View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC Briefing - 12/15/87

Donald L. Kohn

Briefing on Strategies for Open Market Operations

The purpose of the memo from Mr. Sternlight and myself was to alert
the FOMC to the pros and cons of the recent shift in the strategy for
implementing open market operations--that is, greater emphasis on reacting to
the federal funds rate and less on hitting borrowing objectives.

It also was

meant to raise the question of whether, under what circumstances, and by how
much the Committee would like the Desk to shift back toward the previous
strategy.
The extent of the change in strategy shouldn't be exaggerated; the
level of federal funds rate relative to expectations always played an
important role in conditioning open market operations before October 19, and
since then the Manager has continued to take some account of reserve
pressures as indicated by the level of borrowing when planning his
operations.

The market has perceived some shift in emphasis, noting both

stronger reactions from the Desk when funds are trading away from an assumed
center of gravity and a flexible attitude towards borrowing.
The advantage of paying closer attention to the federal funds
rate is that you will be more likely to get the rate you expect; the
disadvantage is that this could be the wrong rate, and concerns about market
reactions and other factor may make it difficult to adjust the rate
sufficiently when appropriate.

This is also a problem with borrowing

objectives, but the use of this technique did allow some limited scope for
the market to ease or tighten on its own--frequently in a stabilizing

2
direction.

This occurred in part because estimates of required reserves

tended to lag reality, but mostly because incoming information on the
economy, prices, and financial markets led to expectations of a change in
system policy.The more the Committee emphasizes a federal funds rate
objective, the less opportunity there is for this to occur.

As the market

comes to recognize the desired federal funds rate, the rate will move to that
level and generally stay fairly close to it.
The problem is that this rate may not be consistent with achieving
the Committee's goals for activity and inflation.

Even if it were the

appropriate rate initially, it probably soon would not be, after
inevitable shifts in the underlying forces working in the economy.

The

danger would seem especially great right now in light of an unusual
uncertainties concerning the strength of demand domestically, the trade
outlook and the dollar. To be sure, discretionary changes in the desired
rate, as in borrowing targets, could be made, but there would be a certain
amount of inertia to overcome.

In these circumstances, if the Committee

decides to continue emphasizing the federal funds rate in open market
operations, it may need to give special consideration to the conditions under
which it would expect that rate to be changed over an intermeeting period.
The likelihood of distortions to reserve management and financial
markets through the year end, especially in light of some residual fragility
in financial markets, will make it difficult and potentially disruptive to
shift back toward a borrowing objective over the next few weeks.

But the

Committee may want to instruct the Desk to review the situation carefully in
the new year, with an eye toward finding opportunities to place more emphasis
on reserve objectives and to allow more scope for the funds rate to
fluctuate.

Donald L. Kohn
December 15, 1987

Monetary Aggregates Targeting

Two of the memoranda distributed to the Committee were intended to
provide background for a discussion of some of the issues related to the

choice of target ranges for the monetary aggregates that will occur in
February.

In particular, it might be useful at this time to review the

place of the aggregates in implementing monetary policy, and whether the
Committee wishes to reestablish a range for M1 or another narrow aggregate.
With respect to the latter issue, the Committee has told Congress it would
re-examine its treatment of M1 before deciding finally on 1988 targets, and
some observers elsewhere in this city have been advocating that greater
attention be paid to M1-A.
The experience of 1987 might provide a useful reference point for
consideration of some of these issues.

The marked slowing of money growth

this year occurred despite a pickup in nominal income growth, and was
accompanied by increases in various velocity measures after several years of
declines.

Most of the behavior of money and velocity in 1987 can be

accounted for by the rise in market interest rates.
this came about involved

The process by which

to a important extent Federal Reserve decisions to

firm money market conditions.

With deposit offering rates either

constrained to zero by law in the case of demand deposits or lagging the
rise in market rates in the case of liquid retail deposit categories,

monetary aggregates became less attractive assets to hold.

The System

validated the weakening in money demand by reducing reserve provision to
prevent interest rates from dropping back as demands for required reserves
declined.

The reduction in demand resulting from the rise in rates is

reflected in the higher turnover of money so that income was less affected,
at least contemporaneously.
Moreover, the aggregates appear to be very sensitive to changes in
rates, as can be seen from the elasticities in Table 1 of the memo
distributed with the bluebook.

The M1 elasticity over four quarters is

about twice as large as was estimated in the late 1970's and early 1980's
when this aggregate was given heavy weight in policy; the M2 elasticity also
is relatively high over the intermittent term relevant to monetary targets.
Given such responsiveness, the models can "explain" 4 of the 5 percentage
point deceleration of M2 from 1986 to 1987 and 6 of the 9 percentage point
deceleration of M1 with interest rate effects alone.
Of course "explaining" and "assessing the implications of" can be
two very different exercises.

They are particularly so in the presence of

high interest elasticities, which in effect enables movements of the
aggregates to depart markedly from movements in nominal income when interest
rates move appreciably.

In this respect, an interest elastic aggregate is

just not a very good policy guide.

If for example there were an unexpected

strengthening in demands for real output, only a small increase in interest
rates might be needed to prevent an accompanying acceleration of the money
stock, while a much larger one would be necessary to rein in aggregate
demand and check the associated inflationary pressures.

Adhering to a money

stock target under these circumstances could result in an increase in
velocity and considerably faster income growth than had previously been
contemplated.

Beyond the problems posed by higher interest elasticities, there
is the gap between what we can explain and what has actually occurred.

Some

of this is just the inevitable noise in any estimated demand relationship.
But part of it also results from the continuing process of adaptation of the
financial sector to deregulation and innovation.

In a deregulated deposit

market, the relationship between money and income depends on the behavior of
depository institutions in setting rates as well as that of the public in
reacting to the menu of rates before it.

We have made considerable

progress in modeling offering rate behavior over the past few years, but it
doesrepresent an additional area of uncertainty.
Variations in the money-income relationship can also occur if the
public changes the way it manages its financial balance sheet for reasons
other than changes in market or deposit interest rates.

Something of this

sort may have been at work in 1987, when households apparently decided to
finance an unusually high proportion of their spending by slowing down asset
accumulation; borrowing by households is estimated actually to have declined
from 1986.

This pattern of behavior reverses a trend of several years in

which both sides of household balance sheets were being built up.

The

reasons for the reversal this year are just as hazy as those for the build
up in previous years, but the changes in incentives under the new tax law may
have had some effect.
The various factors tending to interfere with the connection
between money and income work to some degree on all the aggregates.

In

comparisons among the various aggregates, M1 seems clearly to come out as
the least reliable indicator or target because of its high interest
elasticity.

M1-A looks better using the model results, but the models

themselves have not done well explaining M1-A growth in recent years.

The

pattern of model errors suggests that M1-A is more interest elastic; these
models suggest this is consistent with its velocity movements in recent years,
and would make any comparisons less favorable.

The results of some recent

work on M1-A are based on a questionable specification of the relationship
of this aggregate to the economy, and in any case do not clearly point to
superiority for M1-A.

Thus the benefits of adding M1-A to the array of

aggregates the Committee targets probably would be marginal.
Taken together the evidence and analysis would seem to point
toward the need to continue to interpret movements in the aggregates
carefully in light of other information about financial markets and the
economy.

This of course is what the FOMC has been doing for several years.

The question is whether there is now any reason to change.

Some of the

instability in velocity has been associated with the process of adaptation
to deregulation, and surely much of this has been completed as banks settle
on pricing strategies and the public finishes its initial adjustment to new
instruments.

But much of the variations in velocity have been related to

the swings in interest rates.
the inflation and

These have been associated importantly with

disinflation process since the late 1970's.

Judging by

9-1/4 percent bond yields, this is not yet viewed by the market as completed.

Further sizable swings in interest rates cannot be ruled out,

especially in view of sensitive inflation expectations and uncertainties
facing the global economy.

Notes for FOMC Meeting
December 15, 1987
Sam Y. Cross

The dollar has moved down sharply since your last
meeting, falling by more than 5 percent against most major
foreign currencies.

The decline has occurred in an atmosphere of

pervasive pessimism about the currency.

Market participants

continue to express deep skepticism about the commitment of the
U.S. and others to policies needed to promote exchange rate
stability.

The dollar's decline occurred despite substantial

amounts of intervention, and despite actions by the authorities
in a number of G-10 countries to reduce global imbalances.
In early November, at the start of the period, the
dollar was under heavy downward pressure.

Market participants

were concerned that Congressional efforts to reduce the U.S.
budget deficit appeared to be deadlocked.

There were many doubts

about the official commitment to exchange rate stability
following press reports that the U.S. Administration was more
concerned about preventing recession than about stabilizing
exchange rates.

Meanwhile, remarks from officials abroad made

the market feel that the Germans for their part were unwilling to
adjust their fiscal and monetary policy to stabilize exchange
rates.
In that environment, the Desk intervened from
November 5th through the 10th, to purchase more than $1 billion,
about two-thirds of it against marks and one-third against yen,

2
much of it carried out in cooperation with dollar purchases by
other central banks.

Although the intervention was heavy, market

participants, influenced by the press stories concerning the U.S.
view about the dollar, assumed that our intervention was aimed at
slowing the dollar's downward movement rather than halting its
decline.
Thus, it was not until mid-November that the pressures
on the dollar began to subside, when this continued intervention
was reinforced by official statements--specifically a statement
by President Reagan--that began to make market participants more
confident that the United States was not looking for a further
decline of the dollar.

Also, the drop in the U.S. trade deficit

to $14.1 billion for September, announced about the same time,
suggested that progress was being made in reducing global
imbalances.

Another factor was that U.S. budget negotiations

appeared to be making some progress, and indications were
appearing that the German authorities were in fact willing to
pursue more expansionary measures.

Over several weeks, the

Bundesbank lowered its rate on repurchase agreements with banks
from 3.8 percent to 3.25 percent.
Late in November we had news of coordinated interest
rate adjustments in Germany and several other European countries,
plus the long awaited agreement on a U.S. fiscal deficit
reduction program.

But this provided only limited, temporary

support for the dollar.

Although official commentary welcomed

these actions, market participants remained skeptical.

They

3
questioned the magnitude of the policy moves here and abroad as
well as the willingness of the U.S. Administration to follow
through with other needed changes in an election year when fear
of recession was emerging as a dominant concern.
In these circumstances, the dollar resumed its decline
immediately after Thanksgiving.

The Desk again entered the

market for the second period of intervention during the six
weeks, purchasing a total of $272 million between November 27 and
December 4, once again in cooperation with other central banks.
But it wasn't until the Germans and other Europeans took further
interest rate action, cutting discount rates, and the market saw
those moves supported by coordinated intervention, that the
dollar got a few days respite.

Then, on December 10, when the

U.S. trade deficit for October was announced at $17.6 billion,
dollar exchange rates moved down another step, falling by more
than 1-1/2 to 2 percent against the mark and yen within minutes.
Again the Desk and other central banks entered the market,
purchasing dollars against both marks and yen.

This was the

third episode of intervention in the period, and in the three
business days since the trade figures were announced, the Desk
has bought a total of $351 million.
All in all, the Desk has purchased more than $1.6
billion in its intervention operations since the last FOMC
meeting.

Of this amount, $994 million was against marks and $654

million against yen.

4

The Treasury and the FOMC have operated in roughly
equal overall amounts, but the currency compositions of the two
agencies' intervention have been shifted to take account of the
currency composition of their balances.

Thus, the Federal

Reserve sold $784 million worth of marks and no yen.
Looking ahead, market participants see little to break
their pessimism toward the dollar.

They doubt that the U.S. will

do much to resist further falls in the dollar.

They know that

the current account deficit to be financed next year will be
large.

They know that private inflows financed the bulk of our

deficits in 1985 and 1986, but fell off sharply this year, and
that official authorities have purchased most of the dollars
covering our deficit during 1987.

Indeed, data we collect on

intervention show that official purchases of dollars by the Group
of Ten and other European central banks reached more than $100
billion during the first eleven months of this year.

How much

official financing will come in the next year and under what
terms is not easy to predict, but there are some signs that are
not encouraging.
currencies:

There are reports of shifts into non-dollar

notably, Taiwan is frequently reported to be buying

marks and yen for reserve diversification.

Also, the

has in the past week shifted its market intervention
approach, and has resisted upward pressure on
purchasing large amounts of marks

by

(rather than dollars),

even at

times when the United States and Germany were selling marks to
support the dollar.

These purchases of marks by

were

5
undertaken despite the strong protests of Stoltonberg, and
apparently in contravention of EC agreements.

None of this can

make anyone feel very comfortable about the financing of the U.S.
external deficit next year.

Notes for FOMC Meeting
December 15-16, 1987
Peter D. Sternlight

The stock market plunge of mid-October, and subsequent
market unsettlement, continued to cast a shadow over market
developments, and execution of domestic open market policy during
the recent intermeeting period.

To a considerable extent, the

turbulence abated, and more normal trading patterns and
relationships were restored, but an edge of nervousness remained
as participants and analysts sought to assess the damage that
might have been done and review the outlook.

Regarding specific

financial consequences to market makers, some instances have come
to light of significant damage but in general one is struck by
the absence of crippling losses that "might have been" given the
extent of price moves and the gaps in liquid market making.

As

to the outlook, some of the instant market reassessments that
looked toward an immediate increase in the prospects for business
recession in coming quarters have been modified to call for some
slowing in the economic expansion, but on most evaluations not a
recession.
Desk operations treated reserve targets with particular
flexibility over the period, drawing substantial guidance from
the Committee's desire to see day-to-day funds rates center
around the 6-3/4-6-7/8 percent area, as well as from comparisons
of reserve path levels and projections.

For the first few weeks

of the period, the paths used a $400 million borrowing level, but

2
lower levels were readily accepted in association with desired
money market conditions.

No effort was made to push borrowing up

to that level as it became clear that doing so would entail
appreciably higher funds rates.

By early December, the formal

path allowance for borrowing was reduced to $300 million, but
actual borrowing ran below that level as well, while funds
continued in the desired range.

Indeed, in the two full reserve

maintenance periods since the last meeting, borrowing averaged
just $223 million, and so far in the current period the average
is about $150 million.

Meantime, the funds rate averaged 6.73

and 6.82 percent, respectively, in the first two reserve periods
and also around 6.82 thus far in the current period.

Today it's

around 6-1/4 -- thanks to snowstorms and high float.

Past relationships would have led us to expect
borrowing of $400 million or more in association with recent
funds rates.

The dearth of borrowing may be due in part to a

desire to conserve window use for what could be more stressful
times, or possibly more advantageous times, perhaps around yearend.

Also with credit risk under such close scrutiny there may

be a particular desire to avoid being seen at the window at all.
A further factor, perhaps, is the current low level of seasonal
borrowing; such borrowing is typically at low ebb until late
winter.

To some extent, of course, our own mode of operation

could be contributing to the low borrowing; since larger banks
typically only borrow at the very end of a reserve period, our
actions to relieve this need for a bulge at the end of the

3
reserve period, in order to avoid an upward push on the funds
rate, leave borrowing low for the period. The turn of the year,
or soon thereafter, could bring a return toward a more normal
borrowing-funds rate relationship, but it would be chancy to
place great confidence in this prospect.

Flexible allowance was

also made for swings in excess reserves, which moved in a wide
saw-toothed pattern over the period.
Money growth, which showed signs of rapid expansion in
the immediate wake of the stock market plunge, turned quite
sluggish in November, with no growth at all in M2 and an actual
decline in M1.

This left October-November growth of M2

appreciably below the Committee's 6-7 percent indicated pace.
Growth in M3 tracked the Committee's pace more closely as banks
appeared to take more initiative in adding to non-M2 funding
sources--possibly in order to avoid costly year-end problems or
to build a cushion against the possibility of bank names coming
under pressure.

Early December data suggest continued softness

in at least the narrow money measures.
The Desk met large reserve needs over the period
through a combination of outright and temporary provisions.

The

large needs were essentially the seasonal increases in currency
and required reserves, with currency running a little heavier
than usual and required reserves growing a bit less than usual as
money growth weakened.

The System's total outright purchases

were a little over $8 billion, thus using most of the enlarged
leeway the Committee provided.

Included were market purchases of

4
$2.6 billion in bills and $4.1 billion in coupon issues, along
with $1.4 billion of bills and notes bought directly from foreign
accounts.

Incidentally, so far in 1987, the System's outright

portfolio has increased, net, by about $21 billion including
$4 billion in bills and $17 billion in Treasury coupon issues.
(Last year's net rise was about $20 billion, with much more in
bills than coupons.)

The Desk also made use of repurchase

agreements in the latest period, arranging either System or
customer transactions on many days, although we managed to stay
out altogether after December 4.

Moreover, the size of these

temporary transactions was typically more modest than in the days
just following October 19, though heavier volume was done in the
first couple of days of December when the funds rate temporarily
flared above 7 percent.
Yields on fixed income securities, after their sharp
drop in the wake of the mid-October stock market collapse, worked
slightly higher on balance over the intermeeting period-especially late last week when the market was shocked by a
sharply higher October trade deficit and weaker dollar.

Early in

the intermeeting period, yields declined further, as foreign rate
cuts and early assessments of the economic impact of the stock
market collapse fanned some hopes of more overt easing steps in
monetary policy.

As the period advanced, evidence that the

economy was even stronger than had been envisioned preOctober 19, and that the stock market plunge may not have
entirely derailed the expansion, led to more sober appraisals of

5

interest rate prospects.

The budget deficit reduction exercise,

while considered to be better than nothing, was nevertheless
considered unimpressive and uncertain in its ultimate impact, so
it was more a neutral than a plus factor.

Then, late in the

period, the huge October trade deficit and the tumbling dollar
augmented market concerns about renewed inflation and produced
further upward rate pressure.

Just in the last couple of days,

though, bond prices recovered again, based at least partly on
weaker oil prices.
For the period, intermediate and long-term Treasury
rates were little changed to up about 15 basis points.

The 30-

year bond yield is now around 9.20 percent, up from 9-1/8 before
the last meeting, and a low point of about 8.80 early in the
intermeeting period.

Bill rates were volatile over the period,

swinging particularly in response to the ebb and flow of quality
concerns elsewhere in the market.

Net bill rates rose about 1/4

percentage point over the period.

In the latest auction, 3 and 6

month issues sold at 6.00 even and 6.45 percent compared with
5.80 and 6.24 percent just before the last meeting.

The Treasury

has continued to pay down modest amounts of bills in recent
weeks, while adding to coupon issues to cover the ongoing
deficit.
In other markets, longer corporate and municipal yields
rose less than those for Treasury issues.

Some shorter private

market instruments showed sharper rate increases, however,
particularly where maturities bridge the year-end period.

6
Many market participants have painful memories of rate
pressures at year-end last year.

The general expectation is that

pressures will be considerably less this year, largely because we
don't have the tax-related bulges in credit to contend with.
There is still some concern, though, and funding for the weekend
that begins December 31 is already quoted at elevated rates.
There is also concern that some pressures could begin to build
even before year-end--as indeed happened last year.

That, too,

is expected to be less pronounced than last year, although some
analysts have already been saying they expect to see slightly
higher funds rates in the next couple of weeks even without any
change in policy.
As for policy expectations, market participants pretty
much see a stand-off between forces that might lead to greater
accommodation--chiefly a softening economy in the wake of the
stock market plunge--and forces that could work toward firming,
particularly the declining dollar and related concerns about
inflation.
On a housekeeping note, I'd like to mention some likely
primary dealer list changes coming up.

We plan shortly to add

three firms to the list, one U.S. based, one Japanese and one
British.
year.

These would be the first additions in a little over a

We also expect, quite shortly, applications from two major

Japanese banks to acquire existing primary dealers.

If these go

through--which would entail normal bank regulatory approval as
well--it would mean there'd be 12 foreign-owned dealers, half of

7
them Japanese.

During the past year, we've been following

developments in the Japanese market closely, and believe they
have been making significant progress toward opening their
financial markets to greater foreign participation, as well as
joining others in working toward harmonized bank capital
standards.

We learned this morning about the naming of

additional foreign members to TSE.
to go, though.

There is still some distance

Moreover, the rapid increase in their ranks as

primary dealers gives us some pause and we have in mind giving
some weight to that geographic concentration factor as we look
ahead.

Near term, there may also be some deletions from the

primary dealer list, at least temporarily, reflecting
consolidations and potential sales of operations.
*

*

*

*

*

Leeway recommendation
Mr. Chairman, current reserve projections running
through the next intermeeting period suggest that we may need
additional leeway again for changes in outright holdings--this
time to accommodate large declines in currency and required
reserves in late January and early February.

I would suggest

that the intermeeting leeway which was temporarily raised to
$9 billion in the latest period, remain at that level for the
next period as well.

FOMC Briefing
Michael J. Prell
December 16, 1987

A good number of economic data have been released since we
published the Greenbook a week ago.

The fact is, though, that those

data have done only a little to illuminate the pattern of developments
in the current quarter--and even less to clarify the intermediate-run
tendencies that monetary policy might have to deal with.

None of the

statistical information in hand at this juncture gives us much basis for
gauging, in particular, the ultimate effects of the stock market decline
on aggregate demand.
Under the circumstances, it should not be surprising that the
latest Greenbook forecast is little altered from the one we prepared for
the Committee's November meeting.

Real GNP growth in 1988 was raised by

a couple of tenths of a percent--admittedly not a quantitatively
significant change, but one that is consistent with our sense that the
stock market decline has not had a devastating effect on consumer or
business expectations.
At the same time, however, we clipped a couple of tenths off
our 1988 projection of wage and price inflation.

While we still are

projecting a clear acceleration of wages, it looks to us like pay
increases are coming in a little lower at this point than we had
anticipated, and the prevailing mood of caution and focus on costcutting and job security are likely to continue restraining wage gains
for a while longer.

-2As you know, the key feature of our forecast is the marked
slowing in real GNP growth by early 1988.

Basically, our thesis was

that the stock market drop would begin soon to leave its mark on
consumer spending, and that wary businessmen would move very quickly to
trim orders and production so as to avoid any notable buildup of
inventories.

The available information doesn't provide many hints that

this deceleration is yet in train.

Indeed, the labor market data

through November suggest substantial strength in employment and wage and
salary income, and this was the major reason why we raised our projection of fourth-quarter GNP growth from 2-1/4 percent to 3 percent.
As I noted earlier, the incoming data of recent days have not
added much to our understanding of how this quarter is developing.
Rather, they have created a puzzle.

On the one hand, the strong gains

estimated for industrial production--0.4 percent in November on top of
an upward-revised 0.9 percent in October--reinforce the notion that we
had considerable upward thrust coming from a manufacturing sector that
is benefiting from improved international price competitiveness and
increased business investment.
The other data received since last Wednesday, however, leave us
wondering where all that production has been going.

The November

increase in retail sales was in line with our expectations, but the
sizable downward revisions in September and October would force us to
write down a considerably deeper fourth-quarter decline in real consumer
spending than the 2 percent annual rate shown in the Greenbook.

-3The merchandise trade data for October were similarly
disappointing--especially the surprising decline (on a seasonally
adjusted basis) in our nonagricultural exports.

Even making due

allowance for the tremendous volatility of these numbers, they suggest a
moderate downward revision to the gain in real net exports we had
forecast for this quarter.
Inventory investment in October, in contrast, evidently was
stronger than we had anticipated but the added

accumulation doesn't

seem to have been great enough to fill the gap between output and
spending.

Nor does the anecdotal information give one the sense that a

very large inventory buildup is in process.
We received one additional current indicator this morning.
Housing starts were up somewhat more than we had expected in November,
at 1.64 million units versus 1.52 in October.

The improvement reflected

a bounceback in the multi-family category, which had dropped noticeably
in the prior month.

The decline in interest rates seems to be providing

an offset to the stock market drop in the single-family sector.

These

stronger starts will, however, do little to raise current quarter construction outlays.
My own guess is that we shall see some better numbers on final
spending in the remaining data for the fourth quarter.

However, it also

appears quite possible that real GNP growth will fall a bit short of our
3 percent Greenbook forecast and that a greater share of the output will
end up in inventories.

Such a mix-shift would, of course, make more

likely the first-quarter output deceleration we have forecasted.

-4

-

A poll taken by the National Association of Business Economists
recently showed 7 percent of respondents saying that the economy already
is in recession and another 43 percent saying a recession will occur by
the end of 1988.

While the recession-now scenario seems unduly pessi-

mistic, any reasonable confidence interval around our forecast certainly
would encompass the possibility of a modest downturn in activity.

But,

as we perceive the outlook, even with an allowance for a significant
negative stock market effect, recession does not seem the most likely
outcome.

We continue to believe that the foreign trade sector will

provide substantial support to output and employment growth.

U.S.

competitiveness has improved, and the stronger G-10 expansion in the
third quarter and the easing actions taken by European monetary
authorities also are a source of some encouragement.

The impetus from

trade improvement should, in turn, help to sustain capital spending.

I

might note that the Commerce Department put out its survey of 1988 plant
and equipment spending plans.

It shows a 7.3 percent nominal increase

over 1987--just a shade above our projection.

The survey responses came

in between early October and early December, so they probably don't
reflect any stock-market influence.
We have continued to build a moderate further decline in U.S.
interest rates into our forecast, and this provides additional insurance
that the economy will be able to reestablish solid upward momentum in
the latter part of 1988, after the wealth effects of the stock market
have taken their toll on consumer demand.

Should consumers not respond

-5-

much to that wealth reduction, however, the outlook for 1988 would, in
our view, be considerably more robust--perhaps robust enough to result
in a noticeable decline in unemployment and rise in capacity utilization.

In such circumstances, a substantial increase in interest rates

might well be necessary to temper the rise in aggregate demand and avert
a serious deterioration in wage and price trends.
By depicting these two scenarios, I certainly don't want to
suggest that a wide range of other possibilities doesn't exist.

How-

ever, I believe both scenarios are well within the range of plausible
outcomes, and they point up what we perceive to be a dilemma for the
Committee: namely, given the lags in the effect of policy action, an
easing or tightening step might be appropriate now, but it isn't clear
which.

This, of course, isn't an unprecedented problem, but the present

situation--with its unusual overlay of international considerations-seems to involve extraordinary imponderables.

Donald L. Kohn
December 16, 1987

Monetary Policy Alternatives
A

aajor issue for the Committee in considering its short-run

alternatives is the interpretation of recent monetary data and its
implications for the economy.

Monthly data have been distorted by the bulge

in demand deposits that followed the stock market crash.

The run-off of that

bulge was a major influence on November growth, especially for M1.
weakness has persisted into early December.

But

Indeed, information received over

the past two days suggests that M1 will decline again in December, and that
the pickup in M2 growth will be less than had been projected in the bluebook.
Taking account of our new projections for December, and averaging through the
ups and downs of recent months, we now project that M1 will increase at around
a 1-1/2 percent annual rate over September to December, M2 at around a 3-1/2
percent rate and M3 a little over 5 percent.

This would represent a shortfall

from expectations at the November meeting, and, especially for M1, a further
slowing from the pace previously recorded this year.

Part of the shortfall arises because the staff had built some
heightened liquidity demands into its projections last time, and these haven't

materialized.

In the absence of such demands, fairly slow growth is not

entirely unexpected.

Interest rates had risen through mid-October, and the

same forces that have been restraining monetary expansion through the year
undoubtedly have been at work in the fourth quarter.

In fact, on a quarterly

average basis, growth in the fourth quarter is not far different than would be

predicted by the models, which see earlier increases in interest rates as
still damping money growth.
meeting.

And it is close to expectations at the September

The major surprise continues to be in demand deposits, which are

projected to be dropping substantially further in December.

While demand

deposits have been weak at all types of banks, the very largest money center
banks have experienced a disproportionate decline this year.

The weakness in

these deposits tends to feed through into M2, since it probably does not
reflect shifts into other M2 components.
insights on this subject overnight.

Unfortunately, I have had no new

Committee members may remember that we

were equally puzzled by the strength of demand deposits in 1985 and 1986, and
conducted several special rounds of follow-up calls to banks and their corporate customers.

The answer we received most consistently referred to inter-

est rate effects, especially on compensating balances.

And the concentration

at largest banks suggests that this type adjustment of business accounts
remains an important channel.

A further factor we uncovered in the process of

assessing rapid demand deposit growth was the role of mortgage prepayments,
which, because of certain regulations in the mortgage market, tend to be
lodged in demand accounts for a time.

The rise in prepayments as interest

rates fell likely boosted demand deposit growth in 1986, and their slackening
probably has contributed to weakness this year. For all these rationales, the
question remains as to whether the decrease in the demand deposits and shortfall in broader aggregates is signalling a fundamental tightening of liquidity
in the economy that will lead to considerable restraint on economic activity.
Collateral evidence in financial markets on the thrust of policy in
the most recent period presents a mixed picture, as interest rates rose and

stock prices fell on balance, but the dollar dropped sharply.

While the

decline in the dollar might be consistent with an expectation of a weakening
economy and prospective declines in interest rates, the response of the bond
market suggested that the drop in the dollar was seen to arise from other
sources, and concerns were more that the lower dollar would be strengthening
the economy and prices over time.

The yield curve retains a fairly steep up-

ward slope, which generally indicates that the market, at least, expects that
the trend in policy is more likely to need to be toward restraint than ease.
The bluebook paths have built into them some pickup in money growth
over the next several months.

Basically, this strengthening arises from the

lagged impact of the decline in interest rates in late October.

Under alter-

native B, which assumes that rates remain about where they are, the pickup is
only expected to bring money growth about in line with income, in part because
the decline in interest rates after October 19 merely brought them back to their

levels of August.

Thus, without further rate declines, the impact on money

demand also is modest, essentially undoing the effects of previous increases
since August.
Whether such an outcome is satisfactory, or how the Committee would
like to calibrate the Desk's response to additional information over the
intermeeting period, could depend on a weighing of the risks in the outlook.
Alternative B may not be sufficient to assure a satisfactory expansion of the
economy if the stock price decline does have a substantial impact on demand,
as in the staff forecast.

As Mike has mentioned, that forecast, and in parti-

cular the pickup in activity the second half of the next year, depends in part on

an assumed further easing of policy, indexed by lower interest rates and more

rapid money growth than under alternative B--especially if the unchanged conditions of that alternative were maintained well into next year.

If the risks

were seen on this side, but the Committee did not want to ease until trends
were clearer, it could tilt the intermeeting adjustments in the directive in
the direction of ease.

In this context, a failure of money to pick up sub-

stantially could be seen as adding to, or at least signalling, a shortfall in
the economy.

If this were a concern, the Committee could indicate that in

judging the need for intermeeting adjustments the Desk should put a little
more emphasis on incoming money data, especially if it continued to come in
weaker than expected.
On the other hand, the effects of the recent dollar decline could be
seen as shifting the risks more to the inflation side.

Especially if

the decline in the stock market did not seem to be having very marked effects
on domestic demand, slow money growth in this context would be needed to damp
domestic demand to reduce pressures on capacity and prices as the impact of
the lower-dollar showed through.

Under these circumstances, the Committee

would not want to lean toward ease, and might need to consider the possibility
of tightening should the dollar decline seem to be gathering momentum.
With respect to the directive, the draft in the bluebook moves back
toward the standard language in use in recent years, but retains some sense of
the need for special flexibility.

It is sufficiently general to fit most

choices the Committee might make about the strategy for implementation over
the coming period, except perhaps for either extreme--that is, a complete and
immediate return to borrowing targeting, or a further and more permanent shift
to looking exclusively at federal funds rates.

BOARD OF GOVERNORS
OF THE

FEDERAL RESERVE

SYSTEM

Office Correspondence
To

Federal Open Market Committee

From

Donald L.

Date
Subject:

October

29, 1987

Definition of the Borrowing

Kohn

Objective

The attached memorandum responds to questions about the treatment
of two types of discount window credit in the implementation of monetary
policy under an operating procedure keyed to an objective for discount window borrowing.

The first

section of the memorandum (beginning on page 2)

deals with "special situation" borrowing--borrowing classified as adjustment credit that does not share the usual characteristics of such credit.
Generally the Desk treats such borrowing analogously with extended credit

by excluding it
objective.

from borrowing levels sought under its basic borrowing

The question was raised as to whether such treatment, perhaps

acting through effects of published data on market expectations, might
not result in tighter money market conditions than intended.

The second

section (beginning on p. 8) addresses the issue of whether the inclusion
of seasonal credit in the borrowing objective imparts a systematic seasonal pattern to the federal funds rate.
As discussed in the previous memorandum to the FOMC on the
federal funds rate and the borrowing objective, the relationship between
those two variables is fairly loose.

The evidence presented in this

memorandum suggests that the current treatment of the two types of credit
in question has not contributed to the imprecision of that relationship
or to systematic movements in the federal funds rate.

Thus, the results

do not present a case for altering current procedures.
This subject has been tentatively scheduled for discussion at
the upcoming FOMC meeting, depending on whether there is time available
once the Committee has completed its regular business.

BOARD OF GOVERNORS
OF THE

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Office Correspondence
To

Mr. Kohn

From

David F Lindsey and Gary Gillium¹

Date
Subject

October 29 1987

Treatmnt of Special Situation and

Seasonal Borrowings in Desk Operations

At a recent Board meeting, questions were raised
about the appropriate treatment of special situation borrowing in Desk operations aimed at attaining the FOMC's
specified level of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing.

Also

reemerging was the issue of the appropriate treatment of
seasonal borrowing, which had been briefly reviewed in a
previous memorandum to the Federal Open Market Committee, 2
discussed by the Committee at its July 7 meeting, and examined in more detail at a Board seminar on July 30.

The

body of this memorandum addresses the implications for
policy implementation of both of these issues.

Appendix A

presents econometric evidence on the relation of special
situation borrowing and the funds rate.

Appendix B presents

econometric evidence on the relation of seasonal borrowing
and the funds rate.

1.
James Glassman and Mary Hoffman assisted in the
preparation of this memorandum.
2.
David E. Lindsey and James Glassman, "A Review of the
Relation of the Funds Rate and Intended Discount Borrowings,"
Board staff memorandum to Donald Kohn, July 1, 1987, page 7;
transmitted to the Federal Open Market Committee with a cover
memorandum from Donald L. Kohn, "Attached Study of Borrowing
and the Federal Funds Rate," July 1, 1987.

Special situation borrowing
Special situation borrowing is discount credit
that, while classified officially as adjustment credit,
occurs in circumstances that disrupt the normal interaction
of bidding for funds in the market and administrative pressures at the discount window.

Frequently, such borrowing is

by a troubled institution whose normal market access has
been cut off, but whose borrowing is classified as adjustment until the protracted nature of the funding problem
becomes clearer and the credit is reclassified as extended
credit.

At other times, random events such as computer

breakdowns may give rise to very large short-term funding
needs that force a depository institution temporarily to use
the discount window in volume to avoid an overdraft.
Finally, when borrowings surge on the settlement day just
prior to a Thursday holiday, borrowing in the next maintenance period begins at an artificially high level -- unrelated to reserve pressures in the new statement period

--

and the Desk often will make an allowance by considering
such borrowing to be of a special situation nature.
An extreme example of the first type of special
situation borrowing occurred in May and early June of 1984
when Continental Illinois borrowed massive amounts of adjustment credit -- at one point nearly $5 billion -- before

its borrowing was reclassified as extended credit.

The

computer outage at the Bank of New York on November 21,
1985, which resulted in the bank borrowing nearly $23

3
billion in adjustment credit that night, is a notable
example of the second type of special situation borrowing.
Although the Federal Reserve put considerable pressure on
the Bank of New York to resolve its computer problems as
soon as feasible, and the bank obtained some funds in the
federal funds market, it was impossible for that bank to
raise more than a small fraction of needed funds, and
adjustment credit was provided to cover the bulk of the
associated account deficiency.

As a final example,

borrowing surged on settlement day prior to the Thanksgiving
Day holiday in 1984, giving rise to considerable special
situation borrowing in the following maintenance period, as
may be seen in chart 1.
Because of the character of the circumstances
giving rise to special situation borrowing, the operating
presumption has been that such borrowing is akin to extended
credit in its impact on funds market conditions.

That is,

given an offsetting reduction in nonborrowed reserves to
maintain a predetermined volume of other adjustment plus
seasonal borrowing, special situation borrowing should have
little effect on the federal funds rate.

Thus, the Desk

normally makes either a formal or informal adjustment to
treat special situation borrowing along with extended credit
as similar to nonborrowed reserves and to exclude it from
the measure of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing that the
Desk attempts to keep at the FOMC's specified level.

Chart 1

Federal Funds Loss Discount Rate

1982

Percent

1984

1983

1986
193 1984 1985 1987
1986
1987

1985

21982

$ Millions
-3000

Adjustment Plus Seasonal Borrowing
(Excludes Special Situation Borrowing)

2250

1500

750

----- _

1982

1983

-Thankgiving

Special Situation Borrowing

1986

1987

Holiday Carryover

$ Millions

1985

1984

0

3000
Ohio and Maryland Thrifts

SJuly
Continental
Illinois

4th Holiday

Carryover
" "

-

2250

- Computer Problems
at a NY Bank
1500
Bank of New York

Drysdale/Lombard-Wall/
Comark

750

I1

_A_11
I
1982
1983
NOTE: Maintenance period averages

1984

r 1st Nat'l o f Ok. City

t

AAAA
_________

Al _
1_

1985

__
1986

k
1987

0

4
The issue raised at the recent Board meeting involved the potential in this approach for market
participants to misperceive the FOMC's intentions.

Market

participants monitor published values of adjustment and
seasonal borrowing for indications of the FOMC's current
specification of intended pressure on reserve positions.
However, special situation borrowing is not identified as a
separate component of adjustment credit in the published
statistics.

Thus, market participants could incorrectly

interpret a figure for adjustment credit that is enlarged by
special situation borrowing as a sign of Federal Reserve
tightening of reserve provision when no such policy move is
intended.

The resulting altered expectations of the Federal

Reserve's policy stance could place temporary upward pressure on the federal funds rate independent of actual reserve
provision.
The alternative approach would be to forego the
adjustment for special situation borrowing and for the Desk
to try to keep all adjustment plus seasonal borrowing, including special situation borrowing, at the FOMC's specified
level.

However, if the analysis behind the current treat-

ment of special situation borrowing is correct, this alternative approach would result in an undesired easing of funds
market conditions when such borrowing occurred.

Including

special situation borrowing in a targeted amount of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing would imply a dollar-for-dollar
decline in the rest of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing as

5
special situation borrowing occurred.

Lessened pressure on

reserve positions as the rest of borrowing fell would tend
to induce a decline in the spread of the funds rate over the
discount rate that would be at variance with the expected
funds rate outcome given the FOMC's intended policy stance.
In fact, the occurrence of special situation borrowing does not appear to have systematic effects on the
federal funds rate.

Chart 1 plots the funds rate-discount

rate spread in the top panel, adjustment plus seasonal borrowing excluding all special situation borrowing in the
middle panel, and special situation borrowing in the lower
panel.

The maintenance-period data span the years from

early 1982 to date.

Although a loose association between

the spread and adjustment plus seasonal borrowing excluding
special situation borrowing is apparent to the naked eye, no
clear distortion of the relationship resulting from the
occurrence of special situation borrowing, apart perhaps
from the aftermath of the Continental Illinois episode, is
evident.
Econometric evidence reinforces this judgment.

It

strongly suggests that, since early 1982, special situation
borrowing apart from the fallout of the Continental Illinois
episode in the summer 1984 has had no significant impact on
the funds market once account is taken of the effect of the
rest of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing.
A.)

(See Appendix

The Continental Illinois episode, moreover, appeared

not to reflect a direct impact of Continental's borrowing on

6
the funds rate, but rather an indirect effect on the willingness of other banks to tap the discount window.

With

Continental's funding difficulties shaking public confidence
in the banking system generally, large institutions in particular became more reluctant to use the window out of a
desire to avoid rumors about their own financial condition.
This evidence thus suggests that special situation
borrowing in itself has not systematically added to funds
market pressure through any mechanism.

The Desk's procedure

has been to offset the reserve injections from special situation borrowing by reductions of nonborrowed reserves.

If

such borrowing had put independent upward pressure on the
funds rate, either through market misperceptions of FOMC
intentions or through the market pressures usually
associated with adjustment borrowing, the econometric
evidence (in Appendix A) would be expected to reveal a positive association between the funds rate and such borrowing.
But it does not.

Thus, the treatment of special situation

borrowing in the Desk's implementation of the FOMC's
monetary policy in general does not seem to have given rise
to funds market distortions.
The lack of a systematic effect on the funds rate
through a market misperception channel seems to have
reflected market participants' knowledge of the way the Desk
treats such borrowing and their reasonably accurate
estimates of its approximate size when it appears in published reserve statistics.

Their estimates have been

7
derived in part from the breakdown of Wednesday borrowing
data by Federal Reserve district that appears on the weekly
Federal Reserve condition statement published on Thursday
for the week ending the previous day.

This information,

combined with market intelligence about funding difficulties
of particular institutions, at the very least alerts market
participants that adjustment plus seasonal borrowing may be
unusually high, but may even enable them to identify the
approximate magnitude of the special situation component of
published adjustment borrowing.

As an important supplemen-

tal source of information, the press officer at the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York normally indicates to reporters at
the Thursday afternoon press conference when the amount of
borrowing has been appreciably distorted by a special situation.

In addition to reporting this information, the press

may well attempt to develop the story further through their
own independent inquiries.

The market also has made in-

ferences about FOMC intentions from the behavior of the
funds rate itself.
In the recent instance, when average adjustment
borrowing for the week ending September 30 was distorted by
about $150 million of special situation borrowing associated
with wire problems in the New York district, market participants had a good handle on the size of the impact on
adjustment borrowing.

More special situation borrowing,

arising from further wire problems and the California earth-

8
quake, early in the following week helped to bloat the twoweek average effect on adjustment plus seasonal borrowing to
around $100 million, which the Desk treated as akin to nonEven so, the market apparently correctly

borrowed reserves.

inferred from the actual borrowing of $725 million and
emerging conditions in the funds market that the borrowing
assumption used by the Desk in constructing reserve paths
was in the area of $600 million.
Seasonal borrowing
Seasonal borrowing has displayed a significant
seasonal pattern in the 1980s.

The top panels of charts 2

and 3 show seasonal borrowing as the irregular broken line
for the subperiods of lagged and contemporaneous reserve
accounting, respectively.

(Adjustment borrowing is the

dashed line, while adjustment plus seasonal borrowing is the
solid line.)

With seasonal borrowing related primarily to

the financing needs of small agricultural banks, such borrowing reaches a harvest-season peak during in the third
quarter, and a trough early in the first quarter.
Seasonal borrowing also seems responsive to the
spread of the funds rate over the discount rate, shown in
the lower panel.

For example, the negative spread in 1980

brought seasonal borrowing down to minimal levels, even in
the third quarter of that year, while the relatively sizable
spreads in 1981 and 1984 induced relatively large amounts of
seasonal borrowing.

The evident interest responsiveness of

Chart 2

Discount Window Borrowing

$ Millions
4000

= Adjustment Plus Seasonal'

--------

= Adjustment'
= Seasonal

3500

3000

2500

2000
1

IJ

I

1500

t
S l

I

V-Soo

'

1000

VI

-I-I-'I----

4

1980

1981

1982

Spread of Federal Funds Rate Over Discount Rate

1983

rcntag Points

-

-8

4

0

4
81
1980

1981

1982

1983

4

Chart 3

Discount Window Borrowing

$ Millions
1600

= Adjustment Plus Seasonal*
Adjustment*

--

----

----

Seasonal

1400

S1200

-

I
I

1000

I
I

I

1

9

800

-i 400

'

.

i I

I

Ij \!

,

I

(Il

1985

1984

I

1986

Spread of Federal Funds Rate Over Discount Rate

400

1987

Percentage Points
-3

2

-

-

-1

1984

1985

* Excludes special situation borrowing.

1986

1987

9
seasonal borrowing is clearly less pronounced than for
adjustment borrowing.
Primarily in recognition of the interest sensitivity of seasonal borrowing, the FOMC has included such
credit in the borrowing measure used to index its intentions
for pressure on reserve positions.

This treatment, though,

has produced a long-standing debate about whether or not the
seasonality in seasonal borrowing could tend to induce an
inverse seasonal pattern in the federal funds rate.

For

example, as seasonal borrowing rises for a given spread
going into the third quarter of the year, adjustment credit
will have to decline for the Desk to maintain the sum of the
two at an intended level.

Given the discount rate, the

funds rate in principle would tend to fall each summer to
bring aout the needed decline in adjustment borrowings.
One alternative procedure would be to exclude
seasonal borrowing from the targeted measure, and for the
FOMC to specify its intentions in terms of adjustment borrowing alone.

This approach would be designed to eliminate

the potential for induced seasonality in the federal funds
rate.

Even if seasonal borrowing is responsive to the

spread, the lack of seasonality in the adjustment borrowing
relation to the spread would then preclude seasonality in
the funds rate.

And if the relationship between adjustment

borrowing and the spread is at least as predictable as that
for adjustment plus seasonal borrowing, the funds rate would

10
then be at least as predictable given the FOMC's intentions
as under the current procedure.
Another alternative procedure would be for the Desk
to alter its target for adjustment plus seasonal borrowing
over the course of the year to account for the estimated
seasonal movements in seasonal borrowing.

That is, the

borrowing target would be raised in the third quarter above
its basic level as seasonal borrowing rose and would be
reduced in the winter below its basic level as seasonal
borrowing fell.
Charts 2 and 3, however, do not suggest a tendency
for the funds rate spread to vary inversely with the level
of seasonal borrowing, by falling in the third quarter and
rising in the winter.³ Nor do charts 2 and 3 suggest that
this lack of pattern in the funds rate reflects an offsetting seasonal pattern in the sum of actual adjustment plus
seasonal borrowing -- for example, a systematic rise in the

third quarter and fall in the winter.
Econometric methods confirm the absence of a
statistically significant seasonal pattern in the relation
of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing to the spread despite
a significant seasonal pattern in the relation of seasonal
borrowing alone to the spread under the two-week maintenance
period regime in place since early 1984.

(See Appendix B.)

3. A year-end spike in the funds rate has emerged in the
last two years, but it appears to have been related to
special year-end pressures, such as heavy financial
transactions volume and larger-than-expected demands for
excess reserves, rather than to low seasonal borrowing.

11
One possible explanation is that market expectations of
Federal Reserve intentions and arbitrage by larger banks
across maintenance periods prevent potential seasonality in
the relation of the spread to the sum of adjustment plus
seasonal borrowing from showing through in the funds ratediscount rate spread.

Another possibility is simply that

the seasonal movements in seasonal borrowing, which are
relatively small in magnitude despite their statistical significance, are swamped by random noise in the relation of
total borrowing to the spread and thus difficult to detect
with statistical methods.
Additional statistical evidence (also reported in
Appendix B) indicates that if the Desk had simply been targeting the level of adjustment credit since early 1984, no
significant change in the predictability of the funds rate
would have resulted.

Nor would the funds rate have been

more or less predictable if the Desk had formally adjusted
the operating target for adjustment plus seasonal borrowing
to account for the estimated seasonal movement in the
seasonal borrowing relation over the same period, according
to another test.

4.

Another possible explanation -- that the seasonal

pattern in seasonal borrowing tends to be offset by opposite
movements in adjustment borrowing, as institutions substitute
one form of discount credit for the other -- is rejected by

the lack of statistically significant seasonality in the
relation of adjustment borrowing to the spread.

Appendix A
Econometric Estimates of the Impact of
Special Situation Borrowing on the Funds Rate
The econometric evidence reported in table Al bears
on the responsiveness of the spread of the federal funds
rate over the discount rate to special situation borrowing
given the remaining amount of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing.

Column 1 simply updates through the October 7 main-

tenance period an equation relating the spread as the dependent variable to adjustment plus seasonal borrowing,
excluding special situation borrowing, a constant term, and
two dummy variables representing shifts in the constant term
for the Continental Illinois episode of the summer of 1984
and for the period since 1986.

An equation of this form

was reported and discussed at length in an earlier memorandum to the FOMC.¹ Column 2 then adds to this equation
three variables representing special situation borrowing by
Continental Illinois, the Bank of New York, and all other
institutions, respectively.

1.
See Lindsey and Glassman, op. cit. In this appendix,
though, the equations are estimated with ordinary least
squares rather than the two-stage least squares procedure
with instrumental variables reported in the earlier
memorandum. This change is designed to isolate better the
interaction in the current maintenance period of different
borrowing variables in affecting the funds rate spread over
the discount rate. The results for special situation
borrowing were little different when two-stage least squares
were employed, while the other regression coefficients were
more in accord with a priori expectations.

Table Al
Estimates of Borrowing Functions¹
(The Spread of the Funds Rate over the Discount Rate is the Dependent Variable)
(Percentage points; early 1982 to present)

(1)
Without Special
Situation Borrowing

1.

Constant

(2)
With Current
Special Situation
Borrowing

(3)
With Current and
Lagged Special Situation
Borrowing

.40 (2.1)

.41 (2.1)

.42 (2.0)

.06 (6.7)

.06 (6.6)

.06 (6.5)

-.02 (-1.7)

-.02 (-1.6)

Adjustment plus seasonal borrowing²
2a.

Excluding special situations
Special situation borrowing

2b.
2c.
2d.

Continental Bank

.01

Lagged one period
-.01 (-.5)

Bank of New York

-. 01 (-.6)
.01 (-.3)

Lagged one period
Other special situations
2g.

(.1)

-.01

(-.2)

Lagged one period

.00

(-.1)

.01

(.3)

Dummy variables representing shifts
Summer 1984

.38

(1.3)

.37 (1.3)

(1.5)

1986 to present

.28

(1.0)

.29 (1.0)

(.6)

Summary regression statistics
R²(adjusted)
Standard error of estimate

1. Uses an ordinary least squares procedure. Fit over maintenance periods between January 6, 1982 and October 7,
1987. T-values appear in parentheses.
2. Coefficients represent the rise in the funds rate in percentage points associated with a rise in borrowing of $100
million.

A-2
None of the three variables is statistically significant, judging by the t values in parentheses.

The fit

of the equation also is not altered, as may be seen by comparing the standard error of estimate (line 6) and the adjusted R2 (line 5) in columns 1 and 2.

The variable measur-

ing special situation borrowing by all institutions other
than Continental and Bank of New York has no systematic
effect on the funds rate.

Of course, Continental's funding

crisis had in indirect effect on the borrowing function by
altering the attitudes of other banks toward use of the
window, as represented by the dummy variable for the summer
of 1984. 2

But once account is taken of the impact on the

readiness of other banks to rely on discount window credit
in the summer of 1984 through the first dummy variable
shown, no additional effect of Continental's special situation borrowing per se is indicated.

The results in column 2

suggest that the occurrence of special situation borrowing
has not perceptibly affected the funds rate in the same
maintenance period when the Desk has operated in a manner
that treats special situation borrowing as akin to extended
credit by including it with nonborrowed reserves.
Given that data for adjustment borrowing including
special situation borrowing in the second week of a two-week

2.
This impact shows up as statistically significant using
two-stage least squares, even when Continental's and other
special situation borrowing is included. The indirect
effects of Continental's funding problems surfaced in the
reserve maintenance period following the reclassification of
its borrowings as extended credit.

A-3

maintenance period are published on the first day on the
next maintenance period, column 3 adds special situation
borrowing lagged by one maintenance period to the regression.

Any effect on market perceptions of FOMC intentions

arising from publication might at times occur in the next
maintenance period and the lagged variable would pick up
this delayed effect if it is present in the data.

Once

again, however, these added variables are not statistically
significant and the goodness of the equation's fit is little
changed by their inclusion.

A systematic tightening impact

on the funds rate of special situation borrowing via market
misperceptions in either the current or next maintenance
period does not appear to be confirmed by the data.

Appendix B
Econometric Estimates of the Impact of
Seasonality in Seasonal Borrowing on the Funds Rate
The results of estimating alternative borrowing functions using two-week maintenance period data since early
February 1984 are presented in table B1 for seasonal borrowing (column 1),

adjustment borrowing (column 2) and their

sum (column 3).

The borrowing measures are the dependent

variables, with independent variables represented by a constant, the spread of the funds rate over the discount rate,
and two dummy variables for shifts in the constant term for
the Continental Illinois episode in the summer of 1984 and
for 1986 to date.¹ Results without seasonal dummy variables appear in lines 1-6, while results with seasonal dummy
variables are given in lines 7-14.
For seasonal borrowing, the addition of seasonal
dummies improves the fit of the equation significantly, with
the standard error falling from around $70 million (line 6)
without accounting for seasonality to around $45 million
(line 12) with explicit account taken of seasonal effects.
Many of the estimated additive seasonal factors in seasonal
borrowing for individual maintenance periods are
significantly different from zero, as indicated by the asterisks.

The largest negative seasonal influence is in the

1. This specification is discussed in Lindsey and
Glassman, op. cit.

Table B1
Estimates of Borrowings Functions With and Without Seasonal Variables
(Borrowing Measures are the Dependent Variables)
(Millions of dollars; early 1984 to present)
(1)
Seasonal
Borrowing

(2)
Adjustment
Borrowing

(3)
Adjustment + Seasonal
Borrowing

Without Seasonal Variables
1.
2.

Constant
Funds rate less discount rate

76 (4.4)
120 (5.8)

290
290

(7.5)
(6.3)

366
410

(9.4)
(8.7)

Dummy variables representing shifts
3.
4.

Summer 1984
1986 to present

-45 (-1.0)
-39 (-2.5)

-369 (-3.7)
-221 (-6.4)

-414 (-4.1)
-260 (-7.4)

Summary regression statistics
5.
6.

R²(adjusted)
Standard error of estimate

.31
72

.53
161

.64
163

107 (10.6)
80 (6.8)

277 (7.4)
292 (6.7)

384 (10.5)
373
(8.7)

With Seasonal Variables
7.
8.

Constant
Funds rate less discount rate

Dummy variables representing shifts
9.
10.

Summer 1984
1986 to present

-47 ( 1.7)
-41 (-4.3)

-297
-207

(-2.9)
(-5.9)

-344
-248

(-3.4)
(-7.3)

Summary regression statistics
11.
12.

R²(adjusted)
Standard error of estimate

13.

Bi-weekly seasonal variables
-123*
-99*
-66*
-77*
-51*
-60*
-44*
-42*
-19
-15
15
31
35
60*
45*
80*
81*
87*
60*
69*
50*
46
27
-11
-27
-53*
14.

Joint test of seasonality

Significant
at 1% level

165
-185*
65
-112
39
-38
2
87
143
124
64
47
-40
27
-89
-36
-94
-93
-103
-88
-34
-52
139
46
67
-52
Not
Significant

42
-283*
-1
-189*
-12
-98
-43
45
125
109
79
79
-5
87
-44
44
-13
-6
-43
-20
16
-5
167
35
40
-105
Not
Significant

*--Significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level.
1. Uses instrumental variables in a two-stage least squares procedure. Fitted over maintenance periods
between February 15, 1984 and October 7, 1987. T-values are in parentheses.

B-2
first maintenance period of the year, averaging $123 million.

Though the shortfall diminishes, lower-than-average

seasonal borrowing continues to be statistically significant
through the eighth maintenance period.

The buildup in

seasonal impacts is evident through the summer, with a peak
seasonal boost to seasonal borrowing estimated at $87 million in the 18th maintenance period of the year.

Taken

together, the seasonal dummy variables are highly statistically significant, as indicated in line 14.
By contrast, though not surprisingly, seasonal effects
are not significant in the estimated relation of adjustment
borrowing to the spread (column 2).

The standard errors

(comparing lines 6 and 12) and the adjusted R²s (lines 5
and 11) improve by only small amounts with the addition of
seasonal dummies.
The central issue of seasonality in the relation of
adjustment plus seasonal borrowing to the spread is
addressed in the third column.

Apart from factors for

two maintenance periods, the individual seasonal effects are
not statistically significant, and jointly (row 14) they are
not at all significant.

The standard error of estimate is

lowered and the adjusted R2 raised only by relatively small
amounts when seasonal dummy variables are added to the estimated equation.

These results suggest the absence of a

stable seasonal pattern in the relation of adjustment plus
seasonal borrowing to the spread.

In addition, without

B-3

accounting for seasonality, the standard errors of estimate
in lines 6 for adjustment plus seasonal borrowing together
(column 3) is about the same size as for adjustment borrowing alone (column 2), while the adjusted R2 (line 5) is
improved by including seasonal with adjustment borrowing.
These results suggest there is little to gain in terms of
the predictability of the borrowing relationship from attempting to account for seasonality, whether adjustment
borrowing is taken by itself or considered together with
seasonal borrowing.
Supplemental evidence for this conclusion is provided
in table B2.

The first column simply repeats the third

column of the previous table, in which seasonal factors for
the adjustment plus seasonal borrowing function are
estimated freely by the regression.

Column 2 takes the

seasonal factors estimated for seasonal borrowing alone in
column 1 of table B1 and forces them into the equation for
adjustment plus seasonal borrowing.

The fit deteriorates

despite the fact that, unlike the first column, 26 degrees
of freedom are no longer being used up in estimation of
seasonal influences in the regression.

In effect, this

column shows that seasonally adjusting the sum of adjustment
and seasonal borrowing with seasonal factors derived from
the seasonal borrowing function alone results in a slight
degradation in quality of fit compared with using the
regression equation in column 1 with freely estimated (but

Table B2
Adjustment Plus Seasonal Borrowing Functions with Alternative Seasonal Variables¹
(Adjustment Plus Seasonal Borrowing is the Dependent Variable)
(Millions of dollars; early 1984 to present)
(2)
(1)
Seasonal variables estimated in the:
Seasonal
Adj. + seas.
borrowing
borrowing²
function
function
Constant
Funds rate less discount rate

384 (10.5)
373 (8.7)

397 (10.5)
370 (8.1)

-344 (-3.4)
-248 (-7.3)

-415 (-4.2)
-262 (-7.7)

Dummy variables representing shifts

Summer 1984
1986 to present
Summary regression statistics
2
R (adjusted)
Standard error of estimate
Bi-weekly seasonal variables
1

42

-123

2

-283*

-99

3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26

-1
-189*
-12
-98
-43
45
125
109
79
79
-5
87
-44
44
-13
-6
-43
-20
16
-5
167
35
40
-105

-66
-77
-51
-60
-44
-42
-19
-15
15
31
35
60
45
80
81
87
60
69
50
46
27
-11
-27
-53

*-Significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level.
1. Uses instrumental variables in a two-stage least squares procedure. Fitted over maintenance periods between
February 15, 1984 and October 7, 1987. T-values are in parentheses.
2. The seasonal dummy variables were estimated in the seasonal borrowing equation of column 1 of table B1 and
forced into the adjustment plus seasonal borrowing equation shown here.

B-4
jointly insignificant) seasonal factors.

Moreover, compar-

ing the results in column 2 of table B2 with the upper panel
of column 3 in table B1, in which seasonality in adjustment
plus seasonal borrowing is not accounted for, suggests that
only a negligible improvement in goodness of fit emerges
from attempting to take seasonality into account in this
way.
Table B3 presents results of regression equations with
the spread of the funds rate over the discount rate as the
dependent variable.

In the top panel, the spread is related

without regard to seasonal influences either to adjustment
borrowing alone or to adjustment and seasonal borrowing
together.²

This test is designed to contrast the predict-

ability of the funds rate under current procedures (column
2) with that under a procedure expressing the FOMC's intended borrowing level in terms of adjustment borrowing by
itself (column 1).

The results in the top panel in fact

indicate a slightly, though not significantly, closer relationship between the spread and adjustment plus seasonal
borrowing together than for adjustment borrowing alone,
judging by summary statistics for goodness of fit in lines 5
and 6.
These similar results in the top panel are not surprising given the lack of seasonality in the relation of the

2.
To isolate effects on the funds rate of alternative
ways of accounting for current seasonality in borrowing
quantities, ordinary least squares rather than two-stage
least squares are employed in this table.

Table B3
Estimates of Borrowings Functions With and Without Seasonal Variables
(The Spread of the Funds Rate Over the Discount Rate is the Dependent Variable)
(Percentage points; early 1984 to present)
Adjustment
borrowing
(1)
Without
1.
2a.
2b.

Seasonal Variables
Constant
2
Adjustment borrowing
Adjustment plus seasonal borrowing

Adjustment plus
seasonal borrowing
(2)

-.25 (-2.4)

²-.02 (-.2)
.14 (7.9)

.14

(9.4)

Dummy variables representing shifts
3.
4.

Summer 1984
1986 to present

1.54 (11.2)
.36 (4.4)

1.31 (9.9)
.41 (5.3)

Summary regression statistics
5.
6.

R (adjusted)
Standard error of estimate

.70
.35
(la)
Seasonal
dummies

.75
.32
(2a)
Seasonal
dummies

(2b)
Seasonally
adjusted

With Seasonal Variables
7. Constant
2
8a. Adjustment borrowing
2
8b. Adjustment plus seasonal borrowing

-.08 (-.7)
.15 (6.9)

-. 36 (-2.9)
.16

(8.7)

-. 27 (-2.6)
.14

(9.8)

Dummy variables representing shifts
9.
10.

Summer 1984
1986 to present

1.44
.36

(8.4)
(4.0)

1.27 (8.1)
.43 (5.1)

Summary regression statistics
11.
12.

R²(adjusted)
Standard error of estimate

13.

Bi-weekly seasonal variables

14.

Joint test of seasonality

Footnotes on next page.

.66
.38

.06
.30
-.25
.17
-.08
.08
.05
-.07
-.29
-.06
-.07
.02
-.05
-.11
.09
.00
.15
.17
.16
.08
.23
.05
-.24
-.13
-.16
-.09

.16
.47*
-.11
.30
.00
.17
.10
-.03
-.25
-.08
-.11
-.06
-.07
-.19
.04
-.11
.02
.03
.07
-.01
.11
-.02
-.28
-.10
-.11
.04

Not
significant

Not
sinificant

1.40 (11.0)
.42 (5.5)

*--Significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level.
1. Uses an ordinary least squares procedure. Fitted over maintenance periods between February 15, 1984 and
October 7, 1987. T-values are in parentheses.
2. Coefficients represent the rise in the funds rate in percentage points associated with a rise in borrowing
of $100 million.
3. Adjustment plus seasonal borrowings were seasonally adjusted by subtracting from this sum the seasonal
dummy variables estimated for seasonal borrowing alone that are reported in column 1 of table Bl.

B-5

spread to either adjustment or adjustment plus seasonal
borrowing, as indicated in columns la and 2a in the lower
panel.

In these columns, seasonal influences on the in-

verted borrowing functions are represented directly as dummy
variables.

They are designed to pick up any seasonal move-

ments in the spread that arose from the actual outcomes
generated as the Desk sought to attain the FOMC's intention
for adjustment plus seasonal borrowing without considering
seasonality.
The regression results shown in column 2a indicate that
a statistically significant seasonal influence on the spread
given adjustment plus seasonal borrowing is apparent in only
one maintenance period during the year, while the joint test
for seasonality rejects the presence of seasonal influences
on the spread over the year as a whole.

Reflecting the lack

of significant seasonality, the inclusion of seasonal
dummies has an adverse effect on the goodness of fit, with
the standard error of the estimate and the adjusted R² (rows
11 and 12) being worse than those reported in the top panel
for column 2 (rows 5 and 6).

For column la, no significant

seasonality in the relation of the spread to adjustment
borrowing alone is indicated for the maintenance periods
either individually or jointly.
The lower-panel results in column 2b are designed to
test whether adjustments to the FOMC's basic intention for
borrowing to take account of estimated seasonal influences

B-6
would produce a more predictable funds rate than current
procedures as represented by column 2 in the top panel.
Column 2b in the lower panel represents an alternative
method for taking seasonality into account in the inverted
function for adjustment plus seasonal borrowing.

This

column seasonally adjusts the sum of adjustment and seasonal
borrowing by subtracting from this sum the seasonal factors
estimated for seasonal borrowing alone that are shown in
column 1 of table Bl.³ These results are intended to
represent the predictability of the funds rate if the intended borrowing target were adjusted period-to-period for
the estimated influence of seasonality in seasonal borrowings.
This alternative approach of adjusting borrowings for
estimated seasonal influences does little to improve the
predictability of the funds rate spread shown in column 2 in
the top panel, which ignores seasonality.

Neither the stan-

dard error of estimate nor the adjusted R2 is much affected
by adjusting the sum of adjustment plus seasonal borrowings
for estimated seasonal influences.

Overall, then, these

3. This regression procedure is analogous to that employed
in column 2 of table B2 in the sense that the seasonal
dummies in that regression were forced to take on the values
of seasonal dummies estimated in the seasonal borrowing
equation.
4.
It might be noted that using seasonal factors estimated
over the entire period of fit for seasonal borrowing
provides more information in the exercise than in fact would
have been available to the Desk in operations going through
this period, and hence biases the results in favor of this
alternative procedure.

B-7

regressions show little evidence of seasonal influences on
the spread given the level of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing.