View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC NOTES
February 3 & 4, 1994
Peter Ryerson Fisher
Mr. Chairman:
Through the end of December and into early January, the
dollar rose against both the mark and the yen.

In recent weeks,

however, there has been a growing disparity in the course of
these exchange rates:

while dollar-mark has traded comfortably

in a range, dollar-yen has declined sharply.

In the end of December, the dollar began a sharp rise
against the mark, from 1.70 on December 17th to 1.75 on
January 14th, as market participants positioned themselves to
take advantage of the expected narrowing of interest rate
differentials.

The dollar also rose against the yen, from 109.50

at your last meeting to an intra-day high of 113.50 on
January 5th, as increasingly negative sentiment toward the
Japanese economy and positive sentiment toward the U.S. economy
continued to widen expected interest rate differentials.

On January 6th (and again on the 20th), the Bundesbank
announced that it would continue to conduct its weekly market
operations at a fixed rate of 6 percent, putting off market
expectations for any immediate reduction in official rates.
Although short-term mark interest rates stabilized and the
recently-established 20-basis-point differential in favor of the
10-year U.S. bond was quickly eliminated, the dollar did not give

-

2

-

up its end-of-year gains against the mark.

Instead, dollar-mark

has traded in range from roughly 1.72 to 1.74 while one-month
implied options volatilities have declined to low levels.

Since January 24th, the dollar has declined against the yen,
first gradually and then more sharply, in recent days returning
to levels last seen in late November.

Some in the market view

the end-of-year run-up in dollar-yen as reflecting a speculative
push, and the subsequent decline as a technical correction.
Whether or not that is the case, at the turn of the year the
foreign exchange market appeared to be focusing on the disparity
in current economic fundamentals, and the likelihood that
Japanese interest rates would fall and U.S. rates would rise.
January two things happened.

In

First, there was a reduction in the

extent of expected easing by the Bank of Japan.

Second, market

participants abruptly shifted their attention to the lack of
progress in the bilateral trade talks.

As dollar-yen began to decline, it traded in increasingly
choppy and nervous markets.

These conditions appear to have been

triggered by the still-uncertain consequences of the combination
of:
1st, repeated comments by Treasury officials on the need for
Japan to address its trade and current account surpluses;
2nd, the fluid reality of political reform, tax policy and
fiscal stimulus in Japan;

- 3

-

3rd, the surprising inflow of foreign capital into the
Japanese equity market; and
4th, the lack of apparent progress in bilateral trade talks
leading up to the Clinton-Hosokawa meeting.
Thus, from January 25th to February 1st, the dollar declined by 3
percent against the yen while one-month implied option
volatilities rose sharply and now exceed the level of 12-month
volatilities.

In recent months, both the Bundesbank and the Bank of Japan
have become increasingly sensitive to movements in their
respective dollar exchange rates:

the Bundesbank to a rapid

weakening of the mark and the Bank of Japan to further yen
appreciation.

The Bundesbank sees the dollar-mark exchange rate as the
principal risk in its outlook for German inflation in 1994.
There is both the direct impact on import prices and the indirect
impact on the Bundesbank's credibility of "too rapid" a decline
in the mark.

For the second year in a row, the Bundesbank finds

itself explaining excessive growth in German M3 -- which was
announced today for December at 8.1 percent.

By appearing to

slow the pace of reductions in official rates and by selling
dollars at times of mark weakness, the Bundesbank is seeking to
avoid rapid exchange rate movements that could impair its
credibility as defender of the mark's external value.

- 4 -

The Bank of Japan, on the other hand, is concerned that
a further, sustained rise of the yen could have severe, negative
consequences for the Japanese economy.

Although consumption is

not expected to lead any recovery, the Bank of Japan perceives a
risk that a significant decline in employment could cause a
deterioration in incomes and consumer confidence that would
create a downward spiral for the economy.

While drastic cut-

backs in employment are not a normal feature of the Japanese
economy, the Bank of Japan does expect labor market conditions to
worsen.

Over the last few months, Bank of Japan officials have

Mr.

Chairman,

we had no operations during the period.

Notes for

FOMC Meeting

February 3-4,

1994

Joan E. Lovett

Desk operations continued to seek reserve conditions

consistent with Federal funds trading around 3 percent.

The

borrowing allowance was held at $50 million throughout the period
as the seasonal component remained very low.
At the start of the interval, we anticipated that the
very large add need spanning the year-end would rapidly recede
during January as required reserves and currency fell back from
seasonally elevated levels.

While this general pattern held

true, we faced considerable uncertainty about actual reserve
needs as the estimates were subject to frequent revisions for a
variety of reasons.
In the year-end period, we expected demand for excess

reserves to run high, as is typically the case around this time.
But given the dating of the holiday, it was unclear how much
additional excess banks would want and when in the period they
wanted it.

Late in the next period, ending January 19, the

severe weather front that crossed the eastern half of the country
disrupted normal reserve and information flows.

Residual effects

from the severe weather spilled over into the next period, which
ended yesterday and distorted the flow of tax receipts after the
filing deadline for individual non-withheld taxes.

In fact,

throughout this past interval, there were numerous large

2
projection misses of the Treasury balance, reflecting surprises
on both spending and taxes, and we frequently faced sharply
divergent forecasts of this balance.

Other operating factors

also proved difficult to predict--float, of course, because of
the series of winter storms--and currency which has not behaved
in accordance with past seasonal patterns.
Because of the uneven reserve picture over the
interval, we relied almost exclusively on temporary operations.
To ensure adequate liquidity through the year-end, four large
fixed-term System RPs were arranged early in the first
maintenance period.

On the year-end date itself, the value of

RPs in place was about $15 billion.

As a consequence,

trading in

the money market proved to be generally calm and uneventful.
Weather-related operating difficulties at the close of
the January 19 period made it

difficult to gauge the true reserve

picture, with the funds rate quite firm relative to the
statistical need.

We took our cue from the money market and

added reserves on the settlement day.

As it

turned out,

float

that day also soared well above the elevated level we had already
allowed for.

Even with reserves so plentiful, conditions in the

money market stayed firm as the severe winter weather apparently
disrupted normal trading patterns and left banks desirous of an
unusually high level of excess reserves.
In the period just ended, a reserve surplus was seen
initially, as is fairly typical for this time of year, and the
Desk arranged a round of matched sale-purchase agreements over

3
the first weekend.

The picture soon reversed itself, however, as

tax receipts began to surge, in part reflecting weather-delayed
processing of payments, and government spending persistently fell
short of expectations.

With the Treasury's TT&L capacity at the

banks about exhausted, these revisions had a direct impact on
reserve availability.

We thus provided reserves aggressively

over recent days as these balances peaked.
Federal funds mostly traded close to the desired
3 percent level, and the effective rate averaged 3.04 percent for
the full period.

It was rather high over the last few days and

on isolated other occasions reflecting particular situations.
For the period, adjustment borrowing averaged $71 million.
In the securities markets, interest rates moved in
about a 25 basis point band over the intermeeting period, but
stayed within previously established trading ranges.

On

balance, rates on shorter-term Treasury coupons were down about
10-15 basis points while long-term yields were unchanged to down
10 basis points.
By and large, the economic data underscored the
strength in output in the fourth quarter that had already become
fairly evident, and which was confirmed by last Friday's GDP
report.

The December payroll employment number, however, caused

yields to fall.

The overall report did not seem all that weak,

but the market had come to believe that the recent strength in
output would begin to show through more fully to job creation,

4
and a larger payroll gain had already been discounted.
Meanwhile, price data was generally supportive of the market.
The PPI in mid-January and the latest GDP deflators released last
week brought most rates to their lowest levels of the period.
Investors still have many of the same questions about
the pace of the recent improvement in activity as they had
before.

And now, distortions caused by the severe winter

weather, and possibly by the California earthquake, are seen as
likely to muddy the picture for a while longer.

Currently, the

most prevalent view seems to be that the economy will continue to
forge ahead at least at a moderate pace--after allowing for
distortions to the data.

A firming in policy is seen as a

question of when and not if.

Most participants see a move coming

within the next two months as enough data would be in hand to
give the Fed a visible case for acting.

The Chairman's testimony

led some to consider a move as possible sooner rather than later,
and some see the current meeting a possible forum for that.

This

was not the majority view but has been the source of more active
discussion today.

In part, this comes from some of the recent

data--for example, the price component in the NAPM--but mostly
from some perceptions that Desk inaction to provide reserves this
morning was an attempt to tell the market something.

Most

analysts do not see the Desk operating in this fashion and are
aware that the meeting had not yet begun.

Nonetheless, there is

a vocal group who see it as meaningful, and I mention it as an
indication of market skittishness.

5
Given these crosscurrents, the tendency of dealers has
been to trade from the short side.

Thus, unexpected news or

customer order flows have pressed against these shorts and
produced a fair degree of day-to-day variability in rates.
Meanwhile, the premium on the latest 30-year Treasury bond has
diminished somewhat further,

and the yield on this issue now

stands about 10-12 basis points below the rate on the prior bond.
However,

much of this narrowing in spread reflected widespread

expectations that the Treasury would reopen the current bond at
its

midquarter refinancing,

announcement yesterday.

and the Treasury did so in

its

Michael J. Prell
February 3, 1994

FOMC CHART SHOW PRESENTATION -- INTRODUCTION AND ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

Chart 1 summarizes the staff economic projection.

Before I

run through the numbers, though. I want to say just a few words about
how we arrived at the monetary policy assumption underlying this
scenario.

To start, we assumed that the federal funds rate would

remain at 3 percent for another couple of quarters.

This is somewhat

arbitrary but, especially given the prevailing symmetric directive, we
did not want to presume too much with regard to your near-term
decisions.

However, believing that maintenance of this policy stance

would likely stimulate an expansion of aggregate demand that would
abort the existing disinflationary trend by 1995 or

'96, we assumed a

gradual rise in the funds rate that we judged might be just sufficient
to avoid that outcome.

As was indicated in the Bluebook, we have the

funds rate moving up to 4-1/4 percent by the summer of 1995.
So described, our projection may seem awfully finely wrought,
given the uncertainty of forecasting.

But we hope that it will

provide a useful baseline against which you can apply your own
thinking regarding likely economic relations and the policy risks you
wish to take.

With that preamble, then, I'll turn to the broad

features of the projection laid out on this exhibit.
First, in the upper panel, you can see that we have real GDP
growing 3 percent this year and about 2-1/2 percent in 1995.

As the

panel also illustrates, output growth has been paced over the past two
years by the 5 percent increases in private domestic final demand-that is,

consumption plus business and residential fixed investment.

Over the forecast period, we see PDFD decelerating as pent-up demands

- 2 -

Michael J. Prell

February 3,

1994

and monetary stimulus diminish and as taxes rise; GDP growth will be
buoyed,

however,

by a lessening of the drags from government purchases

and the external sector.
With this output path, we anticipate that the civilian
unemployment rate will drop about 1/4 percentage point further before
leveling out--at what would have been about 6.2 percent under the
existing series,

but at what we are guessing will be about 6-3/4

percent under the new series that will be introduced tomorrow morning.
I can't emphasize too much,

though,

those numbers for some time.
should have noted in

the uncertainties that will attend

Moreover--and this is something we

the Greenbook--the expiration of the emergency

unemployment benefits program may tend to shave a bit from the jobless
rate over the next several months,
likely effects may be lost in

other things equal,

the statistical noise,

although the

if

not the

rounding.
In any event,

by our reckoning,

leave a rather modest degree of slack in

the projected growth will
the economy,

and so we are

expecting only grudging further progress toward price stability.
indicated in the bottom panel,

the core CPI is

As

projected to decelerate

just a tenth of a percent per year; owing to the anticipated paths of
food and energy prices, however, the overall CPI is forecast to
accelerate to something over 3 percent.
As I have noted,

we are assuming that monetary policy will be

shifting in a less expansionary direction.

But, in general, we see

financial conditions overall as positive for growth.
illustrates a few key points in

this regard.

Chart 2

The upper left panel

shows the reduction that has occurred in household debt-service
burdens.

As you know, consumers have shown a willingness of late to

exploit their enhanced debt capacity,

and we anticipate that their

Michael J. Prell

- 3 -

February 3, 1994

borrowing will continue to exceed income growth over the next two

years; still, given our interest rate outlook, this will not raise
their debt-service burdens noticeably.
Similarly, at the right, nonfinancial corporations have
greatly reduced their interest expenses; and other indexes of their
financial health also have improved greatly.

This suggests that,

should they perceive attractive investment opportunities, they will
have the capacity to expand their borrowing.
The middle two panels relate to the supply of funds.

At the

left, you can see that the enormous growth of mutual funds has enabled
them to capture a major share of the debt and equity markets.

We are

projecting that these flows will slacken some, partly on the thought
that much of the most footloose money may already have shifted out of
deposits, and partly in the anticipation that--even if long-term rates
remain in the recent range, as we expect--the returns earned by the
funds will moderate and be less enticing to investors.

But the

projected mutual fund flows are still sufficient to provide
considerable support to the capital markets.
Should there be any glitches in this sanguine outlook, and
investors pull back somewhat more from the mutual funds, commercial
banks appear both more able and more willing to extend credit.

As

shown at the right, our loan officer survey has indicated an ongoing
shift toward easier terms for a while now.
The bottom panel illustrates our expectation that the
projected growth of private spending would not require massive amounts
of external finance.

Total funds raised by households and businesses

increase only moderately relative to GDP, at a time when governmental
borrowing should be diminishing.

- 4 -

Michael J. Prell

February 3, 1994

Let me turn now to a discussion of the spending outlook
behind these credit flows.

Chart 3 portrays key features of our

projection of consumer spending.

As may be seen in the top panels, we

are expecting that the growth of real PCE will decelerate somewhat
over the projection period, as it moves into line with increases in

disposable income.
I suspect that, by now, many of you have heard more than
enough conjectures about the decline in the personal saving rate since
mid-1992.

I'll be happy to return to this topic later if you would

like, but for the time being, I'm going to jump to the bottom line in
terms of the interpretation that shaped our forecast.

Basically, we

think that what may have occurred is simply a variant on the kind of
step-ups in consumer demand and declines in the saving rate that have
occurred during some earlier business cycle upswings.

In the latter

half of 1992--as the unemployment rate finally turned down--low
interest rates, household reliquification, and improving--albeit
erratically--confidence combined with some pent-up demand to produce
an upturn in purchases of durables.
If you look at the black line in the middle panel, you'll
notice that there have been dips in the personal saving rate in each
expansion period.

In each case, there was a marked pickup in spending

on consumer durables; households, in effect, substituted investments
in real assets for financial saving.

An alternative measure of

saving--the red line--that adds on net investment in consumer
durables, tends to flatten out these dips--and has done so in the most
recent period.
The bottom left panel focuses on one of the drivers behind
the surge in durables outlays--motor vehicles.

Sales of cars and,

especially, light trucks, rose substantially in 1993.

In the fourth

Michael J.

Prell

- 5 -

February 3, 1994

quarter, the annual pace was almost 14.6 million units, a respectable
level, and one high enough to begin to eat into the demand for
replacement of the old vehicles on the road.

In the forecast, this

process continues, as sales edge a tad higher.
The right panel looks at other consumer durables and
illustrates the historical correlation of such spending with housing
transactions.

We are projecting that there will be strong increases

in these expenditures in the near term, but that outlays will
decelerate considerably by the latter half of this year as home sales
slow somewhat.
This brings me to the next chart, chart 4, which deals with
the outlook for the housing sector.

There likely was some flukiness

to the extraordinarily strong December numbers on single-family starts
and new home sales.

But, looking at recent survey readings on

consumer attitudes regarding homebuying conditions and the economic
fundamentals, we are persuaded that there is a strong underlying
demand for homes--one that can persist for some time, if long-term
mortgage rates remain near recent levels.

The forecasted volumes of

1.3 million single-family starts in 1994 and just a little less in
1995 are quite high by the standards of recent years.
The case many analysts make against such robust numbers is
the existence of unfavorable demographic trends.

As the middle-left

panel indicates, it has been projected that household formations will
average 1.2 million per year during the first half of this decade.
Translating this into an underlying demand for housing, with due
allowance for demolitions, mobile homes, and so on, one would not
arrive at a demand for units--singles and multis--nearly so high as
the 1-1/2 million that we've forecast.

But there surely is some

elasticity in the rate of household formation in the short run, and

- 6 -

Michael J. Prell

February 3, 1994

there also is the potential for a considerable increase in the rate of
homeownership.

As may be seen at the right, the homeownership rate

has slipped in the past decade or so after trending upward for many
years.

We suspect that not all of this was a voluntary lifestyle

choice, but that it reflected at least in part basic problems of
affordability.

The recent sluggishness of home prices and decline in

mortgage rates hasn't cured all of these problems, but as you can see
at the lower left, the ratio of the typical monthly mortgage payment
on a new home to average household disposable income has dropped
enormously.

We think that this will continue to promote the influx of

first-time homebuyers.
Of course, many of these folks will be moving out of
apartments, and the multifamily rental vacancy rate--graphed at the
right--has only begun to move down from an extremely elevated level.
Conditions for apartment building appear good in some locales, but we
are anticipating that, overall, multifamily starts will post only a
limited advance within the projection period.
Besides consumer durables and housing, the other major source
of strength as the year began was business fixed investment.

As the

upper right-panel of chart 5 indicates, real BFI increased almost 15
percent last year and we are projecting rather hefty, though smaller,
gains in 1994 and '95.

The graph at the left illustrates the major

role of computer outlays in this growth:

they accounted for fully

half the BFI gain in 1993 and, from their now higher base, we expect
that they will account for even larger shares over the next two years,
despite a considerably reduced growth rate.
There are several reasons for this relative strength, but the
middle left panel highlights one rather compelling factor: computers
have been getting cheaper at a fast clip.

Although, in our forecast,

Michael J. Prell

- 7 -

February 3, 1994

interest rates will no longer be moving in a direction that lowers the
cost of capital, the continuing sharp decline in their prices will be
reducing further the expense of using computers.
As I noted, we do expect some slowing in the growth of
computer purchases and of overall business fixed investment.

This

would be anticipated on the basis of the flattening out of GDP growth
over the past couple of years--the so-called accelerator effect--and
it also is consistent with the slower growth of corporate cash flow
going forward.

The panel at the right shows that capital spending,

including inventory investment, is projected to exceed internally
generated funds by a widening--though still not troublesome--margin.
The bottom panels relate to inventories.

We expect that

businesses will be continuing to look for ways to minimize inventory
costs and that this will keep the stock-to-sales ratio tilted
downward, as shown at the left.

On this assumption, we have projected

a moderate rate of nonfarm inventory accumulation, which makes no
significant contribution to GDP growth.
Turning now to the government sector, chart 6 illustrates the
point I mentioned early on, that federal fiscal policy will be
exerting an ongoing drag on domestic demand.

The direct effects of

restraint on federal purchases of goods and services are shown in the
top panels.

Given trends in appropriations, we think that the

contraction in defense purchases probably will slow over the next two
years, but the decline is still large enough to put the annual changes
in total purchases in decidedly negative territory.
The middle panel looks at the federal sector in broader
terms.

Both the unified and the structural budget deficits are slated

to shrink appreciably.

One might argue that the jump in tax revenues

Michael J. Prell

- 8 -

February 3,

1994

this year overstates the current restrictive force, because people-knowing the increases in rates were ahead--may already have adjusted
their spending in 1993.

We believe that this is true to a degree, but

that there will be a significant bite this year.
Many state and local governmental units also have been under
budgetary pressure in recent years.

Nonetheless, real purchases are

estimated to have risen 3 percent last year and we are projecting
further moderate gains in 1994-95.

Demands for services remain

intense, and with the bond markets affording most units ready access
to capital, construction has been quite strong.

We are anticipating

that building activity will remain at an elevated level, and the
operating and capital account deficit of the state and local sector is
projected to shrink only a little.
Peter will be completing the demand picture in a few minutes,
when he discusses the outlook for net exports, but I shall now leap
ahead to the aggregate supply and inflation picture.
some key facets of our labor market forecast.

Chart 7 portrays

First, we are

anticipating that improving efficiency will remain a major goal of
businesses, and that labor productivity will continue to rise
appreciably.

As the upper left panel illustrates, the recent behavior

of output per hour has conformed to the broad patterns of prior
cycles, if one assumes that the underlying trend of productivity
growth has picked up in the 1990s to approximately 1.4 percent per
annum.

If this way of thinking about what has been occurring is

right, productivity moved above trend as firms skimped on hiring with
the initial upturn in output and may not drop back to trend until we
get to the point in the cycle where lower quality labor and older
machinery must be brought into play.

We are projecting that output

Michael J. Prell

- 9 -

February 3, 1994

per hour will rise at the trend rate this year and decelerate just a
touch in 1995.
This implies that, to achieve the output growth we've
projected, there will have to be a moderate increase in hours of labor
input.

This can occur in two ways:

longer workweeks or more workers.

The fixed costs of hiring additional workers make extending hours
attractive; but we hesitate to extrapolate the rise in the workweek
that has already occurred and thus we expect that a larger proportion
of the increase in hours will translate into added employment.

As the

middle left panel illustrates, we are anticipating that payroll
increases will average around 175,000 per month in the near term and
slow to about 150,000 per month, on average, in 1995.
translated into percentage terms in the right panel.

This is
We are

anticipating similar gains in household employment, but the figure for
1994 shown in the table is distorted by the fact that the January
number that will be released tomorrow will incorporate a huge upward
adjustment to reflect the 1990 Census undercount of some segments of
the population.
In developing a projection of the unemployment rate, one of
course also needs to consider the supply of workers.

The labor force

participation rate has been a source of surprises in the past few
years, and our forecast therefore carries with it considerable
uncertainty.

The projection of some increase in the participation

rate assumes that the extended sideways movement of recent years
reflects a combination of trend and cyclical influences.

Our

expectation is that, as job opportunities multiply, participation will
turn upward.

Again, the labor force growth figures, listed at the

right, will be distorted by the adjustment of the population figures.
If we are wrong and the participation rate fails to break out of its

- 10 -

Michael J. Prell

February 3,

1994

sideways channel, then--other things equal--the result could be a more
rapid decline in unemployment and an intensification of pressures on
wages.
This brings me to the next chart, which deals with the
inflation outlook.

The upper left panel shows that we are projecting

that compensation per hour, as measured in the Employment Cost
Indexes, will continue to rise about 3-1/2 percent per year--the pace
observed in 1992 and 1993.

Although we think there is some wage-

damping slack in the economy overall, we are not sanguine about the
prospects for a further deceleration in nominal compensation over the
next two years.

In part, we are simply recognizing the flattening

that has occurred over the past two years when the amount of slack was
considerably greater.

But, in addition, reports of difficulty in

finding desired workers seem to be on the rise; pension funding
requirements appear likely to rise; and with consumer prices widely
anticipated to continue rising 3 percent or so, it appears unlikely
that employers with growing businesses are going to push wage
increases much below that rate.

As the red line indicates, though,

our 3-1/2 percent compensation forecast implies that real compensation
gains, measured in terms of consumer prices, will remain meager.
With trend unit labor costs rising just a little more than 2
percent per year, there would appear to be room for some further
deceleration of prices without reversing the cyclical expansion of
markups that has occurred.

One factor that could affect markup

behavior, however, is capacity utilization.
forecast of the utilization rate.

The right panel shows our

As you can see, revisions of the

figures, to be made public tomorrow morning, indicate slightly lower
utilization than the previous estimates.

Even so, the utilization

rate is projected to run considerably above its long-run average over

- 11 -

Michael J. Prell

the next two years.

February 3, 1994

The level remains below past cyclical peaks, but

-like the jobless rate--it does suggest that the margin of slack will
be getting rather narrow.

Although, as Peter will soon be discussing,

competition from abroad may be a mitigating factor to a degree, the
growing tightness in domestic plant use works against a substantial
narrowing of markups over unit labor costs.
Also working against an improved inflation performance in the
near term is the outlook for energy and food prices.

Foreseeing some

firming of the oil market, we are projecting that retail energy prices
will accelerate in the coming months.

We've anticipated a further hit

early in 1995 from the mandated use of reformulated gasoline.

On the

food side, shown at the right, we are projecting a somewhat firmer
retail price picture than we've seen over the past couple of years, a
legacy of the 1993 crop losses.
The bottom panel shows our projections of the overall CPI and
the core CPI on a quarterly basis.

Having described the broader

contours in my first chart, the main point of this panel is to take
note of the possibility we see that there will be a muted repeat this
year of the acceleration of the core CPI that occurred in the first
part of 1993.

The recent surge in business activity and rise in

resource utilization may prompt firms to be a bit more aggressive in
pricing, and so we've built into our inflation forecast a so-called
"speed" effect that unwinds as activity moderates over the next couple
of quarters.
Peter will now continue the presentation.

Chart Show
Peter Hooper
February 3, 1994
As Mike suggested, a question that is attracting growing
attention these days is the extent to which increasing economic
slack abroad is affecting the potential for inflation to pick up
in the United States.

In reviewing recent developments and our

outlook for the external sector, I will give particular emphasis
to the roles that key foreign variables are playing in damping
U.S. aggregate demand and restraining inflationary pressures.
The effects of weakness of economic activity abroad have
shown up clearly in foreign exchange markets.

As indicated in

the top left panel of Chart 9, since August 1992, the priceadjusted foreign exchange value of the dollar in terms of G-10
currencies

(the solid red line) has appreciated substantially,

from the bottom of the broad range that has prevailed in recent
years to near the top of that range.

Given the average lags of

one to two years over which exchange rate movements affect trade
flows, this most recent upswing in the dollar has important
implications for the current forecast period.
When we add in the currencies of the eight key U.S.
trading partners among developing countries

(as shown by the

dotted line in the chart and at the bottom of the panel on the
right), the dollar has appreciated somewhat less since August
1992.

In fact, the dollar has depreciated on average against the

currencies of these eight countries, whose real growth, on the
whole, has been considerably more robust than that of the G-10.
As indicated in the middle left panel, among the G-10
(and in nominal terms),

the dollar has risen most against the

- 2 -

European currencies, less against the Canadian dollar, and has
depreciated on balance against the yen.

The rise in the dollar

against the G-10 average has been associated with an increase in
the differential in real long-term interest rates (the black line
in the chart above),
rates.

as foreign rates have fallen more than U.S.

The middle right panel shows that German short-term and

long-term rates have declined substantially more than U.S. rates
over the past year and a half.

This is less true of Japanese

rates; and as Peter Fisher has indicated, the relative strength
of the yen is attributable to other factors, including the
influence of Japan's large and growing trade and current account
surpluses on market expectations.
We expect short-term rates abroad to decline somewhat
further over the period ahead and long-term rates to edge down.
Our outlook has the dollar on average remaining about unchanged
from its recent level.
Turning to recent indicators for the G-6 foreign
industrial countries, the top left panel of Chart 10 shows
average industrial production and inflation in the two countries
whose economic recoveries are now well under way.

Output in

Canada and the United Kingdom combined has risen since mid-1992,
and underlying inflation has leveled off in the past year.

In

Continental Europe and Japan, however, IP has continued to
decline, although the rate of decline has slowed; meanwhile,
inflation has receded a bit further.

We think that real output

in Japan and France has bottomed out, but that output in Germany
could weaken a bit further early this year.

- 3 -

The projected economic recovery in the foreign G-6 over
the next two years is sluggish in comparison to previous cycles.
One reason is the significant drag imposed by fiscal
consolidation, as indicated in the middle two panels.

In Canada

and the United Kingdom, both structural budget deficits (the
black bars) and actual budget deficits

(the red bars) are

projected to decline--the actual by amounts exceeding 1 percent
of GDP per year.

In Continental Europe and Japan combined, the

structural deficit is expected to decline, but the actual deficit
could widen slightly this year.

The picture for Europe alone is

considerably more contractionary than that shown here; in Japan,
recent and expected fiscal packages are expected to be a major
source of stimulus in the near term.

The tax cut proposal

announced today is roughly in line with the assumption underlying
our forecast, though the timing of its implementation remains
uncertain.
Outside Japan, we expect that the primary stimulus to
growth will be past and some moderate further easing of monetary
policy.

As indicated in the bottom panels, short-term real

interest rates have declined to near their lows of the past
decade, and we expect rates in Europe to decline somewhat further
this year.

Nevertheless, monetary policy abroad can still be

described as cautious overall, and we do not expect real rates to
move to anywhere near the negative levels seen during the 1970s.
Our outlook for foreign real GDP growth is summarized in
the top two panels of the next chart.

We expect overall foreign

growth (the red bars in the left panel), to continue to fall
short of U.S. growth in 1994, but to exceed U.S. growth in 1995.

-

4

-

The breakdown of foreign growth in the right panel shows the G-6,
other smaller foreign industrial countries, and developing
countries all contributing to the pickup.

As indicated in the

middle left panel, growth in Canada and the U.K. combined is
expected to continue at or slightly above its recent pace, while
growth in the other G-6 countries remains relatively weak this
year and picks up more noticeably in 1995.

The beneficial

effects of the NAFTA for Mexico should be reflected in a
pickup in that country's real growth.

We expect the NIEs and

China to continue growing rapidly, with China's expansion slowing
a bit from last year's pace.
The relatively slow recovery of the G-6 countries on
average is reflected in a slight further widening of their output
gap in 1994, as shown in the middle right panel.
level off in 1995, however.

The gap should

This economic slack will further

depress consumer price inflation in the G-6 countries
line in the bottom left panel),

(the red

and we expect to see the average

rate of inflation fall below two percent over the forecast
period.

As indicated in the bottom right we expect to see

inflation receding in Japan, Germany, France, and Italy.
The importance of the various regions of the world as
markets for U.S. exports is illustrated in the top left panel of
Chart 12.

In 1992, Canada and the United Kingdom together

accounted for about one-fourth of our exports, other industrial
countries about one-third, and developing countries the remaining
40+ percent.

As indicated in the top right panel, over the past

20 years, the share of exports going to developing countries
(line 4) has increased 10 percentage points, with Mexico and Asia

- 5 -

(lines 5 and 6)

the big gainers,

while the share going to

industrial countries has declined.
A breakdown of the recent growth of exports by region is
shown in the middle left panel.
(line 4)

In 1992, developing countries

accounted for all of the growth in

exports.

In

1993,

a

significant portion of the increase went to industrial countries
(line 1),

but that expansion was more than accounted for by

Canada and the United Kingdom (line 2),
industrial countries

as exports to other

(line 3) declined further.

Looking ahead, we expect the growth of real exports of
goods and of services

(lines 1 and 5 of the middle right panel)

to pick up over the forecast period.

The higher growth of goods

exports reflects a slow recovery in shipments of agricultural
commodities

(line 2),

exports of computers.

and, more importantly,

rapid growth of

Computer exports should accelerate as the

new generation of microprocessors shifts demand somewhat toward
U.S. production.

The growth of other exports

(line 4),

which

account for more than three-fourths of total goods exports, is
expected to remain unchanged at 3 percent per year.

We think the

anticipated stimulus from faster growth abroad will be offset by
the depressing effect of the appreciation of the dollar over the
past year and a half.
The growth of real exports of goods and services (the
blue line in

the bottom panel)

growth by a significant margin.

is

projected to exceed real GDP
But most of the pickup in export

growth is in computer exports, which we expect will be offset by
an even greater expansion of computer imports.

Excluding

-

computers

6

-

(the red line) export growth is expected to exceed GDP

growth by a much smaller margin.
Turning to imports, the breakdown of U.S. imports by
region (the top left panel of chart 13)

looks similar to that for

exports, although Japan's share of the import pie is somewhat
larger than it was for exports.

The recent growth of imports

(top right panel) has been fairly evenly distributed across
regions, with the notable exceptions that imports from Mexico
(line 5) grew unusually strongly last year, while imports from
other LDCs fell with the decline in oil prices.
As indicated in the middle left panel, we expect the
growth of real imports of goods

(line 1) and of services

to slow somewhat over the next two years.

(line 5)

The primary factor

influencing U.S. import growth is the growth of U.S. real GDP.
Normally, we expect the largest component of goods imports

(those

other than oil and computers) to grow about twice as fast as GDP.
As shown in the middle right panel, during 1992 and 1993 these
imports grew well over twice as fast as GDP.

Most of the extra

growth of imports probably can be attributed to increasing
competitive pressures on the part of foreign suppliers.

The

pricing behavior of foreign firms in the U.S. market has been
driven by the appreciation of the dollar and by slack demand in
their home markets.

Over the period ahead, we expect the growth

of these imports to slow to something closer to double the rate
of growth of GDP as stimulus from past declines in the relative
price of imports diminishes.
Our outlook for non-oil import prices is shown in the
bottom left panel. Increases in these prices were damped in 1993

- 7

-

by the appreciation of the dollar, and we expect the same to
occur in 1994.

Increases in 1995 will be limited by further

declines in foreign inflation.

The price of oil imports (bottom

right panel) has fallen sharply over the past year and a half as
OPEC and some non-OPEC production has continued unabated in the
face of relatively weak world demand.

In line with market

expectations, these prices should bounce back a bit over the next
several months as world demand picks up and North Sea production
is curtailed.

In the longer term, however, we are assuming that

ample excess capacity among various OPEC countries will prevent
the WTI spot price from rising above $17.50 per barrel on
average.
Our outlook for the overall external balance is
presented in Chart 14.

As indicated in the top panel, by the

black bars, growth in exports of goods and services is projected
to pick up noticeably during 1994 and 1995 while import growth
tapers off.

This projection nevertheless implies a substantial

further widening of the U.S. current account deficit

(line 1 in

the middle panel), which we see reaching about $165 billion by
the end of 1995.

This widening of the deficit fully reflects the

decline in real net exports (in line 6).

However, the projected

rate of decline in real net exports slows over time.

As shown in

line 8, after having subtracted about 1 percent from GDP growth
during 1993, we expect real net exports to subtract 2/3
percentage point during 1994 and only 1/3 percentage point during
1995.
The bottom panel summarizes the implications of the
external sector for the outlook for U.S. inflation.

The primary

-

8 -

channels through which foreign developments influence U.S.
inflation are changes in the relative prices of oil and non-oil
imports, and the contribution of changes in real net exports to
the U.S. output gap.

I should note that we have been unable to

find significant statistical evidence to suggest that
international factors affect U.S. inflation through channels
other than import prices and the aggregate demand effects on real
net exports.

That is, standard output-gap models of U.S.

inflation that incorporate these channels appear to have fully
explained the decline in U.S. inflation in recent years.
We estimate that the decline in oil import prices
relative to U.S. consumer prices

(line 1) subtracted about four-

tenths of a percentage point from the inflation rate in 1993.
Lagged effects of that decline are expected to subtract a bit
more in 1994 despite an anticipated increase in oil prices this
year, but will have no visible effect in 1995.

The relatively

low rate of import price inflation (line 2) subtracts about twotenths percent each year.

The decline in net exports

(line 3)

depresses the inflation rate by an amount that increases over the
period as the cumulative effect of the decline in net exports on
the output gap grows.

This net export effect is purely a partial

equilibrium estimate that assumes no policy easing to keep
aggregate demand from falling.

As totaled up in line 4, we

estimate that external factors will have a negative effect on the
level of U.S. inflation over the next two years, although that
damping effect will diminish somewhat over time.
In your next chart we have considered how the outlook
for U.S. growth and inflation would differ if real activity in

-

9 -

the rest of the world picks up significantly faster than we are
projecting.
key elements.

The alternative scenario presented here has three
The driving assumption is that the annual rate of

foreign GDP growth increases by 1 percentage point relative to
the baseline forecast as a result of stronger growth in private
domestic demand.

This increase in growth is enough, for example,

to reduce the projected G-6 output gap at the end of 1995 by
about 40 percent.

Second, consistent with the increase in world

growth, the scenario also assumes that oil prices would rise $3
per barrel during 1994 and remain unchanged at their higher level
thereafter.

Third, the federal funds rate is assumed to remain

unchanged from its baseline path.

With U.S. short-term interest

rates held unchanged and foreign rates allowed to rise, the
dollar depreciates by roughly 5 percent per year relative to
baseline over the simulation period.
As indicated in lines 1 and 2 in the bottom of the
panel, this alternative scenario implies slightly higher U.S. GDP
growth than the baseline in 1994 and a more noticeable difference
in 1995.

CPI inflation (line 4) would rise to 3.7 percent in

1994 and slightly further in 1995.

The underlying model also

indicates that these effects could be largely offset by a 100
basis point increase in the federal funds rate implemented during
the next several months.
Finally, the direction of this alternative scenario
notwithstanding, we feel that the risks to the outlook for the
external sector are reasonably balanced.

That is, we would

attach equal probability to a scenario involving a 1 percentage

- 10

-

point decline in foreign growth and lower oil prices.

And the

effects would be roughly symmetrical to those shown here.
Let me now pass the presentation back to Mike to
present the Committee's forecasts.

Michael J. Prell
February 3, 1994
FOMC CHART SHOW PRESENTATION -- CONCLUSION

The final chart summarizes the forecasts that you submitted.
In broad terms, most of you are projecting that growth will be
sufficient to achieve small to appreciable further declines in
unemployment, and no further progress toward price stability.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR) CLASS I-FOMC

Materialfor

Staff Presentation to the
Federal Open Market Committee
February 3, 1994

Chart 1

Summary of Staff Projection
REAL GDP AND PRIVATE DOMESTIC FINAL DEMAND
4-quarter percent change

OUTPUT AND SPENDING
Percent change, Q4 to Q4

Private domestic final demand

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

GDP

PDFD

1990

.2

-. 1

1991

.3

-.7

1992

3.9

5.0

1993

2.8

4.9

1994

3.0

4.0

1995

2.4

3.1

1995

CIVILIAN UNEMPLOYMENT RATE

Percent
-- i 8

UNEMPLOYMENT
Level, Q4

New series

Old
series

OseOld series

-1 5

I

I

1985

I

I

I

I

I

1989

1987

I

1991

I

I

1993

CONSUMER PRICES

New
series

1990

6.0

1991

7.0

1992

7.3

1993

6.5

1994

6.2

6.8

1995

6.2

6.8

I
1995

4-quarter percent change

INFLATION
-

Percent change,
CPI

OPIex-food and energy

-14

I

I
1985

I
1987

I

I
1989

I

I
1991

I

I
1993

I

I
1995

Q4

to Q4
Ex food
&energy

1990

6.2

5.2

1991

3.0

4.5

1992

3.1

3.4

1993

2.7

3.1

1994

3.3

3.0

1995

3.1

2.9

Chart 2

Financial Conditions
HOUSEHOLD DEBT SERVICE

Percent of DPI
20

Consumer and Mortgage Loans

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

CORPORATE GROSS INTEREST PAYMENTS
Percent
RELATIVE TO CASH FLOW
Nonfinancial Corporations

1975

MUTUAL FUND INVESTMENTS AS A
SHARE OF TOTAL FUNDS SUPPLIED Percent

1980

1985

1990

BANK LENDING TERMS

1995

Percent*

By Size of Firm Seeking Loan
30

20
Medium
10

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

Tighter

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

*Net percentage reporting tighter standards and terms.
NET FUNDS RAISED, RELATIVE TO NOMINAL GDP

Percent

Households and Businesses

1975

1979

1983

1987

1995

Chart 3

Consumption
REAL DPI AND PCE

INCOME AND SPENDING

4-quarter percent change

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

1991

1990

1992

1993

1994

DPI

PCE

1990

1.1

.7

1991

.7

0

1992

4.9

4.0

1993

1.0

3.1

1994

2.3

2.4

1995

2.2

2.3

1995

PERSONAL SAVING RATES

Percent

-1

Saving and net investment
inconsumer durables as
a share of DPI

: :

20

15

10

_
ii
1968

1971

LIGHT VEHICLE SALES

5

Savings as a share of DPI

i

1974

-

1977

1980

1989

1995

1992

HOUSING ACTIVITY AND SPENDING
4-quarter percent change

Millions of units
-

1986

1983

18

20

.

:~ii~~ii!:~ii~~~ii~:!!:::........:...::
i~::iAu s~::ii~~ii
....
=============
.... ===================
............
....

,

J

.

Single-family housing starts
and existing home sales
0

I

40
1980

1985

1990

I I I
1995

Chart 4

Housing Sector
HOUSING STARTS

TOTAL STARTS

Millions of units, SAAR

Millions of units

Multifamily
Single-family
1985
1987
-

^iii1989

1991

;

:Z
Z;
::::
;:
::
::
::
ZZ
:i::
: : :: : :
:.
..: :.: .
. .... :....

:
:

:: :: :: :: :: :: : ::

.. ........
:
::

;

1991

1.01

1992

1.21

:g!iii!::iiiii
ii::^
1993

1.29

:::
.............
::::::::::::::
.

: : .

:

..................

:: .
: ;: : :: : : :: : :: : : ::: :: : :
...........
i~i~iiii
~~~ii??i~iii!?!i~
?i??????}~
?!!iii??:
i!!i!i;~ii!ii~ii!:?iii~
...........
...

:

.....
......
..... ...... ...... ......

HOUSEHOLD FORMATIONS

1.20

1993
1995
. .. ...... . ....

:1
22
12
:2
::
:2:
:::
i:
::
:::
:::
::
::
:::2
:1
:i
: ::::::::::::::::::
::::::::::: :2.
::

1990

Millions/year

1994

1.49

1995

1.48

HOMEOWNERSHIP RATE

Percent of households

-

70

-- 65

CASH-FLOW BURDEN

Monthly payment/DPI
-0.7

I

I

I

I

i

1953

1961

1969

1977

1985

i
1993

MULTIFAMILY RENTAL VACANCY RATE

Percent

Fixed-Rate Mortgage

11111111111111111 Illil1ll
1974

1981

1988

I I I I III
1995

1973

I I I I
1978

1983

1 l lI I I i l
1988

1993

Chart 5

Business Investment
REAL BUSINESS FIXED INVESTMENT

BFI GROWTH

Billions of 1987 dollars
800

Percent change,

Q4 to 04
.7

1990

ili
iiiii~iiiiiii
i
i~~iijiii
600

.......... ..
......
.........
e... .......................
:s..................

.. ........N

....

....

400

...............................................
.............
....
...............................
.........................................
............ ................................................
...................
..........
.....................
............................
......
...................
.........................................................
:::'.......".......
Othe pro ucer' duable ::::::.:::.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.::..............

..... ......
...
.......
....
_.. ...... ..
..
::.::.... ; ..
......Oth.erproducers durabes
............
'--"
'- '' ~~
.....................
:-: ::.:::::::
..............
:: ' :::''';;
r.
:::-::::: . .:: : ::::
. .. ... .. :.... .: ::~::: ::-::. .............

200

1991

-6.3

1992

7.4

1993

14.7

1994

11.5

1995

0
1985

1989

1987

1993

COST OF CAPITAL

1985

1987

Index, 1985=100

1989

1991

1993

1995

INVENTORY-SALES RATIO*

Ratio

1995

RATIO OF CAPITAL SPENDING
TO CASH FLOW

1965

1972

I

1985

I

I

1987

I

I

1989

I

I

1991

*Ratio of inventories to business final sales.

I

I

1993

I

I

1995

1986

1993

NONFARM INVENTORY INVESTMENT
Billions of 1987 dollars, SAAR

l
I I

1979

Ratio

1993l1992 1994

i

i

1992

1993

19

i1
1994

I
1995

Chart 6

Government Sector
CHANGE IN REAL FEDERAL PURCHASES
04 to 04, billions of 1987 dollars

TOTAL PURCHASES
Percent change, Q4 to 04

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1990

2.8

1991

-3.7

1992

.4

1993

-6.4

1994

-4.0

1995

-2.7

1995

FEDERAL BUDGET DEFICIT*

GDP
Percent of potential

Billions of dollars
Unified

~----.e.

I I I

I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I II

II I I

1960
1967
1974
1981
*Excluding deposit insurance and contributions for Operation Desert Storm.
REAL STATE AND LOCAL PURCHASES

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

I

I
I

.I

II

I

I
I

II
I

I

I
I

I

I
1995

1988

OPERATING DEFICIT
Billions of dollars

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1990

35.7

1991

51.2

1992

52.2

1993

56.5

1994

53.1

1995

45.9

Chart 7

Labor Market
LABOR

PRODUCTIVITY

PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH

1987 dollars per hour

Business Sector

Percent change, Q4 to Q4
-- 26

1990
1991

1992
-

1993

-.. ...

• ::::
1994

1995
1974

1977

1980 1983

PAYROLL GROWTH

1986

1989

1992

1995

EMPLOYMENT

Average monthly rate in thcusands

S300
Percent change. Q4 to Q4
Payroll

HH

1990

.6

-.2

1991

-.9

-.6

1992

.7

1.0

1993

1.8

2.0

1994

1.9

2.9

1995

1.6

1.5

200

100
.. .
.......
...

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION RATE

Percent

LABOR FORCE GROWTH
Percent change, Q4 to Q4

1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995

1974

1977

1980

1983

1986

1989

1992

1995

Chart
Inflation

LABOR COSTS

CAPACITY UTILIZATION

4-quarter percent change

Percent

6

92

Manufacturing
86
3

ECI

Average
1967-93 Average

81.2
80

ECI-CPI

74

I

I
1990

I
1991

I
1992

CPI ENERGY PRICES

I
1993

I
1994

I
1995

Percent change, SAAR

68
1979

1991

1983

CPI FOOD PRICES

1995

Percent change, SAAR
10

5

1.,1ll I III M
I
1992

1993

1994

1995

1992

CPI INFLATION

I
1993

I
1994

I

+

0

5

1995

Percent change, SAAR
6

Total
Excluding food and energy
4

2

1992

1993

1994

1995

Chart 9

Exchange Rates and Interest Rates
PRICE-ADJUSTED
DOLLAR*

THE DOLLAR AND THE INTEREST DIFFERENTIAL
Index, 1980 Q4 = 100
Percent
I
I-

Percent change
8/92 to 1/94

G-10
LDC-8

Reallong-term
interest differential**

G-10 + LDC-8

V

1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
994
Weighted
averages against foreign countries using world trade shares, adjusted by relative prices.
Difference
between
rates on long-term U.S. government bonds and a weighted average of foreign
government or public authority bond rates, adjusted for expected inflation.
long-term
G-10

NOMINAL INTEREST RATES

NOMINAL DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATES

Level
2/2/94

Percent change
8/92 to 2/2/94
Three-month
Germany
Japan
United States
Ten-year
Germany
Japan
United States

italian lira
Pcund sterling
Deutschemark
Canadian dollar
Yen
G-10 Average

THREE-MONTH INTEREST RATES

Percent

Change
8/92 to 2/2/94

5.70
2.20
3.18

-4.09
-1.67
-0.13

5.71
3.60
5.77

-2.28
-1.42
-0.82

10-YEAR INTEREST RATES
Weekly

Percent

8/92

Foreign*

United States
-I

I
1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

*Multilateral trade-weighted average for foreign G-10 countries

1989

I
1990

I
1991

I
1992

I
1993

1994

6

Chart 10

Industrial Production and Consumer Prices*
CANADA AND UNITED KINGDOM
12-month percent change
Index, 1990=100

CONTINENTAL EUROPE** AND JAPAN
12-month percent change
Index, 1990=100
105 8

100 6

95

H-

4
\

-.

--

CPI

S.

2 -

85

1990

1991

1992

0

1993

1992

1991

1990

1993

Structural and Actual Budget Deficits as a Share of GDP
CANADA AND UNITED KINGDOM
CONTINENTAL EUROPE** AND JAPAN
Percent

Percent

SStructural

SActua!

I

I

I

1990

II 1

I
1991

1992

1993

1994

1990

1995

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

Real Short-Term Interest Rates
CANADA AND UNITED KINGDOM

CONTINENTAL EUROPE** AND JAPAN
Percent
-.

Percent

19~

A
-

4

I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

Note: Aggregation across countries is based on U.S. nonagricultural export weights.
*CPI excludes food and energy prices; U.K. index also excludes mortgage interest rates. The IP and CPI series are both 3-month moving
averages.
**Germany, France, and Italy.

Chart 11

Foreign Outlook
FOREIGN REAL GDP*

REAL GDP: U.S. AND FOREIGN*
Percent change, Q4 to Q4

[

7G-

United States

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

* F:'
^_

J&

-

I

JF

im~

1992

1993

1994

1992

1995

W1

tL

1994 1995

G-6 OUTPUT GAP: DEVIATION FROM
Percent
POTENTIAL GROWTH

FOREIGN GROWTH

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

Canada + U.K.
Other G-6

1993
2.9
0.2

1994
3.0
1.1

1995
3.3
2.5

Mexico
NIEs**
China

0.3
5.2
12.0

2.1
6.3
10.2

2.8
6.8
10.7

1985

1980

1995

CONSUMER PRICES

CONSUMER PRICES: G-7 COUNTRIES
4-quarter percent change

Percent change, 34 i -..
4

United States
3

Foreign
Foreign***

1992

1993

-**-",-

1994

S2

1993
1.8
2.7

1994
1.9
3.1

1995
1.9
3.3

Japan
Germany
France
Italy

1.2
3.7

1.0
2.7

0.8
2.1

G-6

2.0

1.8

1.6

Canada
U.K.****

1995

*G-6 countries, 16 other indusrial and 9 developing countries, U.S. nonagricultural export weights.
**Hong-Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan, U.S. nonagricultural export weights.
***G-6 countries, U.S. non-oil import weights.
****Excludes mortgage interest payments.

4

Chart 12

Exports
SHARES (Percent)

SHARES (1992)

1972

1992

CHANGE
(92-72)

1. Industrial

69

59

-10

2. Canada+UK

30

25

-5

3. Other

39

34

-5

4. LDCs

31

41

10

4

9

5

6. Asia

13

21

8

7.

14

11

-3

5. Mexico

GROWTH

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

Other

GROWTH IN REAL EXPORTS
Percent change, Q4 to 04
1953

1992

1993*

0

4

CanadaUK

5

18

1. Goods

Other

-3

-7

2.

Agricultural

15

3

3.

Computers

7

4.

Other

5. Services

Industrial

LDCs
Mexico
Asia

17

2

Other

14

2

6

4

Total

4

17

1994

8
27

*Estimate, based on October-November

REAL EXPORTS AND GDP

v,:,.

/.

/ --" P

/

GDP

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1995

9

35

Chart 13

Imports
GROWTH

SHARES (1992)

Percent change, 04 to Q4

Other
LDCs

1992
Industrial

Asia

11

11

Canada+UK

10

13

Other

11

9

10

10

Mexico

11

28

Asia

11

11

Other

8

-1

11

11

LDCs
Mexico

lapan
Other
Indust.

1993*

Total

*Estimate, based on October-November

GROWTH IN REAL IMPORTS
Percent change, 04 to 04

4-quarter percent change
Rea Non-oii imports ex Computers

1. Goods

1993

1994

1995

14

10

10

9

3

4

2.

Oil

3.

Computers

37

32

29

4.

Other

10

7

6

5

3

3

5. Services

A

1990

NON-OIL IMPORT PRICES
Percent change, 04 to Q4
STotal

1991

1992

I,

1993

OIL PRICES

1994

1995

Dollars per barrel

West Texas Intermediate (Spot)
(monthly)
A

SNon-Computer

------------

\

,----------

U.S. Import Price "
(quarterly)
1992

1993

1994

1995

1992

1993

1994

1995

-

15

Chart 14

Summary of the External Sector
REAL EXPORTS AND IMPORTS OF GOODS AND SERVICES

-

Exports

I

ip1crts

1992

Percent change, 04 to 04

1994

1995

EXTERNAL BALANCE

Current account balance
Goods
Services
Investment income
Transfers

Real net exports of goods and services
Level change (1987$)
Change as percent of GDP

Billions of dollars, Q4 levels, SAAR

1993
-119
-141
58
-1
-35

1994
-149

1995
-166

-172
63

-191
72

-5
-35

-10
-36

-96
-57

-128
-32
-2/3

-147
-19
-1/3

-1

CONTRIBUTION OF EXTERNAL FACTORS TO U.S. CPI INFLATION

Percentage points, 04 to 04

1993

1994

1995

1. Relative price of oil imports

-0.4

-0.2

0.0

2. Relative price of non-oil imports

-0.2

-0.2

-0.2

3. Real net exports of goods and services

-0.2

-0.3

-0.4

4. Total contribution

-0.8

-0.7

-0.6

Chart 15

Alternative Scenario

Baseline:

Greenbook forecast.

Alternative:

Foreign real GDP growth averages one percentage
point above baseline.
Oil prices rise $3 per barrel above baseline in 1994,
and remain at higher level thereafter.
Federal funds rate unchanged from baseline.

Percent change, Q4 to Q4
1994
U.S. Real GDP
1. Baseline
2. Alternative

U.S. Consumer Prices
3. Baseline
4. Alternative

1995

Chart 16

ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR 1994
FOMC
Central
Tendency

Range

Staff

Percent change, Q4 to Q4
Nominal GDP

4 3/4 to 71/2

51/4 to 7

5.4

Real GDP

21/4to 33/4

23/4 to 31/2

3.0

CPI

21/4 to 4

21/2 to 3

3.3

Average level, Q4, percentUnemployment rate

61/2

to 63/4

to 63/4

6.8

Central
Tendency

Staff

61/2

ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR 1995
FOMC
FOMC
Range

Percent change, Q4 to Q4
Nominal GDP

41/4 to 63/4

43/4 to 61/4

4.6

Real GDP

21/4 to 31/2

21/2 to 3

2.4

CPI

13/4

to

41/2

21/2

to 31/4

3.1

Average level, Q4, percent-Unemployment rate

6 1 4 to 63/4

61/4 to 61/2

NOTE: Central tendencies constructed by dropping top and bottom two from
distribution, and rounding to nearest quarter percent.

6.8

February 4, 1994
Short-run policy
Donald L. Kohn
The decision facing the Committee at this meeting with regard
to its immediate policy options would seem to be whether a firming of
reserve market conditions should occur now, or can be safely and appropriately put off.

In the staff forecast, as Mike discussed, it is

delayed until the second half of the year.

Aggregate demand underly-

ing that forecast is not so strong or the amount of slack so small
that postponing the beginning of the rise in rates deflects the core
inflation rate from a slight downward trend.

A willingness to accept

inflation at its current rate. rather than keeping it moving lower,
would correspondingly further reduce the urgency for raising rates at
this time.
The "wait and see" policy of alternative B also would allow
the Committee to better assess the extent to which the recent strength
in demand seems likely to persist in the new year--an evaluation a
number of you thought important at the last

Committee meeting, but one

that is complicated in the near term by the effects of the quake and
severe weather.

Over the balance of the year, the economy may well

slow considerably and inflation potential remain damped without
Federal Reserve action, as tax increases take effect, key foreign
economies founder, and additions to household stocks of durables and
houses moderate.

Moreover, the market has done some tightening on its

own: the rise in long-term interest rates and exchange rates since
last fall should damp demand in the quarters ahead.

To be sure, these

increases will tend to reverse, at least in real terms, if they are
not validated at some point by rising short-term rates.

Still, some

delay is

not likely to have a major effect on the degree of restraint.

especially if

markets continue to expect the Federal Reserve to firm.

However, if the Committee desired a more definite downward
tilt

to inflation than in

output,

inflation,

the staff

forecast,

or saw the risks on
to the up side,

as tilted

and inflation expectations

firming at this time would seem appropriate.
The proximity of the economy to

its

potential does increase

the danger that even moderate unexpected strength in aggregate demand
would feed through over time to an unacceptable increase in inflation
pressures.

In this situation, real short-term rates would seem quite

low, and the Committee has already expressed its view that these rates
must be raised at some point to contain inflation.

Given the lags,

tightening might need to begin fairly soon to avoid difficulties in
1995 and beyond.

Both the Committee and the staff foresee a pickup in
Leaning against this

nominal GDP growth in 1994 relative to 1993.

tendency might be seen as consistent with the Committee's

longer-run

objectives.
Tightening ahead of any deterioration in inflation expectations could have salutary effects

on capital markets.

Such expecta-

tions may not have picked up appreciably yet, at least judging from
the most

recent evidence in

direct surveys of price expectations

or in

outside economists' forecasts of inflation, and the dollar has remained firm in foreign exchange markets.
they could if

But there is some risk that

the Federal Reserve postponed

its

action very long,

light of recent data on activity and commodity prices.
inaction was motivated by factors

widely anticipated--even

A sense that

unrelated to the conduct of monetary

policy would be especially damaging.
rate is

in

if

An increase in the federal funds
the dating is

in

question.

Delay

risks raising questions about our priorities and necessitating more

drastic action later.

A modest rise in the federal funds rate would

have small effects on the economy, but would remind the markets that
the Fed is still on the job.
As usual, growth of money and credit is of only limited use
in guiding the Committee's decision.

Broad money growth remains weak-

albeit not quite as weak as early last year.

The staff has forecast

growth of 2 percent on average in M2 over coming months and 1-1/4
percent in M3.

Both aggregates would be in the lower halves of their

provisional ranges.

Borrowing by private sectors,

on the other hand.

strengthened significantly in the second half of the year, suggesting
that the balance sheet constraints on borrowers and lenders have been
ebbing rapidly.

We expect growth in private debt to continue at this

more rapid pace, but not to pick up significantly further.

February 4,

1994

Long-run Policies
Donald L. Kohn

As background for the Committee's discussion of longer-run
policy objectives that might be presented in the report to Congress,
and of the annual ranges for money and credit, the staff presented in
the bluebook a number of long-run scenarios for monetary policy.
Given the limitations of economic forecasts in general, the projections obviously shouldn't be taken too seriously.

But we think that

the simulations may expand on the Greenbook forecast in ways that are
useful in the context of your consideration of longer-range strategy.
The first set of simulations gives three possible strategies
for policy in terms of the Committee's emphasis on moving to full
employment or price stability.

The results are found on the table on

page 8 and the chart on the following page.

One important point is

evident from the chart--all three scenarios start from the premise
that real short-term interest rates need to rise from current levels
to prevent prices from accelerating.

In the models, long-term inter-

est rates and exchange rates are the key financial variables driving
the economy, but short-term rates are the instrument through which the
Federal Reserve influences these variables.

The monetary policies

associated with the strategies vary by when and how much short-term
rates are raised.
You will note that the differences among the alternatives--in
terms of the outcomes or the interest rates needed to get them--are
not large.

For the most part, this reflects the fact that the economy

currently is not far from both full employment and price stability.
The baseline strategy makes some progress toward full employment and
price stability, but doesn't get to either objective.

Full employment

can be achieved fairly promptly, however, by keeping the federal funds
rate at the current level for only a little longer;

alternatively,

price stability can be approached by moving the funds rate up by the
same amount as in the baseline, but sooner and less gradually.

In the

out years, policy in the latter two alternatives must be calibrated to
avoid overshooting in one or the other direction.

On one side, over-

staying an accommodative policy could quickly push the economy past
its potential and give an upward nudge to inflation; avoiding this
possibility requires a fairly sharp rise in short-term rates beginning
in 1995 in the easy strategy--to a level in nominal terms above that
for the other two strategies.

On the other side, an aggressive policy

of pushing up nominal rates to approach price stability within the
period of the simulation risks arriving at this ultimate objective
with an unemployment rate that implies future deflation; avoiding this
outcome dictates a drop in rates mid-way through the period in the
tighter strategy.
Charts 2 and 3 look at the implications of some potential
risks to the outlook.

These exercises make two types of points.

First, they show the importance of some key assumptions in shaping the
staff projections.

And second, they illustrate the difficulties for

monetary policy caused by lags in the response of policy to changed
circumstances and by lags in the response of the economy to policy
actions.

Chart 2 following page 10 addresses the possibility that the

NAIRU is 1/2 percentage point higher or lower than assumed in the
baseline.

If it is higher, a possibility raised by recent compensa-

tion data, the economy is already operating beyond its potential.

In

this circumstance, even the rapid and pronounced tightening, shown by
the dashed line, which is delayed a bit until the problem becomes
apparent, can't avoid some small pickup in inflation in the near term.

If the natural rate is lower, as recently asserted by some, the dotted
line, keeping policy on hold for a considerable period has no adverse
consequences--in fact it allows attainment of both the lower
unemployment and lower inflation possibilities implied by this favorable situation.
Chart 3 posits stronger and weaker aggregate demand in 1994
than in the staff forecast.

In this case, in designing the scenarios,

we assumed that evidence of the change in circumstances would be
easier to detect, as indicators of demand continued to deviate from
levels assumed in the baseline.

Even so, the excess or shortfall in

aggregate demand feeds through quickly to labor and product markets,
whereas the influence of an alert and prompt monetary policy response
is only felt some quarters later.

Thus, even fairly rapid and robust

responses do not avoid rising unemployment in the weak demand case or
more rapid inflation in the strong demand case.
In constructing the money growth paths for each strategy, we
took account of movements in both short-term and long-term rates, as
well as the behavior of nominal spending.

In addition, we assumed

that some of the unusual intermediation patterns of recent years would
persist--but that they would fade out over time as loan demands at
depositories picked up and as savers became better adjusted to the
availability of mutual funds and to their greater inherent riskiness
relative to deposits.
These factors informed our projections of money and credit
for 1994 and 1995, shown on page 13.

We expect debt growth about in

line with nominal GDP again in 1994.

More comfortable balance sheets

and greater credit availability lead to a pickup in borrowing by
sectors other than governments.

In the total, this is about offset by

a drop in federal borrowing, owing to the effects of deficit reduction

measures and a stronger economy.

A greater proportion of this credit

is financed at depositories, reflecting both an increased willingness
to lend and the strengthening of private credit demands.

Moreover,

depositories are assumed not to raise quite as much funds in bond and
stock markets,

given their already hefty capitalizations,

and thus M3

growth is projected to pick up to 1-1/2 percent in 1994 and 2 percent
in

1995.

M2 growth also strengthens--to 2 percent this year, and

2-1/2 percent next--as flows to long-term mutual funds slow, in part
reflecting

a flatter

yield curve and smaller capital gains than

through much of 1993.

The ebbing of the diversion to non-M2 assets is

strong enough to offset the effect of an expected drop-off in
refinancing this

year and the more general

term rates assumed in the forecast.
advance,

but by a bit

less than in

influence of higher

mortgage
short-

M2 and M3 velocities continue to
1992 and 1993.

Against this background, page 16 lays out two alternative
sets of annual ranges for money and debt

for 1994.

Alternative I con-

sists of the provisional ranges from last July; these were set equal
to the 1993 ranges,

which,

as you recall,

were reduced at that time.

With growth in the aggregates expected to be a little higher in 1994
than in

1993 under the staff

pressing rationale

forecast,

there would seem to be no

for reducing the ranges,

assuming that something

like the staff

forecast for the economy is

able outcome.

Of all the provisional ranges, the one for M2 would

seem to be most at risk,
that aggregate
rates is

in

the sense that the staff

consistent with its

expectation for

outlook for spending and interest

only one percentage point above the lower end of the range.

A greater or earlier

increase

in

short-term rates than assumed in

forecast conceivably could cause M2 to fall
range.

considered to be an accept-

On the other hand,

short of its

the interest elasticity

the

alternative

of the aggregate

I

has not been very large in recent years, and, moreover, if rising
short-term rates are associated with some upward movement in long-term
rates,

appetites

for capital market alternatives to M2 assets

could be

even more damped than we have assumed.
Nonetheless, alternative II would adjust the M2 range to
center it better on the staff expectations, reducing the risk of
shortfall in response to tighter reserve conditions.

Because it

would seem to allow for such actions, and implies less tolerance for
a major acceleration in money growth, this range might be seen as more
consistent with intentions to reduce inflation appreciably further in
the next few years, as under the tighter strategy outlined earlier.
Alternative

II

also lowers the range for debt,

Committee could take even if
provisional levels.

left

the M2 and M3 ranges

Growth of debt in

percent range seems high,
expand together,

it

especially

as they have in

an action the

if

at their

the upper part of a 4 to 8
debt and GDP again tend to

recent years; the Committee's nominal

GDP forecast centers around 5-1/2 percent.

The Committee might also

be concerned about very rapid debt growth as symptomatic of over-exuberance in

asset markets and a return to balance

sheet leveraging,

perhaps fueled by a pickup in inflation expectations.

A drawback to

lowering the debt range alone might be a tendency to draw too much
attention to this

variable,

whose link to spending has not been that

tight.
The downgrading of the monetary aggregates as guides to
policy,

for both the Committee and the public,

has raised questions

about whether there are ways we might better communicate intermediateterm policy objectives and strategies.

Humphrey-Hawkins reports and

testimonies have given a sense of the ultimate objectives

of the Com-

mittee, the Committee members' projections for key economic variables

for the next year to year and a half, and the risks to the forecast.
Of necessity, the discussion has been vague as to desired trajectories
toward ultimate objectives and to how the Committee might respond to
deviations from projections.

When money velocities were reasonably

predictable, target ranges for the aggregates perhaps gave a little
better sense of the intermediate-term strategy of the Committee and
its reaction to unexpected strength or weakness in spending that was
reflected in growth of money relative to its ranges.

A distinct ad-

vantage of aggregates for intermediate targets was that they did not
force the Committee to specify its notions of short-run output/inflation tradeoffs or long-run characteristics of the real economy.
Members of Congress and their staffs have asked whether the
Committee could supplement money ranges with other methods of explaining important intermediate-term considerations guiding the conduct of
policy.

One possibility is to stretch out the forecast period, and it

was with this in mind that we asked for your 1995 projections.
A key aspect of projections two years out is that they probably can be viewed as representing to an important extent Committee
members' desired outcomes, within the constraints imposed by the
starting point and the structural relationships embedded in the
economy.
long

That is, the lags in policy effects are probably not so

that if the Committee viewed the outcomes as not the best

available, it would still have time to take actions to improve the
situation.

Seen in this way, the projections do contain some informa-

tion about the Committee's preferences and its view of the short-run
tradeoffs .

Your 1995 projections, for example, show no deceleration

in inflation from 1994 coupled with some further decline in the unemployment rate to the neighborhood of 6-1/2 percent.

This suggests

that, on average, you share the staff's view of the level of the

NAIRU, and hence, absent a sharp weakening on aggregate demand in
1996, would not anticipate further disinflation.

You also have lower

unemployment rates associated with roughly the same levels of inflation as the staff, perhaps indicating a more favorable slope in the
short-run Phillips curve than assumed with staff projections.
The risk in giving long-run projections is that Congress may
focus on these as targets--especially on the real variables, such as
the unemployment rate.

These forecasts tend to highlight short-run

tradeoffs without focussing on longer-term consequences of trying to
exploit these tradeoffs.

Without the discipline of an explicit price

stability goal for the central bank, we could find ourselves under
greater pressure on real variables over which our power is limited
over a period of years, and for which we have no authority to set objectives.

What was once an adjunct to the monetary ranges could be-

come the centerpiece;

indeed, we would be giving projections for a

years in which we had no monetary targets.

If the forecasts are used,

the report and testimony ought to emphasize both that the FOMC does
not control the level of growth of potential GDP and would welcome the
lowest possible unemployment rate consistent with sustainable growth,
and that an attempt to exploit short-term
counterproductive.

tradeoffs

can be