized borrowing limit.

After taking very negatively the

news of the breakdown in the Baker-Aziz talks in early January,
the market responded favorably to the early reports of Allied
military successes just after hostilities began at mid-month.
But that merely brought the 30-year yield back to around the
8.20 percent level prevailing in mid-December.

A further yield

decline after last Friday's weak employment report and discount
rate cut led to the moderate net decline for the full period,
with the long bond now yielding a bit over 8.00 percent.
Throughout the period, there has been market
expectation of further Fed easing to come, though with much
variation of views about the timing and extent of specific moves.
In general, the actual moves in the recent period seemed to come
a bit sooner and more aggressively than most participants had
anticipated.

At the moment, in the wake of last Friday's policy

steps it is not yet clear how much more the market looks for.

My

sense is that most participants anticipate nothing further for at
least a few weeks, with the timing and extent of any subsequent
moves dependent on information on the economy, credit and money
growth, and Middle East developments.

Many share the view that

if the war ends quickly, this could give a big lift to business
and consumer sentiment.
are far less certain.

The consequences of a longer conflict

-9Finally, I should mention that another firm left
primary dealer ranks in the recent period.

Security Pacific,

after a restructuring that dismantled its merchant bank had at
first sought to keep the primary dealer going and perhaps place
it in a joint venture with a foreign bank, but then decided to
draw back to just a localized dealership.
of primary dealers back to 40.

That shrank the number

Michael J. Prell
February 5, 1991

CHART SHOW PRESENTATION -- DOMESTIC ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

We are going to depart today from our past approach.

Rather

than giving you a complete sector-by-sector recitation of our
projection, we are going to try to zero in on some key questions that
previous discussions led us to think might be on your minds.
The first chart outlines our presentation.

I'll start by

summarizing the forecasts you gave us; then, I'll say a few words about
the war and the budget, and about the credit crunch.

Larry Promisel

will take the floor next, examining the exchange rate outlook and also
the prospects for the oil market.

He'll then address the concern a

number of you have expressed previously about the consequences for our
exports if growth abroad is disappointing.

Another question that you've

asked previously, namely, what will propel our projected economic
upturn, is partially addressed by looking at the external sector, but
Larry Slifman will try to give you a more complete answer.

He'll also

examine the issue of whether we've turned the corner on the core rate of
inflation and he'll address the question of how fast the economy can
grow without invigorating inflation.

I shall then conclude by

exploring, through model simulation, the consequences of a substantial
Fed easing; this seems even more germane now, given that our assumption
that the fed funds rate would remain at 6-3/4 percent already has been
violated.
So let me get the ball rolling by turning to chart 2, where
you'll find the familiar table summarizing your forecasts for 1991.

- 2 -

Before I say anything more, I probably should give you a few seconds to
look at the figures--and to discern where you stand relative to your
colleagues.
The central tendencies I've listed encompass the vast majority
of you.

In case you are curious, the median forecasts were one percent

for real GNP, 3-3/4 percent for the CPI, and 6-3/4 percent for the yearend unemployment rate.

On this basis, you shared the Administration's

view of the real outlook but were more optimistic with respect to
inflation.

I should note that, despite comments by Administration

officials about the scope for further Fed easing, their forecast
involves a 3-month bill rate averaging 6.4 percent in 1991, about a
half-point above today's level.
The staff finds itself with precious little company in its
optimism about growth prospects for the year; we're a shade above your
median inflation forecast, with that difference being entirely
consistent with our lower expected unemployment rate.
The lower table summarizes the staff forecast.

As you know, we

have projected that the recession will end in the next few months and
that growth thereafter will be sufficient to push
down to 6 percent in 1992.

unemployment back

Consumer price inflation should slow

markedly in the current quarter, owing to the drop in energy prices, but
we also see a considerable deceleration in the CPI ex food and energy
over the ne::t two years, as a result of the slack in the economy.
I perhaps should say a word at this point about how news since
last Wednesday's Greenbook publication would alter our expectations.
a nutshell, the latest data suggest to us that activity probably was a

In

- 3 -

little weaker at the start of the year than we estimated.

We said in

the Greenbook that we thought GNP might decline "somewhere between...1
and 2 percent" in the current quarter, and we'd be inclined now to move
to the 2 percent end of that range.

On the other hand, the 1/2 percent

further reduction in the funds rate and the accompanying easing of long
rates would seem adequate to roughly offset that negative surprise by
the end of the year, and, if maintained, perhaps to put us on a slightly
higher path in 1992.

All of this really is finer tuning than anyone's

forecasting skills would warrant, however, and my basic message is that
we still believe the odds favor an early and solid, though not
spectacular, upturn in activity--given our conditioning assumptions.
One of those assumptions is that fiscal policy will place less
restraint on aggregate demand than we previously had anticipated, owing
in part to the war.

The top panel of chart 3 depicts the change in our

projection for defense purchases since the December Greenbook.

As you

can see, purchases already considerably exceeded our expectations in the
fourth quarter.

Moving the troops and equipment to the Gulf accounted

for a good chunk of the outlay, but there are also indications that new
supplies were purchased, a portion out of added current U.S. production.
Once the war commenced, we had to make some

assumption regarding its

length and cost, and about the degree to which the future path of
defense purchases would be affected.

As indicated, the result was an

elevation of the pace of defense purchases by roughly $20 billion, at an
annual rate, through next year.
As we said in the Greenbook, however, incremental expenditures
of the magnitude we've assumed might well involve no expansion of the

-

4 -

federal deficits for fiscal 1991 and '92, thanks to the contributions
from other countries.

Even so, we've raised our projections of the

deficits, somewhat, based in part on new information about the costs of
other programs, and as the first line of the table shows, we foresee
deficits of around $275 billion, plus or minus several billion, this
year and next.

In economic terms, these deficits greatly overstate the

government's absorption of national saving.

If you strip out the

transfers associated with the deposit insurance programs, the deficits
drop under $200 billion, and if you take out other purely financial
transactions and make a few more technical adjustments, you get a
deficit on a national income accounts basis that moves down to $136
billion in fiscal 1992.

That's just a little more than 2 percent of

GNP, a low figure, by recent standards.
Our fiscal impetus measure, charted in the bottom panel,
suggests that, despite the recent additions to our spending projection,
the federal government still will be imposing a modicum of restraint on
growth in aggregate demand.
I'd like to turn now to the question of the credit crunch.
This is still a rather murky area, but the ne::t couple of charts contain
a few relevant facts.

The solid line in the top panel of chart 4

indicates that net funds raised by domestic nonfinancial sectors,
measured relative to GNP, decreased substantially after the mid-1980s,
but have changed little in the past year and a half.

Although the

current level of this ratio is low by the standards of the 1970s and the
1980s, it isn't by those of earlier years.

-

5 -

There are a whole lot of things going on in this time series.
However, it strikes me as interesting that, if one were to shift the
date of the onset of the current recession back to sometime in 1989, the
recent behavior of the funds-raised ratio would look more similar to
previous cyclical patterns.

Perhaps not just coincidentally, this would

fit with the fact that interest rates peaked in mid-1989, after which
there was a period of very slow economic growth.

As you know, this

recession differs from those in the past in that rates turned down well
before the business cycle peak and growth was unusually weak prior to
that peak.
Even with this time-shift I've suggested, the behavior of
depository credit in the current episode would stand out.

As indicated

by the dashed line, there is no recent precedent for the kind of
deceleration in depository credit that we're experiencing.

Moreover, in

previous recessions sluggishness of depository credit often was clearly
importantly related to weak aggregate credit demand or to voluntary
shifts by corporate borrowers to the bond markets to fund-out short-term
debts.

You'll recall that, in our surveys early last year, weak credit

demands were cited by bankers as damping loan growth.

But with many

banks and thrifts obviously capital-constrained, if not out of business
entirely, one wonders whether the sharp decline in depository lending
isn't signaling a supply-side pressure that is further depressing
overall financing volumes and economic activity.
There can be no doubt that the sudden loss of intermediation
services from depositories--not to mention the problems of insurance
companies and other institutions--has adversely affected the cost and

- 6 -

availability of credit to ultimate users of funds.

Just how seriously

is the only real question.
One may note, to begin with, that the bulk of the contraction
of depository credit is accounted for by the shrinkage of the thrift
industry, and the availability of the mortgage-backed securities market
has permitted a fairly efficient rechanneling of flows to the home
mortgage sector--the S&Ls' primary clientele.
Of course, commercial banks did not take up the S&L slack and
bank credit has decelerated recently, a swing that looks rather modest
by historical standards, but nonetheless a source of concern, especially
in terms of the supply of credit to businesses.

The middle panel shows

a couple of the traditional indexes of strains in the business credit
market.

The spreads of private short- and long-term rates over

Treasuries have widened, but they remain well below previous cyclical
peaks; indeed, they've exhibited nothing like the swings we've observed
in the past.

Of course, what isn't shown here is the junk bond spread,

and the effective shut-down of that market clearly made a difference for
a significant class of borrowers.
But a greater focus of concern in discussions of the credit
crunch is the plight of the smaller businesses, which always have been
more dependent on loans from banks and other intermediaries.

The

results of the survey of the National Federation of Independent
Business, charted in the lower panel, show a surprisingly mild increase
in the past year in the net percent of respondents reporting credit
harder to get versus those reporting it easier to obtain.

Consistent

with one's expectations, however, the swing is much more noticeable

among firms in New England, where credit was comparatively easy to come
by in the mid-'80s.

Indeed, this morning, we got a

revised fourth-

quarter number and a January figure, which put the New England index
around the 1982 peak of 26 percent.

The national index for January was

14 percent, versus 13 percent in the fourth quarter.
The bottom line would seem to be that, overall, small
businesses are suffering, but perhaps not generally to the degree
suggested by the outcry we're hearing--or perhaps even as much as they
have in other business slumps.

This conclusion seems to be supported

by the fact that, although it has moved up on the NFIB members' "single
most important problem" poll, financing still ranks only sixth, vastly
outdistanced by taxes, regulation and poor sales.
Whatever the magnitude of the tightening in credit supply
conditions to date, we expect that things will get worse before they get
better.

Some reasons for that conclusion are indicated in chart 5.

As

shown at the upper left, the rating services have been downgrading
corporate securities at an unprecedented clip in the past year, and we
see no abatement in the near term, in part because the recession is
further eroding already slim interest-coverage ratios, reflected at the
right.

We expect quality spreads to widen further and, with firms

moving down the rating spectrum, this means a double-whammy in their
financing costs.

Banks are likely to be cautious lenders, too, in this

environment.
The bottom left panel shows two household loan delinquency
series.

The message they, and other series, convey is that debt-

servicing performance among households has been better, but it doesn't

- 8 -

look especially bad against the experience of the past 10 or 15 years-despite the run-up in debt-servicing burdens depicted in the right-hand
panel.

The delinquency rates only go through the third quarter of last

year, however, and we would expect to see some rise in subsequent
quarters and some greater degree of caution, as a result, on the part of
lenders.
Our conclusion on the credit crunch, then, remains what it has
been for some time:

the strains in the financial sector have been a

negative for aggregate demand, and credit quality problems are likely to
intensify those strains in the near term; however, we don't think the
credit crunch was so severe a negative as to explain the recession or
that it will override the other forces that will work to produce an
economic upturn.
Let me now ask Larry Promisel to carry on the presentation.

- 9-

Larry Promisel

February 5, 1991

Chart Show, February 5, 1991 -- International Developments

An expectation that U.S. exports will grow strongly has
been an important feature of the staff forecast for some time.
Anecdotal evidence, including information reported from many
districts in the Beige book, is consistent with a fairly strong
outlook for exports; so is the Survey of Purchasing Managers
released last Friday.

However, as was suggested in Mike's list

of questions, what happens with respect to the dollar, oil
prices, and foreign demand will play a determining role in the
actual outcome.
Chart 6 provides some perspective on the dollar.

As

shown by the black line in the top panel, the price-adjusted
exchange value of the dollar has declined significantly --

about

18 percent -- from a peak in mid-1989, with half of that decline
coming in the past 6 months.

The dollar is now trading around

its historic lows, on a weighted-average basis.

In broad terms,

the dollar's depreciation has corresponded with relative
movements in real long-term interest rates.

Using one measure of

expected inflation, foreign rates in real terms now are higher
than they were a year and a half ago, though not as high as they
were last fall.

In contrast, real rates in the United States are

little changed on balance over that whole period, so that the
differential has moved against dollar assets by about 1
percentage point.

-

10 -

As shown in the middle left panel, the dollar has
declined more than 10 percent against European currencies and the
yen since the previous chart show, but is little changed against
the Canadian dollar and the currencies of Korea and Taiwan.
Three-month interest rates -- the middle right panel -- have

risen almost a percentage point in Germany and Japan since June,
while U.S. rates have declined -- indeed, by a bit more than is
shown in the chart because the full effect of Friday's easing is
not reflected there.

Long-term rates edged down abroad, though

not as much as here.
In our forecast, the dollar remains near its recent
lows.

This assumption is based in part on the view that monetary

policy abroad will change little, on balance.

If the dollar does

follow something like its assumed path -- depicted by the black
line in the bottom panel -- it will enhance the competitiveness
of U.S. goods to a degree that is unusual in previous cyclical
experience.

On average in four previous cycles, beginning in

1969, the dollar had been fairly flat over the 4 quarters
preceding the peak of the cycle and rose slightly in subsequent
quarters.

The extent to which the dollar fell prior to the peak

of the present cycle, fell a bit further after the peak, and
remains low in the forecast was matched only by the 1973-74
experience.
Chart 7 addresses the oil market.

I hesitate to say

much about oil, given the uncertainties associated with it, but
it obviously has the potential to affect significantly the
outlook for world activity and inflation.

Following the spike in

- 11 -

spot prices for West Texas Intermediate -- the red line in the
upper panel -- the U.S. import unit value for oil -- the black

line -- rose sharply in the fourth quarter, but we assume it will
decline in the current quarter and will settle at $21 per barrel
over the remainder of the forecast horizon.

This is above the

price assumed in last July's chart show, prior to the Iraqi
invasion, but is lower than in the December Greenbook.

For

reference, futures prices, also drawn in the panel, imply a price
path somewhat below the staff forecast.
A structure of OPEC production that we believe would be
consistent with our price path is shown in the middle panel.
Essentially, Saudi Arabia is assumed to be able to maintain
production at its recent high rates of 8.5 mbd before letting it
fall back as Iraqi production gradually, and Kuwaiti production
even more gradually, come on stream.

Obviously, one could come

up with variations on this theme; the controlling premise is that
once things settle down in 1992, OPEC, and Saudi Arabia in
particular, will adjust production to achieve the $21 per barrel
target price agreed upon in the OPEC Accord last July.
As implied in the bottom panel, stocks, which were built
up as production exceeded consumption in the first half of 1990,
will be run down in 1991.

With stocks expected to be in

reasonable balance in 1992, production next year is set to equal
consumption at volumes consistent with a price of $21 per barrel.
The next chart addresses the question of foreign growth.
Industrial production in the major foreign industrial countries
(the G-6) is shown in the top panel.

One aspect that is

- 12 -

immediately apparent is the divergence of growth performances
over the past year.

Prominent in the upper left panel is the

decline in production last year in Canada and the United Kingdom
combined, with the decline starting earlier and extending deeper
in Canada.

The experience in Canada and the United Kingdom

contrasts sharply with that in Japan, where industrial production
increased rapidly during 1990.

There is widespread expectation

of a slowing of activity in Japan, partly in response to monetary
tightening that began last spring and partly reflecting presumed
effects of declines in prices of equities and land.

Indeed, one

can point already to some signs of slowing: weak auto sales and
housing starts, and rising corporate bankruptcies.

But labor

markets remain tight and, on balance, the Japanese economy still
seems to be strong.
Activity in Western Germany -- the upper right panel --

has been boosted by demand associated with unification with
Eastern Germany, coming on top of an already strong economy.

A

declining German trade surplus suggests some spillover of German
demand to other countries, but such a spillover is not yet
apparent significantly in data for Germany's principal European
partners.

In these circumstances, it is not surprising that the

Bundesbank's actions to tighten policy, even though taken in
response to strong demand, have not been welcome elsewhere in
Europe.
Germany continues to enjoy a good inflation performance,
especially relative to the United Kingdom and Italy -- the two
middle panels.

This inflation differential exacerbates pressures

- 13 -

on exchange rates within the European Monetary System; it makes
it more difficult for France, Italy, and the United Kingdom to
reduce their interest rates, which they might otherwise choose to
do.
Therefore, as noted in the bottom panel, we expect
monetary policy abroad to remain cautious.

German interest rates

are still assumed to move a bit higher before coming back down
later this year and next.

Scope for interest rates to decline in

other countries is assumed to arise only as inflation rates come
down, suggesting little change in real interest rates.

In

nominal terms, declines in interest rates are likely to be
especially large in the United Kingdom and Canada, where monetary
policy tightened sooner to bring inflation rates down.

We are

anticipating that interest rates in Japan will fall gradually as
both economic growth and inflation subside.
We expect fiscal policy abroad to be essentially neutral
on average.

In Germany, spending associated with unification

will add fiscal stimulus this year but, we think, less next year
as other government spending is cut or as taxes are raised.
The outlook for activity and prices abroad is shown in
Chart 9.

As shown by the red bars in the upper left panel,

growth of real GNP in the rest of the world, which slowed last
year, is forecast to pick up this year and further in 1992.

As

shown in the upper right panel, this is true both for the G-6
countries and for the rest of the world.

With respect to G-6

countries, recoveries from the recessions in the United Kingdom
and Canada starting in the second half of this year are an

- 14 -

important element in our forecast.

We expect that growth will

slow somewhat in Germany and Japan but will remain in both
countries in the 3.5 to 4 percent range.

Inflation rates in

major foreign industrial countries, which were boosted last year
by the rise in oil prices -- the middle panels --

to decline.

are forecast

On a fourth-quarter to fourth-quarter basis,

consumer prices are forecast to rise next year at about the same
rate in G-6 countries as in the United States.
We think our forecast for growth of real GNP in other
major countries, shown again by the black line in the bottom
panel, is reasonably balanced; it does not differ significantly
from other forecasts.

We see upside risks, including the

possibility, which seems to be gaining some acceptance in
financial markets, that the Bundesbank will not raise interest
rates further and may even lower them, with a corresponding
easing of policy constraints elsewhere.

However, we recognize

that there are downside risks, as well.

Some of these are

specific to individual countries.

Other risks, like greater

disruptions in the oil market, adverse effects from problems in
real estate or financial markets, or weaker outcomes in Eastern
Europe -- are common to many countries, albeit to varying

degrees.

To provide a feel for the sensitivity of U.S. exports

to these downside risks, the dashed red line presents an
alternative, more pessimistic, outlook for growth in major
foreign countries.

The level of real GNP at the end of the

forecast period is about 2 percent lower on average in this
alternative than in the Greenbook forecast, with some variation

- 15 -

across countries.

I will describe the simulated effects of lower

foreign growth on U.S. exports in a moment.
The Greenbook forecast for exports is shown in the upper
panels of the next chart.

The quantity of non-agricultural

exports was flat in the middle quarters of last year, following a
spurt early in the year.

Nevertheless, strong growth again in

the fourth quarter boosted growth over the year to 10 percent.
We are forecasting that exports will continue to grow at a rate
of about 10 percent over the next two years, supported by recent
gains in U.S. price competitiveness and the projected pickup in
growth abroad.
Agricultural exports -- the middle panels -- also were

weak in the middle quarters of 1990 and, indeed, for the year as
a whole.

We are forecasting that, after sales of grain to the

Soviet Union and China boost shipments in the first half of this
year, agricultural exports will change little over the remainder
of the forecast horizon.
The implications for exports of the alternative scenario
for growth in major foreign countries are shown in the bottom
panels.

The difference in growth between the Greenbook and that

alternative is especially great for Canada, the United Kingdom,
and Japan, which together account for a 40 percent share of U.S.
exports.

We did not assume significantly different growth in

countries other than the G-6, which purchase half of our exports.
By the end of the forecast period -- shown at the bottom right --

the quantity of exports of goods and services combined would be
about $15 billion (or 2 percent) lower with the alternative path

-

than in the Greenbook.

16 -

Some of the contractionary effect from

lower exports would be absorbed by lower imports, so that net
exports would be only $9 billion lower.

In this simulation, we

held U.S. money growth to the baseline path.
While exports are seen as a crucial element in the
overall outlook, imports obviously are important too.

As shown

in the top panel of Chart 11, the quantity of non-oil imports is
forecast to rise only 2 percent from the fourth quarter of 1990
to the fourth quarter of 1991.

We expect the decline in the

dollar that has occurred to date to give a further boost to U.S.
activity by shifting demand away from imports toward domestic
production.

The slow growth of imports also reflects the

weakness of U.S. aggregate demand, and to that extent, of course,
cannot be said to boost domestic activity.

In 1992, as U.S.

demand picks up and the effects of the decline in the dollar wear
off, the quantity of non-oil imports is forecast to rise more
rapidly.
The quantity of oil imports, shown in the middle panel,
fell in the fourth quarter of last year, because of the decline
in activity, warm weather, and a shutdown of some refineries for
maintenance.
prices.

The value, of course, rose sharply with the jump in

A withdrawal from the strategic petroleum reserve will

restrain imports in the current quarter, after which the quantity
of oil imports is expected to grow over time as consumption
increases and as domestic production continues to trend down.
In nominal terms, as shown in the bottom left panel,
U.S. external balances are forecast to continue to improve over

-

the forecast period.

17 -

The current account -- the black bars -- is

forecast to improve more rapidly than the merchandise trade
account, reaching a deficit of only $33 billion in 1992.

The

faster improvement in the current account reflects, in part, a
further increase in net receipts for a variety of services.

The

relative improvement in the current account also reflects the
cash transfers the United States expects to receive from other
countries in connection with the financing of the war in the
Persian Gulf, which are counted in the current account but not in
GNP; these are assumed to equal $20 billion in both 1991 and
1992.
In real terms -- the bottom right panel -- we are

forecasting that exports of goods and services will grow more
rapidly than imports.

As a result, net exports

(in 1982 dollars)

will continue to improve, adding $29 billion to GNP (or nearly
3/4 percent) over the course of this year, and another $17
billion over the course of 1992.
Larry Slifman will continue our presentation.

- 18 -

Lawrence Slifman
February 5, 1991

CHART SHOW PRESENTATION -- GNP AND AN ECONOMIC UPTURN

Let me continue with the staff GNP projection and the question:
"What will bring about an economic upturn?"
Chart 12 highlights a key element in our assessment of the
outlook--that is, the inventory situation and the balance between
production and aggregate demand.

The upper panel shows real GNP--the

heavy line--and real final sales.

The area between the two lines is

inventory investment--with periods of liquidation indicated by the
shaded portions.

As can be seen, producers moved aggressively in the

fourth quarter to hold inventories in check, cutting output while final
sales were essentially flat.
had the desired effect.

These pre-emptive production adjustments

As shown in the bottom panel, the inventory-

sales ratio for all nonfarm businesses--already quite low by historical
standards--is estimated to have fallen further in the fourth quarter.
You can see from the insert panel that we expect final sales to
fall at about a 1-1/4 percent pace in the first quarter.

However, we

think that producers will continue to cut output even faster, thereby
pushing the inventory-sales ratio even lower.

With inventories

relatively lean, a firming in final sales beginning in the second
quarter should be translated promptly into higher production.

Indeed,

for a few quarters, we expect output to grow faster than sales as
producers swing from inventory liquidation to a modest rate of
accumulation.

- 19 -

Your ne::t chart highlights the sources of the upturn in final
sales that we expect will begin in the spring.

The lower portion of the

table shows contributions to real GNP growth--measured in percentage
points.

We project that real final sales--line 2--will account for 1.7

percentage points of the growth in real GNP during the second quarter.
As Larry just explained, foreign demand for U.S. goods should provide
important support to domestic production.

Among the components of

private domestic final purchases, lines 7 through 9, we are projecting a
resumption of consumption growth that is quite modest compared with
previous cyclical recoveries, and a halt to the slide in residential
construction activity.

Because of the critical role of consumption and

housing in our projected upturn, the next chart highlights some of the
elements that went into our thinking about these two sectors.
The sharp rise in oil prices and a heightened sense of
uncertainty in the aftermath of the invasion of Kuwait, combined with
rising joblessness and pervasive fears about recession and financial
fragility, dealt a blow late last year to consumer sentiment--the upper
left panel--and consumer spending, and likely will depress consumption
in the current quarter as well.

But consumer outlays, especially for

big-ticket items, had been subdued for some time prior to the Iraqi
invasion.

As shown in the upper right panel, demand pent up during the

long, deep 1982 recession led to an extraordinary surge in sales of
autos and light trucks in the mid-1980s.

Thus, as we have noted before,

the slowdown in sales that began in the second half of 1989 probably
represents, at least to an extent, a stock adjustment.

As shown in the

middle left panel, a similar pattern occurred for other types of durable

- 20 -

goods--VCR's, household furnishings, jewelry, and so forth--as spending
growth during the mid-1980s far exceeded real income gains (the middle
right panel).

Then, while consumers were catching their breath after

the 1980s spending spree and increasing their saving, real income in the
last part of 1990 took a hit from the oil price shock, further
depressing demand.
Looking forward, we expect a recovery in consumption to begin
sometime this spring, although we think it will be quite moderate, with
the saving rate remaining elevated.
several factors.

The pickup in spending reflects

Perhaps most important, the drop in consumer energy

prices since the November peak, which began to affect real income in
December, will boost real DPI further in the first half of 1991, giving
households the wherewithal to spend more.

In addition, with the assumed

ending of hostilities in the Gulf, we anticipate that some of the
uncertainties currently depressing consumer sentiment will be
eliminated, and household willingness to spend will rise.

Finally, with

spending having been depressed during 1990, we think households will
have some pent up desire to spend.
Another influence on the projected upturn is a bottoming out of
the housing market.

A key element in that projection is affordability.

As shown in the bottom panel, the declines in mortgage rates over the
past two years and the softness in house prices have combined to ease
the cash-flow burden of homeownership since mid-1989.

Although lower

house prices are a two-edged sword, we think that their positive
influence on affordability will outweigh their negative influence on
investment motives for homebuying.

In this regard, we view the recent

-

21 -

rise in sales of existing homes as suggesting that prices may have
reached levels acceptable to both potential buyers and sellers, which,
if correct, might signal a bottoming out of the real estate slump.
Nonetheless, housing clearly is a risky sector in our projection,
especially in light of the possibility of continued constraints on
builder financing.

One encouraging note, however, is that--despite

reports for more than a year now of cutbacks in loans for land
acquisition and development--a recent survey by the homebuilders
association suggests that builders still have an ample inventory of
finished and unfinished lots.
On balance, then, we expect the projected economic upturn in
the second quarter to be brought about by relatively strong growth of
exports, a resumption of growth in household spending, and an end to the
housing slide, accompanied by a swing in inventory investment.
Your next chart addresses the question, "Have we turned the
corner toward lower core inflation?"

One key element, of course, is the

behavior of wages--the subject of the upper panel.

In this chart, we

have split the employment cost index into two components--sales workers
(the striped bars) and other private industry workers

(the shaded bars).

The reason is that commissions are an important part of the compensation
of many sales workers.

Thus, changes in the ECI for sales workers

appear to be quite sensitive to changes in activity or unemployment,
while changes in compensation for non-sales workers appear more
sensitive to the level of activity or unemployment.

This was quite

clear in 1990, when the unemployment rate averaged 5-1/2 percent--about
equal to our point estimate of the natural rate; for the year as a

whole, compensation for non-sales workers rose at about the same pace as
in 1988 and 1989, while the ECI for sales workers slowed sharply as real
estate transactions were falling and other sales were sluggish.
With the unemployment rate projected to peak at nearly 6-1/2
percent in the second quarter, and then level off at about 6 percent
during 1992, we expect slack demand to put downward pressure on
compensation of non-sales workers over the course of the next two years.
During the first half of this year, compensation of sales workers is
projected to hold down the overall ECI; but as the economy begins to
recover, we expect rising commissions to restrain the deceleration in
total employment costs a bit.
The deceleration of wages, along with a relatively mild
expansion of activity that is not expected to create any bottlenecks,
shortages, or capacity constraints, leads us to project a slowing in the
core inflation rate--proxied in the bottom panel by CPI's excluding food
and energy.

Much of the slowing is in the services component, the

shaded bars, which had been accelerating through much of 1990.

Prices

of consumer commodities other than food and energy are projected to pick
up in 1991, in part because of this January's hike in excise taxes as
well as the passthrough of the lower value of the dollar to prices of
imported goods.

But an underlying deceleration becomes evident in the

latter part of this year and throughout 1992.
As I just indicated, the inflation projection depends
critically on our expectation that the economy will continue to have
some slack in resource utilization over the next two years.

The staff

report on the outlook for potential GNP that we sent to you last week

-

23 -

addresses the supply side of this issue in detail.

Chart 16 summarizes

the results of the report in the context of the latest Greenbook GNP
projection.

Our analysis suggests that the growth rate of potential GNP

averaged 2.6 percent during the 1980s, and that the pace probably has
slowed a bit recently.

Through the middle of the 1990s, we are

projecting potential to rise 2.3 percent per year.
As shown on line 3, part of the projected slowing between the
1980s and 1990s is simply a matter of demographics--there will be fewer
people reaching the age of 16.

More difficult to forecast is the

behavior of the participation rate (line 4)--especially in light of the
drop over the past year.

Sorting out the trend, cycle, and random

components of the recent numbers is hazardous at best, but it appears to
us that most of the shortfall reflects cyclical or random elements, and
we expect the underlying trend during the first half of the 1990s to
slow only by a tenth of a percentage point.

At the same time, we are

projecting a small pickup in the growth of labor productivity

(line 8).

Given the wide swings over the past three decades in the residual
component of productivity (line 15),

our forecast of trend productivity

also has a great deal of risk.
The bottom panel shows our estimates of the levels of actual
and potential GNP.

As explained in the report, our central forecast of

the projected level of potential is consistent with a 5.6 percent
natural rate of unemployment.
uncertainty.

This, too, has a wide band of

The shaded area takes into account some of our

uncertainties about both the current level and the projected growth rate
of potential.

In any event, you can see that even using the lower bound

- 24 -

of this uncertainty band, the level of real GNP is projected to remain
slightly below potential at the end of 1992.

This, of course, suggests

the possibility for further progress in reducing inflation in 1993.
Mike will now complete our presentation.

-

25 -

Michael J. Prell
February 5, 1991

CHART SHOW PRESENTATION -- CONCLUSION

The final chart presents the results of a "what if" experiment
that your action last week suggests may not be entirely fanciful.
Anticipating that there might be considerable skepticism about our
relatively rosy Greenbook projection for economic growth, we thought it
would be useful to offer you some idea of what it might take to achieve
a similar result if the economy were weaker, in terms of underlying
demands for goods and services at given interest rates.

In scenario 1,

we've assumed that the economy, in this sense, is one percent weaker in
1991 and 1992, and that, as a consequence, you ease policy in the near
term enough to overcome that greater weakness and to achieve the
Greenbook output level by late next year.

There are many interest rate

paths that might achieve this result; the one we ran through our
econometric model is shown in the bottom panel and has the funds rate
reaching 5 percent in the next couple of months and then moving back up
to 6-3/4 percent by the end of 1992, so as to avoid overshooting.
Of course, there is, I hope, at least the possibility that the
staff is correct in its more bullish view of aggregate demand.
we have concocted Scenario 2.

And so

Here we assume that we are right about

the underlying strength of the economy but that you either don't believe
us or feel it appropriate to take out some insurance.

You lower the

funds rate to 5 percent, only to realize around midyear that the economy
actually is as strong as we predicted and so you switch gears to
restrain aggregate demand enough to hold real GNP in late 1992 to the

- 26 -

Greenbook level.

The last line in the bottom panel shows that our model

says you would need to jack the funds rate up to around 8 percent by
early ne::t year in order to achieve that outcome.
Admittedly, these scenarios are quite arbitrary constructs, but
they do seem relevant in light of the differences between the staff and
FOMC forecasts that I presented earlier.

I hope that, in combination

with the model simulations presented in the Bluebook, they will at least
give you some rough indication of the sensitivity of the economy to your
policy decisions.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR) CLASS I-FOMC

Materialfor

Staff Presentationto the
FederalOpen Market Committee
February5, 1991

Chart 1

OUTLINE OF THE PRESENTATION

1. What are the FOMC projections?
2.

What has been assumed about the war and its budgetary
consequences?

3.

What about the credit crunch and other financial stresses?

4.

Where is the dollar headed?

5.

What might the oil market look like?

6.

What if foreign growth were disappointing?

7.

What will bring about an economic upturn?

8.

Have we turned the corner toward lower core inflation?

9.

How fast can the economy grow?

10.

What if the Fed were to ease substantially in the near term?

Chart 2

ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR 1991

THE STAFF PROJECTION
(Percent change, annual rate)
1991

1992
02

03

04

6.8

6.0

6.0

5.9

3.1

2.8

2.6

2.5

2.4

4.3

4.1

4.1

4.0

3.8

3.7

4.5

4.7

4.6

4.3

4.1

3.9

3.8

6.4

6.2

6.1

6.1

6.1

6.0

6.0

Q3

Q1

Q2

3.3

6.7

6.8

6.7

-1.5

2.8

3.1

CPI

3.4

3.8

CPI excluding food and energy

5.2

Unemployment rate 1

6.4

Nominal GNP
Real GNP

1. Percent.

Chart 3

REAL DEFENSE PURCHASES

Billions of 1982 dollars

This Greenbook

December Greenbook

1989

'

1990

1992

FEDERAL BUDGET OUTLOOK
Billions of dollars

FY1990

NIPA deficit

283

266

162

192

172

158

Ex deposit insurance

FY1992

220

Total deficit

FY1991

165

136

FISCAL IMPETUS

Percent of real federal purchases

Calendar Years

Stimulus
Restraint

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

Chart 4

FINANCIAL FLOWS*

Percent of GNP

Net funds raised by nonfinancial sectors
Depository credit

* Four-quarter moving average, adjusted for RTC.

YIELD SPREADS

Percent

6-month commercial paper less 6-month T-bill
Baa corporate bond less long-term T-bond

1962

1966

1970

1974

1978

1982

1986

1990

SMALL BUSINESS CREDIT CONDITIONS *

Percent

National total
New England

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

* Index from the NFIB survey. Credit harder to get minus easier to get.

1984

1986

1988

1990

Chart 5

CHANGES IN BOND RATINGS

INTEREST PAYMENTS TO CASH FLOW*

Percent

Number

Nonfinancial Corporations

Nonfinancial Corporations
Moody's

300

Downgrades
Downgrades

/
/
200

100

I

I

1984

I

0

1986

1988

1990

1984

1981

1987

1990

*Gross interest to cash flow including interest payments

LOAN DELINQUENCY RATES

Percent

DEBT-SERVICE BURDEN

Percent of DPI

Last observations, 90Q3

1963

1969

1975

1981

* Consumer loans overdue 30 days +. ABA series.
** Mortgages overdue 60 days +. MBA series.

1987

1963

1969

1975

1981

1987

Chart 6

THE DOLLAR AND THE INTEREST DIFFERENTIAL
Percent

Ratio scale, March 1973 = 100

Real long-term
interest differential*

Real long-term
90
Price-adjusted
dollar**

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

* Difference between rates on long-term U.S. government bonds and a weighted average of foreign G-10 long term government or public
authority bond rates, adjusted for expected inflation.
** Weighted average against foreign G-10 countries, adjusted by relative consumer prices.

Nominal Interest Rates
Percent

Nominal Dollar Exchange Rates
Percent change
6/90 to 2/1/91
Pound Sterling
Deutschemark
Canadian Dollar
Yen

Change
6/90 to 2/1/91
0.9
0.8
-1.5

9.10
8.19

-0.2
-0.3
-0.6

8.62
6.78
7.92

Three-month
Germany
Japan
U.S.
Long-term
Germany

-13
-13
-1
-14

S. Korea
Taiwan Dollar

Level
2/1/91

1
-1

Japan

U.S.

6.75

DOLLAREXCHANGE RATE: PAST AND PRESENT CYCLES

Index, peak=100

Maximum
125

115

Average
Present

Minimum

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Number of quarters from peak
Weighted average against foreign G-10 countries. Present and four previous cycles since 1969 are depicted. Peak of present cycle is
third quarter of 1990.

9

Chart 7

Petroleum and Products
OIL PRICES
Dollars per barrel

West Texas Intermediate*

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

* Spot prices through January 1991. Future prices February through December 1991.

OPEC CRUDE PRODUCTION*
(Million barrels per day)
1990-H1
Total
Saudi Arabia*
Kuwait*
Iraq
Other OPEC
*

23.5
5.7
2.0
3.0
12.8

1990-Q3

1990-Q4

1991

1992

21.7
6.5
0.7
1.4
13.2

23.1
8.3
0.1
0.4
14.3

22.3
8.5
0.0
0.6
13.3

24.1
6.9
1.0
3.0
13.3

OPEC Accord
(July)
22.5
5.4
1.5
3.1
12.5

Does not include natural gas liquids or lease condensates.
* Includes half of Neutral Zone production through July 1990. Beginning in August, all Neutral Zone production
is attributed to Saudi Arabia.

WORLD PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION
Million barrels per day

Production
Consumption (right bar)

1989

1990

* Excludes consumption and production consumed in current and former centrally-planned economies.

Chart 8

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION *

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION *

12-month percent change

CONSUMER PRICES *

12-month percent change

CONSUMER PRICES *
12-month percent change

12-month percent change

Canada and U.K.
France and Italy

1988

1989

1990

1988

1989

1990

ECONOMIC POLICY ABROAD
* Inflation has slowed in recent months, but concerns remain;
dispersion of growth has widened.
* Monetary policies will be cautious, but interest rates may decline as
inflation eases.
* Fiscal policy will be essentially neutral on average, with Germany an
important exception.

*Average using U.S. non-agricultural export weights, 1978-83.

Chart 9

REAL GNP: U.S. AND FOREIGN

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

Foreign GNP**
Percent change
Q4 to Q4

United States *
Foreign ** (right bar)

G-6
1989

1.3

1.9

1.8

2.6

1992
1991

2.8

1991

1990

3.2

1990

1989

Other

2.6

3.8

1992

CONSUMER PRICES: U.S. AND G-6 COUNTRIES **
4-quarter percent change
United States

Percent change
Q4 to Q4
G-6***
1989

4.8

4.6

1990

5.1

6.3

1991

4.4

3.9

1992

3.8

3.9

U.S.

G-6

1989

U.S.

1990

1992

REAL GNP IN G-6 COUNTRIES **

4-quarter percent change
6

4

Greenbook

Alternative forecast
1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

* Excludes drought effects.
* Average of industrial and developing countries using U.S. non-agricultural export weights, 1978-83.
** G-6 average using U.S. non-agricultural export weights, 1978-83.

1992

Chart 10

NON-AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS
Ratio scale, billions
of 1982 dollars, SAAR

Ratio scale, billions
of dollars, SAAR

Percent change
Q4 to Q4

Quantity
Quantity

1990 1991 1992
Value

Value
225

Price
1982$

1987

1988

1989

1990

AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS
Ratio scale, billions
of 1982 dollars, SAAR

1991

11

11

13

1

2

1

10

10

11

1992

Ratio scale, billions
of dollars, SAAR
Value

Percent change
Q4 to Q4

Quantity
Quantity

1990 1991 1992
Value

1989

1990

SHARE OF U.S. EXPORTS, 1990

1991

8

-3

8

7

1982$
1988

12

Price

1987

-6

-3

4

1

1992

ALTERNATIVE SCENARIO

Deviation from Greenbook,
1992-Q4

Billions of 1982$, SAAR
Exports of goods
Exports of services
Net exports
(goods and services)

* Estimated shares for 1990

Chart 11

NON-OIL IMPORTS
Ratio scale, billions
of 1982 dollars, SAAR

Ratio scale, billions
of dollars, SAAR

Percent change
Q4 to Q4
Value

-- 450

1990 1991 1992

400

Value

5

4

8

Price

2

2

1

1982$

3

2

7

350

300

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

OIL IMPORTS
Ratio scale,
millions barrels per day

Ratio scale,
billions of dollars

10

Quantity

Q4 Level
Price
MBD
($/barrel)

1989

17.67

8.2

1990

28.85

7.4

1991

21.00

8.5

1992

21.00

9.1

Value

I

I
1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

REAL NET EXPORTS

EXTERNAL DEFICITS
Billions of dollars, SAAR

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1987

1988

* Goods and services.

1989

Ratio scale, billions
of 1982 dollars, SAAR

1990

1991

1992

Chart 12

REAL OUTPUT AND SALES

Billions of 1982 dollars
4500

4400

4300

4200

Real GNP
4100

REAL FINAL SALES

Change, annual rate, percent
4000

Real Final Sales
3900

3800

1991

1992

3700

1986

1987

1989

3600

1990

INVENTORY-SALES RATIO*

Ratio
3.3

3.1

2.9

2.7
1969
Nonfarm, 1982 dollars.

1972

1975

1978

1981

1984

1987

1990

Chart 13

CONTRIBUTIONS TO REAL GNP GROWTH

1990

1991

Q4

Q1

Q2

H2

1992

Percent change, annual rate

1. Real GNP

-2.1

-1.5

2.8

3.1

2.6

Contribution, percentage points
2. REAL FINAL SALES

-. 1

-1.3

1.7

2.0

2.5

.4
1.3
.9

.4
1.4
1.0
2.1
1.4
.3
.4
-. 1
-. 3

3.
4.
5.

Net exports
Exports
Imports

2.2
1.1
-1.1

1.5
.0
-1.5

.5

6.
7.
8.
9.

Private domestic final purchases -3.3
Consumption
-2.1
Residential structures
-. 7
Business fixed investment
-. 6

-2.9
-1.0
-. 7
-1.2

.9

-. 6

1.6
1.2
.3
.1

.1
.2

.3
-. 3

-. 1
-. 3

1.1

1.1

10.
11.

Government
Defense

12. INVENTORY INVESTMENT

1.0
.9
-2.0

Note: Components may not sum to totals because of rounding.

-. 2

.5

.1

Chart 14

CONSUMER SENTIMENT

SALES OF AUTOS AND LIGHT TRUCKS
Millions of units

Index
140

Michigan SRC Survey
120

100

80

60

1981

1984

1987

1990

1981

PCE DURABLES, EX. MOTOR VEHICLES
Percent change, annual rate

1984

REAL DPI

1987

1990

Percent change, annual rate

12

9

6

3

0

1983-1988
avg.

1989

1990

1991

1983-1988
avg.

1989

1990

AVERAGE MONTHLY MORTGAGE PAYMENT FOR A NEW HOME

Percent of DPI

Jan.

1987
1987

1988
1988

1989

1989

1991

1990
1990

Chart 15

EMPLOYMENT COST INDEXES*

Percent change, annual rate
12

Private industry workers excluding sales

Sales workers

6

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

Compensation.

CIVILIAN UNEMPLOYMENT RATE

Quarterly average, percent
8

7

6

5

4

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

CONSUMER PRICE INDEXES

1992

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

8
Commodities, ex. food and energy
Services, ex. energy

2

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

Chart 16

SUPPLY-SIDE COMPONENTS OF GNP
Annual average growth rate
Projection

Long-term trends
1948-73

1973-79

1979-89

1. GNP

3.7
1.2

2.0

1.5

1.4
.1
.0

1.9
.8
-. 2

.4
.1

-. 4
.1

-. 7
.1

-. 1
-. 1

2.5

.6

.8
.2

.7
.0

1.5

1990-95

2.6

2.

1989-90

-. 1

3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.

LABOR INPUT
Working-age population
Labor force participation rate
Employment rate
Average weekly hours
Technical factors 1
LABOR PRODUCTIVITY 2

9.
0.

Private capital deepening
Public capital deepening

11.

TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY

2.
3.
4.
5.

1.0

.0
-. 1

1.1
.7
.0

.7
.0
.6

Energy
Research and development
Education and experience
Other

.0
.2
.4
.0

1.Technical factors include: the ratio of GNP to the output of the nonfarm business sector; the ratio of nonfarm
business employment to household employment; and rounding error.
2.Nonfarm business sector
n.a.Not applicable

ACTUAL AND POTENTIAL GNP

Billions of 1982 dollars
4700

2.6% potential
4500

2.3% potential
4300

4100

3900

3700

1985

1986

3500
1987

1988

1989

1990

1992

Chart 17

WHAT IF THE FED WERE TO EASE SUBSTANTIALLY IN THE NEAR TERM?

SCENARIO 1:

FOMC judges, correctly, that the economy is "one percent
weaker" than Greenbook suggests; it lowers fed funds rate
to achieve the same output level in late 1992 as in the
Greenbook.

SCENARIO 2:

FOMC judges, incorrectly, that economy is weaker than
Greenbook suggests; it eases now, but realizes by midyear
that the Greenbook was right and reverses course to avoid
seriously overshooting the Greenbook output path in 1992.

1991

1992

Greenbook

1.9

2.6

Scenario 1

1.6

2.9

Scenario 2

2.3

2.2

Greenbook

6.1

6.0

Scenario 1

6.2

6.0

Scenario 2

6.0

6.0

Greenbook

3.9

3.9

Scenario 1

3.9

3.8

Scenario 2

3.9

4.0

Real GNP, Q4/Q4

Unemployment rate, Q4

CPI, Q4/Q4

Q1

Q2

1991
03

Q4

Q1

Greenbook

6.75

6.75

6.75

6.75

6.75

6.75

6.75

6.75

Scenario 1

6.25

5.0

5.0

5.0

5.25

5.5

6.0

6.75

Scenario 2

6.25

5.0

6.25

7.5

8.0

7.75

7.25

6.75

Q2

1992
Q3

Q4

Federal funds rate

February 5, 1991

Long-run Ranges
Donald L. Kohn
The Committee today is asked to choose annual ranges for money
and debt consistent with its objectives for the economy and prices.

While

the ranges are wide, and movements in the aggregates are only one factor
taken into account in policy decisions, the choice of the ranges and the
accompanying report to Congress do give the Committee a chance to address
and explain its objectives and strategy.

In this regard, last July the

Committee chose on a provisional basis ranges for 1991 for M2 and debt
that were a half point below those for 1990, as another step toward the
lower money and credit growth thought likely to be needed to move toward
price stability; the M3 range was left at its 1990 specification, which
already had been reduced markedly to take account of the shrinkage of the
thrift industry.
The current economic situation, of course is somewhat different
from what the Committee expected to confront when it established these
provisional ranges in July.

At this time the Committee is faced with

balancing near-term concerns about the state of the economy, and longerterm desires to contain and reduce inflation.

Both of these objectives

may have particular implications for objectives for money and debt.

The

current state of the economy seems partly intertwined with credit conditions and associated money growth, while favorable long-term results on
inflation will depend on the force with which the economy expands following recession, and satisfactory results in this regard may in turn be

keyed by containing the associated rebound in growth of money and credit.
Although the economic circumstances may be different from those envisioned
seven months ago, it would appear that the ranges chosen provisionally in
July still are consistent with a policy strategy that both allows for
recovery and puts in place conditions that will produce modest deceleration in inflation.

That is, we see these ranges as supporting the

greenbook forecast of 6 percent growth in nominal GNP in 1991, given its
judgement of the strength of underlying demands for goods and services.
That consistency, however, also depends on the credit situation
that prevails in 1991; both the volume and channels of credit flows in
1991 are expected to be influenced by many of the same forces that operated in 1990, imparting an added degree of uncertainty to the relationships
of money and credit to spending.
With credit market developments so central to financial forecasts, it might be useful to start with consideration of the debt measure.
The debt of domestic nonfinancial sectors is expected to increase 6-1/2
percent in 1991, about half a point below its growth in 1990, and in the
middle of its provisional 4-1/2 to 8-1/2 percent range.

As in 1990, mea-

sured debt growth will be boosted relative to spending by the double
counting involved with the Treasury's financing of the asset acquisitions
of the RTC.

Even aside from RTC borrowing, federal government debt growth

is expected to accelerate this year, as the deficit is boosted by the
effects of the weak economy.

Credit supply restrictions as well as weak

demand are apparent in the sluggish expansion of the debt of private
domestic nonfederal sectors--at only 4-3/4 percent.

Such slow private

6 percent nominal GNP growth not only because of

debt growth can support

the prominence of government spending, but also because net exports contribute importantly to that growth, and demands from abroad do not need to
be supported by credit growth to domestic sectors.

Nominal private domes-

tic purchases are projected to increase a little less than 5 percent in
1991--a figure, I should note, that was incorrectly reported in the bluebook.
What credit growth does occur is expected again to be concentrated outside of depositories.

We are projecting thrift assets to drop sub-

stantially, on the assumption of additional funding for RTC and even
greater activity in resolving dead thrifts than last year.

Bank credit

also is projected to be weaker than in 1990 as a whole, extending the
basic trends of the second half of the year.

Banks are presumed to be

under continuing pressure to restrain asset growth as their capital is
eroded by loan losses and the cost of capital and other wholesale funding
sources remains elevated.

Consequently, total funding needs of depositor-

ies are damped, and M3 growth is projected at only 2 percent, about in
line with 1990, and in the lower half of its tentative range.

The recent

reduction in reserve requirements is not expected to have much effect on
M3:

In the context of higher FDIC premiums, lower reserve requirements

are not anticipated to boost overall asset growth very much or to cause
much substitution of CDs or other M3 sources for nondeposit sources, except possibly at U.S. branches and agencies of foreign banks, which need
not pay FDIC premiums.

The combined effects of sluggish domestic private

demand and borrowing relative to income, and of the continued reluctance

of banks and thrifts to fund that demand, produces an even larger increase
in M3 velocity in 1991 than in 1990.
As in 1990, sluggish depository credit also is expected to leave
its imprint on M2, along witn continued depositor caution.

M2 is project-

ed to pick up a little under the influence of stronger income growth and
the drop in interest rates in late 1990 and early 1991, including Friday's
policy actions, but only to 4-1/2 percent--the middle of its provisional
range.

This growth is expected to be sufficient to support nominal income

growth of 6 percent, producing a 1-1/2 percent rise in velocity.

Relative

to money demand model results, the staff forecast assumes a velocity shift
of nearly the same dimensions as for 1990 as a whole, though at a slower
rate than in the second half of the year.
The forecast of the velocity shift in 1991 implies that policy
should not seek M2 growth in line with historical relationships to the
expansion of income.

Looking back over last year, it seems clear that

there were forces operating in financial markets that were damping both M2
and GNP, but with greater effect on M2.

Weak M2 growth was partly a sig-

nal of unanticipated contemporaneous shortfalls in income, partly a leading indicator of future economic weakness to the extent it reflected the
unwillingness or inability of banks to extend credit, but also partly a
velocity shift that would not show through to GNP.

It will be difficult

again to sort out these effects as we go through 1991.

We are in unchart-

ed waters when we try to relate M2 to credit and spending under circumstances of an unprecedented restructuring of flows through depositories.
Nonetheless, deviations of M2 from expected paths can be sufficiently

large to swamp the uncertainties and justify a policy response because
they would be seen as giving some information about the credit process or
about concurrent spending.

Such quite likely was the case for the flat

pattern of M2 over the past four months.

And we should not rule out the

possibility that rapid M2 growth in a recovery also would require some
attention.

In such situations, validating unusually weak or strong money

by holding interest rates unchanged will produce, respectively, a tighter
or easier monetary policy than desired.
As noted, M2 growth at the middle of the range is consistent with
the staff greenbook forecast, so that the provisional range would leave
some room on either side for surprises in spending propensities or money
demand.

However, as Mike showed, your projections are for somewhat less

growth and inflation, and on average about 1-1/2 percentage points less
nominal GNP growth.

Assuming first, that your projections did not embody

major interest rate movements and second, that last Friday's events would
have roughly offsetting effects on your forecasts, it would appear that
your outlook is more consistent with M2 growth in the lower half of the
provisional range.

Thus, the provisional ranges would seem to imply con-

siderable scope for a somewhat easier policy than you had assumed, which
might be welcome if you were concerned about the sluggish real economy
projected.

Indeed, if you were concerned that the provisional ranges

themselves did not seem to call for sufficiently vigorous action to move
against the economic downturn, consideration might be given to raising the
ranges.

One option would be to retain the M2 and debt ranges used in

1990.

In effect, the long-term downtrend in monetary ranges would be

suspended in the interests of fighting recession.
On the other hand, your forecasts do have somewhat less inflation
on average than the staff forecast and, with a higher employment rate at
the end of 1991, have in place conditions for a more rapid deceleration in
the future.

If the Committee wished to emphasize an objective of emerging

from the current recession with greater progress toward price stability
and then to build on that progress in the subsequent expansion, a further
reduction in the ranges might be appropriate.

In the current cyclical

context, the requirement for achieving substantial, lasting reductions in
inflation will be first, to avoid exerting too much stimulus in the recession, and second, to tighten in a timely manner in the recovery.

A lower

floor on money ranges will help with the first requirement, since it implies that the Federal Reserve is willing to tolerate slow money growth in
the interval between easing in reserves markets and response in money and
later economic activity.

Timely tightening may be the more difficult

requirement to meet, since it may imply a firming of money market conditions while there is still an appreciable margin of slack and perhaps few,
if any, visible signs of accelerating inflation.

A lower ceiling on money

growth would help to meet this challenge because a pickup in money would
approach the upper limit of the range sooner, contributing to consideration of a prompter response in terms of tightening money market
conditions.

February 6, 1991
Short-Run Policy Briefing

Donald L. Kohn

With regard to the coming intermeeting period, the key issue
facing the Committee clearly is how aggressive to be in undertaking any
further easing moves.

The question has two dimensions in so far as the

directive under consideration--first, whether to ease further at this
time, and second, how to frame the instructions to the Desk about
responses to incoming data, that is, the tilt in the language governing
policy actions between meetings.

Most of the arguments on both sides

have already been voiced by various Committee members, but I thought it
might be useful as background for the discussion to review the bidding.
An aggressive posture would be characterized by a further
easing at this time, or at least by retaining the current asymmetrical
language in the directive so that appreciable further weakness in the
economy or in money and credit elicit prompt policy response.

The case

for such a posture is built on the sense that the risks and costs of a
long and deep contraction are greater than those of a strong rebound.
Both the risks and costs are seen as closely related to the health of
the financial system and its effect in the price and availability of
credit, as well as to the persistently gloomy attitudes of consumers and
businesses, both of which may continue to affect spending propensities.
In this environment, an unusually aggressive easing of policy
could be needed to improve confidence and to stimulate sufficient spending through channels that do not require the immediate participation of

depository institutions; these latter would include net exports induced
by a lower dollar and financed outside the country, and demand from
sectors that have access, directly or indirectly, to credit available at
the lower interest rates in securities markets.

Concerns about a tepid

response to previous easings are accentuated by the behavior of the
monetary aggregates, whose persistent weakness, despite persistent staff
forecasts of a pickup just around the corner, suggests continued shortIf,

falls spending and a lack of credit at depository intermediaries.

in fact, the economy does rebound with considerable vigor, policy can be
tightened at that time to head off any greater inflationary pressures.
A less aggressive policy stance might be characterized by no
change in policy at this meeting and symmetrical language for the
intermeeting adjustments; such language would not foreclose the possibility of policy actions to change money market conditions, only
require stronger evidence than under an asymmetrical directive.

The

case for such a directive rests on concerns about the lags in the
effects of the substantial policy easings already undertaken and about
the timeliness of any subsequent tightening should it be needed.

In

terms of short-term interest rates, the system has eased quite sharply
in the last few months, and the effects would not be expected to show up
in money for a little while, and in activity for a considerable period.
The dollar is at a low level, and under downward pressure.

Both bond

and stock markets seem to be anticipating an upturn; the failure of bond
yields to decline much on balance since the last FOMC meeting, and the
consequent sizable steepening of the yield curve, is as striking as the

upswing in the stock market--especially since volatility measures suggest a lessening of perceived risk over this interval.

The staff, once

again, is predicting a strengthening of M2 growth--to 4 percent in
February and 5 percent in March--but this time there are even a few
weeks of sizable increases in data already in hand for the second half
of January to support such a projection.
From this perspective, there is significant risk of overreacting to incoming data, which even under the greenbook's rosy scenario
would continue to show weakness before the effects of the recent easings
and lower oil prices take hold.

Problems in interpreting such data will

be particularly acute over coming months, if in accord with yesterday's
reports of CNN effects the data are distorted by the impacts of temporary disruptions to demand from the events of the Persian Gulf.
an insurance policy

While

against a shortfall in the economy can in theory be

resold if necessary through a subsequent tightening of policy, such
moves are always difficult, and will be made even more so this time by
the poor condition of financial institutions, which is likely to persist
for a time even in a rebounding economy.
If the Committee had concerns on both sides of this issue, one
way to encompass them would be to refrain from further easing at this
time, retain the asymmetrical language, but still temper to an extent
the response to incoming data.

No change in reserve pressures at this

meeting would recognize the extent of the policy actions over the last
intermeeting period and a desire to let them filter a bit more through
financial markets and get a better fix on the trajectory of the economy

and prices; asymmetrical language would acknowledge that the risks were
still seen on the downside, that the Committee wished to remain especially alert to evidence that a steep slide in activity was continuing,
and that as a consequence, if an action were taken before the next meeting, the Committee would expect it to be an easing move; but in light of
the size of the recent actions and the difficulty of sorting through
incoming data, the Committee might want to allow evidence of unexpected
weakness in the economy or shortfall in money to build for a time before
reacting.