View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

Output Gaps and Inflation in DSGE Models
Jonas Fisher and Alejandro Justiniano1
December 10, 2009
Summary

The Philadelphia-Richmond memo “Gaps and Monetary Policy,” hereafter the
“PR memo,” argues that output gaps based on Dynamic Stochastic General Equilib­
rium (DSGE) models cannot be taken seriously for three reasons. First, the output
gaps that emerge from these models are sensitive to the underlying assumptions and
it is difficult to choose among alternative assumptions. Second, fluctuations in DSGE
models are typically driven in large part by shocks of indeterminate origin, hence
anything derived from them is inherently suspect. Third, in practice output gaps
from these models are not useful in guiding policy.
Research over the past 18 months, in a collaboration between the Chicago Fed
and Northwestern University, has direct bearing on these points. We describe it
here. This research demonstrates that many of the problems highlighted in the PR
memo stem from challenges in dealing with low and high frequency movements in
hours, wages and inflation that all applied macro theories must confront. These
movements can be explained with identifiable, albeit non-structural shocks. Once the
low frequency trends and high frequency fluctuations are addressed head-on, then a
very close association between model-based measures of the output gap and inflation
emerges.
The Role of Shocks in DSGE M odels

Before describing this research it is instructive to return to the issues raised in the
PR memo about the inclusion of shocks in DSGE models. All DSGE models have
recognizable structural shocks. The more data the model attempts to explain, the
more it becomes necessary to introduce disturbance terms with little or no structural
interpretation. In any structural empirical macroeconomic analysis one is faced with
a trade-off between parsimony and realism. The trade-off is particulary challenging
in DSGE analysis. These models attempt to understand all fluctuations in a large
1Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. We thank Spencer Krane for very helpful comments.

1 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

number of variables. The models thus need a large number of shocks in order to fit
all aspects of the data and to avoid stochastic singularity.2 Ideally, we would like
to have ready structural interpretations for all of these shocks. But, parsimony dic­
tates leaving out features of the economy's structure that cannot be modeled without
introducing considerable complexity. So non-structural disturbance terms naturally
take the place of the un-modeled features.
There are three areas in which such unmodeled shocks are major issues for DSGE
analysis. First, there are demographic trends, such as changes in rates of labor force
participation, that influence the supply of labor and wage determination. Most an­
alysts have not attempted to model these factors because they are not necessarily
crucial for understanding business cycle fluctuations. Second, there are obvious low
frequency movements in inflation which are likely to have been heavily influenced
by changes in monetary policy. Modeling the low frequency dynamics of policy for­
mation is an enormously challenging task, which is naturally set aside for the sake
of parsimony. Third, wages and inflation are subject to high frequency fluctuations
which one might suspect have little to do with the fundamental forces driving the
real economy, and so are left unmodeled. In all these circumstances it is natural to
include reduced form shocks to address the missing model structure.
The research in Justiniano and Primiceri (2008) and Justiniano and Primiceri
(2009) is a case in point. They specify a version of the Christiano, Eichenbaum,
and Evans (2005) model which includes disturbances to neutral technology, the ef­
ficiency of investment, the representative agent's discount factor and labor supply,
wage markups, price markups, inflation drift, the Taylor-type rule, and government
(plus net export) spending.3 In line with the discussion above, we view some of these
shocks as structural and others as reduced form proxies for complexities beyond the
scope of the model. The labor disutility shock is designed to account for the low
frequency trend in hours, the inflation drift shock accounts for the low frequency
component of inflation, and the wage and price markup shocks account for the high
frequency movements in wages and inflation. The government spending shock should
also be viewed as a reduced form disturbance. It is included to make up the difference
2Stochastic singularity refers to the absence of at least as many shocks as observable variables
used for inference, in which case at least some of the variables must be perfectly co-linear.
3For details of the model described here see Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti (2009).

2 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

between observed consumption plus investment, and output. The interpretation of
discount factor shocks is less clear. However, there is a long tradition in real business
cycle analysis of considering these shocks.4
The Role of Shocks in Explaining O utput Gaps and Inflation

It is possible to decompose the endogenous variables in the model into components
accounted for by each of the disturbances. In what follows we focus on a decomposi­
tion of inflation across different categories of shocks.5
Figure 1 displays quarterly GDP deflator inflation (solid, grey line) along with
the component of inflation driven solely by the inflation drift term (dashed, black
line) that we call “trend.” The role of this shock in picking up low frequency vari­
ation in inflation is clear. Figure 2 displays model-detrended inflation (solid, grey
line), that is inflation less trend inflation from Figure 1. It also shows what Jus­
tiniano and Primiceri (2009) call fundamental inflation (dashed, black line).6 Table
1 summarizes this definition of inflation as well as other concepts discussed below.
Fundamental inflation corresponds to the component of inflation driven by shocks to
neutral technology, the efficiency of investment, the representative agent's discount
factor and labor supply, the Taylor-type rule, and government spending. Put another
way, fundamental inflation is model-detrended inflation after removing the influence
of the wage and price markup shocks. The difference between the solid and dashed
lines thus indicates the role played by the markup shocks in explaining high frequency
fluctuations in inflation.
Figure 3 displays fundamental inflation (dashed, black line) along with the modelbased output gap (solid, grey line).7 The output gap is defined as the difference
between actual observed GDP and the model-based estimate of potential output.
Potential output is defined as the level of output obtained at the estimated model
parameters after eliminating the nominal rigidities, the markup shocks, the inflation
drift term and the Taylor-type rule shock. That is, the level of output in an economy
driven entirely by real disturbances and with complete price flexibility.
4Two examples include Eichenbaum and Singleton (1986) and Fisher and Hornstein (2000).
5The model is estimated on the sample 1962q1 to 2009q2. Similar results are obtained using the
post-1984 sample.
6Means also have been removed from the variables before plotting them.
7Means again have been removed from the variables before plotting them.

3 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

The high degree of co-movement between the output gap and fundamental infla­
tion in Figure 3 is striking (the correlation is 0.86).8 The co-movement between the
gap and fundamental inflation seems to be better before the mid-1990s than after.
Still, in the recent period there is also a high degree of co-movement. So, while this
measure of the output gap is clearly not a sufficient statistic for fundamental infla­
tion, Figure 3 suggests that it could be a valuable summary indicator of inflationary
pressures.
Even if this output gap co-moves strongly with a suitably filtered measure of
inflation, one may still be skeptical of its use depending on what ends up explaining
this co-movement. Table 2 addresses this question. This table shows fractions of
business cycle variation (fluctuations of period 6 to 32 quarters) of various endogenous
variables attributable to markup shocks (column A), the inflation drift shock (column
B) , shocks to the Taylor-type rule, labor supply and government spending (column
C) , and shocks to neutral technology, the efficiency of investment, and the discount
factor (column D).
The main real variables, output and hours, are driven almost entirely (80 percent)
by shocks to neutral technology, investment efficiency and the discount factor. The
first two account for 67 and 65 percent of output and hours fluctuations on their own
(not shown). Shocks to the Taylor-type rule, government spending and labor supply
account for less than 10 percent of fluctuations in these variables. Combined, these
results stand in contrast to the findings in Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2009) who
argue that the bulk of business cycle fluctuations in output and hours are driven by
shocks to markups, labor supply, government spending, and the discount factor.
A large fraction of inflation, even at business cycle frequencies, is driven by markup
shocks, which highlights the need to understand these disturbances. Nonetheless the
fraction of inflation fluctuations at business cycle frequencies that is driven by shocks
to neutral, investment efficiency and the discount factor exceeds 20 percent. And, by
definition, all of fundamental inflation is driven by shocks other than to markups or
the inflation drift.
As seen in the bottom panel of Table 2, the model-based output gap at business
8Obviously these are two endogenous variables so this correlation does not reflect causation. We
address causation below by decomposing the variability in these series across the model's shocks.

4 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

cycle frequencies is mostly driven by shocks other than to markups or the inflation
drift. This means that an alternative version of this gap that excludes the influence
of the markup and inflation drift shocks (to put the gap on a comparable basis to
fundamental inflation) strongly resembles the one plotted in Figure 3 and thus still
tracks fundamental inflation closely (the correlation is 0.90).
Furthermore, the output gap is strongly correlated with model-based and empirical
measures of marginal cost.9 This is reflected in Table 2 where we see that modelbased marginal cost is 62 percent driven by shocks other than to the markup and
the inflation drift. Given that the New-Keynesian Phillips curve equation is sitting
inside the model and marginal cost is a key term in this equation, then the correlation
between the model-based output gap and marginal cost should not be surprising.
Finally, the model-based output gap bears some resemblance to simple statistical
output gaps. This is demonstrated in Figure 4 which displays the model-based output
gap along with linearly detrended GDP (the correlation is 0.44).10
Conclusion

Overall, these results build confidence in the usefulness of the model-based output
gap as an indicator of underlying inflationary pressures. The underlying determinants
of inflation are the model's shocks; but, the output-gap itself appears to be a useful
summary statistic for these shocks.
Obviously, results depend on the assumptions. All economic analysis involves
assumptions. What matters is how compelling the assumptions are. We think the
arguments supporting the modeling choices driving the results here are compelling.
They are driven by reasonable considerations of empirical exigency and model par­
simony. This suggests that the issues raised in the PR memo are more about poor
model specification than a fundamental flaw in the DSGE methodology.
We do not wish to suggest this is the end of the story. Justiniano and Primiceri
have not concluded their research. It is unclear at this stage what optimal policy
looks like. And, there are many parts of the current generation of DSGE models that
can be improved on. In particular, the treatment of wage and price setting, financial
9For example, real unit labor costs in the non-farm business sector as published by the BLS.
10This might be surprising in light of the results in Gali and Gertler (1999).

5 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

markets, and commodity prices needs work. However, until there is a viable alterna­
tive, the research described in this memo suggests that there is useful information for
policymakers in state-of-the-art DSGE models.

References
Chari, V. V., P. Kehoe, and E. McGrattan (2009). New keynesian models: Not ready
for policy analysis. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (1), 242-266.
Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans (2005). Nominal rigidities and the
dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113 (1),
149-158.
Eichenbaum, M. and K. Singleton (1986). Do equilibrium real business cycle theories
explain postwar U. S. business cycles? NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1, 91-135.
Fisher, J. D. and A. Hornstein (2000). (S, s) inventory policies in general equilibrium.
Review of Economic Studies 67(1), 117-146.
Gali, J. and M. Gertler (1999). Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis.
Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2), 195-222.
Justiniano, A. and G. E. Primiceri (2008). Potential and natural output. Northwestern
University Manuscript.
Justiniano, A. and G. E. Primiceri (2009). DSGE-based output gaps and inflation
determination. Chicago Fed Presentation.
Justiniano, A., G. E. Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti (2009). Investment shocks and
business cycles. New York Fed Staff Report 322.

6 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

Table 1: Definitions of Potential Output and Fundamental Inflation
Exogenous
l
Shocks Included
ExogenousShocksIncluded
ExogenousShocksIncludedExogenusShckIld

Nominal
Rigidities
Included

All remaining
disturbances1Sefotn1.][

Markups

Series
Monetary
Policy:
Yes
shocks to
Taylor-type
rule and
drifting
No
average
inflation

Output2[Sefotn2.]

Yes

Yes

Yes

Potential Output3[Sefotn3.]

No

No

Inflation4efotn4.][S

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Fundamental Inflation5Sefotn5.][

Yes

No

No drifting
average
inflation

Yes

Yes

Notes to table 1:
1[Fotne1. Shocks to neutral technology, investment efficiency, discount factor, government and
labor supply.dfotne1.]E
2[Fotne2.Output corresponds to real GDP per-capita.Endfote2.]
3[Fotne3.Potential output is the model-based level of output that would prevail in an economy
without nominal rigidities, and, with constant markups in prices and wages.Endfote3.]
4[Fotnoe4.Inflation corresponds to the 400 times the quarterly log-difference in the GDP deflator.Endfote4.]
5[Fotnoe5.Fundamental inflation is the model-based measure of inflation explained by all shocks
except for the markup shocks in prices and wages and the shock to drifting average
inflation.Endfote5.]

7 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016
T a b le 2 : M o d e l- b a s e d V a r ia n c e D e c o m p o s itio n o v e r th e
B u s in e s s C y c le 1[Sefotn1.]
Percentage of variation explained by exogenous shocks 2]2.eotnfS[
Column

A

B

C

D

Neutral
Taylor-type Technology,
rule,
Investment
Government Efficiency and
and Labor
Discount
Supply 3 [Sefotn3.]
Factor3

Markups

Drifting
Average
Inflation

Output

7

2

9

82

Hours

7

2

9

81

Inflation

56

18

3

23

Nominal Interest

10

5

29

55

Output Gap

13

4

29

55

Marginal Cost

37

1

2

60

Shocks

Actual Data 4[Sefotn4.]

Model-Generated Data 5 efotn5.][S

Notes to table 2:
1[Footnote 1. Defined as cycles of between 6 and 32 quarters. End footnote 1.]
2[Fotnote2.May not add up to 100 due to rounding.Endfote2.]
3[fotnote3.T his presents a more disaggregated taxonomy of shocks than in table 1.ndfote3.]E
[Fotne4.Corresponds to the level of GDP per-capita (although the model is estimated
using the first difference of this series), hours per-capita, quarterly inflation in the
GDP deflator and the effective Federal Funds rate.Endfote4.]
5[Fotne5. The model-based output gap is defined as the difference between observed
output and potential output, where the latter is described in table 1. Marginal cost is
in real terms.dfotne5.]E

8 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

Figure 1: Observed Inflation and Model-Based Trend Inflation

Figure 2: Model-Based Detrended and Fundamental Inflation

9 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

Figure 3: Model-Based Output Gap and Fundamental Inflation

10 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 04/29/2016

Figure 4: Model-Based Output Gap and Observed Output Deviations
from a Linear Trend

11 of 11