View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in
the

offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

in Washington, D. C., on Tuesday, February 4, 1969, at 9:30 a.m.
PRESENT:

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Martin, Chairman
Hayes, Vice Chairman
Brimmer
Daane
Galusha
Hickman
Kimbrel
Maisel
Mitchell
Morris
Robertson
Sherrill

Messrs. Clay and Coldwell, Alternate Members of
the Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Heflin, Francis, and Swan, Presidents
of the Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond,
St. Louis, and San Francisco, respectively
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Sherman, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Kenyon, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Broida, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Molony, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Brill, Economist
Messrs. Axilrod, Hersey, Kareken, Partee,
Solomon, and Taylor, Associate
Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market
Account
Mr. Cardon, Assistant to the Board of
Governors
Messrs. Coyne and Nichols, Special
Assistants to the Board of Governors
Mr. Gramley, Adviser, Division of Research
and Statistics, Board of Governors

2/4/69
Mr. Wernick, Associate Adviser, Division
of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Mr. Keir, Assistant Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Mr. Bernard, Special Assistant, Office of
the Secretary, Board of Governors
Messrs. Hilkert and Helmer, First Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve
Banks of Philadelphia and Chicago,
respectively
Messrs. Eastburn, Parthemos, Baughman,
Jones, Tow, and Craven, Senior Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve
Banks of Philadelphia, Richmond,
Chicago, St. Louis, Kansas City, and
San Francisco, respectively
Messrs. Eisenmenger and Green, Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of Boston and Dallas, respectively
Mr. Garvy, Economic Adviser, Federal
Reserve Bank of New York
Messrs. Bodner and Geng, Assistant Vice
Presidents, Federal Reserve Bank of
New York
Miss Beekel, Assistant Vice President and
Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland
By unanimous vote, the minutes
of actions taken at the meeting of
the Federal Open Market Committee
held on January 14, 1969, were
approved.
The memorandum of discussion
for the meeting of the Federal Open
Market Committee held on January 14,
1969, was accepted.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of the

2/4/69

-3

System Open Market Account on foreign exchange market conditions
and on Open Market Account and Treasury operations in
currencies for the period January 14 through 29,

1969,

foreign
and a

supplemental report covering the period January 30 through
February 3, 1969.

Copies of these reports have been placed in

the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Bodner said
that the market price of gold had held at about $42.50 in recent
days with turnover generally moderate.

In the early part of the

period since the Committee's previous meeting the price had tended
to advance somewhat, reflecting the uncertainties over future
U.S. gold policy and the continued tensions in the Middle East.
Secretary Kennedy's statement on January 22 had been generally
received both at home and abroad as an unequivocal reaffirmation
of the U.S. commitment to the $35 official price, although there
had been skepticism expressed in some quarters which--not
surprisingly, of course--included Switzerland.

Under the initial

impact of the Secretary's statement the opening quotation for gold
on January 23 had been as low as $41.75 but the fixing that day
took place at $42.20.

Thereafter, trading volume had been

small--with prices moving up somewhat--until this week when there
had been a brief easing and some increase in volume.
the price was $42.47.

This morning

The situation remained one in which

-4

2/4/69

persistent industrial demand and the regular flow of gold to Asia
provided good demand while the explosive Middle East situation
encouraged many holders to retain their positions.

At the same

time, however, it should be noted that at the current price level
a sufficient supply was being made available from existing hoards
to meet the demand and there was no evidence of any current
selling by South Africa.
On the exchange markets, Mr. Bodner continued, the past
few weeks had been relatively calm, with sterling beginning to
show some seasonal strength.

The massive outflow of funds from

Germany had tapered off for a while, although in the past few days
there had been some further outflow.

With the relaxation of the

squeeze in the Euro-dollar market around the middle of January,
sterling began to firm and the Bank of England had been able to
take in a few dollars.

The spot rate for the pound reached a

level of about $2.39 by January 22 and held around that level
subsequently.

However, despite that advance in the rate, and

despite the gains made by the Bank of England earlier in the
period, the fact was that the market remained extremely skeptical
about the future of sterling and there was no significant demand.
Indeed, while the overseas sterling area countries had been
building up their balances, the balances of the non-sterling
countries--which typically had mirrored the state of confidencehad fallen further in recent weeks.

Forward discounts were

2/4/69

-5

narrower but remained at levels that discouraged covered inflows
of funds to the United Kingdom, while the lack of confidence
precluded any but very short-term uncovered inflows.

Thus,

although the British had been able in January to reduce the
volume of their overnight borrowing, they had not been able to
make any progress in reducing other commitments.

Figures for

January released today showed a net increase in British reserves
of only $12 million.

More fundamentally, with the trade deficit

remaining large and consumer spending high, the Bank of England
had felt it necessary to reemphasize to the banks the need to cut
their lending for non-essential purposes.
There had been no significant change in the underlying
position of the French franc in recent weeks, Mr. Bodner observed.
The French current-account deficit seemed quite clearly to be
reflected in the exchange losses of the Bank of France earlier in
the period, while further tightening in some aspects of the
exchange controls had once again produced some temporary inflow
of funds in recent days.

While liberalizing somewhat the rules

on the acquisition of forward cover by French importers, the Bank
of France had imposed further restraints on the French banks'
management of their foreign exchange positions--restraints which
were designed to force the deposit of surplus exchange holdings
with the Stabilization Fund.

Those measures had begun to produce

-6

2/4/69

some flow of funds into the Bank of France and the French had used
some of the money to reduce their commitments to the System.

At

the end of January the Bank of France repaid $112 million of their
swap drawings, bringing their commitments to the System down to
$293 million.
Mr. Bodner noted that Mr. Coombs had observed at the
previous meeting of the Committee that it was problematical how
long the massive outflow of funds from Germany could continue.
In fact, that outflow had tapered off in the last two weeks of
January.

From January 1 to January 22 the Germans had put out

about $1.3 million net, although since the latter date they had
been receiving about as much from maturing swaps as they had lost
through new spot sales or swaps.

The drain on German reserves had

actually reached the point at which they were running low on cash
and were becoming concerned about the continuation of the losses.
Consequently, the German Federal Bank raised its rates on swaps
to make them less attractive to the commercial banks, and at the
same time it permitted the spot rate to fall well below par.
Moreover, the German Federal Bank bought $30 million from the
System and $50 million from the U.S. Treasury.
As the Committee was aware, Mr. Bodner continued, the
System had used the marks acquired from the German Federal Bank
and additional marks purchased in the market to fully liquidate
System swap drawings; and yesterday the Treasury used the marks

-7

2/4/69

it had acquired from its dollar sale to Germany to pay off a
maturing foreign-currency note.

At month-end the swap maturities

of the German Federal Bank were running ahead of spot sales and
consequently they had begun to rebuild their dollar holdings.
The Germans had anticipated some further rebuilding of their
dollar position as a result of swap maturities this week and next.
In the last two days, however, when there had been some tightening
in the Euro-dollar market, the Germans had experienced large

losses--$130 million yesterday and $170 million today.
Mr. Bodner went on to say that perhaps the only other item
of significance in foreign exchange developments in the recent
period had been the easing in the Swiss franc as the Swiss banks
reestablished their Euro-dollar positions.

During the period the

Swiss National Bank had begun to intervene once again to supply
dollars to the market, and that outflow had provided an opportunity
for the System to begin covering its outstanding swap commitments
in Swiss francs.

So far the System had purchased a total of $100

million equivalent of Swiss francs from the Swiss National Bank
and would use those francs on February 6 to make an equivalent
reduction in System swap drawings.

In addition, arrangements had

now been completed for the pay-down of a further $100 million of
those commitments through the issue by the Treasury of $75 million
in foreign-currency securities and the sale of $25 million in gold.

2/4/69

-8

Those transactions also would be completed on February 6, at which
time the System's over-all indebtedness in Swiss francs would be
reduced from $320 million to $120 million.

The Swiss expected

further outflows of funds throughout February, and the Account
Management hoped to make further reductions in the swap position
in coming weeks.
Mr. Bodner said he would add a few words about developments
in the Euro-dollar market, to which he had already referred in
passing.

As the members knew, Euro-dollar rates had peaked just

prior to the previous meeting of the Committee.

From about

January 13 to January 21 there had been a progressive decline
which brought the three-month rate to 7-3/16 per cent while
shorter maturities fell even further--the call money rate, for
example, fell to 6-5/8 per cent from 8 per cent earlier in the
month.

That decline coincided with reduced--although still very

substantial--takings by U.S. banks, continued large outflows from
Germany, and smaller outflows from the Belgian, French, and Swiss
central banks.

In the latter part of January, however, rates

began moving up again.

That rise followed a firming in U.S.

interest rates at the same time that the outflow from Germany
tapered off, the Belgian franc strengthened, and both the French
and British began taking in funds.

In the past few days rates

had continued to advance, especially at the shorter end of the

2/4/69

-9

maturity range; at present, call money was at 7-1/2 per cent and
the three-month rate was 7-13/16 per cent.

U.S. bank branches

evidently were not significantly increasing their borrowings, but
they were bidding strongly simply to maintain their present
positions, while the Italians also were now bidding for funds.
In reply to a question by Mr. Brimmer, Mr. Bodner said it
was difficult to make any firm judgments about the availability of
Euro-dollars during the next month or two.

The Swiss probably

would be supplying funds to the market in February.

It had been

expected that the Germans would be withdrawing funds, but
developments during the past two days made that look less likely
and there might in fact be further outflows from Germany.

On the

whole, he thought the flows of Euro-dollars would be reduced from
the very large volume of the last four weeks.

With respect to

Euro-dollar rates, he certainly would not expect any significant
easing, and there might be some further firming.
Mr. Mitchell noted that U.S. bank liabilities to their
foreign branches had declined by about $1.4 billion in the last
three weeks of December, but had risen in January to a level
about $1.2 billion above the peak prior to the December run-off.
He asked whether Mr. Bodner thought it was likely that U.S. banks
would be able to acquire as much as an additional $1 billion of
Euro-dollars during the next month.

2/4/69

-10
Mr. Bodner replied that he would be surprised if the

volume of Euro-dollar inflows was that high.

While he was not

prepared to estimate the probable flows, it seemed clear to him
that U.S. banks would have to pay high rates simply to maintain
the present level of their Euro-dollar liabilities.
Mr. Brimmer asked whether the Swiss were likely to become
increasingly interested in supplying funds to the Euro-dollar
market if rates advanced there.
Mr. Bodner responded that they probably would become
somewhat more interested in that event.

However, he doubted that

any additions to the supplies of Euro-dollars from Switzerland
would be very large, since a substantial part of the funds
available to the Swiss for the purpose were already invested in
the Euro-dollar market.
Mr. Hickman asked whether increases in Euro-dollar
rates--resulting, say, from continuing demands by U.S. banks in
the face of reduced supplies--would not have important effects
on rates in domestic money markets in Europe.
Mr. Bodner replied affirmatively.

He noted that rising

Euro-dollar rates tend initially to push up the forward exchange
rates for other currencies.

In recent weeks, however, when the

German Federal Bank had been supplying forward marks relatively
cheaply there had been large outflows from Germany into Euro-dollars

2/4/69

-11

and fairly significant increases in German domestic interest rates.
Swiss rates, too, had risen.
By unanimous vote, the System
open market transactions in foreign
currencies during the period
January 14 through February 3,
1969, were approved, ratified, and
confirmed.
Mr. Bodner then noted that a System drawing--originally in
the amount of $200 million--on the Swiss National Bank would mature
for the first time on February 27.

The swap repayments that he had

mentioned earlier covered not only the $120 million in maturities
that Mr. Coombs had discussed at the last meeting but also $80
million of the drawing in question, so that the balance outstanding
on the latter was only $120 million.

As he had indicated, further

reduction in that commitment was expected before February 27, but
he would recommend renewal of the drawing for a second three-month
term if necessary.
Renewal of the System drawing
on the Swiss National Bank was noted
without objection.
Mr. Bodner observed that there were no other System swap
commitments falling due in the coming period, but swap drawings
by the Bank of France, the Bank of England, and the Belgian
National Bank would be maturing.

The Bank of France had three

drawings, totaling $260 million, that would mature for the first
time in the period February 18-20.

As he had indicated, the Bank

-12

2/4/69

of France had made further progress in reducing its swap commit
ments but, in the event that it requested renewal of the drawings
in question, he would recommend approval.

The Bank of England had

seven drawings, totaling $850 million, that would mature for the
first time in the period February 18 to March 11.

In addition,

there were two Bank of England drawings of $50 million each that
would mature for the second time on March 5 and March 10,
respectively.

He would recommend renewal of all nine drawings

if requested by the Bank of England.

Finally, on February 25 a

$2 million drawing by the National Bank of Belgium would mature
for the first time, and he would recommend renewal if requested
by the Belgians.
Renewal of the drawings by the
Bank of France, Bank of England, and
Belgian National Bank was noted
without objection.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System
Open Market Account covering domestic open market operations for
the period January 14 through 29, 1969, and a supplemental report
covering January 30 through February 3, 1969.

Copies of both

reports have been placed in the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Holmes
commented as follows:

2/4/69

-13

During the period since the Committee last met
market psychology was subjected to a variety of
influences. Early in the period there was a reaction
to the extreme gloom that prevailed in December, partly
reflecting the seasonal improvement in the position of
the money market banks and the greater availability of
Euro-dollars and partly reflecting an improvement in
market attitudes as prospects for the Vietnam peace
talks and the budget improved. But as the period
progressed, steady pressure on the banks through open
market operations and the continued CD attrition
resulted in greater market uncertainty. Fears of a
credit crunch appear to have subsided on balance, but
the period of relative euphoria apparent a week or so
ago appears also to have subsided. There again seems
to be a growing conviction in the market that the
Federal Reserve and the Treasury are determined to
resist inflation. There are many in the market who
now expect further action on the part of the System
as soon as the Treasury refunding is out of the way.
A fair degree of skepticism about the System's willing
ness to keep up the pressure exists, based in part on
misinterpretation of some of the money supply figures
that appeared earlier in January. Certainly, not many
of the large banks have felt constrained to make major
changes in their lending policies, although some spotty
tightening is apparent. The fact that banks have not
made further adjustments reflects in part the seasonal
absence of strong demand. As seasonal factors shift,
however, continuation of the present degree of System
pressure on the banking system will inevitably have an
effect on attitudes and on markets as the basic reserve
position of the money market banks is reversed in the
weeks ahead.
Interest rate developments largely reflected the
changes in market psychology over the period and special
supply-demand situations. Short-term interest rates
declined quite sharply early in the period, with the
three-month Treasury bill rate falling to as low as
6.04 per cent about the middle of the month. Any hope
that a continued decline would make it possible for the
banks to avoid continued CD attrition was soon dispelled,
however, with rates moving back to about the levels
prevailing at the time of the last meeting. In yester
day's regular auction of three- and six-month Treasury

2/4/69

-14-

bills, average rates of 6.25 and 6.36 per cent, respec
tively, were established, little changed from the rates
established in the auction just before the last meeting
of the Committee.
In the long-term markets there was, during the
period, some hopeful talk about interest rates peaking
out based on the new Administration's apparent concern
with inflation, budget and Vietnam developments, the
absence of large-scale commercial bank liquidation of
municipal securities, and an undercurrent of feeling
that the Federal Reserve would pull back from restraint
as soon as any signs of hesitation in the economy
appeared. By the close of the period, however, there
was a far less optimistic attitude prevalent. The
municipal market particularly showed signs of strain,
as commercial bank buying contracted. New issues
were poorly received despite new high yield levels.
Corporate bond yields also moved to record levels.
The improvement in the basic reserve position of
the major money market banks has been amply commented
on in the written reports to the Committee. In
addition to the usual seasonal movements of deposit
flows, the increased availability of Euro-dollars
appears to have been a major factor in this development.
The source of Euro-dollars appears to have been a
combination of the return to deficit in January of our
balance of payments and successful efforts by the German
Federal Bank to encourage a short-term capital outflow
from Germany. Both of these developments appear to have
had a widespread impact on the banking system as net
payments on balance of payments account moved deposits
from domestic to foreign accounts and as domestic
investors had to pay for the Treasury bills sold by the
German Federal Bank. These funds were then channeled
through the Euro-dollar market to the largest banks,
with an actual basic reserve surplus developing in New
York City banks last week and a record level of
borrowing by country banks. These twin developments
had the result of taking some of the pressure off the
Federal funds market as the most aggressive bidders had
less urgent needs and country banks made greater use of
the discount window. This in turn helps explain last
week's anomaly of the highest level of net borrowed
reserves in 16 years and a relatively comfortable
Federal funds market.

2/4/69

-15-

As far as open market operations are concerned, the
System maintained steady pressure and this involved the
absorption of the seasonal reflux of reserves to the
banking System. Extensive use of matched sale-purchase
agreements was made, and outright market sales of
Treasury bills provided a useful signal to the market
at a time when the Treasury bill rate was under downward
pressure. As you know, the credit proxy, adjusted for
Euro-dollars, appears to have declined at about a 2 per
cent rate in January, a somewhat weaker performance than
had been anticipated at the time of the last meeting.
Nonetheless, given the relatively comfortable position
of the money market and the continued market skepticism
about the System's intentions, no effort was made to
implement the proviso clause of the directive on the
side of somewhat less restraint. For February the
projection is for a further decline in the proxy, in
a zero to minus 3 per cent range after allowance for
the maintenance of Euro-dollar borrowings at the
expanded January level. As usual, it would be most
helpful to have the views of Committee members as to
their interpretation of the suggested proviso clause
of the directive.1/
Books on the Treasury refunding of $14.5 billion
Government securities maturing February 15 will close
tomorrow night. The announcement last Wednesday that
the Treasury would offer, in exchange for the maturing
securities, a 15-month 6-3/8 per cent note priced to
yield 6.42 per cent and a 6-1/4 per cent 7-year note
priced to yield 6.29 per cent failed to generate much
market enthusiasm. This was so despite the fact that
the Treasury is offering the highest return in over a
century and despite the judgment of most market
participants that the issues were fairly priced. While
the offering has not generated much market activity and
the maturing issues have little or no "rights" value,
many market observers expect that the high coupons will
draw a fair response from holders of the maturing
issues. Attrition, however, is expected to be consid
erably greater than the normal 10 per cent. The degree
of market uncertainty is likely to restrain dealer
participation in the financing and there appears to be

1/ The draft directive submitted by the staff for consideration
by the Committee is appended to this memorandum as Attachment A.

2/4/69

-16-

little danger of any speculative interest in the
issues. While any deepening of market uncertainty
could turn the financing quite sour, the outlook is
for a moderate extension of debt, with some observers
expecting subscriptions for the 7-year note to center
around $1 billion to $1-1/2 billion and attrition in
about the same range. On this basis I would expect to
enter subscriptions for about one-third of the System's
holdings of about $8-1/2 billion maturing securities
for the 7-year note and the balance for the 15-month
note, but we may get a more accurate picture of market
expectations by tomorrow.
There is little to add to my memorandum to the
Committee on the Treasury's cash and debt ceiling
problem.1/ Since then there has been an improvement
in the Treasury cash flow, which--if it is sustainedreduces the likelihood that the Treasury would have to
resort to the warehousing proposal. The improvement
is neither large enough nor sure enough, however, to
eliminate the Treasury's desire to have a back-stop
facility available.
I might make a final comment about the apparent
anomaly between the expected budget surpluses for
fiscal 1969 and 1970 and concern about the debt ceiling
between now and April and again in the autumn. The
consolidated budget surpluses arise from the sizable
surpluses of the trust funds. Such surpluses, unlike
an improvement in tax receipts relative to spending,
involve an increase in debt subject to ceiling as
the Treasury issues non-marketable debt to the trust
accounts. There is little question that a change in
the debt ceiling will be required, but the question
of timing of the Treasury approach to Congress remains
a complicated one.

1/ This memorandum, entitled "Treasury cash and debt ceiling
dilemma," and dated January 30, 1969, was distributed to the
Committee on that date. Two related memoranda were distributed
subsequently. These were from the Committee's General Counsel,
entitled "Legal aspects of proposals for assisting Treasury in
connection with cash and debt ceiling problems," and dated
January 31, 1969; and from the Secretariat, entitled "Additional
material re the Treasury debt ceiling problem," and dated
February 3, 1969. Copies of these memoranda have been placed in
the Committee's files.

-17

2/4/69

Mr. Daane asked whether the debt ceiling problem could be
relieved at this time by Treasury redemptions of special issues
held by the trust funds and investment of the proceeds in
outstanding marketable issues.
Mr. Holmes replied that the Treasury might be able to
redeem some special issues.

However, its flexibility in that

connection was quite limited at present since it faced the
problem of a low cash position in addition to that of the debt
ceiling, and investments by the trust funds in marketable issues
would, of course, reduce the Treasury's cash balance.

It might

be feasible, however, to use that approach in the fall to help
meet the debt ceiling problem anticipated then.
Mr. Brimmer asked whether there were any techniques
available to the desk to take explicit account of Euro-dollar
inflows, or whether the Desk necessarily looked only to the
total availability of reserves in its operations.

He was con

cerned that access to the Euro-dollar market might leave a few
large banks relatively free of the impact of monetary restraint.
Mr. Holmes replied that the Desk had no selective means
of influencing the behavior of banks that could draw funds from
the Euro-dollar market.

However, the Desk recognized that

Euro-dollar flows could have an important influence on total
bank credit, and they were taken into consideration in connection

2/4/69

-18

with the proviso clause of the directive.

As he had noted, the

recent relatively comfortable position of major money market banks
had resulted largely from seasonal influences which had tended to
redistribute reserves from country to money market banks, and
those seasonal influences were expected to be reversed soon.
By unanimous vote, the open
market transactions in Government
securities, agency obligations,
and bankers' acceptances during
the period January 14 through
February 3, 1969, were approved,
ratified, and confirmed.
The Chairman then called for the staff economic and
financial reports, supplementing the written reports, statistical
tables, and charts that had been distributed prior to the meeting.
Copies of these materials have been placed in the files of the
Committee.
Mr. Brill made the following introductory remarks for
today's staff presentation:
Our presentation this morning departs from precedent
in several respects. It has been the custom, you will
recall, for the staff to present a chart show at this
time of year describing and evaluating the economic
model underlying the Budget of the United States, and
outlining the monetary policy that would be consistent
with it. We will not be presenting such a chart show
today. First, because of the hassle on continuation
of the surtax, the budget model became available much
too late to permit the luxury of a full-fledged chart
show. But more importantly, there is serious question
in our mind as to whether the official model represents
either an appropriate target for monetary policy this

2/4/69

-19-

year or an accurate evaluation of the prospective strength
of upward price pressures. It is not the staff's function
to set policy targets, of course, but we would be somewhat
less than sensitive to the substance of discussion around
this table if we were to burden the Committee with policy
strategies leading to an economy in which a rapid rate of
inflation persists, just as it would be a waste of your
time and of staff resources for us to describe strategies
bound to produce a serious recession and a high rate of
unemployment.
But these boundaries leave a wide range of possible
price and employment trend combinations. The official
model describes an economy closer to one end of the range
of combinations; as we diagnose their model, price
pressures would remain strong, and unemployment would
edge up very slowly. As an alternative, the staff has
prepared another projection, using the same fiscal policy
assumptions as in the official model, but incorporating
a somewhat more restrictive monetary policy assumption
that--if our calculations are in the ball park--would
produce a gradual but persisting deceleration in prices,
at the cost of a somewhat faster rise to a somewhat
higher rate of unemployment.
Let me summarize the official model briefly; more
details--some of them imputed to the Council of Economic
Advisers by us--are provided in the materials distributed
this morning. Over the first and second quarters of this
year, the economy described in the official model does
not look a great deal different from our projection. The
pace of economic activity slows down markedly in this
period, with growth in real GNP dropping to a little more
than a 1 per cent annual rate in the spring quarter,
compared with the 1.5 per cent rate in our projection.
But the CEA model bounces back sharply after mid
year, spurred by the Federal pay raise, the end to the
retroactive payments on the surcharge, and a monetary
policy that is significantly easier than the one in
effect recently or that we are postulating by our
exercise. Perhaps the best index to the relative
degree of monetary restraint is the pattern of housing
starts embodied in a projection. In the CEA model,
housing starts flatten out in the first half of this
year, then begin to edge up, to average over 1.6 million
in the final quarter.
It is our rough calculation that this degree of
strength in the housing area would require credit market

2/4/69

-20

conditions to return to the levels prevailing last fall,
with bill rates perhaps centering around 5-1/2 per cent
and fund flows to thrift institutions--and to banks,
which were such an important element in the mortgage
picture last year--recovering significantly from the
recently reduced volume. And these conditions would
have to be achieved soon, so that the spring building
season could get under way relatively unimpaired.
The strength of housing in the Council's model,
and the renewed vigor in consumption, along with easier
credit conditions, induce businessmen to maintain a
fairly strong pace of inventory accumulation and new
plant investment in the third and fourth quarters.
Over all, the economy moves back to a 4 per cent real
growth rate, but happily, the recovery is not marred
by resurgence in inflation. The GNP price deflator,
which drops sharply over this half year, levels off at
a rate of about 3 per cent after mid-year.
Our reservations about this model rest on our
skepticism that two quarters of reduced real growth will
be enough to remove so much of the inflationary heat
stored up in an economy that has moved at an excessive
pace for so long. We, too, anticipate some easing in
the rate of price advance this spring, but far less than
does the CEA. And we doubt that the 3 per cent rate in
the deflator could be held if the economy bounces back
rapidly to a 4 per cent real growth rate. The rebound
in prices in the second half of 1967 is a reminder that
inflationary pressures break out swiftly in a period of
resurging demands that follows a brief period of price
stability achieved by pinching profit margins.
Critical in our projection is an objective of
limiting the potential rebound in activity in the second
half of the year, when the impact of fiscal restraint is
scheduled to be less severe than in the first half.
This, then, calls for monetary conditions in the first
half a significant order of magnitude more restrictive
than those underlying the CEA projection.
A more detailed description of the financial
conditions we have in mind will come later in our
presentation.
Mr. Partee then presented the following description of the
real economy which the staff saw emerging over the course of 1969
under the conditions of monetary restraint postulated.

2/4/69

-21-

Recent evidence continues to suggest some slowing
in the earlier excessive pace of economic expansion.
True, weekly sales reports indicate a snap-back in
retail trade from the depressed pre-Christmas level,
but this had been anticipated. Perhaps more importantly,
unit sales of domestic autos in January declined further,
and scattered announcements of production cutbacks in
this and some other consumer lines have begun to appear.
Though complete figures are not yet available, the
December inventory increase apparently was very large;
taking this in conjunction with a downward drift in the
real volume of sales and a leveling in manufacturers'
new orders, it appears likely that efforts to adjust
inventories will tend increasingly to slow production
in the months ahead.
Accordingly, our GNP projection continues to call
for further reduction in over-all economic expansion
during the first and second quarters. The most important
factor in this cooling off, as in earlier projections, is
an expected leveling off and then decline in inventory
accumulation and a marked shift in the budget into
substantial surplus. Final sales should continue to
expand at about the reduced $14 billion fourth-quarter
rate, reflecting some rebound in consumer spending from
the exceptionally low fourth-quarter gain, continued
though diminishing strength in business investment, and
the topping out of housing starts in the current quarter.
Real growth in the economy is expected to drop more
sharply than growth in dollar expenditures, given the
probability of continued sizable price increases, and
by the second quarter is expected to be down to a
1-1/2 per cent annual rate.
For the last half of the year, the course of GNP
that we have projected depends importantly on the
assumption of continuing and increasingly effective
monetary restraint. Around mid-year, the impact of
fiscal policy will become more stimulative, and could
well launch the economy on an accelerated uptrend again
unless the forces of expansion are contained by monetary
policy. The offsets that we see are the possibilities
of inducing a decline in residential construction, a
tapering off in business fixed investment outlays, and
a reduction in inventory accumulation to very moderate
rates. Given sufficient restraint, we calculate that
GNP growth might be held to around $13 billion in each

2/4/69

-22-

of the last two quarters, with real growth tending
moderately upward as inflationary pressures diminish.
This GNP outcome assumes that the surcharge will
be maintained at least through calendar 1969. But
even so, fiscal restraint will diminish abruptly after
mid-year. The bulk of the rise in Federal expenditures
in the third quarter is due to increases in military
and civilian pay, estimated at $2.8 billion at an
annual rate. Excluding the pay raise, defense outlays
are expected to continue on a plateau, with reductions
in Vietnam spending offset by increases on other
military programs. Nondefense expenditures also rise
somewhat more rapidly in the last half of the year
because of the removal of some budget controls and
a step-up in the growth of transfer payments and
grants-in-aid to States.
In contrast to the somewhat faster rise in Federal
expenditures shown in the Budget for the last half of
the year, we expect receipts to stay on a plateau for
several quarters, even though the surcharge is maintained.
This reflects the ending of retroactive payments, together
with the projected slowdown in personal income and
corporate profits. Consequently, the NIA budget, which
is expected to show a sharp spurt toward surplus in the
first half of the year, should move to a small deficit
in the second.
The impact of the surtax on disposable income was
appreciable in the last half of 1968. Gains in income
should continue to be limited in the first half of
this year as a result of higher tax payments and the
anticipated slowing in economic growth. Therefore,
we expect that growth in consumer expenditures will
continue relatively moderate, despite the prospect of
some rebound this quarter. The rise that we have
projected in consumer expenditures would likely require
a decline in the saving rate to a 6.2 per cent average
in the first half, well below the fourth-quarterrate.
A drop of this magnitude does not seem unreasonable,
assuming that the fourth-quarter rise in the saving
rate was due mainly to special factors--such as the
flu epidemic--and that the saving rate will fall in

keeping with the slower growth in disposable income.
In the third quarter of 1969, however, the
projected spurt in disposable income provides the
potential for a renewal of strong consumer buying. To
some extent, the abrupt upward adjustment in income

2/4/69

-23-

should be neutralized by a rebound in the saving rate,
but we are also depending importantly on the success
of restrictive monetary policy in altering business
expectations and spending decisions. If this can be
accomplished, slower growth of nonconsumption demands
should act to dampen aggregate demand and to offset
the latent strength in consumer markets.
Higher mortgage interest rates, a reduction in
the flow of loanable funds through banks and other
depository institutions, and an anticipated curtailment
in the volume of new mortgage commitments should bring
down housing starts before too long. Perhaps the drop
in December was a harbinger of things to come, but we
are inclined, as of now, to regard it as a temporary
dip. In fact, we are projecting a modest further
increase in starts in the first quarter to an annual
rate of 1.6 million. By the second quarter, however,
starts are expected to be trending down, and a continued
fall-off is projected in the second half, to an annual
rate averaging 1.35 million. The decline projected is
much smaller than in 1966, when the financial crunch
reduced housing starts by a third. But given the strong
underlying demands for housing, the pronounced swing in
emphasis to apartment construction and the very low
rental vacancy picture, it will require substantial
pressure on mortgage markets even to bring about a
decline of the size projected. Residential construction
expenditures, of course, will follow a similar pattern,
although the drop in dollar outlays will lag behind and
be less sharp than that in starts.
The current surge of investment in plant and equip
ment in the face of a relatively low rate of capacity
utilization would appear to reflect considerable business
optimism about the course of the economy in the near term.
Expectations of furture growth in sales, concern about
rapidly rising prices, and the need to offset some of the
increasing pressures from labor costs--all combine to
support a continued uptrend in investment outlays. A
year-end survey of businessmen's anticipations indicates
that they had not begun to make changes in their spending
decisions, but this did not yet reflect reactions to the
recent shift toward tighter money. Once the uptrend in
production flattens out, declining capacity utilization
rates and lower profit margins, together with credit
restraint, should tend to dampen optimism. Therefore,

2/4/69

-24-

we anticipate a marked slowing in the plant and equipment
surge by about mid-year. Although expenditures are
projected to rise 10 per cent for the year as a whole,
there is not much further dollar growth--and probably
some decline in real terms--beyond the first quarter.
We are also optimistic about the prospects for
cooling off investment in inventories, given our
assumptions about holding growth of final demands in
check. We should get some help here from the imbalances
which already have developed between output and consump
tion. But exactly when accumulating stocks will begin
to outrun businessmen's confidence in the prospects for
higher sales and further price increases is problematical.
The easing of sales in the fourth quarter may have laid
the base for a questioning of earlier rosy forecasts, but
production so far seems to be continuing at a brisk pace
in most sectors, and our projection calls for inventory
accumulation in the current quarter at close to the
relatively high fourth-quarter rate. By early spring,
however, we think that downward production adjustments
to temper the inventory buildup should become more
general. With only moderate further growth in demands
anticipated in the second half, as well as the greater
cost and difficulty of holding large stocks when funds
are tight, the rate of inventory accumulation is
projected to decline somewhat further.
As growth of real output moderates over the quarters
ahead, the pressure on both physical and manpower resources
should gradually abate. The rate of capacity utilization
in manufacturing is expected to fall to not much more than
80 per cent by the end of the year, reflecting both the
slowing of growth in industrial production and continuing
large additions to manufacturing capacity. At the same
time, employment gains are likely to fall short of net
additions to the labor force in 1969. The adjustment is
expected to occur mainly in manufacturing, where cutbacks
in workweeks are likely to be followed by hiring freezes
and layoffs, once it becomes clear that prospects for
further growth in product demand are not so ebullient.
The uptrend in employment in nonindustrial sectors will
undoubtedly persist, but probably at a slower pace than
in the last several years. As a result, the unemployment
rate is projected to rise gradually from below 3-1/2 per
cent in the fourth quarter of 1968 to about 4-1/4 per
cent by the last quarter of 1969.

-25-

2/4/69

The upward pressure on wage levels would abate
somewhat in 1969 if this projection is realized, as
labor markets ease. Key factors here include a sharp
reduction in the number of workers covered under
collective bargaining agreements up for renegotiation
this year, the smaller second- and third-year wage
increases under earlier settlements, and the smaller
and less pervasive increase in the minimum wage scheduled
for this year. However, the effect on costs is likely
to be offset in large part by a slowing in productivity
gains as output growth slackens. Thus, the increase in
unit labor costs is projected to continue at close to
the recent 4 per cent rate during the first half of
1969, then edging down to around a 3 per cent rate of
increase by the fourth quarter as demands moderate.
With labor and other costs continuing to climb and
business demands very strong, industrial prices have been
moving up at a fast pace. But if the slowing in growth
in the economy shown in our projections is achieved,
then the rise in industrial prices should also slow,
especially in the latter part of the year after upward
wage pressures have begun to ease and business
expectations and spending plans have lost some of their
steam. The sharp consumer price gains witnessed during
most of last year also seem likely to moderate in 1969.
Prospects are for some slowing in consumer product price
advances in response to smaller increases in industrial
prices, although service prices seem certain to continue
climbing at a fast pace--around a 6 per cent annual
rate--for some time to come.
On balance, if we can continue to make headway in
slowing excessive rates of expansion in GNP, the rise
in the over-all price deflator might be expected to
diminish. We are hoping for a steady downward progres
sion in the deflator, allowing for the third-quarter
Federal pay raise, to something less than 3 per cent
by the end of 1969.
Mr. Brill continued the presentation with a description of
the financial market conditions and the policy assumptions which
the staff felt to be consistent with the projections for the real
economy, as follows:

2/4/69

-26-

The nonfinancial economy just described by Mr. Partee
is one in which, hopefully at least, stabilization policies
succeed in cooling off inflationary expectations relatively
soon, with fiscal restraint biting into the economy in this
half year, increasingly reinforced by a degree of monetary
restraint which prevents too fast a rebound in the economy
in the second half. Accomplishing all this will not be easy,
given the length of time we have been running with over
heated conditions, and given the technical problems involved
in maintaining the appropriate degree of financial restraint
this spring.
We are currently experiencing a substantial swing in
Federal borrowing requirements--from an annual borrowing
rate of over $15 billion in the last half of 1968 to debt
repayment at a $2 billion annual rate this half year. A
large part of this change reflects the movement of the
budget into surplus, but movements in the Treasury's
cash balance also are involved. The big increase in
Treasury cash in the last half of 1968 is not expected
to be repeated.
Repayment of Treasury debt will be exerting downward
pressures on short-term market rates, especially after
mid-March, and monetary policy will have to lean against
these pressures if we are to reduce the public's incentives
to switch back into bank deposits--especially CD's; this
is essential to success in keeping down the rate of bank
credit growth. Private credit expansion is also expected
to recede a little in the first half--but this is a
reflection partly of the assumed effects of monetary
restraint in reducing the growth rate of mortgage borrow
ing at banks and the volume of State and local government
security issues. By the second half, we expect a slowing
in the pace of economic activity to reduce private credit
expansion further, but Federal borrowing should then be
increasing enough to bring the total of funds raised up
a little.
The projected effects of monetary restraint on private
credit expansion include a decline in total borrowing by
businesses and households taken together, despite continued
high needs for credit. For example, even though the rate
of inventory investment is expected to decline, business
needs for external financing will be sustained in the
first half by large tax payments and rising plant out
lays at a time when profits are being pinched. And
consumer demands for housing credit should remain intense.

2/4/69

-27-

But the very essence of monetary restraint is to
prevent some of these credit demands from being satisfied.
Given the degree of restraint assumed, businesses and
consumers should have to dig further into their liquid
assets to realize spending plans, and--more importantlyto trim these plans in areas heavily dependent on credit
availability. The ratio of borrowing to net investment,
in our projection, falls below 90 per cent during the
current half year, the lowest we have seen since the
last half of 1966. The ratio then levels off in the
second half, with a further decline in borrowing
paralleling a reduction in net investment.
It would take a taut policy to obtain these results,
given the underlying strength of expansive forces in the
private sector, particularly in the second half of the
year when the impact of fiscal restraint wanes. Trans
lating our target GNP projection into financial flows
and interest rates, we find that it would involve
limiting bank credit growth to an annual rate averaging
about 5-1/2 per cent from March onward, following an
expected slight contraction in the credit proxy in
January and February taken together. These projected
growth rates of bank credit would mean that the banking
system would be supplying only about one-fifth of total
funds raised in the first half of this year--and only
a little more in the second.
While this policy would properly be characterized
as taut, it is not one that requires additional pressure
by the System beyond that being exerted now. On the
contrary, CD runoff is now so rapid--the decline was
nearly $2 billion in January and we are projecting another
$1-1/4 billion or so in February--that unless something
is done soon to moderate the CD outflow, we could find
ourselves in another 1966-style crunch.
Among the hazards of going too far is the possibility
that a crunch and its immediate aftermath would be seized
on as an excuse for not extending the surcharge. Extension
of the surcharge is not, to my mind, in the bag; the new
Administration's endorsement of it has been lukewarm,
and it is hard to detect much enthusiasm for it in the
halls of Congress. But just because it is not in the
bag, we dare not ease up too soon or too much.
Given the dangers of overdoing restraint, but also
the dangers of failing to get enough, it seems to us that
the appropriate policy would be one of firm, steady, and

2/4/69

-28

consistent pressure on the banking system, avoiding either
any sudden jamming on of the brakes or any unintentional
easing up. There are a number of packages of policy
measures which might accomplish this. Intensifying
restraint to raise short-term rates further--accompanied
by an increase in Regulation Q ceilings to moderate the
CD hemorrhage--would be one combination worth considering.
Such a combination could have unwanted side effects,
however; the boost this would give to short-term interest
rates could have a more-than-desirable impact on thrift
institutions. Moreover, many in the financial community
mistakenly regard an increase in ceiling rates as an
easing, rather than a tightening action.
Perhaps a safer package is a combination of open
market operations and/or reserve requirement changes
aimed at keeping bill rates averaging close to but a
shade below present CD ceiling rates.
What we are assuming in this regard is bill rates
a shade below the 6 per cent ceiling on 3-6 month CD's.
Somewhere within the projected range, we estimate, the
attrition rate on CD's should decline to around $250
million a month, or thereabouts. If such a decline
continued for an extended period, the large banks would
find themselves forced to stiffen lending policies as
well as to sell liquid assets. But the rate of decline
we are projecting would be much less than in January--or
that projected for February at existing rate levels--and
it would not seem large enough to generate panicky
reactions.
Of course, bill rates would have to come down a
little from current levels to get this outcome, but the
System would not have to take overt action to get them
there. As I noted earlier, the problem this spring will
probably not be that of holding short rates down, but of
keeping them from falling too far. What the System
would need to do, once the present even-keel period is
over, is to lean against the wind just enough to keep
three-month bill rates from falling below the projected
level during a period of large Federal debt repayment.
Perhaps, at that time, reserve absorption through a
reserve requirement increase would combine desirable
flow and psychological impacts, but additional actions
might be needed to stem too large or too rapid declines
in the short-term interest rate complex.
There are obvious pitfalls in this course of action.
The response to fluctuations in the spread between market

2/4/69

-29-

rates and CD ceilings is neither smooth nor easily
predictable; at times a shade of difference can trigger
large inflows to or outflows from banks. We would have
to be prepared to vary the intensity of restraint on
bank reserve positions rapidly to keep the degree of
tautness needed. There will be misses, of course, but
if the general direction of policy is maintained, and
increasingly appreciated by the market, the effects
should be observable in all credit markets.
For example, we would expect this policy to push
up key long-term rates. The intensification of loan
rationing at banks is expected to force businesses
increasingly into the bond and commercial paper markets,
and thus lead to a rise of 1/4 of a percentage point
or more in the corporate new issue rate. For mortgages,
the strength of underlying housing demands pressing
against a limited supply of funds is likely to produce
mortgage rates shading upward from 8 per cent. At these
levels, credit costs as well as availability should help
to curb spending--not everyone, presumably, expects the
current pace of inflation to last for the next 25 years.
The reduction in mortgage credit availability will
come partly from reduced inflows to the nonbank
intermediaries. A credit policy as stringent as that
recommended will not leave the nonbank intermediaries
untouched, even though bill rates do decline a little
from current levels. Inflows to these institutions
were curbed in December and January, and we think they
will stay at the reduced volume. The projected growth
rates--around 5 per cent--are only a little above the
amounts that result from interest crediting. With
essentially no new money flowing in, these institutions
will have to cut their new mortgage commitments, more
likely sooner than later. The mortgage market will also
feel the pressure arising from the curtailment of fund
availability from commercial banks.
In the banking system, the effect of restraint is
likely to show up mainly in time deposits rather than in
demand balances and the money stock. For time deposits,
the projected descent from the high growth rate in the
second half of 1968 is steep indeed. Much of it relates
to the decline in CD's discussed earlier. For household
deposits, we are projecting a decline to about a 9 per
cent annual growth rate. This is less than the rate in
the latter half of 1968, when market rates averaged

2/4/69

-30

lower than those projected, and seems consistent with
rates of growth that appear to have occurred during
January.
We do expect, however, some slowing in the rate
of expansion in the money stock--in part because the
interest rate levels projected will help to induce some
further economization of cash, but also because GNP
growth (and hence transactions demand) is projected to
moderate. Our projected GNP growth path and interest
rate assumptions are probably consistent with an
expansion of the money stock at roughly a 5 per cent
annual rate during the first half of the year, and at
about a 4 per cent rate during the second.
To summarize, the monetary restraint pictured here
is substantial, particularly in light of the downward
rate pressures expected to emerge in money markets this
spring, although it stops short of putting the banking
system through the wringer. By keeping banks alive but
on a short tether, it would prevent a rapid buildup in
liquidity this spring that could fuel too vigorous a
rebound in economic activity after mid-year. In holding
down the rate of expansion below potential for several
quarters, it would provide time for some of the factors
tending to cool off price pressures to work. It is a
dangerous course, for a slowing economy can stall, and
we will have to be especially alert to any signs that
this may be developing. Nevertheless, it seems to us
that the risk is worth taking, for both domestic and
international reasons.
Mr. Hersey concluded the presentation with a discussion of
the implications of the projected nonfinancial and financial
developments for the balance of payments, as follows:
The U.S. balance of payments in 1969 looks tolerable,
as Mr. Solomon said here three weeks ago, "in the sense
that the U.S. balance of payments itself is unlikely
to induce unrest in exchange or gold markets or large
foreign purchases of gold from the United States." What
we want to give you now is first, an outline of one
possible structure of the 1969 balance of payments, and
second, a sense of the precariousness of its tolerable
ness. Certainly we are very far from anything that could

2/4/69

-31

be called a reasonable equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.
I shall try to spell out explicitly a number of
relevant assumptions as we go on. The first assumption,
which is contained in the domestic GNP projection, is
that there will be a gradual dissipation of the present
widespread expectations of inflation in the United
States and a gradual slowing of the inflation itself.
So far as the balance of payments is concerned, the
lasting payoff via price relationships comes only later.
Statistical indexes of export unit values for the United
States, Germany, and Japan clearly illustrate the need
for making a new start toward checking the deterioration
that has been going on since 1965 in our costs and prices
compared with those of some of our dynamic rivals in
world trade. Of course there is no hope of rolling
prices back.
Over the past several years U.S. nonagricultural
exports have risen about in line with total world
exports of manufactures, and our percentage share has
not changed significantly. This performance is
creditable so far as it goes, though in the light of
U.S. propensities to import goods and invest abroad it
is grossly inadequate. Our second main assumption today
is that continental European economic activity will
continue to rise strongly this year, helping to ensure
an advance in the value of U.S. merchandise exports by
8-1/2 per cent--nearly $3 billion annual rate--from the
second half of last year to the second half of 1969.
Our third major assumption relates to imports,
and has two parts. First, the underlying trend of
U.S. imports--a major cause of the world payments
disequilibrium--will remain strongly upward, for this
can be modified only slowly by cost and price develop
ments. Second, last year's swing above trend will be
followed by a dip below trend this year, as happened in
the 1967 mini-recession. Imports of materials may
decline, but we are not projecting an absolute decline
in the total in 1969, only a slowing of the increase to
3 per cent between second half-years, or about $1 billion
annual rate. For the year's trade surplus we project
something under $2 billion in 1969, compared with about
$100 million last year.
When we add in flows of services, investment income,
and military expenditures abroad, net exports of goods
and services may be over $4 billion this year, compared

2/4/69

-32-

with $2.1 billion in the year 1968 and a $2.3 billion
rate in the second half. High U.S. interest rates will
enlarge the rise in interest payments to foreigners,
offsetting much of the gain in income receipts. While
growth in payments for transportation may be below
normal in a year of slow import expansion, and while a
renewed acceleration in receipts from foreign travel in
the United States may occur, these and other services
will add little on balance to the improvement in net
exports. As for military expenditures abroad, they
are projected as leveling off now, and then dipping
slightly later this year, but on the other side of the
account military export sales also are passing their
peak.
Outflows of U.S. private capital are projected for
1969 at about the rate of the second half of 1968. Here
we have several additional assumptions. We assume that
the direct investment control program will remain in
effect, preventing corporations from retiring any
significant part of the foreign debts created in recent
years to finance direct investment. We assume that the
interest equalization tax will be renewed with a tax rate
high enough to restrain unregulated U.S. investors from
large-scale buying of the American company Euro-bonds and
convertible debentures that are subject to I.E.T. or of
outstanding European securities, as well as to prevent new
issues here of foreign securities other than the exempted
issues of Canada, Israel, international institutions, and
a scattering of others. And we assume that the VFCR will
remain in effect. The I.E.T. and the two control programs,
backing up the general credit restraint that is needed to
bring inflation under control, will effectually prevent a
resumption of the trends shown in earlier years toward
much greater outflows of U.S. private capital.
For foreign private capital, we project an inflow
next year of $2 billion, compared with nearly a $5 billion
rate in the second half of last year and about $4 billion
in the full year 1968. These figures do not include
Euro-bond issues to the extent the proceeds are used for
direct investment or otherwise held abroad, nor do they
include the flow of liquid funds to the United States
through commercial banks abroad.
Before explaining these figures, I should mention
our final major assumption, that long-term interest rates
in Germany will not decline further next year, since the

2/4/69

-33

German Federal Bank will not inject into the German
banking system the liquidity that would be required to
over-balance the prospective forces of demand and supply
in German Financial markets. On the other hand, we are
not projecting any such rapid tightening of the German
financial system as occurred in 1965 and 1966. German
public authority bond yields are now moderately above
6 per cent, while U.S. Government long-term bond yields
are somewhat below 6 per cent. We should bear in mind,
however, that general levels of interest rates for
business borrowers here are higher relative to U.S.
Government bond yields than is the case for corresponding
levels in Europe relative to German public authority bond
yields. To some extent, there have been rate pressures
encouraging U.S. businesses to obtain credit from European
businesses and banks; such pressures may continue, but we
assume they will not become stronger in 1969.
The projected shrinkage in foreign capital inflows
is explained mainly by factors other than interest rates.
First, over half of last year's $4 billion inflow was to
acquire U.S. stocks and to make direct investments here,
and it seems reasonable, or at least prudent, to suppose
that there may be a pause this year after such a tremen
dous surge of equity buying. Second, nearly $1-1/2
billion of last year's inflow was in such miscellaneous
accounts as commercial credit, advance payments for
civilian and military aircraft, bank loans to U.S.
companies, and security issues abroad to the extent that
proceeds were brought back to the United States by the
issuers. The inflow in these miscellaneous accounts
should be much smaller in 1969, partly because aircraft
deliveries are catching up, but mainly because last
year's borrowings abroad built up a large mass of target
leeway under the Commerce Department controls, which
companies will not want to expand much further and may,
on balance, be using up.
Our projections for 1969 add up to a balance of
$3 billion to be covered by liquid liabilities to
commercial banks abroad and by official reserve trans
actions. Last year the corresponding figure was about
$2 billion and that was more than covered by $3-1/2
billion of liquid funds from U.S. bank branches and
other commercial banks abroad, leaving a surplus on the
official settlements basis. This year we have already
seen a net inflow through bank branches and foreign

2/4/69

-34

banks of about $2 billion in January. We believe that
further growth of this borrowing this year will be
severely limited by high cost of fresh supplies of
foreign funds to the Euro-dollar market, in the absence
of new waves of distrust in other currencies and in the
presence of central bank policies that will limit
portfolio shifts by their commercial banks out of
domestic currency assets. Nevertheless, it does seem
possible that our 1969 deficit on the official settle
ments basis may be quite small. One possible pattern
might be an inflow of $2-1/2 billion of funds through
banks and $1/2 billion of official reserve transactions.
With this picture, pressures on our gold reserves
should be moderate--and tolerable. The state of the
U.S. balance of payments should not itself prevent
progress toward creation of SDR's and deliberate
consideration of other changes in the international
monetary system. But the footing on which we will
stand looks precarious in a longer view, because this
year our net exports get the benefit of a favorable
cyclical conjuncture here and abroad; because capital
controls to which many people are unsympathetic are
still in force; and above all because interest rate
relationships are more favorable now for the U.S.
balance of payments than they may become later.
Mr. Hayes said he thought the staff presentation was
excellent.

While he had found little that he disagreed with, he

did have one technical question relating to the behavior of CD's
after February.

In his judgment, given current Regulation Q

ceilings a three-month bill rate in the projected range of 5.70 to
5.90 per cent might be associated with a tendency for the volume
of CD's outstanding to stabilize; a somewhat higher bill rateperhaps 6 per cent or slightly above--was more likely to be
consistent with CD run-offs of the dimensions anticipated by the
staff.

Perhaps the Manager had some views on the matter.

-35

2/4/69

Mr. Holmes said he thought a three-month bill rate
consistently above 6 per cent might well be needed to produce the
projected attrition of CD's.

If the rate were around 6 per cent

for some period of time banks probably would not have great
difficulty in finding customers for CD's, particularly since many
customers were willing to sacrifice a few basis points in yield
in the interest of maintaining good banking relationships.
Mr. Brill noted that after February the projected CD
run-off was relatively small--averaging around $250 million per
month.

Of course, he would not want to be dogmatic about the

particular rate relationships which would produce that result.
The projected bill rate range should be regarded as an approxima
tion that might well require some adjustment.
Mr. Partee added that the bill rate figures under discussion
were on a discount basis, whereas CD rates were quoted on an
investment yield basis.

Since a three-month bill rate in the

neighborhood of 6 per cent would be adjusted upward by roughly 20
basis points when converted to an investment yield basis, it was
clear that the range in the staff projection was actually a range
around the current 6 per cent ceiling rate for 90- to 179-day CD's.
Mr. Hickman remarked that the Committee could experiment
to determine the particular bill rate levels that were likely to
be associated with bank credit growth at about a 5-1/2 per cent

-36

2/4/69
annual rate.

He was somewhat puzzled, however, by the relationship

between the longer-run projections given in the presentation
today--which called for moderate growth in bank credit and a
three-month bill rate below 6 per cent--and the projections for
February given in the blue book.1/

The latter called for a bill

rate in the range of 6.0 to 6.30 per cent and a decline in the
bank credit proxy, including Euro-dollars, at an annual rate in
the range of 0 to 3 per cent.

He wondered whether the differences

between the projections for February and for the longer run were
related, at least in part, to the fact that February included a
period of even keel.
Mr. Brill replied that the February projections did reflect
the fact that even keel constraints would be in effect.

The

estimated rate of bank credit expansion he had cited as likely to
be consistent with the GNP projections applied to the period
beginning in March, and was based on the assumption that the
February projection would be realized.

After February, when a

slowing of CD attrition was expected to be associated with a
somewhat lower level of bill rates, growth in bank credit was
expected to resume at an annual rate averaging about 5-1/2 per
cent, although not necessarily at that specific rate from month
to month.

1/ The report, "Money Market and Reserve Relationships,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

-37

2/4/69

Mr. Mitchell observed that he was a little surprised to
find that the staff was recommending major reliance on Regulation Q
ceilings and a little disturbed at the implied delicacy of the
operation required to obtain the bank credit growth rate projected.
He agreed that Regulation Q ceilings could be a useful tool for
controlling the rate of CD attrition.

He woundered whether, in

the staff's estimation, it would be possible to introduce
additional flexibility in that instrument by restructuring the
ceiling rates applicable to different maturities.
Mr. Brill replied that the effect of changes in Regulation Q
ceilings would depend on prevailing bank attitudes and expectations.
For example, if the Board were to raise ceiling rates on CD's of
longer maturity at the present time, banks might well construe the
action as a first step in the direction of an easier monetary
policy.

And if banks concluded that interest rates were going to

ease, they might not take advantage of the higher rate ceilings to
expand their CD outstandings because that would mean a commitment
to pay prevailing rates for 6 or 9 months.

In short, the potential

reaction of banks to an increase in Regulation Q ceilings would be
affected by their attitudes about their liquidity positions and
their outlook for interest rates.
In response to a further question by Mr. Mitchell,
Mr. Brill indicated that the basic policy strategy proposed by

-38

2/4/69

the staff would be to exert continuing pressure on the banking
system through open market operations and, if necessary to
maintain the pressure, to supplement those operations by use of
whatever other policy tools seemed appropriate.

In the latter

connection, if market psychology appeared to be changing in a
manner that did not seem to be in accord with the basic economic
situation, consideration might be given to the possibility of
absorbing reserves in the spring by an increase in required
reserves and perhaps also to the possibility of an advance in
the discount rate.
Mr. Mitchell observed that a key point in the staff's
prescription still seemed to him to be the curtailment of bank
credit expansion by fostering a continuing run-off in the volume
of CD's at large banks.
Mr. Brill remarked that although the initial impact of the
proposed restraint would tend to fall on the money market banks
most dependent on the availability of CD funds, he would expect
that the restraint would soon permeate the entire banking system.
Indeed, there already were some indications of such a development.
Mr. Maisel noted that the bank credit proxy had declined
at an 8 per cent annual rate in the six weeks since mid-December.
The staff's projection was for a smaller average rate of decline
in February and an increase at a 5-1/2 per cent annual rate in

-39

2/4/69
succeeding months.

It was not clear to him how bank credit could

shift from experiencing a fairly rapid decline to a period of
moderate expansion under a policy which maintained steadily firm
pressure on the banking system.
Mr. Brill observed that the policy strategy recommended by
the staff was based on the expectation of a substantial diminution
in financial market pressures once the Treasury began its seasonal
debt repayments in March.

If the switch in the Treasury's position

were allowed to be translated into a sizable decline in short-term
interest rates, banks would be likely to move aggressively to
replace the CD's they had lost and a bulge in bank credit growth
could result.

The staff's prescription was to resist much of the

downward pressures on interest rates but to permit enough to
diminish the CD run-off and thereby allow for the growth in bank
credit that would be needed to accommodate the requirements of the
economy.
Mr. Partee noted that one element in the staff's projection
was liquidation by banks of their holdings of U.S. Government
securities at a $12 billion annual rate in the first half of 1969
and at a $4 billion annual rate in the second half.

Continuing

pressure would have to be maintained on banks to force them into
such liquidation.
Mr. Brimmer commented that the staff's GNP projection
implied that the corporate sector would absorb an increased share

-40

2/4/69

of available resources in 1969 as a result of an expansion in
expenditures on plant and equipment.

The projected rise in those

expenditures would account for nearly one-sixth of the increase in
GNP in 1969, compared with one-tenth in 1968.

That re-allocation

of resources would be partly at the expense of the Federal sector
and partly at the expense of the housing sector.

Despite

anticipated pressure on the banking system, the projection assumed
that banks would help finance a volume of business fixed investment
that would be growing nearly 30 per cent faster than in 1968.

He

wondered if there would be any way to change the incidence of
monetary restraint if reliance were placed entirely on the general
policy instruments Mr. Brill had mentioned.
Mr. Brill replied that in the staff projection most of the
expansion in plant and equipment expenditures occurred in the
first quarter.

Some further rise in real fixed investment was

projected in the second quarter, but thereafter the projection
suggested that--while the current dollar value of plant and
equipment spending would rise slightly--spending in real terms
would decline.

The projection implied that before the end of the

year corporations would be limited both by a squeeze on profits
and by monetary restraint in their ability to finance rising
inventories and increased real investment in plant and equipment.
Mr. Brill added that the figures on business capital expenditures

-41

2/4/69

incorporated in the projection were consistent with the year-over
year rise in such expenditures reflected by the latest confidential
survey of the Department of Commerce.
Mr. Mitchell observed that with interest rates relatively
high in the United States there might now seem to be less need for
the voluntary foreign credit restraint program and the Commerce
Department controls on direct investment.

That conclusion would

seem valid particularly if foreign monetary authorities were going
to keep their domestic interest rates down by making fewer dollars
available to the Euro-dollar market, which he took to be the
implication of staff comments today.
Mr. Hersey agreed that actions of foreign monetary
authorities to restrict the availability of funds in the Euro
dollar market might tend to keep interest rates in their countries
lower than otherwise.

He believed, however, that supply and demand

pressures in German financial markets would tend to bring higher
interest rates in that country.

No doubt financial conditions

projected in the.United States, along with the interest equalization
tax--which he regarded as still quite important--would be major
factors favorable to the U.S. balance of payments.

Whether the

VFCR would exert much extra effect in 1969 seemed doubtful, but in
view of the uncertainties that remained he thought the programs
were still necessary.

2/4/69

-42Chairman Martin then called for the go-around of comments

and views on economic conditions and monetary policy, beginning
with Mr. Hayes, who made the following statement:
Few new business data have come to light since the
last FOMC meeting. The underlying situation undoubtedly
remains one of excessive strength, with consequent
inflationary pressures; prices continue to move up
strongly. On the other hand, business sentiment is
perhaps a bit less ebullient. There is some uncertainty
about the current state of business inventories and the
strength of consumer demand, but the statistics needed
to assess whether any significant imbalance is developing
between stocks and final sales are not yet available.
Looked at in perspective, the level of new orders for
machinery and equipment and other advance indicators of
capital spending have been very high since mid-1968 and
suggest continued strength in this area during the
current quarter. On the other hand, I believe the
fiscal program, coupled with our own policies, is
likely to induce a slower rate of over-all economic
expansion in the months ahead--although it remains
quite possible that upward pressures created by the
current widespread inflationary expectations may still
prevent this much-to-be-desired tendency.
On the balance of payments front it is no surprise
to find a sizable recorded liquidity deficit reappearing
in early January data, following the remarkable capital
inflow of late December. Very heavy borrowings of
American banks from their foreign branches in January
were provided in large part by a movement of funds out
of Germany; and much of this movement in turn represents
the unwinding of the speculative inflows of November.
It seems reasonable to suppose that availability of
Euro-dollars to meet American bank needs will be a good
deal smaller in the coming months. As for the dollar's
position in exchange markets, there has been general
improvement in the past month, no doubt attributable
in good measure to recent U.S. monetary and fiscal
policy developments. Welcome though this is, it
should not cause us to forget what a serious balance
of payments problem we continue to face until we
succeed in restoring a sizable trade surplus.

2/4/69

-43-

As for credit developments, we find considerable
strength in the business loan statistics; but in
New York at least this seems to result more from
unexpectedly slow loan repayments than from a surge
of new loan demands. Among the latter, large loans
to finance corporate acquisitions seem to be playing a
leading role among the large banks. It seems to me that
if we should end up with a small decline in the credit
proxy for January and February together, after adjustment
for Euro-dollars, this would be a most welcome develop
ment, coming on top of the very excessive expansion of
the second half of 1968. Of course I would not advocate
a decline extending over a long period. But I think we
should bear in mind that the growth of total credit may
remain large for some time as direct lending in the
credit markets is substituted for lending through the
banking system. For this reason it would appear
necessary to maintain a very moderate average rate of
bank credit expansion for a fairly extended period of
time if monetary policy is to have the desired effect
on total credit flows and total aggregate demand in the
economy.
Even keel considerations certainly preclude any
major policy change in the next couple of weeks. But
I believe purely economic factors also point to the
wisdom of a "no change" policy at this time. Our
objective should be to bring steady but not extreme
pressure to bear on the banking system in order to
induce a more restrictive attitude toward lending and
investing. Despite some remarks in the press and
reports by some banks and security dealers to the
contrary, I think many banks are moving toward the
adoption of more restrictive policies. And while there
has been a fair amount of skepticism about the System's
firmness of.purpose in combatting inflation, I believe
that money market participants have lost a good deal of
that skepticism in the past week. The credit proxy
data also suggest that we are beginning to get results.
Although the monetary and credit flow variables
are clearly our principal policy target, even keel
requirements will call for careful scrutiny of money
market conditions over the next few weeks. I would
think of bank borrowing in the $500 to $800 million
range, or perhaps $600 to $900 million in view of the
recent high figures to which the market has become
somewhat accustomed. Net borrowed reserves, to which

2/4/69

-44

I would give less emphasis, might range from around $400
to $600 million, but subject to temporary deviations
outside these figures. The Federal funds rate might be
around 6-1/4 to 6-1/2 per cent, and the bill rate might
center in a 6.10 to 6.30 per cent range.
As far as the directive is concerned, the staff
draft looks fine to me. Since we start out with a
projected decline in the credit proxy for February,
including Euro-dollars, I would accept some modest
increase--say 2 to 3 per cent--before implementing the
proviso on the side of mildly greater restraint.
Similarly, if the proxy appears to be declining more
than 4 or 5 per cent I would then favor some modest
relaxation of operations, provided that market expecta
tions are not questioning the System's resolve to
maintain an over-all policy of restraint. Psychology
will be an important factor in determining the economy's
response to anti-inflationary restraint, and open market
operations will have to be conducted flexibly with this
consideration in view.
Looking beyond the next few weeks, I can see a
possibility that further System policy actions will be
called for. For one thing, whereas banks have not had
undue difficulty adjusting so far, a drying up of the
supply of Euro-dollars could put increased pressure on
the money market banks where the CD run-offs have been
heaviest. Up to a point this increased pressure might
be welcome. But if the pressure were to become
excessive, particularly with respect to the consequences
for the foreign exchange markets, there might be a need
to review the Regulation Q ceilings. The question of
applying reserve requirements to Euro-dollar borrowings
by U.S. banks involves a number of complex considerations
and the answer should not be rushed as part of a short
run strategy.
There is also a possibility that an additional
visible and overt tightening move may later be needed
if doubts about System policy resolve should grow. A
discount rate rise might become appropriate, especially
if the smaller banks continue to borrow as heavily as
in the past weeks. Another possible move might be a
reserve requirement increase. But these are not issues
that must be dealt with at present.
Mr. Francis remarked that seven weeks ago the Committee had
adopted a policy designed to exercise a restrictive influence on

-45

2/4/69
the economic system.

For seven weeks, it had been the System's

intention to reduce inflationary pressures.

To accomplish that

required getting total spending growth down significantly from
However,

the 9.5 per cent growth rate of the past four quarters.
the evidence was still not clear that the System had been

exercising a restrictive influence in the past seven weeks.
Since the week ending December 18, total member bank reserves
had increased $1 billion; the monetary base had increased $600
million; Federal Reserve credit had grown $900 million; and the
money supply had grown $1 billion.

Interest rates, after

continuing their December rise for a week after December 17, had
changed little.
Mr. Francis observed that member bank borrowings had
averaged $840 million since the Committee's December meeting,
compared with $550 million in the period from November 6 to
December 18.

That increase might be a sign of increased tightness

in the credit markets but it was not a sign of Federal Reserve
restriction.

In view of the increased margin of market rates over

discount rates since November, the demand for bank loans, and the
disintermediation caused by impingement of Regulation Q, it was to
be wondered that borrowings had not risen more.

The fact that

they had not would seem to be due to the liberal supplying of
reserves by open market operations.

2/4/69

-46
Mr. Francis said he hoped the Committee would not feel that

it had been exercising a restrictive influence since December 17
by virtue of the fact that total bank credit had ceased to grow.
As the members knew, that development was due to the fact that the
present relationship between Regulation Q rate ceilings and market
interest rates prevented the commercial banks from acquiring or
even holding time deposits.

That put the banks in a tight

position, but it did not restrict the credit markets in general.
It forced the flow of funds into channels different from those
they would have otherwise followed.

That might or might not be a

good thing, but it did not exercise a restraint on total credit
and total spending.

When Regulation Q caused disintermediation-

or reintermediation when its effects were withdrawn as market
rates declined relative to ceilings--total bank credit became a
distorted and misleading indicator.
Not only was the moderation of growth of bank credit a
misleading indicator of restraint, Mr. Francis continued, but the
associated decline of time deposits released reserves to provide
for further credit creation, growth of total credit in the economy,
and growth of the narrow measure of the money supply.

An insidious

effect of the disintermediation caused by Regulation Q might be to
put commercial banks under such pressure that the System would be
impelled to expand Federal Reserve credit, total bank reserves, and

-47

2/4/69

the monetary base at continuing and even accelerating inflationary
rates..
Mr. Francis remarked that Committee members might think
monetary policy was tight because interest rates were high.
However, the increase in rates had occurred mainly in the period
from September to December 17.

Thus, the rise had come prior to

the time when the System's policy moved toward tightness.

He

urged the Committee to give some evidence that it was exercising
restraint by limiting growth of bank reserves, the monetary base,
and the narrow measure of money supply--or, if the members
preferred, a measure of bank credit exclusive of commercial bank
time deposits--to about 3 per cent per year.
For about four years, Mr. Francis said, the Committee had
been led into unintended inflationary monetary expansion while
following interest rate, net reserves, and bank credit objectives
and the even keel constraint.

He suggested that, if the Committee

meant business now, it should try some other guides.

Not only

could the old guides lead to further inflation as long as demands
for credit continued to rise, but when and if contrary trends set
in they could lead to an undue contraction of total spending.
Mr. Francis observed that he was not proposing to have
the Manager give the market a signal of a change of policy either
tomorrow or any other particular day.

He was proposing simply

-48

2/4/69

that the Desk be instructed to implement, gradually and carefully,
the policy of intensifying restraint that was decided upon on
December 17.

He thought it would be a great mistake to postpone

that step until the Committee's March meeting.
Mr. Francis reported that the directors of the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis thought the discount rate was at least
1/2 of 1 percentage point too low.

At their meeting a week from

Thursday (February 13) they were likely to vote for submitting a
rate increase.

At the present time the discount rate was about

3/4 of 1 percentage point below its average relationship with
other money market rates, and since early December the volume of
Federal Reserve credit extended through the discount window had
been rising.
Raising reserve requirements as opposed to selling
securities had not proved in the past to be an effective way to
restrict the growth in aggregate member bank reserves, Mr. Francis
commented.

When the Manager used money market conditions as a

guide to action, the effects of the reserve requirement change
were offset; in addition, the System usually sought to facilitate
the transition to higher requirements by supplying some additional
funds.

In January 1968, the System had raised reserve requirements,

absorbing $550 million of reserves, to obtain some monetary
restraint without placing direct upward pressure on interest rates.

-49

2/4/69

But in the first quarter of that year Federal Reserve credit, even
adjusted for the reserve requirement change, rose at an excessive
15 per cent annual rate, and the three-month Treasury bill rate
went up about 1/4 of 1 percentage point.
Mr. Kimbrel remarked that the Committee's intention, as he
understood it, was to follow a policy of moving gradually toward
moderate restraint rather than moving suddenly toward drastic
restraint.

Consequently, the members need not be disappointed if

dramatic effects were not yet showing up.

At the same time, it

seemed to him that the Committee should be cautious about accepting
the idea that it could necessarily count on the current posture to
bring about the desired slowing down.
Mr. Kimbrel said he found it especially difficult to
interpret the signals being given by the financial variables.

He

had been advised that even with the most skillful seasonal adjust
ment techniques it was hard to sort out the effects of the seasonal
forces that were so strong at this time of the year.

Lack of

extended experience with the lagged reserve plan created interpre
tative problems.

The massive shifts out of time deposits made the

bank credit proxy and the net borrowed reserve figures far from
reliable as guides for the total credit availability.

On top of

that, there was the heavy use of Euro-dollars.
Consequently, Mr. Kimbrel observed, he could well understand
the hard time that financial writers seemed to be having in deciding

-50

2/4/69

whether the Federal Reserve was actually carrying through on a
policy of moving toward restraint.

He noted that one writer had

pointed out last week that, since the money supply was continuing
to grow, talk of restraint was just that--talk.

Another writer

who had looked at the deepening net borrowed reserve figures was
convinced that the System really meant business.
Mr. Kimbrel thought the Desk had performed admirably in
terms of specifications given at the Committee's previous meeting.
Perhaps as a result the point was approaching at which policy would
begin to bite even though so far there had been no large cutbacks
in bank lending and investing.

In his judgment, the decline in

the credit proxy in January and the prospective decline in February
did not mean that policy had already become too restrictive.

Those

declines had to be considered in the context of the shift out of
time deposits.
January.

Total reserves apparently had continued to grow in

The continued growth in loans suggested that the pinch

was not very great.
With the behavior of the financial variables so hard to
interpret, Mr. Kimbrel said, he supposed it was necessary to give
even more attention than usual to the way the economy was behaving.
Although the staff's presentation today suggested some hope for a
moderate slowdown in the future, there was little evidence that
it had occurred thus far.

He found that to be characteristic of

-51

2/4/69

conditions in the Sixth Federal Reserve District.

The District

economy had ended 1968 on a strong upbeat, with the unemployment
rate down to 3.5 per cent.

In no major type of manufacturing had

seasonally adjusted employment been lower in December than in
November.

A high construction contract volume for December

promised a continued active construction industry.
of major expansion plans were frequent.

Announcements

Typical were three

announcements made in the last quarter of 1968 for paper mills in
Mississippi, Alabama, and Louisiana to cost $250 million.
That active pace was being supported by continued growth
in bank loans, Mr. Kimbrel continued.

In January there was an

increase at large District banks in business loans, whereas--judging
by past experience--a decline should have been expected at this time
of the year.

But more compelling evidence that policy had not

really begun to bite at District banks was that not a single banker
had complained to him about tightness.
to what had happened in 1966.

That was directly contrary

Seemingly, they were enjoying a

banker's paradise--lots of loans at high rates.

Moreover, their

actions implied that they were counting on the Federal Reserve to
see that they did not come up short.
Under those circumstances, it seemed to Mr. Kimbrel that
the Committee would have to be guided more by the availability of
funds than by rates if it was going to contribute to a slowdown.

-52

2/4/69

It might be that careful consideration should be given to a change
in reserve requirements.

In his opinion a change in the discount

rate would be ineffective at this time.
Treasury financing limited the Committee's freedom of
action for part of the next period, Mr. Kimbrel observed.

In any

event, he would favor a policy of no change, assuming no change in
policy would be accompanied by the money market conditions
described in the blue book.1 /

That set of conditions implied a

decline in the rate of increase in reserves.

Under those circum

stances, he favored the draft directive as written.

By the time

of the next meeting the Committee might be better able to observe
the effect or lack of effect of gradual restraint.
Mr. Hilkert remarked that the problems faced in making a
recommendation on policy today were twofold:

(1) judging the

impact of policy actions already taken; and (2) reading the
economic signs for indications of how strong the economy was

1/ The blue book passage referred to read as follows: "As
February progresses, the basic reserve position of major money
market banks can be expected to worsen, partly as the recent
seasonal easing reverses and possibly also because of increased
demands for day-to-day funds which might stem from the Treasury
refunding. The Federal funds and dealer loan rates may,
therefore, tend to rise somewhat from recent levels, for any
given level of total member bank borrowings. Moreover, continued
CD run-offs may tend to impel somewhat greater borrowing demands
from the Federal Reserve. If borrowings are in a $600-$850
million range in February, the funds rate might be most frequently
around 6-3/8 - 6-5/8 per cent. The 3-month bill rate, under these
conditions, may be expected to be in a 6 - 6.30 per cent range."

2/4/69

-53

likely to be some months ahead.

In judging the impact of actions

already taken, he had the impression that attitudes on the part of
bankers had not been consistently what policy had intended.

It

was desirable to foster the psychology that the System intended to
exert steady pressure so as to bring inflation under control.
During at least part of the past three weeks, he had had some
question whether that objective was being accomplished.

Neverthe

less, he was impressed by the sharp downward changes in bank credit
and the money supply during January.
suggesting considerable impact.

Those were firm statistics

In addition, projections for

February suggested more of the same.
Mr. Hilkert said that reading the signs for indications
of how strong the economy would be some months from now was
particularly important because monetary policy choices now would,
in part, determine results then.
indicated continuing strength.

Most of the firm statistics
Among them were production,

employment, and business spending for plant and equipment.

In

addition, the behavior of industrial commodity prices made it
clear that inflation continued to be the primary economic problem.
Until inflation was brought under better control, no satisfactory
solution to the balance of payments problem could be found.
Economic data for the Third District were not so timely as
the national figures, Mr. Hilkert continued, but the information

-54

2/4/69

that was available also indicated over-all strength.

In December,

industrial production maintained its upward movement, and unemploy
ment remained low in all District areas.

The Reserve Bank's most

recent business outlook survey, conducted several weeks ago,
showed growing short-term optimism and a continuing bullish
outlook for the coming six months.
Information suggesting slower growth was harder to come
by and more difficult to interpret, Mr. Hilkert observed.

For

example, the cutbacks in auto output and resulting layoffs last
month, and the December decline in retail sales, might be only
temporary trouble spots or they might be harbingers of more
widespread softening of demand.
As he added up those several observations of the economic
signs and the effects of policy, Mr. Hilkert concluded that a
policy of watchful waiting was the most appropriate.

The basic

posture should be one of restraint, but of alertness to new
developments.

That policy, of course, was also consistent with

even keel considerations.

However, he was concerned with the

possibility that restraint might be overdone.

Thus, if necessary

to avoid pressing growth in bank credit and the money supply below
the ranges projected in the blue book, he would want to give the
Desk discretion to ease money market conditions to the extent
possible within even keel.

-55

2/4/69

Mr. Hickman said that the much-publicized cutback in auto
production and the need to adjust inventories in other industries
suggested that the slowdown in economic activity was becoming
more widespread.

Durable goods orders declined in November and

December, and steel output was expected to decline by about 3 per
cent in February, after four months of increase.

Thus, advances

in industrial production should moderate in the near future along
with the growth of employment and income.
Mr. Hickman noted that expectations of some slowing of
economic activity were widely shared by the business economists
from major corporations who had met at the Cleveland Federal
Reserve Bank on January 24.

The group's median forecast of the

index of industrial production for 1969 showed successive quarterly
gains of one, zero, one, and two points, following gains of 1-1/2
points and 2 points, respectively, in the third and fourth quarters
of 1968.

The median forecast for the production index for 1969 as

a whole was 169, which would represent a 2-1/2 per cent rise above
the average for 1968, compared with about 4 per cent for 1968 over
1967.

The group anticipated median quarterly gains in GNP this

year of $12 billion, $11 billion, $14 billion,and $16 billion,
which were modest by 1968 standards, but somewhat larger than had
been expected at their last meeting in October.

The group's

median forecast for the year 1969 was $919 billion, which would

2/4/69

-56

represent a 6-3/4 per cent gain from 1968, closely matching the
current "consensus" forecast.

The group's forecast compared with

a gain of 6.9 per cent presented in the staff's projection this
morning and 7.1 per cent in the CEA forecast.

Apparently,

economists had revised their notions about the timing of the
impact of fiscal changes on economic activity.

Different

assumptions about prolonging the income surtax had little visible
effect on individual GNP forecasts for 1969.
Mr. Hickman observed that the business economists had
voiced serious concern about continued inflation, to which no one
saw an early end.

Many doubted that the recent shift in monetary

policy had had a significant effect on inflationary psychology.
In fact, considerable skepticism was expressed about the strength
of the System's resolution to check price inflation through
monetary policy, suggesting that it might take a fairly lengthy
period of time to change expectations.
Mr. Hickman felt that policy since the last meeting had
been somewhat firmer than he thought desirable as an intermediate
term objective, but perhaps about right considering the general
sentiment that the System was not serious in its resolution to
check inflation.

While the System had managed to avoid a credit

crunch, CD attrition had been more extensive than he would prefer
for the next several months.

The credit proxy, including

2/4/69

-57

Euro-dollars, actually declined in January and would probably
decline again in February, if present conditions in the money
market were maintained.

Moreover, CD attrition had forced an

increasing number of banks heavily into the Euro-dollar market
and was creating undesirable pressures in foreign money markets.
Severe monetary restraint might be needed to close the "credibility
gap" but should not be continued indefinitely.
In the current environment, Mr. Hickman said, he would
prefer to maintain the bill rate in a range of 5.90 to 6.15 per
cent, which would temper somewhat the CD runoff and encourage a
modest and even growth in bank credit.

Such a policy would also

be consistent with even keel considerations, which would prevail
throughout most of the period.

To the extent that supplementary

reserves would have to be provided to accommodate the current
Treasury financing, they should be withdrawn as soon as possible
after the financing was completed.

His position was slightly

less restrictive than the staff's draft directive, although the
differences were minor, particularly in a period when "even keel"
would be the dominant consideration.

Accordingly, he was prepared

to vote in favor of the draft directive.
Mr. Sherrill said he favored the staff's draft directive
as written.

He had found the projections presented by the staff

this morning to be quite helpful and thought the targets were

-58

2/4/69
correctly formulated.

In particular, he felt that the objective

of growth in bank credit over an extended period at an annual rate
of about 5-1/2 per cent was a proper one, and in his judgment the
bank credit contraction in January and February would result in
an appropriate starting point for growth at such a rate.
As Mr. Brill had noted, Mr. Sherrill continued, there were
likely to be downward pressures on short-term interest rates after
mid-March, when the Treasury would be repaying debt.

It would be

desirable to prevent substantial declines in rates, which could
be misinterpreted as reflecting a backing-off in the degree of
monetary restraint.

But it might be quite difficult to prevent

interest rates from falling too far while maintaining bank credit
growth at about a 5-1/2 per cent annual rate.

While open market

operations probably would be the principal tool of policy, the
System should be prepared to take supplementary action, if
necessary, on reserve requirements or discount rates.

For the

time being, however, he would prefer to hold such other policy
tools in reserve while watching the course of developments.
Mr. Sherrill agreed that it was distressing to find that
the recent policy intentions of the Federal Reserve had not been
clear to outside observers and were being misinterpreted by many
commentators.

He thought, however, that the System should not be

dissuaded from its present course by such reactions.

Certainly,

-59

2/4/69

it was only a matter of time before observers would reach a correct
understanding of System policy intentions from the statistics that
would be coming out.

The Federal Reserve was likely at that point

to be faced with the opposite kind of criticism, and it would be
important then for the System to hold as steadily to its policy
course as it was doing now.
Mr. Brimmer said he also was prepared to accept the staff's
draft of the directive.

However, he was troubled by the way

monetary policy was operating.

In particular, he was disturbed by

the fact that a small number of very large banks had been able to
offset a good part of the effects of monetary restraint by drawing
in Euro-dollars.

According to a preliminary analysis by a member

of the Board's staff, the eleven banks accounting for the bulk of
U.S. bank Euro-dollar liabilities had been able to offset about
one-half of their CD run-offs between December 11 and January 22
by Euro-dollar inflows.
process.

Further staff work on the subject was in

Although Mr. Bodner was confident that the availability

of Euro-dollars would be reduced in coming months, he (Mr. Brimmer)
was not convinced that the large U.S. banks would find it extremely
difficult to continue to acquire substantial additional amounts of
such funds.
Moreover, Mr. Brimmer continued, he was convinced that
the recent large Euro-dollar inflows were one source of the

-60

2/4/69

uncertainty in the market as to whether monetary policy was
sufficiently restrictive.

Many of the comments in the press

about the stance of policy reflected interviews with officials
of large New York City banks, and--because of their access to
Euro-dollars--it was easy to see why such banks did not feel that
they were under much pressure.

He had encountered a similar

attitude among Chicago bankers when he visited with them during
the third week of January.
Mr. Brimmer noted that the large banks in question accounted
for a substantial part of total bank credit.

Those banks were

unlikely to reduce the rate at which they were making loan commit
ments so long as they thought they could continue to count on the
availability of Euro-dollars.

It was necessary, however, to

persuade them to cut down on their loan commitments.

He was

concerned about the risk that the System might find itself applying
an unduly great degree of over-all restraint--in an attempt to
compensate for the successful efforts of the large banks in effect
to opt out of the pressure on their reserve positions by drawing
in Euro-dollars.
Accordingly, Mr. Brimmer said, he thought the Board should
consider the desirability of some action in the matter.

He agreed

with Mr. Hayes that there should not be hasty action to apply
reserve requirements to Euro-dollar liabilities, but that possibility

-61

2/4/69
should be studied.

He also thought the Board should consider an

increase in reserve requirements on domestic deposits in about
three or four weeks.

He would hope that any such increase would

be made in a way that would shift part of the burden of restraint
from small to large banks.
Mr. Brimmer then referred to the question Mr. Mitchell had
raised as to whether it was necessary to continue the voluntary
foreign credit restraint program.

He personally was convinced

that the program should be continued; if it were not, he thought
the prospective deficit in the U.S. balance of payments would be
larger than Mr. Hersey had indicated.

As the members knew, he

(Mr. Brimmer) was currently holding regional meetings to develop
information on how the program had been operating.

In his

judgment it would be desirable to make any necessary modifications
of the program but to keep it in place.
Mr. Maisel said the draft directive was acceptable to him.
He agreed that the staff's presentation today had been highly
valuable.

As he understood it, the goals for coming months

suggested by the staff involved growth in real GNP at an annual
rate of about 2 per cent, in dollar GNP at a rate in the range of
5 to 6 per cent, and in bank credit also at a 5 to 6 per cent
rate.

In his judgment such goals were logical.

He also thought

it was appropriate to cast the System's goals in terms of GNP

-62

2/4/69

with bank credit as an intermediate target variable--rather than,
as was sometimes suggested, in terms of correcting press misinter
pretations of the System's policy intentions or influencing that
unmeasurable variable "inflationary psychology," except as such
variables were affected by actual developments with respect to
capacity use, profits, bank credit, and so forth.

He also was

opposed to employing, as intermediate goals, measures of price
changes or statistics on the balance of payments, except as they
could be influenced by actual changes in demand and capacity
utilization rates.
In his judgment, Mr. Maisel continued, the System should
stay with its goal of bank credit growth at about a 5 to 6 per
cent rate--perhaps varying the target a little depending on market
developments--simply because that represented about the limit of
what monetary policy could reasonably be expected to do.

He would

hope that the System would not add to inflationary pressures by
the creation of excessive bank credit.

In a period such as the

present, perhaps a little more could be accomplished by maintaining
bank credit growth at a rate slightly below normal.
Beyond that, Mr. Maisel observed, it would be necessary to
rely on fiscal policy.

The aspect of the projection that worried

him most was the sharp diminution in fiscal restraint expected
after mid-year, even if the surcharge were retained.

Clearly, it

-63

2/4/69

would be preferable for the System to stress the dangers of
relaxing fiscal restraint rather than intensifying monetary
restraint.
One problem for the immediate future, Mr. Maisel remarked,
was the risk of an overreaction in bank credit.

There had been a

tendency during the past several years for the System to over-shoot
its targets, particularly around times of policy change.

Thus,

bank credit growth had tended to fall below staff projections in
periods of firming and to come out above the projections in periods
of easing.

In view of that history, he thought that more than the

usual degree of fine-tuning with respect to the money market and
reserve variables would be required in the coming period to keep
bank credit within the projected range.

The Desk should interpret

the proviso clause more narrowly, particularly if bank credit
growth were negative, than it had at times in the past, including
the most recent period.
Such a course should be appropriate for the next month or
two, Mr. Maisel observed.

Problems of maldistribution of funds

within the banking system might then arise; if so, it might be
necessary to consider the use of other instruments of policy.
Mr. Daane remarked that the Treasury financing called for
an even keel policy in the period immediately ahead.

He accepted

the staff's analysis and draft directive, and he was prepared to

2/4/69

-64

see bank credit decline further in February, as projected in the
blue book.

He thought that for purposes of the proviso clause

the Manager should focus on the bank credit proxy series which
included Euro-dollar borrowings.
Mr. Daane added that on the basis of the evidence available
and the analyses made to date, he did not believe that monetary
policy had been or was likely to be vitiated by Euro-dollar
developments.

Unless further evidence and analysis led to a

contrary conclusion, he would not be willing to select that area
for special policy action.
Mr. Mitchell thought that while the System should not
overreact to current criticism of monetary policy it should not
take such criticism lightly.

Mr. Maisel had suggested that the

Committee should focus on quantitative targets rather than on
market psychology; but the rate at which banks were making loan
commitments at present was influenced by the prevailing psychology.
If banks were making commitments today on the basis of a misreading
of monetary policy intentions, their efforts to meet those
commitments later could produce a credit crunch.

Thus, market

attitudes were of importance to the System, and they seemed to him
to be particularly important at the present juncture.
Nevertheless, Mr. Mitchell said, the latest monetary
statistics offered evidence that the System was achieving its

-65

2/4/69
goals,

and he thought market participants would soon be, persuaded

of that fact.
by Mr.

Francis'

money supply.

In that connection, he had been rather surprised
observations this morning with respect to the
According to the blue book, money supply growth

had fallen to a 4-1/2 per cent annual rate on average in January
and contraction at a rate of 1 to 4 per cent was projected for
February.

The January figure was still an estimate, but probably

a good one; and the February projection seemed to be based on a
reasonable analysis.

He did not see how one could ask for a more

pronounced change.
Mr. Mitchell observed that the Committee members appeared
resolved to fight inflation.

He thought the System would need all

the resolution it could muster in coming months--particularly
after the Treasury began repaying debt--when it was likely to be
subjected to criticism of a nature entirely different from that
it was now experiencing.
In concluding, Mr. Mitchell said the staff's draft of the
directive was acceptable to him.

He commented that he would have

favored no change in policy at this time even in the absence of a
Treasury financing.
Mr. Heflin reported that the latest information on the
Fifth District suggested a moderation in
expansion,

the pace of business

although it was difficult at this stage to make very

-66

2/4/69

precise allowances for seasonal factors.

Respondents in the

Reserve Bank's latest survey reported cutbacks in the rate of
both automobile and general retail sales, with further softening
in residential construction.

Textile markets continued to show

little buoyancy, and nondurables manufacturers in general reported
declines in new orders and backlogs.

Nonetheless, industrial

construction apparently continued to move ahead at a good clip.
Business loans at District weekly reporting banks so far this
year showed only normal seasonal strength.
At the national level, Mr. Heflin observed, more substantive
evidence of some moderation in the business advance was beginning
to appear, although the recent sharp run-up in industrial prices
should remind the Committee that its job was far from finished.
Moreover, business investment spending continued to move ahead at
a disturbing rate in the face of a substantial moderation in the
growth of final sales.

That, it seemed to him, suggested a

potential imbalance in the economy that could make problems for
the System later this year.
Mr. Heflin said he was not entirely sure just what the
System could do to slow down business spending before serious
excesses developed.

But it was reasonably clear to him that high

interest rates were not likely, in the current climate, to produce
that result.

The business community apparently was still not

-67

2/4/69

convinced of the System's determination to contain the boom and
to dissolve the inflationary expectations that underlay their
spending plans.

For that reason, he thought it would be a serious

mistake to relax the present degree of restraint to any extent at
all.

Rather, he thought it was important that all the policy

indicators should reflect the System's determination to combat
inflation.

To him it was especially important at this juncture

to keep a tight rein on bank credit.

While he would not like to

see a zero or negative rate of growth of credit over any extended
period, he believed that the January figures could well produce a
desirable sobering effect on market expectations.

He would hope

that rate could be kept near zero over the next four weeks although,
by way of emphasizing the System's determination, he would be
prepared to accept some further decline for that period.

In any

event, he thought that in the present circumstances it would be a
mistake to allow bank credit to show any substantial growth over
the next month.
The February refunding would no doubt complicate the
Desk's task over most of the period until the Committee's next
meeting, Mr. Heflin remarked.

Markets had preserved a surprisingly

good tone lately despite the large run-off of CD's.

Nevertheless,

he believed that the market situation was still potentially
unstable and he was not confident that the market would take the

-68

2/4/69
refunding in stride.

Even so, he would be inclined in the current

circumstances to interpret even keel as allowing some upward drift
of market rates if that was necessary to keep bank credit from
growing much faster than the rate projected in the blue book.
Mr. Clay commented that the basic economic problem that
had to be solved remained essentially the same as earlier--namely,
an overextended economy with strong price inflationary pressures
and expectations.

Evidences of change in the current and

prospective patterns of economic activity were mixed.

While

there was some indication of a slower rate of over-all growth,
the attainment of a balanced performance at a sustainable pace
was still something to be hoped for.

The demand for qualified

manpower outran the available supply, and upward pressure on
costs and prices persisted with continuing inflation as a general
public expectation,
Monetary policy had to maintain its recent posture of
restraint, Mr. Clay said.

The indicated decrease in bank credit

probably was more restrictive than was intended by present policy,
but it should be acceptable as a short-run development following
the large credit growth of recent months.

Moreover, the deposit

contraction thus far was quite concentrated in the largest banks
and did not permeate the banking system generally.
Consideration also had to be given to the risk involved in
giving any misleading signal to the public concerning the drive

2/4/69

-69

against price inflation, Mr. Clay continued.

While the monetary

policy of restraint should be implemented in an orderly fashion,
it was important that the public should become convinced of the
resoluteness of purpose of the Federal Reserve System to restrain
price inflation.
Mr. Clay observed that Treasury financing would be a
constraint on monetary policy for a substantial part of the
period until the next meeting.

He thought that, quite apart

from that factor, monetary policy should continue essentially
unchanged.

The draft policy directive appeared to be satisfactory.

Mr. Helmer commented that the current outlook was for some
easing of pressures on economic resources.

Thus far, however,

economic activity continued to maintain a strong momentum in the
Seventh District.

With the exception of passenger cars, no

important District industry had reported significant adjustments
in production plans.

And in the automobile industry, production

in the first quarter normally was cut back substantially as
inventories of new models were brought to desired levels.

It

appeared now that first-quarter production was likely to be at
least 90 per cent of the fourth-quarter total.

There appeared

to have been no weakening in the vigorous demand for trucks and
trailers.
Mr. Helmer noted that orders for machine tools, railroad
equipment and various other capital goods and components had

-70

2/4/69
strengthened late in 1968.

Except for isolated cases, producers

of capital goods in the District currently were concerned more by
rising material costs and severe labor shortages than by the trend
of new orders.
Steel orders improved further in January, Mr. Helmer said.
In the last full week of January output of raw steel in the
Chicago and Detroit areas had been within 91 per cent of the 1968

peak rate, compared to 88 per cent for the nation.

Except for

autos, he had been unable to uncover any concern that inventories
might be excessively large.
Price increases were posted in late January for a sizable
list of commodities, Mr. Helmer continued, including textiles,
chemicals, sugar, asbestos, and numerous products containing
nonferrous metals.

Unemployment compensation claims were at an

extremely low level in the District, as in the nation, in January.
Increases in wage rates still appeared to be accelerating.
Demand for funds to finance construction projects--both
construction loans and permanent financing--was intense, Mr. Helmer
observed.

Interest and commission charges had reached new highs,

and special deals with an equity interest for lenders were
increasingly common.

Seven per cent usury limits applicable to

loans to noncorporate borrowers in Illinois and Michigan might be
revised.

One proposal under active consideration in Illinois

-71

2/4/69

would raise the limit to 9 per cent, and would clarify troublesome
ambiguities with regard to various classes of borrowers and
lenders.

Institutional lenders other than savings and loan

associations had virtually abandoned the market for mortgages on
single-family homes.

While housing and home construction financing

might be handicapped by existing institutional obstacles to the
free flow of credit, that should not be an important consideration
in the Committee's current policy decision.

It might be helpful,

however, for the System to call attention again to the tendency
for legal limits on interest rates to interfere with optimum
flows of credit to various sectors.
The dock strike was having an adverse impact on exports of
District agricultural products, Mr. Helmer said.

With exportable

supplies available from other sources, delays in shipment from the
United States were likely to cause loss, not just deferment, of
exports from this country.
Mr. Helmer noted that credit demands at District banks
continued strong.

Although business loans had declined rather

sharply in the final week of January, net repayments for the month
as a whole had been smaller than usual despite the rapid rise in
those loans during November and December.

Borrowing at District

banks by metals manufacturing firms had increased much more than
seasonally and relatively heavy use of bank credit was reported

-72

2/4/69

for most other industrial categories also.

Consumer and. mortgage

loans had continued to increase fairly steadily, but lending to
finance companies and securities dealers had been cut back sharply
and a substantial volume of Government securities had been
liquidated as CD's had run off.

The two largest banks had now

more than recouped their year-end outflow of Euro-dollars.
Mr. Helmer observed that the cumulative decline in
negotiable CD's at the large Chicago banks now exceeded $400
million--a loss of about 20 per cent from the December peak.
But attrition since the first of the year was somewhat less than
had been feared and, because of their ability to draw on the
Euro-dollar market and the liquidity built up last fall, it had
not caused severe problems as yet.

Nevertheless, their borrowings

at the discount window had been more frequent and further
tightening in either Euro-dollar or domestic securities markets
would be likely to result in increased use of the window.

A

growing share of recent borrowing, however, had originated from
smaller reserve city banks, some of which had also lost relatively
large amounts of CD funds.
Mr. Galusha observed that since the recent experience of
Ninth District banks and savings and loan associations seemed to
have been roughly the same as that of others across the country,
there was no need for him to go into any detail on the subject.

2/4/69

-73

He would note only that, generally speaking, inflows of funds to
District banks and thrift institutions had decreased, and that
the outstanding CD liabilities of the largest banks had declined
by $75 million--or by around 60 per cent of the dollar value of
maturing CD's--in the four weeks ending January 22.

Unless

Committee policy was changed, institutional flows would likely
not increase again soon; and that being so, he was not confident
that the sharp economic advance of the fourth quarter would be
sustained very far into the future.
Mr. Galusha remarked that he favored no change in
Committee policy at this time and would have taken the same
position even if the Treasury had not just opened its subscription
books.

The policy of the past few weeks, perhaps with slight

modifications in months to come, would bring relatively small
increases in nominal GNP--and not just over the first half of the
year, but straight through to the end of 1969.
Mr. Galusha said he accepted the various monetary targets
specified under "Prospective Developments" in the blue book, and
favored the staff draft directive as written.

He would caution

the Manager, however, against an excessive run-off of CD's--or,
what might come to the same thing, against letting market rates
go above their specified upper limits.

In a very brief period,

the Committee had effected a considerable change in the rate of

2/4/69

-74

growth of bank credit, possibly even too considerable a change;
and however much inflation there had been, the Committee had
constantly to be mindful of the risk of being too restrictive.
The present was definitely a time, he believed, for the two-way
proviso clause in the directive.

However much heat a posture of

moderation might engender--and he had no doubts at all that the
voices of the System's critics would become quite shrill before
the current episode was in the past--the long-run interests of
the country would be better served by persistent and consistent
policies applied flexibly in modest increments rather than by
overreactions.
By the same token, Mr. Galusha said, he endorsed Mr. Brill's
suggestion that the System should lean against the wind to keep
the bill rate from falling significantly below 6 per cent if
interest rates came under downward pressure later.

He thought

Mr. Hayes had stated admirably the conditions on which he
(Mr. Galusha) would want to have the proviso clause implemented.
Mr. Swan remarked that in the Twelfth District, as
elsewhere, it was difficult to find specific evidence of any
substantial change in the economic situation.

He would note that

data into early January on initial claims for unemployment
compensation in the District suggested that the unemployment rate
might have risen from its relatively low level in December.

While

-75

2/4/69

the damage from recent rains and floods had been heavy, particularly
in the Los Angeles area, early indications suggested that there had
been little crop damage and probably little interruption to economic
activity except construction activity.
There appeared to have been no great change in the last
three weeks in the positions of major banks in the District,
Mr. Swan said.

Those banks were still able to borrow heavily

under repurchase agreements with corporations.
Turning to policy, Mr. Swan noted that even keel constraints
would apply in the coming period.

However, he would have favored

no change in policy even if the Treasury were not engaged in a
refunding.

In his judgment, the changes in bank credit and the

money supply projected for February, taken in conjunction with
the estimated changes in January, were not necessarily inconsistent
with the objective of moderate rates of growth over a longer run.
That was particularly true in light of the rapid growth rates of
the latter part of 1968.
by the staff.

He would accept the directive as drafted

He thought the two-way proviso clause shown in the

draft was appropriate, and he agreed with Mr. Hayes' comments
regarding its implementation.
Mr. Coldwell reported that the economy of the Eleventh
District remained at a high level.
and unemployment was extremely low.

Employment was still strong
The unemployment rate in

-76

2/4/69

Dallas, for example, was 1.2 per cent, which was practically
equivalent to no unemployment.
Recent developments at District banks reflected seasonal
influences and a reduction in time and savings deposits,
Mr. Coldwell said.

CD run-offs had been nominal thus far and

February maturities were small.

Business loan demand was very

strong, and bankers with whom he had talked indicated that high
interest rates were having little restraining effect on borrowers.
Although data on the liquidity positions of banks revealed that
the margin of available funds was narrowing, the banks still
appeared to be able to take care of their customers.
During the past ten days, Mr. Coldwell continued, there
was evidence that, for the first time since 1966, large national
customers were beginning to draw on lines of credit at interior
banks.

District bankers were only now beginning to believe that

there might be some restraint over the horizon, but they reported
that their customers remained in a "business as usual" mood.
Mr. Coldwell remarked that he had little to add to what
had already been said regarding national economic conditions.

It

seemed to him that the economy was still operating at a high level.
Growth had slowed, but there was no evidence visible of an economic
downturn and no convincing evidence that the slowing was marked.
Cost-price inflation and expectations of further inflation were

2/4/69

-77

deeply rooted, and he did not think that much of a dent in the
prevailing inflationary psychology had been made thus far.
National financial conditions reflected massive seasonal flows,
with CD run-offs offsetting injections of Euro-dollars and with
declines in needs for dealer financing nearly offsetting net
liquidity drains.

Credit restraint was just beginning to be

evident at the margin; few banks had changed lending policies
as yet.
As to policy, Mr. Coldwell commented that while the
Treasury refunding argued for maintaining steady conditions some
marginal shift was still possible.

Since high interest rates

were exerting little restraint, and since credit availability was
only now beginning to be limited, one could make a case for a
slight intensification of monetary restraint.

In that connection

it should be recognized that maintenance of a given level of net
borrowed reserves meant the replenishment of reserves used by the
banking system.
However, Mr. Coldwell continued, in view of the beginnings
of mild restraint through the export of national borrowers to
interior banks, and in view of the Treasury refunding, he would
support the staff's draft directive calling for maintaining
prevailing firm conditions.

He would favor maintaining such

conditions even if that required deeper net borrowed reserves,

2/4/69

-78

larger member bank borrowings, and higher interest rates, since
the alternative would mean once again backing down too early from
a policy of restraint.
Mr. Morris noted that he had dissented from the directive
adopted at the previous meeting because it would have permitted
an absolute contraction in bank credit.

He had felt then--and

felt still--that while the trends in the economy warranted a
moderately restrictive policy they did not warrant a severely
restrictive policy.

In his judgment current policy, if adhered

to for too long a period, would prove to be a policy of too much
too late.
Since the meeting of the Committee three weeks ago,
Mr. Morris continued, there had in fact been a contraction in
bank credit--even though large banks had been able to tap the
Euro-dollar market on a massive scale--and a further contraction
was projected for the month ahead.

He had the impression from

conversations with officials of a large Boston bank with access
to the Euro-dollar market that they did not feel they were
escaping the impact of monetary restraint.

Assuming that

availability of additional Euro-dollars would be limited in the
months ahead, it seemed to him that the current posture of policy
could not be adhered to for long without generating disorderly
markets.

Given the current trends in the economy, which seemed

-79

2/4/69

to be pointing clearly toward further deceleration of economic
growth, he would prefer to have the Committee establish a more
moderately restrictive policy of a kind that could be maintained
for a longer period of time.
Mr. Morris noted that the staff projections for 1969
suggested that growth in the economy would slow substantially
from the excessive pace of the last half of 1968.

The projections

also suggested that by the fourth quarter of 1969 the unemployment
rate would have risen to 4.2 per cent and the increase in the GNP
deflator would have subsided to an annual rate of less than 3 per
cent.

Those projections seemed reasonable to him, both in the

sense that they were consistent with current economic data and in
the sense that they represented appropriate goals for policy.

He

noted, however, that no account had been taken of the possible
deflationary implications of a settlement in Vietnam.
Mr. Morris went on to say that the staff projections
implied a shift in the behavior of bank credit from contraction
in the first two months of the year to growth at a 5-1/2 per cent
rate thereafter.

In his judgment, a more nearly steady pattern

of bank credit growth would be appropriate to the economic
conditions of 1969.

It could be argued that the logic of economic

events had made a financial crunch almost inevitable in 1966, but
in his judgment no such case could be made for 1969.

2/4/69

-80

Since his convictions had placed him in the role of the
devil's advocate, Mr. Morris remarked, he would be bold enough
to suggest that the Committee might be overreacting to the
misjudgments of last summer and fall.

As a consequence, the

Committee might be giving too much weight to discussions of
monetary policy such as were appearing in some parts of the
press and too little weight to the staff's economic projections.
The article by Edwin Dale in yesterday's New York Times, captioned
"Laughing at the Fed," had prompted him to make an informal survey
of his own of some of the people who were active in the Boston
financial market.

He found no one who was laughing about the

current stance of monetary policy.

Even officials of the large

banks which had been tapping the Euro-dollar market had no doubts
about the effectiveness of current policy in the short term.
Some evidence that that feeling might be spreading southward from
Boston was provided by the signs of technical deterioration that
had developed during the past ten days in the stock market--the
first signs of technical weakness since last August.
The main concern of the people in Boston with whom he had
talked, Mr. Morris said, was that a short period of excessive
monetary restraint would be followed by a period of excessive
monetary ease, on the pattern of 1966-68.

If that should happen,

long-run inflationary psychology might become more deeply rooted
than it was today.

-81

2/4/69

In arguing for a policy of moderate rather than severe
restraint, Mr. Morris observed, he was arguing for a policy that
could be maintained for more than a few months.

To implement

such a policy, he would suggest that the proviso clause of the
directive be revised to read as follows:

"provided, however,

that operations shall be modified to the extent necessary to
avoid a contraction in bank credit including Euro-dollar."

The

difference between the staff's draft of the directive and the
modification he had suggested might seem minor, but he thought
it could represent the difference between a policy which could be
sustained for a longer period and one which would have to be
reversed in March or April.
Mr. Robertson presented the following statement:
We are, of course, in a period of "even keel", and
that calls for a basically unchanged monetary policy
for its duration. This gives us the chance to use this
time to weigh very carefully the effectiveness of the
policy actions we have already taken. Obviously some
financial flows are shifting, but we have to be sure to
look through superficial movements to focus on those
with real potential for cooling off the thrust of the
economy.
Given the strength of the inflationary pressures
we are battling, we may well find we have more work to
do, and if so, we ought to be prepared to act again as
quickly as we can. In that case, we might be well
advised not to wait for our next regularly scheduled
meeting on March 4, but instead to call a special
meeting just as soon as we can regard "even keel" as
being over.
If we find we need to tug still harder on the
monetary reins, we should lead off with an increase in
reserve requirements, using open market operations and

-82

2/4/69

a discount rate increase as follow-up actions if and as
needed rather than as initial steps. Final judgment as
to what order of policy actions might be best, of course,
can only be reached when the day arrives; but as of now
it seems to me that we are most likely to need a widely
visible signal of curtailed availability of reserves--and
reserve requirement action fills this bill better than
any of our other instruments. Whether it should apply
to demand deposits or time deposits--and when and in
what fashion--or even to funds brought back from foreign
branches (if, by then, we are in a position to do so)
are questions to be decided then.
In my view, it would make most sense to key any
discount rate increase to the development of overborrow
ing at the Reserve Bank discount windows, if and as that
occurs.

One action I am reasonably sure I would not favor
is any increase in Regulation Q ceilings. I think they
are very much a part of such monetary restraint as we
have been able to introduce up to now, and raising them
could only relax the bite on the banks and add to the
impression that the System lacks the determination to
carry through on a really restrictive credit policy.
And that, I submit, would be a damaging blow to the
posture of the Federal Reserve as a responsible central
bank.
Against the background of these views, I would be
prepared to vote for the draft directive as submitted by
the staff. I would not favor adoption of the proviso
clause suggested by Mr. Morris.
Chairman Martin remarked that there appeared to be relatively
little disagreement among the members with respect to policy today.
He concurred in the view that the Treasury financing precluded a
policy change and that no change would be appropriate at this time
even apart from the financing.

However, the current period of even

keel did offer the System an opportunity to reassess its general
policy stance.

-83

2/4/69

The Chairman then observed that in his judgment a proviso
clause of the type Mr. Morris had suggested probably would not
prove workable.

Since the other members had spoken in favor of

the staff's draft of the directive, he suggested that the Committee
vote on that draft.

If that directive was not acceptable to

Mr. Morris he could, of course, cast a dissenting vote.
Mr. Morris said he thought he would have to dissent from
such a directive since he would find it difficult to associate
himself at this juncture with a policy that was consistent with a
continuing decline in bank credit.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that in his opinion the difference
between Mr. Morris' position and that of other members was smaller
than might appear at first glance.

Mr. Morris wanted to avoid

bank credit contraction, whereas other members were prepared to
accept a decline in February at the rate projected by the staff.
However, the mid-point of the range projected in the proxy series
including Euro-dollars was minus 1-1/2 per cent, which was not
very far from zero.

Mr. Morris also had indicated that he would

not want to have bank credit continue to decline for an extended
period.

He (Mr. Mitchell) shared that view, although he would

not object to some decline in February since he thought there was
a pool of liquidity that should be absorbed.

Indeed, he agreed

with almost everything Mr. Morris had said except with respect to
the desirable timing of a resumption of growth in bank credit.

-84-

2/4/69

Mr. Morris remarked that while one could easily overempha
size small arithmetical differences, he thought there was a
significant difference between a directive that could be viewed
as consistent with a decline in bank credit at an annual rate of
up to say, 5 per cent, and one under which the Manager would be
subject to criticism if a decline of that magnitude occurred.
Chairman Martin said he did not think the Committee would
be contemplating a decline in bank credit at a 5 per cent rate in
February if it adopted the directive submitted by the staff.

In

his judgment, the members actually were not far apart.
Mr. Maisel concurred in the views expressed by Messrs.
Morris and Mitchell.

He hoped the Manager would not construe the

directive as permitting any major deviation in bank credit from
the projection.

It was important for the Manager to keep looking

three or four weeks ahead for indications of the path on which
bank credit was moving.

The rather sharp drop that had occurred

in the past two weeks probably implied that the daily average for
February would be lower than that for January.

Since those monthly

relationships would reflect past actions, they were less important
as this juncture than were the changes in credit expansion which
occurred in future weeks.

The Manager should make certain that

no acceleration occurred in the rate of decline since to achieve
the goals outlined in the staff report, expansion not contraction
was necessary.

-85

2/4/69

Mr. Morris said that in light of the comments just made
he would find it possible to cast an affirmative vote on the
directive.
Mr. Hickman observed that he agreed in general with the
views of Mr. Morris and he concurred in the opinion that it would
be important for the Manager to watch bank credit developments
closely in coming weeks.
Mr. Hayes remarked that he would like to add a few brief
observations.

First, he was fully in accord with the majority

view today and was prepared to vote favorably on the directive.
At the same time, he had sympathy for an even-handed, persistent
approach, and he thought that many of the members felt the same
way.

Certainly, he would want to guard against adopting an unduly

restrictive policy that would have to be reversed quickly.
However, he did not think the policy course under discussion
today was of that type.
Secondly, Mr. Hayes said, he agreed with Mr. Daane that
Euro-dollar acquisitions by U.S. banks had not vitiated monetary
policy and were not likely to do so.

As far as banks in New York

were concerned, he did not have the impression that their positions
were considerably easier, apart from seasonal factors, than those
of other banks in the country.

There had been a short-run seasonal

swing in reserves in the favor of New York banks during the last

2/4/69

-86

few weeks.

At the same time, they had experienced a higher rate

of CD attrition than the banking system as a whole, and that might
well continue.

From his conversations with New York bankers he

had the impression that they felt no more comfortable than the
Boston bankers to whom Mr. Morris had referred.

Insofar as there

was talk of monetary ease in banking circles, it seemed to be no
more extensive in New York than elsewhere.
Mr. Francis said he would like to amplify his earlier
observations on the money supply in view of Mr. Mitchell's comment
during the go-around.

He certainly preferred the January growth

rate of 4-1/2 per cent to the average rate of close to 8 per cent
in the three preceding months, but the money supply in January
nevertheless was still on the trend line of the past 24 months.
He hoped the lower rate of money growth projected by the staff for
1969 would be realized.

His basic concern, however, was that the

growth rates of the monetary aggregates, which he believed had an
influence on total demand, were "fall-outs" of policy rather than
the object of policy under the present method of System policy
formulation.
By unanimous vote, the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York was author
ized and directed, until otherwise
directed by the Committee, to execute
transactions in the System Account in
accordance with the following current
economic policy directive:

2/4/69

-87-

The information reviewed at this meeting suggests
that expansion in real economic activity has been
moderating, but that upward pressures on prices and
costs are persisting. Prospects are for some further
slowing in economic expansion in the period ahead.
Market interest rates recently have fluctuated near
the highs reached around the turn of the year. Bank
credit contracted slightly in January on average, as
the outstanding volume of large-denomination CD's
continued to decline sharply, inflows of other time
and savings deposits slowed, and growth in the money
supply moderated. The U.S. balance of payments on the
liquidity basis appears to have reverted to deficit in
early 1969, but large inflows of Euro-dollars have had
the effect of keeping the official settlements balance
in surplus. In this situation, it is the policy of the
Federal Open Market Committee to foster financial
conditions conducive to the reduction of inflationary
pressures, with a view to encouraging a more sustainable
rate of economic growth and attaining reasonable
equilibrium in the country's balance of payments.
To implement this policy, while taking account of
the current Treasury refunding, System open market
operations until the next meeting of the Committee
shall be conducted with a view to maintaining the
prevailing firm conditions in money and short-term
credit markets; provided, however, that operations
shall be modified, to the extent permitted by the
Treasury refunding, if bank credit appears to be
deviating significantly from current projections.
Mr. Farrell, Director of the Division of Federal Reserve
Bank Operations,.Board of Governors, entered the meeting at this
point.
Chairman Martin suggested that the Committee consider the
memoranda relating to the Treasury's cash and debt ceiling problems
to which Mr. Holmes had referred earlier.

He had discussed the

matter at some length with the Treasury people, and he understood

-88

2/4/69

the latter were canvassing the views of other officials of the
Administration and also members of the appropriate Congressional
Committees.

The possibility of seeking legislation to increase

the statutory debt ceiling was being actively explored.

The

proposals for assisting the Treasury in connection with their
problems should be viewed as measures for possible use in case of
an emergency need; it was to be hoped that the Treasury would not
have to rely on them. At the moment some people thought that the
Treasury's problems were not as acute as had appeared earlier, but
not everyone was agreed that that was the case.
In response to the Chairman's request for comment, Mr. Holmes
said he had little to add to his memorandum of January 30.

As noted

in that memorandum, the Treasury had been reviewing alternative
means of meeting their combined cash and debt ceiling problems,
including three that would require Federal Reserve assistance.

Of

the three, one would have involved immediate credit by the Reserve
Banks for Government deposits.

However, it was the opinion of

Federal Reserve counsel that the Reserve Banks were not authorized
to grant immediate credit to the Treasury while denying such credit
to other depositors, and the Treasury had agreed to withdraw that
suggestion since alternative means of System assistance were

available.

The second means would involve a speed-up of payments

to the Treasury of interest on outstanding Federal Reserve notes

-89

2/4/69

not secured by gold certificates, and there appeared to be no
particular problems with such a procedure.

While the benefits to

the Treasury would be relatively small, they might conceivably
help to ease the Treasury through the crucial period.
The third possible means of Federal Reserve assistance,
Mr. Holmes continued, would involve warehousing by the System of
foreign exchange assets held by the Exchange Stabilization Fund.
At the moment, the Fund held slightly over $800 million of foreign
currencies, including about $730 million of sterling.

Thus, the

warehousing approach, if implemented, undoubtedly would provide an
adequate backstop for the Treasury.
In his judgment, Mr. Holmes said, the Treasury's position
now looked better than it had earlier.

Treasury officials were

continuing to explore avenues other than those involving Federal
Reserve assistance.

It would be unthinkable for the Federal

Government to violate the debt ceiling, and the prospect of the
Treasury's failing to pay its bills was not a pleasant one.
Accordingly, if as a last resort the Treasury asked the System to
warehouse foreign currencies temporarily, it might be desirable
for the System to cooperate.
The Chairman then noted that a memorandum from the
Committee's General Counsel, on the legal aspects of the matter,
had been distributed on January 31.
comment.

He asked Mr. Hackley to

-90

2/4/69

Mr. Hackley said it seemed fairly obvious that the best
solution to the Treasury's problem would be an increase in the
statutory debt ceiling.

Since, as Mr. Holmes stated in his

memorandum, "the Treasury's problem was not related in any way
to current developments in the international situation," the
proposed warehousing of foreign currencies might be criticized
not only on the grounds that it involved a direct extension of
credit to the Treasury but also on the grounds that it was a
device to enable the Treasury to get around the statutory debt
ceiling.

However, if it appeared that a timely increase in the

debt ceiling was not likely, and if System warehousing of foreign
exchange holdings of the Stabilization Fund appeared to be the
only practicable means by which the Treasury could avoid either
breaching the debt ceiling or failing to meet its contractual
obligations, he thought such warehousing operations would be
legally defensible.
The Chairman then noted that a third memorandum on the
subject, from the Secretariat, had been distributed on February 3.
He asked Mr. Holland to comment.
Mr. Holland observed that the bulk of the Secretariat's
memorandum consisted of a hypothetical entry for the Committee's
record of policy actions that might be used if and when the
Committee formally approved the warehousing proposal.

The staff

thought the hypothetical entry might be helpful to the Committee

-91

2/4/69

in articulating a possible basis for Committee agreement on the
matter.

That basis would consist of the following elements.

First,

the Committee would agree to approve the warehousing proposal
formally--perhaps by telegraphic vote of the members--only after
receipt of advice from the Treasury that there was no practicable
alternative if the Treasury were to meet its cash needs while
staying within the debt ceiling.

Secondly, the agreement to

warehouse foreign currencies would be temporary in two senses--in
that warehousing would be undertaken only "in the months immediately
ahead," and in that any foreign currencies warehoused by the System
would be reacquired by the Exchange Stabilization Fund "within a
reasonably short period."

The staff had not proposed any explicit

time limits, but the Committee might want to specify particular
dates.
In addition to offering the hypothetical policy record
entry, Mr. Holland said, the Secretariat's memorandum raised the
question of whether immediate public disclosure of the warehousing
operations should be made if they were undertaken.

The memorandum

noted various possible forms of disclosure, either by the System
alone or in a joint announcement with the Treasury.
Mr. Heflin remarked that since the System could be subject
to hostile criticism in the matter it was important in his view to
proceed extremely carefully.

In that connection, he noted that

2/4/69

-92

Mr. Hackley had said in his memorandum that his opinion that there
would be no legal objection to adopting the warehousing proposal
was "premised, of course, upon the assumption that legislation
increasing the debt ceiling cannot reasonably be expected in time
to resolve the Treasury's problem."

He (Mr. Heflin) thought the

Treasury should be urged to seek an increase in the debt ceiling
before asking the System to warehouse foreign currencies.

In his

judgment warehousing operations would be hard to defend if an
increase in the debt ceiling had not been sought.

There would be

a better justification for such operations if legislation had been
requested but for some reason was not enacted in time.
Chairman Martin commented that Mr. Heflin's point was well
taken.
Mr. Maisel said he had no objection to the general principle
of the proposed warehousing operations.

He objected strongly,

however, to the basis for such operations suggested by the staff
in the hypothetical policy record entry.

In particular, he was

disturbed by the language of the draft proposing agreement by the
Committee that "under existing circumstances it would be appropriate
in the months immediately ahead for the Federal Reserve to warehouse
Stabilization Fund holdings of foreign currencies temporarily if
necessary for the purpose of enabling the Treasury to meet its cash
needs while staying within the debt ceiling."

That statement

2/4/69

-93

implied to him that the System's objective would be simply to
enable the Treasury to avoid the legal debt ceiling.
In his judgment, Mr. Maisel continued, a much better basis
for the proposed warehousing operations was available--namely, the
need to coordinate the foreign currency operations of the System
and the Treasury.

That was an area which the Committee had

considered and acted upon on a number of occasions in the past.
On those occasions, he had pointed out the need for a better
coordination in concepts and decision-making of the System's and
Treasury's operations with respect to short- and intermediate-term
credit to and from central banks and governments.

The present

situation made clear the need for such coordination.
One means by which the Treasury might resolve its current
problems, Mr. Maisel observed, would be to sell the foreign
currency holdings of the Stabilization Fund in the market, but
such sales clearly would have highly undesirable consequences
from the point of view of the System as well as the Treasury.

He

thought it would be appropriate for the System to warehouse foreign
currencies temporarily for the Treasury for the purpose of avoiding
the need for their sale in the market.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that he shared that view.

He noted

that Mr. Hackley's memorandum had referred to the possibility that
the Treasury might find itself obliged to sell large amounts of

-94

2/4/69

foreign currency holdings in the market in order to stay within
the debt ceiling, and that such sales could result in disorderly
exchange market conditions.

However, in a postscript to the

Secretariat's memorandum Mr. Hackley had asked that that statement
be regarded as omitted, and the Secretariat's memorandum itself
made no reference to market sales.

He (Mr. Mitchell) favored

assisting the Treasury temporarily by warehousing foreign currencies,
but would prefer to do so on the grounds that Mr. Maisel had
mentioned.
Mr. Daane said he thought there would be difficulties with
the course Mr. Maisel had proposed.

For the Committee to imply in

its published policy record that the sale in the market of the
Stabilization Fund's foreign exchange holdings had even been
considered as a realistic possibility could have damaging effects
on the attitudes of the System's central bank partners.

The general

approach taken in the staff's hypothetical entry seemed appropriate
to him, although some editorial changes and a shortening of the
text might be desirable.
Mr. Hayes indicated that he agreed with Mr. Daane.

He

noted that an early draft of the Secretariat's memorandum, which
had been sent to Messrs. Coombs and Holmes for comment, had
referred to the possible sale in the market of the Stabilization
Fund's foreign currency holdings.
would be unrealistic and dangerous.

In his judgment, such language

2/4/69

-95
In response to a request for comment, Mr. Bodner said he

thought the problem with which Mr. Maisel was concerned seemed
less serious when the passage the latter had quoted from the
hypothetical policy record entry was read in the context of the
full entry--particularly against the background of a preceding
statement to the effect that "among the factors contributing to
the currently low cash position of the Treasury were past operations
of the Exchange Stabilization Fund in acquiring pounds sterling and
German marks . . . in implementing the international financial
policies of the United States."

Perhaps any residual problem could

be met by modifying the draft language while maintaining the present
general framework.
Mr. Bodner went on to say that, as Mr. Holmes had noted
earlier, the bulk of the Stabilization Fund's present foreign
currency holdings consisted of sterling.

Of the latter, $383

million consisted of guaranteed sterling.

There were certain

understandings between the Treasury and the Bank of England
regarding the disposition of such holdings.

The remaining $355

million of sterling represented the counterpart of short-term swap
drawings by the Bank of England on the Treasury.

In his judgment

it would be completely counter to the purpose of the arrangement
for the Treasury, having extended short-term credits to a foreign
central bank, to think in terms of selling the related IOU's in
the market.

To do so would simply render such swaps meaningless.

2/4/69

-96
More generally, Mr. Bodner said, any suggestion that

under certain conditions the Treasury would consider dumping a
substantial part of its sterling holdings on the market could
have extremely serious effects in the market itself.

In addition,

as Mr. Daane had indicated, such a suggestion could have adverse
effects on the attitudes of the System's central bank partners.
Mr. Maisel noted that the Committee had already authorized
System warehousing of Stabilization Fund holdings of guaranteed
sterling to assist the Fund if its resources were inadequate to
meet the demands on them. As to the Fund's other holdings of
sterling--those that were a counterpart of British swap drawings
on the Treasury--the System might agree to take over those drawings
temporarily if the Treasury could not afford to carry them.

It

seemed to him that such procedures were to be preferred over a
procedure in which the System, in effect, lent money to the
Treasury to enable it to get around the debt ceiling statute.
Chairman Martin remarked that extensions of credit to the
British might well have originally been undertaken exclusively by
the System rather than jointly by the System and the Treasury.
Mr. Brimmer said he wanted to associate himself with
Mr. Heflin's view that the Treasury should be urged to seek an
increase in the debt ceiling before asking the System to assist
it by warehousing foreign currencies.

If the Treasury then still

2/4/69

-97

needed assistance he would hope that the System would provide it
by warehousing guaranteed sterling--in the manner already provided
for under earlier arrangements--rather than by taking over other
assets of the Stabilization Fund.

He added that the hypothetical

policy record entry said past operations of the Stabilization Fund
were "among the factors" contributing to the Treasury's low cash
position.

But certainly the most important factor was the level

of Federal expenditures, and it was with the latter in mind that
Congress had enacted the debt ceiling statute.

He thought it

would be highly undesirable for the System to act simply on the
basis of helping the Treasury avoid the debt ceiling.
Mr. Hickman said he was disturbed by the proposal to
publish a statement which could be read to imply that the System
had warehoused Stabilization Fund assets to enable the Treasury
to avoid the debt ceiling.

He would favor deletion of the passage

in the hypothetical policy record entry that Mr. Maisel had quoted
earlier if an entry on the matter were eventually published in the
Committee's policy record.
Mr. Holmes noted that any warehousing transactions the
System might undertake would be reflected in the figures shown in
the System's weekly condition statement.

Since the Treasury's

debt ceiling problem was well known, it would not be difficult
for an outside observer to make a connection between that problem

-98

2/4/69

and the change in the figures shown in the condition statement.
In his judgment it would be better to search for language for the
policy record that would make the proper connection between
warehousing operations and the debt ceiling problem rather than
to delete references to the debt ceiling from the entry.

Mr. Daane concurred in Mr. Holmes' observation.
Mr. Brimmer added that if the Treasury sought legislation
to increase the debt ceiling the subject would clearly be in the
public domain.
Mr. Daane commented that in the interest of reducing the
likelihood that System warehousing operations would be needed it
might be desirable to urge the Treasury to go as far as feasible
in shifting securities held by the trust funds into outstanding
marketable issues.

He agreed with the view of counsel that it

would not be appropriate for the Reserve Banks to grant immediate
credit on Government deposits.

However, he thought the proposal

to speed up System interest payments on Federal Reserve notes
should be given favorable consideration, particularly if, as the
Manager had suggested was conceivable, the marginal contribution
of that step might be adequate to meet the Treasury's problem.
Chairman Martin remarked that he thought there would be
no disagreement with respect to the desirability of speeding up
System interest payments if that would be helpful to the Treasury.

2/4/69

-99

The question, of course, was whether it would be particularly
helpful.
The Chairman then said he would pursue his discussions of
the warehousing proposal with the Treasury on the basis of the
comments today, which he understood to reflect a general sentiment
in favor of assisting the Treasury in that manner if there were no
practicable alternative available.

To his mind the issue Mr. Heflin

had raised was a key one, and in his discussions he would try to
make sure that the Treasury officials fully understood the System's
position on the matter.

The Committee did not have to decide today

on the language of the policy record entry to be published in the
event such warehousing was undertaken, but he was sure that the
members would want to adhere to the System's policy of full
disclosure.
It was agreed that the next meeting of the Committee would
be held on March 4, 1969, at 9:30 a.m.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

ATTACHMENT A
February 3, 1969
Draft of Current Economic Policy Directive for Consideration by the
Federal Open Market Committee at its meeting on February 4, 1969
The information reviewed at this meeting suggests that
expansion in real economic activity has been moderating, but that
upward pressures on prices and costs are persisting. Prospects
are for some further slowing in economic expansion in the period
ahead. Market interest rates recently have fluctuated near the
highs reached around the turn of the year. Bank credit contracted
slightly in January on average, as the outstanding volume of
large-denomination CD's continued to decline sharply, inflows of
other time and savings deposits slowed, and growth in the money
supply moderated. The U.S. balance of payments on the liquidity
basis appears to have reverted to deficit in early 1969, but
large inflows of Euro-dollars have had the effect of keeping the
official settlements balance in surplus. In this situation, it
is the policy of the Federal Open Market Committee to foster
financial conditions conducive to the reduction of inflationary
pressures, with a view to encouraging a more sustainable rate of
economic growth and attaining reasonable equilibrium in the
country's balance of payments.
To implement this policy, while taking account of the
current Treasury refunding, System open market operations until
the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a view
to maintaining the prevailing firm conditions in money and
short-term credit markets; provided, however, that operations
shall be modified, to the extent permitted by the Treasury
refunding, if bank credit appears to be deviating significantly
from current projections.