View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

Notes for FOMC Meeting
December 17, 1984
Sam Y. Cross

the dollar has again

Since your last meeting

climbed

than 6 percent

higher in the exchange markets, gaining more

against the

against the European currencies and 3 percent

Following President Reagan's reelection the

Japanese yen.

dollar rose strongly throughout November, and eased only

slightly and temporarily after the Federal Reserve announced a
1/2 percent cut in the discount rate.
the dollar, while still

Since early December,

at high levels,

has fluctuated without

any clear trend.
During
approached

this period the

the highs against

late-September and
sins ,

dollar has once again

to a downward move,
The

dollar down.

intervened

the dollar seemed
to help knock

reserves, and

from rising at

to prevent

a time when

its

the mark

foreign
is weak,

interest on

sells

market will

clearly the case when

That was

impact on

those

the

largest.

its

exchange reserves

dollars at times when it believes
be

the

Bundesbank receives a steady stream of

dollars from U.S. troop expenditures and from
dollar

those earlier occa-

On both of

in mid-October.

the Bundesbank, picking times when

vulnerable

in

the mark reached

the exchange
the

- 2 Bundesbank intervened on September 21 and the dollar fell
nearly 4 percent in a couple of hours.

During the latest

intermeeting period,

the Bundesbank has sold dollars on a

number of occasions,

a total of $1.2 billion,

but with much
Also, Bundesbank

less market effect than in September and October.

total sales of dollars were more than offset by purchases
of dollars by other central banks.
The dollar's resiliency in November reflected
the continued attractiveness of the investment climate
in

the United States

rates.

It

despite the declines

was noted that interest

much narrower,
currencies,

still

favored

and also that

in

U.S.

rate differentials,

though

the dollar over other major

inflation expectations

appeared to be moderating.

interest

in

the U.S.

Also, the dollar has gained

from currency conversions into dollars or

some support

borrowings in other currencies by the debt-troubled countries.
In particular there were reports of conversions of the foreigncurrency portion of bank loans to Mexico taken down at the
end of November.
The
forces

recent

support

for the dollar seems

to reflect

that have dominated the markets for most of 1984.

attraction of a brisk U.S. economic expansion,
lower
inflation,

relatively high interest rates and a good

environment for business has been sufficient not
only to
finance the large U.S. current account deficit, but
also
to exert upward pressure on the dollar.

The

-3-

The dollar also continues to look attractive because
European alternatives have lost their luster, with sluggish
economies, increased political uncertainties, and in some
cases vulnerability to labor unrest.

Thus far in 1984 the

currencies of continental Europe have lost 14 percent against
the dollar,

The yen has lost 7 percent, and now stands near

its all-time high against the German mark.
With the dollar now close to
the third time, the exchange markets
the higher level.

its historic highs for
appear to be adjusting to

While most market observers acknowledge

that the dollar's 4-year rise will reverse at some point, few
entertain the likelihood of any significant drop in the near
future.

Most participants expect continued wide fluctuations,

but generally around a steady or still rising trend.
Recommendation
As discussed at the last meeting, we have negotiated
the extension of all

of the Federal Reserve System's regular

swap arrangements with foreign central banks and the B.I.S.,
which have come up for renewal in December.
technical changes were reauired.

Only two minor

One, which was approved by

the Committee at its last meeting, makes the applicable
exchange rate in the agreement with Japan that of two days'
prior to the value date of the drawing, rather than one day,

-

4-

to reflect a recent change in Japanese market practice.

The

second change is in the agreement with the National Bank of
Denmark.

That agreement referred to a specific Danish

Treasury security issue as the basis for setting the interest
rate on drawings in Danish krone, and that security is no
longer being issued.

Since changes may occur again, we have

agreed that the rate applied will be the rate on a Danish
Treasury security comparable to the U.S. Treasury bills,

as

agreed between the two parties at the time of any drawing.
I recommend that the Committee should authorize
renewal of all

the agreements for another year.

PETER D. STERNLIGHT
NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
DECEMBER 17-18, 1984
Against a background of lagging growth in narrow money
supply, sluggish growth in the economy, subdued inflation, and a
strong dollar. Desk operations since the last meeting have sought to
fill reserve needs promptly and fully, while aiming at a gradual
reduction in pressures on bank reserve availability.

Although broader

aggregates grew robustly, exceeding the September-December growth
rates indicated by the Committee, greater significance was attached to
the sub-par performance of M1, which appeared to be falling short of
the Committee's specified 3 percent September-December pace--a pace
that in a sense was considered minimal and that the Committee would
have found it acceptable to exceed.

Moreover, the slow pace of M1

seemed more consistent with the signs of laggard growth in the economy
than did the larger expansion of broader money measures.

These

broader measures may have benefited from the greater attractiveness of
money market deposit accounts and money market mutual fund accounts as
the yield declines on these accounts lagged the rate decreases on
marketable money market instruments.
As the period began, reserve paths incorporated $575 million
of adjustment and seasonal borrowing, down from the $700 million level
used just before the November 7 meeting.

Two weeks later, the

borrowing assumption was pared to $500 million, and two weeks after
that to $400 million.

Given these reductions in intended pressure,

further punctuated by the 1/2 percent reduction in the discount rate
announced November 21, the federal funds rate worked down from 9.80
percent in the two weeks ended November 7 to 8.70 in the week ended
December 12, and an average of about 8.30 percent in the first few

days of the current week.

Today it is around 8 percent and that will

pull the averages down further, although a firming is likely before
this reserve period ends on Wednesday.
Actual borrowing levels did not always behave quite as
intended, with aberrations mainly on the high side because of
unexpected reserve shortfalls, unusually heavy demands for excess
reserves, or post-period upward revisions to required reserves.

The

day of the last meeting in fact saw particularly high borrowing due to
a combination of reserve shortfall and heavy repurchase agreement
withdrawals, boosting average borrowing in the two-week period ending
that day to nearly $1.2 billion.

In the first two-week period of the

new intermeeting interval, borrowing averaged a close-to-path $588
million, although this was higher than intended since an effort had
been made in the final days of that period to provide reserves
relatively generously against indicated path levels to guard against
unwanted firming.

In the second maintenance period, borrowing

averaged $763 million, well above the level assumed in the path,
partly because of heavy borrowing on Thanksgiving Day which really was
carried over from the end of the previous period and partly because of
reserve shortfalls and high demand for excess reserves that led to a
taut money market at the end of the period.

In contrast, the current

reserve maintenance period has seen relatively light borrowing so far
--about $250 in the first 11 days.

At this point, to achieve a $400

million average, borrowing for the current two weeks could imply an
appreciable firming in the next couple of days.
For the two full maintenance periods since the last meeting,
nonborrowed reserve levels somewhat exceeded the path levels as of the
day the reserve period was ending, although in the case of the
November 21 period there was a subsequent upward revision to required

reserves and a nonborrowed objective based on that revised level was
not quite met.
The Desk provided reserves in large size over the period,
meeting seasonal needs for currency and required reserves, as well as
offsetting a decline in extended credit borrowing.

Net intermeeting

outright purchases totaled a record $7.4 billion, requiring two
temporary increases in the normal leeway to cover intermeeting
changes.

Purchases included $5.6 billion in three market operations

--two in bills for about $4.1 billion and one in notes and bonds for
$1.5 billion.

The System also bought $1.7 billion in bills and notes

from foreign accounts.

System and customer-related repurchase

agreements were used on a dozen occasions, while a temporary reserve
glut was absorbed through matched-sale purchase transactions in the
market on one occasion.
It may be of interest to note that so far this year, the
System's outright holdings of Treasury and agency securities are up by
a net of $6.4 billion, about evenly divided between bills and coupon
issues with a small decline in agency securities.

This year's

increase is substantially smaller than the record $16 billion rise
during all of 1983, although when account is taken of the $3.5 billion
FDIC note and the rise of about $3 billion in extended credit, both
essentially stemming from the Continental Illinois situation, the
annual changes are fairly similar.

The further reason for the bigger

rise in 1983 was the $3 billion larger increase in currency in
circulation in that year.
While federal funds worked fairly steadily lower in rate over
the period, other market interest rates followed a somewhat erratic
course, generally ending up lower for shorter maturities but little
changed at the longer end.

The System's accommodative stance provided

encouragement through the lessening of reserve pressures and the
decline in the discount rate midway in the period, but day-to-day news
on the economy and monetary growth was considered a mixed bag and the
market alternately blew hot and cold on whether there was further
easing to come.

The net result was a steeper yield curve as the lower

funds rate and related dealer financing costs pulled short rates down
while longer rates responded more to the shifting day-to-day
psychology on bits of business news and money growth reports.
Expectations of rate declines were already built into the longer end
as the period began, in anticipation of a sluggish economy and System
moves to pep up M1 growth, so the easing of reserve pressures and
mixture of sluggish and not-so-sluggish news produced about a standoff.
Bill rates fell by about 70 to 85 basis points over the
period while the Treasury tapped this market for roughly $15 billion
of new funds.

Three- and six-month bills were auctioned today at

about 7.97 and 8.15 percent compared with 8.82 and 9.07 percent just
before the last meeting.

Similarly, CD rates came down 80-95 basis

points, and most banks cut their prime rate in two or three steps by
75 basis points to 11-1/4 percent.

The gap between the prime rate and

bank funding costs remains fairly wide.
Rates on Treasury notes and bonds were down about 30-45 basis
points for 2-5 year issues, little changed in the 10-year area, and up
a few basis points for the longest maturities.

Counting the whole

November refunding, which was partly auctioned just before the last
meeting date, the Treasury raised $19 million in coupon issues over
the period.

The offering included the Treasury's second foreign-

targeted issue, a $1 billion add-on to the 5-year note.

This issue

attracted much less aggressive bidding than the similar 4-year note

sold in October, saving the Treasury just 7 basis points as against 32
in the 4-year note.

In the secondary market trading of both targeted

issues, the rate spread between the foreign and domestic versions
entirely eroded, or even turned to show a slightly higher return on
the foreign issue--prompting some holders of the 4-year note to
convert to the companion domestic issue.

While a viable long-run

market in the target issues does not seem to be developing, the
attention surrounding their issuance may be said to serve a purpose in
quickening foreign appetite for U.S. Treasury issues in general.
Rates on longer corporate issues moved in roughly similar
fashion to longer Treasurys.

New issuance was light to moderate until

late November when there was a burst of supply to take advantage of
lower rates--but this clogged the market for a time and backed rates
up to about the same level as several weeks earlier.

Tax-exempts

fared better, somewhat out-performing the taxable market for the first
time in several months as dealers and investors began to see an end to
the heavy new supplies being brought to beat year-end deadlines for
certain types of issues.
It seems harder than usual to summarize the state of market
opinion on the rate outlook at this point.

There are not even well-

defined "schools of fish" swimming this way and then that as another
crust of information is tossed in the water.

In some average sense, I

think the market is about adjusted to a funds rate centering around
8-1/2 to 8-3/4 percent, maybe leaning to 8-1/2.

The strength of the

economy is seen as the main influence on rates but there is a wide and
shifting range of views about whether the recent lull is giving way to
renewed vigor, recession, or just more lull.

Few expect significant

inflationary pressures near term, unless the dollar should weaken
appreciably and this does not seem to be widely expected.

Most

participants expect little near-term progress on reducing the budget
deficit, although this is not seen as having a big rate impact except
by those--and there are some--who expect a fairly vigorous expansion
to resume.
Request for Leeway
Current projections suggest a need to drain on the order of
$4 to $6 billion of reserves in the weeks through the end of January,
due chiefly to a seasonal return flow of currency and declines in
required reserves.

I would suggest a temporary increase in the

standing $4 billion leeway to $6 billion until the next meeting date,
although I can't rule out the possibility that even more might be
needed, particularly with persisting uncertainties about what might
happen to extended credit.

James L. Kichline
December 17, 1984

FOMC BRIEFING

Economic activity appears to be expanding at a sluggish
pace this quarter.

Domestic sales on average seem to be growing

rather slowly, production has been weak, and inventories have
backed up somewhat.

Compared with the forecast presented at the

last meeting of the Committee, the current staff forecast
entails a little lower growth in real GNP this quarter and next,
but it is not fundamentally different.

We still believe the

economy is on a track that will provide moderate expansion in
1985, that is real growth of around 3 percent.

For inflation we

expect the GNP deflator to rise about 4 percent next year, the
same as anticipated in 1984.
This is the season to discuss consumer spending, and
consumer behavior in recent months has been an area of concern
and confusion.

Major retailers generally have been describing

sales in November and early December as disappointing, with

heavy promotions required to elicit much consumer interest.

The

statistical evidence on consumer spending outside of autos is

that sales dropped in October and recorded a huge advance in
November.

Total auto sales were at a 10 million unit rate in

October and November, down a little from that in September and

- 2 -

the third quarter as a whole; sales of domestic units reportedly
are still constrained by shortages of the more popular models.
The staff's forecast projects consumer spending rising
about 3 percent in real terms in the current quarter, a moderate
expansion coming after the erratic pattern of the preceding two
quarters.

During the spring, real personal consumption expendi-

tures rose at an unsustainable 8 percent annual rate followed by
virtually no growth over the summer quarter.

Most of the influ-

ences on consumer spending seem to be pointing in the direction
of moderate expansion: for example, incomes and employment continue to exhibit growth, attitudes reportedly are still quite
good, and consumers hold large amounts of liquid assets and
don't seem to be averse to taking on debt.

Thus, taking a mid-

dle ground on consumer spending has seemed the best bet to us.
But that moderate growth of consumer spending this
quarter along with weak business fixed investment does not seem
sufficient to clean up excess inventories.

We expect that some

final demands both this quarter and next will be satisfied out
of inventories, which acts to damp growth of GNP in the forecast.

Accumulation of inventories in the aggregate was still

very large in October, the latest available data, even though
production declined and imports were reduced.

For November,

industrial production increased 0.4 percent with most of the
gain in the motor vehicle sector where output earlier was held

- 3 -

down by strikes and other production difficulties.

It appears

that producers basically have been making fairly prompt adjustments to emerging trends of orders and inventories, and continued restraint on domestic production over the next few months is
expected to alleviate lingering inventory difficulties.
In the business fixed investment sector, the quarter
started off weak with sizable declines in domestic orders and
shipments while imports of capital goods also fell.

Some

rebound in orders and shipments in later months of the quarter
is assumed in the projection, but this would only provide very
small growth of business capital spending for the quarter as a
whole.

On average, the staff believes business fixed investment

will continue to be supportive of expansion in the overall economy in 1985, although growing at a much more moderate 6 percent
pace in real terms.

This rate of expansion takes account of the

weaker trend of orders and contracts that has been developing
and recognizes the reduced incentives to investment in an environment of slower growth of final sales and few upward pressures
on capacity utilization rates.
In the housing sector, starts data for November will be
available tomorrow morning.

Nevertheless, the decline in mort-

gage interest rates is expected to provide a little lift to
starts going into 1985, and indeed appeared to be affecting home
sales in September and October.

Mortgage rates are presumed to

-4

-

remain high enough to limit activity, however, and with rental
vacancy rates on the rise and affecting multifamily starts,
total housing starts averaging 1.8 million units next year would
only match the performance in 1984.
On balance, the staff forecast of real activity is a
bit weaker in the short run given the evidence on final sales
and the apparent need to work down inventory accumulation.

This

is still a forecast nevertheless of an economy in transition to
moderate expansion after a surprisingly strong first half of
1984.

There is a bit more slack in labor markets and capacity

utilization in the forecast and along with an upward revision to
the projected value of the dollar, the projection of wage and
price inflation was cut back a few tenths.

TO:

Federal Open Market Committee

FROM:

S. H. Axilrod

DATE:

December 11,

1984

SUBJECT: Comments on operating
procedures and certain monetary
targeting issues

There are three interrelated issues that can be raised in
connection with a general discussion by the Committee at this time of
monetary policy formulation and implementation.

One pertains mainly to

implementation, and relates to questions about the most effective open
market operating procedure in the context of a predominantly judgmental
approach-a matter that was raised by President Morris at the last
meeting in connection with the behavior of interest rates and borrowing
over the summer and fall and has been discussed in one way or another
by other Comittee members in the course of the past year or more.
The other two issues have to do with the reliability of M1 as
an intermediate objective for policy, particularly in light of its recent
weakness,

and the related question of whether its recent weakness should

be taken specially into account when setting next year's ranges.

A few

comments can be offered on these two topics at this time partly as
background for more formal consideration of specific ranges and their
policy significance at the February meeting.
Operating procedures
Reserve paths for guiding open market operations have for
some time now been based on an assumed level of adjustment plus seasonal
borrowing at the discount window.

This borrowing assumption is used to

derive for each two-week reserve period a nonborrowed reserve path-which

is what the Desk can really hit (aside from the unpredicted effects of
market factors).

That path is derived by subtracting assumed borrowing

from the sum of estimated required reserves, updated in the course of a
reserve period, and a projection of excess reserves.
In practice the actual level of borrowing can deviate from
assumption even if the nonborrowed reserve path is hit perfectly and actual
required reserves are as estimated.

In this case, free reserves (the

difference between nonborrowed and required) will turn out as expected, but
borrowing may not since the composition of free reserves between excess
reserves and borrowing is not within the System's control.

However, as

noted, we do attempt to estimate in advance the market's demand for
excess reserves during any given reserve period in setting the nonborrowed
reserve path.

There are inevitably unexpected developments in that respect,

but they tend to average out over time, and the actual level of borrowing
will tend to vary around the assumed level within a reasonable range of
tolerance.

Over short periods, the market will often look to the level of

free reserves as more indicative of System intentions when, for instance,
both excess reserves and borrowings are relatively high or when both are
relatively low.
An assessment of borrowing, or implied free reserves, as a guide
for open market operations involves examination of two kinds of problems.
One relates to conditions when money demand is proving to be stronger or
weaker than anticipated.

A borrowing guide would automatically accommodate

such behavior, since open market operations would supply or absorb the
unexpected shortfall or overshoot in required reserves.

This is not a

disadvantage to such a guide when the Committee does not wish to resist
unanticipated behavior in money-either because a money demand shift may

be under way or because more time may be required to assess the significance
or durability of the change in money.
On the other hand, the accommodative characteristic of a borrowing
guide is.a drawback at times when the Committee wishes to achieve closer
control of money, particularly M1 (the aggregate most directly related to
reserves),

as would be the case when unanticipated movements in money are

more likely to be reflecting or foreshadowing undesired economic performance.

In that case, adherence to a nonborrowed or total reserve aggregate

guide would be more likely to achieve the desired outcome.
Our present procedures strike something of a compromise.

The

nonborrowed reserve paths are adjusted within a reserve operating period for
unanticipated changes in money and required reserves,
the initially implied borrowing level.

so as to maintain

Over a whole intermeeting

period, though, the Committee specifically allows for judgmental adjustments
in

borrowing in an attempt to resist, at least in part, undesired movements

of the aggregates.

However,

these adjustments are considered not only in

the context of behavior of the monetary aggregates but also in

relation

to economic indicators and financial market conditions generally.
The second problem with borrowing (or free reserves) as a guide
emerges in circumstances when money demand and the economy might be about
as anticipated, given current interest rates, but when banks'
toward borrowing, and free reserves, begin to shift.

attitudes

In that case

adherence to a borrowing guide will cause actual money supply, as well as
economic performance, to depart from anticipations.
growth will fall

short when banks'

For example, money

demand for borrowing declines (demand

for free reserves rises) at given interest rates, because the System in
its

operations will force banks to be less liquid than they want (unless

-4the borrowing target is

changed),

leading to interest rate increases,

and, with some lag, to less money demand and actual money growth than
anticipated and to weaker economic growth.
The behavior of M1 during the summer was to some extent an
example of this problem with borrowing as a guide.

Short-term interest

rates rose from May through mid-summer, despite an unchanged level of
borrowing, and money growth began to weaken.

Based on results from our

money market model, perhaps about 2 percentage points at annual rate of
the M1 weakness over the summer might be attributed to a shift in
borrowing demand.
However, the unanticipated weakness in money growth extending
into the fall,-as short-term rates began to drop substantially, more
exemplifies the first problem noted above with a borrowing or free reserve
guide.

The extended weakness in M1 in good part was associated with

diminishing transactions demand as economic growth decelerated sharply.
In line with Committee decisions and operating procedures, successive
reductions in borrowing targets, and increases in free reserves, were made
beginning in late summer.

Nonetheless, nonborrowed reserves and total

reserves by November were still about at their July levels, as not enough
reserves had been supplied both to satisfy banks' demands for liquidity
and to attain M1 objectives.
While there are these problems with the current operating
technique-as there would be problems, though perhaps different ones, in
any procedure chosen-the procedure has worked reasonably well over a
difficult period in which the Committee has not wanted to be tied as
closely as earlier to an M1 aggregate that was subject to transitional
uncertainties,

and has wished to give more emphasis to over-all economic

and financial considerations.

In any event, economic performance has

been reasonably satisfactory during the period in which these procedures
have been in place, and financial conditions have been more stable than
in the 1980-82 period.

Since mid-1983 M1 and M2 have generally remained

within their long-run ranges, in part because demand for these aggregates
has been less variable than previously; recently, though, M1 has been in the
lower portion of its range, an outcome that had not been expected earlier
in the year.
Some modifications to current operating procedures could, nonetheless, be contemplated.

While the problems caused by shifts in the

borrowing function might be mitigated by aiming at a Federal funds rate,
I would not suggest elevating the funds rate to a day-to-day target
as before October 1979.

In the first place, it would not help in the

more fundamental case when money demand on the part of the public, and
the economy, is weakening relative to expectations.

Secondly, it would

work to eliminate a very valuable degree of responsiveness of the funds
rate, and short rates generally, to actual or anticipated changes in
credit or money demand--a degree of responsiveness that often is in a
direction consistent with, and helpful to, policy toward the aggregates
and the economy, as was the case, for example, in early fall.

With the

funds rate as a target, by contrast, money market conditions will be much
less responsive to factors other than the System's intention.
While the funds rate would not seem to be a desirable target, a
reasonable argument can be made for evaluating movements in the funds rate
and the money supply relative to borrowing levels, taking account of
identifiable factors affecting changes in bank borrowing behavior, to
determine whether there have been shifts in the borrowing function that

may call for technical adjustment in reserve paths.

This might tend to

minimize problems associated with shifts in the borrowing function, but it
would not address the first drawback with the current procedure noted
earlier--that is,

its tendency to accommodate,

swings in money demand.

in part at least, undesired

That drawback may be best addressed by introducing

some degree of automaticity in borrowing in response to deviations from
the FOMC's path for M1 and related required reserves, if a reasonable
degree of reliance can be placed on that monetary aggregate, a question
to be discussed in the next section.
Because of remaining uncertainties under current circumstances
about the significance of M1 movements, any automaticity should probably
be relatively limited in its scope.

For example,

in any given reserve

period, an automatic change in borrowing might be limited to about 25 to
50 percent of a deviation in required reserves associated with an unacceptable variation in M1 from path.

If M1 were unacceptably low by an average

of $2 billion, this would mean an automatic drop in borrowing of only $35
to $70 million, given the existing 7 percent average required reserve
ratio on transactions deposits.

One of the advantages to relatively small

automatic borrowing changes-and the Committee could always indicate a
dollar maximum--is that erratic movements in M1 will not lead to very
significant volatility in money market conditions.
Judgmental adjustments would presumably remain as the principal
source of sustained movements in borrowing over time in the context of
something like the current directive structure, which conditions changes
in borrowing on a variety of nonmonetary as well as monetary developments.
In connection with factors influencing the judgmental setting of borrowing,
it

may well be that in current circumstances assessment of the real

-7-

degree of financial restraint or ease-which has often been judged by
interest rates, credit flows, and liquidity conditions-depends more than
usual on indicators of price pressures and on the value of the dollar in
exchange markets.

Inflationary expectations are, and have been, in a

state of flux, and obviously affect the real restraint implied by nominal
interest rate levels.

Price indicators in that situation would need to

be evaluated more closely than usual not only for what they may suggest

about aggregate demand but also for their impact on inflationary expectations.

In addition, international forces today have become a significant

factor affecting U.S. economic activity and prices, arguing for relatively
more attention than usual to the dollar exchange rate, which has risen
more or less persistently since early this year, in assessing the over-all
degree of financial restraint or ease.
Reliability of M1
Even if operating procedures are essentially judgmental, the
degree to which adjustments are made in borrowing will depend to a great
extent on confidence in the reliability of the aggregates-particularly of
M1 if some degree of automaticity were allowed in operations-as indicators
of current and future economic activity and prices.

Over the years, much

research has been devoted to comparisons of M1 and other aggregates as they
relate to GNP and prices.

Our work has generally shown that, of the

various aggregates, M1 has conveyed the most information about current and
future GNP and has also had the most stable, or predictable, demand
relationship to income.

There have, however, been episodes when these

relationships have broken down in one way or another-for example 1975-76
and most recently 1982-early 1983.

Even apart from such periods, the

-8-

relationship between money and GNP is subject to considerable noise and
uncertainty, particularly the shorter the time period considered.
Because of the sharp, atypical drop in the velocity of M1 in
1982-early 1983, the Committee greatly reduced the weight on M1 for
guiding day-to-day operations.

In the latter part of 1983, the velocity

of M1 began to behave more typically, given the stage of the business
cycle, and after a time the Committee increased the weight on M1 in some
degree.

It was still not given the importance it had over the three

years following October 1979, partly because of lingering uncertainties
about the likely behavior of M1 under varying economic and financial
circumstances, in light of the institutional changes of recent years.
Our most recent examination of M1 behavior in relation to other
aggregates and GNP from a variety of statistical perspectives suggests
that on balance M1 is still the most reliable of the aggregates as a policy
guide and that, following the 1982-early 1983 deterioration, its reliability
since around mid-1983 seems to have been improving.

As

noted, its

velocity has begun to behave more typically in recent quarters.

It has

also shown less unreliability than in 1982-early 1983 as a predictor of
GNP behavior in monetarist-type models.
In addition, a recent regression analysis that compares the
indicator properties of M1, M2, and M3 relative to each other shows that
M1 still bears the preponderant weight in conveying information, with
comparatively little additional information imparted by M2 and M3.
However, the regression work also suggests that, while the average performance of M1 as an indicator of GNP remains high relative to the other
monetary aggregates, the precise weight that one would attach to M1 has

-9-

become more uncertain in recent years, as is also the case for M2.1/
This perhaps reflects institutional changes of recent years that also
may have contributed to some decreased reliability of the aggregates as a
group as indicators of GNP.
Thus, examination of recent data provides some assurance that
M1 is a noticeably more reliable guide than broader aggregates, but it is
still far too soon to be reasonably confident about the underlying trend
of its velocity, and its cyclical responsiveness to income and interest
rates.

In large part, this reflects the need for more experience with

the public's financial asset behavior in light of the changed composition
of M1 itself as well as the new deposits and fund outlets (such as money
market deposit accounts and money market funds) in other, higher-order
aggregates that also serve to one degree or another as both as means of
payment and a repository for savings.

For instance, the weak behavior of

M1 thus far in the fourth quarter could be attributable in part to the
public's placing funds in MMDA's that in prior years might otherwise have
been deposited in M1-type accounts-given present interest rate incentives
favoring MMDAs and increased familiarity with such accounts.
Base for the M1 target next year
The specific longer-run ranges for 1985 will be considered by
the FOMC at its February meeting, against the background of a broad
review of the economic outlook in the chart show and analysis of policy
options.

It may be useful at this time to raise an issue about the base

for the targets, in particular for M1 in light of evidence that, of all

1/

Preliminary memorandum by Messrs. Porter and Swartz, "Relative Indicator
Properties of M1, M2, and M3: Regressions of GNP Growth on Distributed
Lags of Weighted Averages of the M's."

-10-

the aggregates, it may still be a relatively more reliable guide for
policy.

As will be recalled, the tentative ranges for next year adopted

in July entail reductions for M1 and M2,
percent, respectively.

to 4 to 7 percent and 6 to 8-1/2

Ranges for M3 and total debt were left unchanged.

The table below compares these tentative ranges with the ranges and
estimated outcomes for 1984 (all data measured from QIV to QIV).
Ranges for
1984

Actual

Tentative
Ranges for 1985

Ml

4 to 8

5

4 to 7

M2

6 to 9

7-1/2

6 to 8-1/2

M3

6 to 9

10

6 to 9

Debt

8 to 11

13-1/4

8 to 11

The Committee early this year had indicated an expectation that
M1 growth over 1984 would appropriately be in

assuming normal velocity behavior.
if

the middle of the range,

The velocity of M1 this year looks as

it will grow by about 4 percent, somewhat above previous experience in

the second year of expansion.

But this velocity outcome has been

accompanied by noticeably slower nominal GNP growth (currently estimated
at 9.1 percent from QIV '83 to QIV '84)

than anticipated by the Committee

at midyear, and at the low end of the FOMC's central tendency indicated
in February.

Real GNP growth was also slower than expected at midyear,

but was above the central tendency expectation of early this year.

Price

behavior has been better than anticipated early in the year and at the
low end of the midyear central tendency.
With the over-all economic outcome for the year somewhat worse
than anticipated at midyear, and with M1 growth for the year in the lower
part of the range, it can be questioned whether the range for 1985 should

-11be based on the actual outcome for the fourth quarter, or instead should
be based on the midpoint for that quarter of the 1984 target range.

This

type of question has, of course, arisen often in the past when the Committee
has discussed questions of "base drift."
If
for 1985,

the Committee retained the present 4 to 7 percent M1 range

aimed at its

5-1/2 percent midpoint,

fourth quarter midpoint of the 1984 range,

and based the range on the

actual growth for 1985 would

be 6-1/2 percent--making up for the one percent point shortfall relative
to this year's midpoint.
is

Such an approach, whatever its

awkward presentationally since it

economic merits,

would be difficult to avoid public

confusion between actual growth expected and the somewhat artificial
specification of the target growth range.

In addition, there is

always

the question of why rebasing was undertaken this year, after many years
of not formally offsetting overshoots and undershoots-which to a degree
have averaged out over time, depending on the starting point.
Moreover,

it

may be difficult, though perhaps not overridingly

so, to explain why the range for one aggregate is
of a previous year's range,

based on the midpoint

whereas others are based on the actual outcome

for a previous year.

For M2, which looks as if

the current midpoint,

there is

it

may end the year near

no meaningful problem.

credit, which are above current ranges,

But for M3 and

in part because of special factors,

a rebasing to the fourth quarter midpoints of their 1984 ranges would
seem to imply much too limited growth relative to M1 and GNP should their
tentative growth ranges for 1985 be retained.

However,

special factors affecting M3 and credit-for example,

reference to the

merger activity--does

provide a rationale for different treatment relative to M1.

-12If

the Committee wished to foster somewhat more rapid growth of

Ml next year in
second half,ยน/

light of the shortfall for this year that developed in the
it

could do so more consistently with past targeting practice

by continuing to base on the actual fourth quarter outcome and by simply
indicating that actual growth is

expected to be toward the upper end of

the 4 to 7 percent range for 1985.2/
course,

is whether it

But the more fundamental question, of

would be desirable policy to compensate for the some-

what slower than expected M1 growth in 1984.

The economic issue revolves

in part around the question of whether the shortfall represents a
"permanent" downward shift in demand for money, which need not be offset
later, or whether it

reflects a degree of restraint on money supply that

will eventually unduly constrain demands for goods and services.

In the

latter case, the lower money growth would need to be subsequently offset.
Our quarterly model does suggest the possibility of a downward
shift in money demand since, given estimated income and interest rates,
the model forecasts stronger money growth in
points, than actually is occurring.

1984,

by about 1-1/2 percentage

However, most of this "shift" took place

in the fourth quarter, when actual income and to a lesser degree money
(on a quarterly average basis) are still
forecast error this year differs little

1/

uncertain.

Moreover, the model's

from what would be encompassed by

The concurrent seasonal adjustment procedure (as of now and before
benchmark adjustments to the underlying data) would raise second
half growth (QII to QIV) by 1/2 percentage point to about 3-1/2 per-

cent at an annual rate and lower the first half by the same amount,
2/

which would moderate but not significantly change the pattern of
steady deceleration in M1 growth quarter by quarter.
Although this procedure would produce the same growth for the year as

rebasing the current range and aiming at its midpoint, a rebased range
would imply scope for more rapid growth early next year. This occurs
because a rebased range starts at a higher level, thus arithmetically
leading to relatively high actual growth early in the year if money
is

to move promptly to the midpoint of the new cone.

-13-

its normal range of uncertainty.
demand shift is ambiguous.

Thus, model evidence about a downward

It is also difficult to point to institutional

developments that clearly would lead to a lasting downward shift in M1
demand this year, though the recent popularity of MMDAs could be contributing to such a development.
Whether or not there have been demand shifts for money, practical,
presentational considerations tend to argue against rebasing M1 at the
fourth quarter midpoint of its 1984 range.

In addition, the degree of

looseness in the M1 to GNP relationship is such that the impact of only one
percentage point of slower or faster money growth may readily be absorbed,
or offset, by compensating unexpected movements in velocity.

This loose-

ness has led the Committee to express its annual growth targets for the
aggregates as relatively wide ranges.

But the Committee has often expressed

its view about whether an aggregate can be expected to be high or low in,
or at the middle of, its target range.

If there is a desire to compensate

for this year's relatively slow growth of M1, the size of the year's
shortfall is small enough for that objective to be accomplished by growth
in the upper part of the range for 1985 without altering past practice.
The issue of what particular actual M1 growth would be desirable in 1985
can be more readily addressed in February, when the Committee will have
more evidence about the basic strength of demands for goods and services
and perhaps about the underlying behavior of M1 velocity.