View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS

Date:

December 7, 2004

To:

Federal Open Market Committee

From:

Flint Brayton and Dave Reifschneider

Subject:

Revised Bluebook Estimates of the Equilibrium Real Rate -

Overview

Strictly Confidential (FR)
Class II- FOMC
Introduction
For some time, estimates of the equilibrium real interest rate (R*) have
regularly appeared in the Bluebook and in other FOMC-related material. Unfortunately,
a recent survey of Bluebook readers and informal conversations suggest that the
usefulness of these measures to the Committee has been impaired by two factors: (1) the
lack of clarity and uniformity in the concept of R*; and the incomplete characterization
of the uncertainty associated with estimates. In response, the staff has greatly revised the
computation and the presentation of R* estimates for the December Bluebook.
In the new presentation, all estimates are derived as answers to one of two
specific forecasting questions. The first question is short-run in nature and relates to the
stimulus required from monetary policy to close the output gap in twelve quarters. The
second question is longer-run in nature, and concerns the projected level of the real funds
rate consistent with output at potential seven years in the future, long enough for all
transitory factors currently buffeting the economy to have faded away.
As part of this overhaul, the staff has also reviewed and modified the
forecasting models used to estimate R*. The revised presentation features estimates
derived from three models -

a simple equation for the output gap, a small economic

model, and the large-scale FRB/US model. It also incorporates estimates of R* derived

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

-2from financial data as well as measures that are consistent with the staffGreenbook
projection. Although we regard the value of R* implicit in the Greenbook projection as
the best available measure, the estimates derived from the three econometric models and
the bond market are useful benchmarks against which to compare the staff estimate. We
also use the three models to generate confidence intervals for R* that account for
different sources of uncertainty, including model specification, equation coefficients, and
errors in the real-time measurement of potential output.
The rest of this memo is organized as follows. In the next section, we discuss
two different concepts of R* and consider how these concepts can be used in monetary
policymaking. We then turn to the limitations of R*, and explain why the equilibrium
real rate by itself is not an adequate guide for setting the real funds rate. After briefly

discussing the models and procedures used to estimate R*, we finish with an overview of
the new R* exhibit that will appear in the December Bluebook. An accompanying
memo, "Revised Bluebook Estimates of the Equilibrium Real Rate - Technical
Documentation," provides background information about our estimation procedures and
results.

Defining R*

Economists use the terms "equilibrium" and "natural" real rate of interest in
various ways, depending on the issue under discussion. The Board staff, in discussions
related to monetary policy decisionmaking, has tended to define R* as "the real funds
rate at which the output gap would gradually return to zero, barring further disturbances

to aggregate demand and supply." Published papers in this field typically use similar
definitions.'
¹ The quote is taken from Thomas Laubach and John Williams, "Estimates of a Time-Varying Equilibrium
Real Federal Funds Rate," memorandum to Members of the Board (December 14, 2000). Examples of
recent papers by Federal Reserve System economists that define R* in a similar manner include: Antulio
Bomfim (1997), "The Equilibrium Fed funds Rate and the Indicator Properties of Term Structure Spreads,"
Economic Inquiry, 35 (4), 830-46; Thomas Laubach and John C. Williams (2003),"Measuring the Natural
Rate of Interest," Review ofEconomic and Statistics, 85 (4), 1063-1070; and Todd Clark and Sharon
Kozicki (2004), "Estimating Equilibrium Real Interest Rates in Real Time," Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City Research Working Paper 04-08. There is also a considerable body of published work, carried
out by economists within the System and elsewhere, that deals with the related issue of how estimates of R*
should be used in monetary policymaking; see, for example, Athanasios Orphanides and John C. Williams,

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

-3This definition addresses a key question facing policymakers: What level of
the real funds rate is consistent with full resource utilization? But left vague is a critical
dimension of the problem - the time required for the output gap to close. Although the
standard practice is to say that full resource utilization is achieved in the "medium term,"
whether this state should be considered as something likely to occur two, five, or ten
years into the future is not clear. To be more precise about the time dimension of R*, we
believe it is necessary to settle on one or more specific questions that define R* as the
answer.
Of course, many questions can be asked about the relationship between the
stance of monetary policy and economic slack. But one of the most basic questions is
whether the current funds rate is consistent with making significant progress in the near
term toward restoring a normal degree of resource utilization in labor and product
markets. We therefore define the following short-run concept ofR*: the value of the
real funds rate that, if sustained, would be projected to close the output gap twelve
quarters in the future. This concept, which we denote as R*SR, has the advantage of
being the answer to a well-defined forecasting problem that can be addressed with a
variety of economic models.
Some may object that this definition is insufficiently short-run in nature and
that R*SR would be better defined as the real rate projected to close the output gap within
eight or even four quarters. However, the lags in the monetary transmission mechanism
are sufficiently long that closing the output gap within two years would occasionally
entail extremely large fluctuations in the funds rate, and closing the output gap within
one year might at times be impossible without wildly unrealistic movements in the funds
rate. Given these constraints, defining R*sR using a three-year window seems consistent
with the goal of determining the setting of the funds rate that would make substantial
near-term progress in achieving full employment.
"Robust Monetary Policy Rules With Unknown Natural Rates," Brookings Paperson Economic Activity, 2,
63-145. Finally, there is a somewhat different concept of R* that is in common use in academic circles specifically, the real rate of interest consistent with instantaneous market clearing in the absence of wage
and price frictions. Estimates of this concept - which has been discussed in papers by Michael Woodford
among others - can be derived in a straightforward manner only in the context of macroeconomic models
with strict micro-theoretic foundations.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

-4Not all monetary policy questions concerning R* are so oriented toward
conditions over the near term. For example, policymakers may be interested in
comparing the current stance of monetary policy to that prescribed by the Taylor rule.
Such a comparison requires an estimate of the intercept in the Taylor rule, which
conceptually equals the value of the real funds rate consistent with output at potential and
inflation at its target once all transitory influences on aggregate demand and supply have
passed. To address these sorts of questions, we therefore propose the following mediumrun concept ofR*: the value of the realfunds rate projected to prevail in seven years
under the assumption that monetary policy will act to eliminate economic slack in
three years and to hold output at potential thereafter. This concept, which we denote
by R*MR, is similar to R*SR in that it answers a well-defined forecasting problem.
As might be expected, both measures of the equilibrium real rate are strongly
influenced by fundamental factors such as fiscal policy and trend productivity growth,
with the difference being that R*SR is more closely tied to the current state of these
factors whereas R*MR depends only on their projected values in the longer run. Another
difference between the two concepts is that the value of R*sR - but not the value of
R*MR - is strongly influenced by the current amount of slack in the economy: Because
the output effects of even transitory shocks take time to dissipate and because monetary
policy works only with a substantial lag, a large starting output gap requires a low real
funds if the gap is to be closed in twelve quarters.²
In principle, one could compute an equilibrium real rate based on an even
longer view than that used to define R*MR. Such a measure might equal the expected
level of the real funds rate once the economy reaches a steady state in which all markets
clear, all flow variables (output, spending, and the factors of production) expand along
their long-run growth paths, and all stocks are stable as ratios to an appropriate scale
variable, such as GDP. However, such a concept would not be of much practical help in
2 A link

exists as well between the Taylor rule and R*sR, although the connection is less clear than the link

to R*MR. The Taylor rule can be written as R = R*MR + a xgap + 3 pgap, where R is the real funds rate,
xgap is the output gap, and pgap is the difference between the actual and target rates of inflation. Given the
dependence of the short-run equilibrium funds rate on the initial level of the output gap, the sum of the first
two terms in the Taylor rule, R*MR + a xgap, is likely to be highly correlated with R*SR as long as the value
of the coefficient a in the rule is set to yield closure of the output gap within twelve quarters on average.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018
-5monetary policymaking: Achievement of full stock equilibrium can take decades,
especially if underlying investment and borrowing flows are not projected to stabilize in

the near future, as is now the case for the deficits in both the federal budget and the
current account. For this reason, we focus only on estimates of R*sR and R*-mr-3
The two proposed concepts of R* are inherently real-time in nature: Today's
estimates obviously do not and cannot incorporate information unavailable today.
Therefore, if we wish to study how R* has changed over time, or to compare its historical
path to the real funds rate path actually chosen by policymakers, past estimates of R*
should be computed on a comparable basis - that is, with only the information that was
available at a given point in the past. As a practical matter, such real-time estimates are
usually impossible to obtain in full because of the lack of comprehensive real-time
datasets. The closest feasible approximation to the real-time forecasting problem is to
compute the value of, say, R*sR in 1990:Q1 using data through 1989:Q4 as currently
published. We take this approach in producing the revised model-based estimates of the
equilibrium real rate.
Limitations of R* for monetary policymaking
Estimates of R* are not intended to be complete prescriptions for setting the
funds rate; rather, they are among the set of indicators that might be considered by the
Committee in deciding how best to meet the dual objectives of price stability and full
employment. An obvious limitation of R* is its exclusive real-side orientation: Most
importantly, although setting the real funds rate equal to the short-run or even the
medium-run estimate of the equilibrium real rate would be expected to ensure full
resource utilization eventually, such R* policies would not necessarily achieve the
Committee's inflation objectives. Instead, such policies would allow the inflation rate to
3 The estimates of R* previously published in the Bluebook did not conform to the short-run concept of R*
because they were designed to exclude the effects of transitory factors likely to influence aggregate
spending over the next few years. However, the old estimates did not conform to R*mr, either, even though
they were intended to be medium-term in nature. In the case of the statistical filter estimate, the poor
correspondence resulted from a model misspecification that caused the variability of the medium-run value
of R* to be overstated, effectively making it a short-run measure. In the case of the FRB/US estimate, the
problem was that it was not computed using medium-term projections of fiscal policy, trend growth, and
capital stocks, but instead was estimated using the current values of these slow-moving variables.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

-6drift over time because they would make no provision for offsetting the inflation effects
of shocks to aggregate demand and supply. At a minimum, price stability requires a
policy that raises the real funds rate above R* when inflation is undesirably high and
does the opposite when inflation is too low.
A second limitation is that the estimates of R*SR and R*MR only crudely
approximate a trajectory for the real funds rate that policymakers might find desirable,
even in the absence of inflation concerns. For example, on our assessment real activity is
presently being restrained by transitory factors that appear to be dissipating only
gradually. In response to that situation, the Committee might prefer to have the real
funds rate climb for some time and then settle down at some longer-term sustainable rate.
But rather than fully outlining this path, R*SR at best measures only the average value-of
the desired real rate over the first twelve quarters, and R*MR describes only its endpoint.
Another factor that limits the usefulness of R* is the uncertainty associated
with estimates of its value. Some of this imprecision reflects our ignorance about the true
nature of the economy - that is, our ignorance about both the specification and the
coefficients of our models of real activity. Such uncertainty is especially germane for
monetary policy, because it concerns not only the level of aggregate spending that is
consistent with a given level of interest rates (additive uncertainty) but also the shift in
aggregate spending generated by a given change in the funds rate (slope uncertainty). R*
uncertainty also arises because of errors in the measurement of potential output,
especially on a contemporaneous basis: Although we can infer with some accuracy what
the level of potential output was, say, five years ago by taking account of the subsequent
behavior of inflation and other factors, we have more difficulty gauging how much
economic slack exists currently and thus judging what size of a change in the funds rate
is needed to close the output gap. Finally, because we do not know what future
disturbances will hit the economy, we can never be sure in advance what setting of the
real funds rate will, after the fact, prove to have been consistent with full resource
utilization.
Overall, in no sense can setting the real funds rate equal to R* be interpreted
as "optimal." As already noted, such policies ignore inflation and are generally too

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

-7simple to describe the full trajectory for the real funds rate that would be needed to
stabilize output. They also might at times deliver a speed of closure of the output gap
that Committee members would find unacceptably slow. Finally, R* policies take no
account of any other considerations, such as uncertainty, that may be germane to setting
policy. In short, such policies do not substitute for a comprehensive strategy that
balances the Committee's objectives and that takes into account all relevant factors.4

Three forecasting models
After reviewing the forecasting models used to compute the estimates of R*
that have appeared in previous Bluebooks, we have modified the specifications of the
pair that had been used and added a third model to the group. We believe that, although
this expanded group by no means includes all the models that could be used to estimate
R*, it yields estimates of uncertainty likely to provide a realistic sense of the range of
uncertainty that might be estimated from a larger set of models. We leave open the
possibility of expanding or altering our set of forecasting models at some future date.
Single-equation model. This model consists of an equation in which the
output gap depends only on a constant term and lagged values of the output gap and the
real funds rate. This equation is similar in spirit to the statistical filter that has heretofore
been employed to derive one set of estimates of R* for the Bluebook, in that both rely on
a simple characterization of the relationship between output and the real funds rate. But
the two approaches differ in the details of this characterization. One difference is that the
new equation includes additional lags of the output gap and the real funds rate. Not only
are these lags statistically significant, but they also affect the fundamental nature of the
model's long-run value of the equilibrium real rate. In the statistical filter, the
4 An R*SR policy would also create a type oftime-inconsistency problem. By definition, setting the real
funds rate at R*sR and holding it there would be predicted to close the output gap in twelve quarters, barring

any further economic disturbance. In the next quarter, the same setting for the real funds rate would be
expected to close the output gap in eleven quarters, assuming no new shocks to the economy. But if at that
point one recalculated R*sR according to the definition laid out in the text, one would ordinarily obtain a
different estimate because the new calculation would show the value of the real funds rate needed to close
the output gap in the standard twelve quarters. Thus, under an R*sR policy, one would choose to change the
stance of monetary policy even though economic conditions had unfolded exactly as expected because the
effective planning period had advanced one period. A side effect of such an ever-advancing endpoint is
that the elimination of economic slack might take appreciably longer than three years.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018
-8relationship between the output gap and the real funds rate is subject to both transitory
and permanent shocks. However, the estimated variance of permanent shocks falls to
zero with the added lags in the new output gap equation, indicating that all shocks are
transitory and that the long-run value of R* is a constant (estimated to be about 2-1/4
percent).
Small model. This five-equation model permits R* to be affected by changes
in trend GDP growth, fiscal policy, and stock prices. In the model's key equation, the
output gap responds gradually to movements in the real bond rate, trend GDP growth, the
ratio of the high-employment federal budget surplus to potential output, and the equity
premium. The structure of the equation implies that in the long run R* moves one-for-one
with changes in the trend rate of GDP growth; a sustained increase of one percentage
point in the ratio of the federal surplus to GDP reduces long-run R* about 30 basis
points, and an increase of one percentage point in the equity premium boosts R*LR about
¾ percentage point. Each of these economic determinants of R* is modeled with a
simple time-series equation. A final equation specifies that the real bond rate depends on
the real federal funds rate, the expected value of the real funds rate seven years into the
future (that is, R*MR), and the lagged output gap.
FRB/US. FRB/US is the staff's large-scale model of the U.S. economy. The
estimates of R* from FRB/US reported in previous Bluebooks were based on a special
flow-equilibrium version of the model that is ill-suited for calculating the new short-run
concept of R*. The standard version of FRB/US reported in the Greenbook and Bluebook -

the one routinely used in simulations

is more easily applied to this task. Estimates

of the equilibrium real rate using FRB/US depend on a broad array of economic factors,
some of which take the form of projected values of the model's exogenous variables.
These projections are based on several simple forecasting rules that are appropriate for
the three-year period relevant for R*SR but are less sensible at longer horizons. Thus, we
do not compute R*MR with FRB/US.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

-9Greenbook-consistent estimates of R*
If the Greenbook projection were derived from an explicit economic model,
that model could also be used to generate estimates of R*. Although such a formal
"staff' model does not exist, we are able to derive estimates ofR* that incorporate most
of the information in the Greenbook by using the FRB/US model in place of the unknown
staff model. Specifically, we first produce an FRB/US baseline that exactly matches the
Greenbook forecast and then run a simulation in which the model's multiplier properties
are used to determine the value of the real funds rate that satisfies the short-run definition
of R*. 5 To construct a consistent set of historical values of R*sR associated with past
Greenbooks, we employ not the current version of FRB/US but rather the version in use
at the time. Thus, our historical Greenbook-consistent estimates of R* are the same as
those that would have been calculated at the time the original Greenbook forecast was
published and so are "real-time" in nature.
The revised Bluebook exhibit
Associated with the new procedures for estimating the equilibrium real rate is
a revised presentation of this information in the Bluebook, shown here as chart 1. The
chart has two parts. The upper panel is a figure that plots current and historical estimates
of the short-run concept of R*; the bottom panel is a table summarizing the latest
estimates of both the short- and medium-run concepts of R* for the current quarter only.
Except for changes arising from revisions before the close of the forecast, the chart is the
same as the one that will appear in the December Bluebook.
As noted earlier, some notion of the degree of uncertainty associated with the
various measures of R* is a prerequisite for these estimates to be useful to policymakers.
Information of this type is represented in the upper panel by three shaded "confidence"
bands, which have been derived using the econometric models. The simplest source of
uncertainty is the availability of more than one model with which to estimate R*. The
5 Because

the Greenbook forecast extends only two and a half years (at most) into the future, we are unable
to compute Greenbook-consistent estimates of R*MR. Also, because the Greenbook forecast period is
always less than twelve quarters, we must modify our R*SR estimation procedures somewhat; see the
accompanying technical memo for details.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018

-10magnitude of this type of uncertainty, shown by the inner red band, is approximated by

the range spanned by the set of point estimates of short-run R* from the three models. In
the current quarter, this range runs from 1.9 to 2.6 percent and is 0.7 percentage point
wide. The width of the inner band has averaged 1-1/4 percentage points since 1990 but
has varied considerably over time.
A more complete characterization of uncertainty about R* takes account of
the degree to which each model's estimate of short-run R* is itself imprecise. Two
primary sources for this imprecision are uncertainties associated with the estimation of
each model's coefficients and those associated with the measurement of potential output.
The combined effect of these two sources of uncertainty, together with the uncertainty of
not knowing which of the three models is correct, provides a broad-based measure of R*
uncertainty. The magnitude of this type of uncertainty is summarized by the two blue
bands in the figure: As constructed, the short-run value of R* has a probability of 70
percent of being within the dark-blue band, and a 90 percent probability of being within
the light-blue bank. For the current quarter, the 70 percent confidence band extends from
0.7 percent to 3.6 percent, while the 90 percent band ranges from -0.1 percent to 4.4
percent. Over history, the width of these two bands has on average been about 3
percentage points and 4-3/4 percentage points, respectively.
As noted earlier, the fact that the economy is subject to unpredictable shocks
is another source of uncertainty: Even a "good" estimate of R* is likely with hindsight to
be wrong because shocks to aggregate demand and supply that could not have been
anticipated will occur after the estimate is made. However, in revising the Bluebook
exhibit we have elected to focus only on uncertainty associated with predictions of R*,
not uncertainty about what R* will actually turn out to have been in hindsight.
Accordingly, all the uncertainty estimates presented in the new exhibit exclude the
effects of future shocks to the economy. But an argument can be made that the latter
source of uncertainty is also pertinent to monetary policy, and so should be incorporated
into the confidence bands. If we did so, the bands would widen considerably; for
example, the 70 percent confidence interval would almost double.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018
-11-

Another perspective on the current and expected stance of policy is provided
by the Greenbook-consistent estimate of short-run R* (dotted black line). The current
estimate is 1.5 percent, a value that is somewhat below the midpoint of the confidence
intervals. Thus, the Greenbook projection is that, for a given level of the real funds rate,
output will be tend to be weaker relative to potential than it is in the models' forecasts.
However, the fact that the Greenbook-consistent estimate is within the 70 percent range
suggests that the difference is not terribly significant. Moreover, over the past several
years the Greenbook seems to have been more accurate at describing the relationship
between output and interest rates than the three econometric models. Support for this
conclusion seems strongest for the Greenbook-consistent estimates from late 2001, for
which the twelve-quarter forecasting period associated with short-run R* is now
observed. The Greenbook-consistent estimate of short-run R* associated with the
December 2001 projection was 1/2 percent, a value at the lower end of the 70 percent
model-based range at the time. With hindsight, the value of short-run R* for this date
was likely less than the average value of the actual real funds rate from the fourth quarter
of 2001 to the third quarter of 2004 (-1/4 percent), given that the staff currently estimates
that output remains below potential.
Current estimates of the medium-run concept of R* are reported in the table
for two of the forecasting models, together with an estimate derived from the indexed
securities market. The model-based estimates average about 2-1/2 percent and in both
cases are higher than the corresponding short-run estimate of R*. In large part, this
pattern reflects the current economic slack: With output below potential, short-run R* is
held down by the need for extra stimulus from interest rates to boost output to potential in
the twelve-quarter planning interval. By definition, this factor is absent in the mediumrun estimates. The 70 percent confidence bands for the medium-run estimates of R* which are defined to exclude the effects of future economic shocks - range from 1-1/2
to 3-1/4 percent. This range encompasses the market-based estimate of R*M, which
currently stands at only 1-3/4 percent.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 05/25/2018
Chart 1
Equ ilibrium Real Federal Funds Rate
Short-Run Estimates with Confidence Bands
-

Percent

Actual real federal funds rate
Range of model-based estimates
70% confidence band
90% confidence band
Greenbook-consistent measure

-

8
7
6

5

4
3

2

25 b.p. Tightening
Cu rrent Rate

0

·1

Notes: The real federal funds rate is constructed as the difference between the quarterly average of the actual nominal funds
rate and the log difference e of the core PCE price Index over the previous four quarters. For the current quarte r, the nominal
funds rate used IS the target federal funds rate as of the close of the Bluebook.

Short-Run and Medium-Run Measures for 2004:04
Current Estimate

Previous Bluebook

Short-Run Measures
Greenbook-consistent measure
FABIUS model
Small structural model
Single-equation model
Confidence Interva ls for three model-based estimates
70% confidence interval
90% confidence interval

1.5
2.1
2.6
1.9

1. 1
1.8

2.6
1.9

o.7 - 3.6
-0.1 - 4.4

Medium-Run Measu res
TIPS-consistent measure
Small structural model
Single-equation model
Confidence intervals for two model-based estimates
70% confidence interval
90% confidence Interval

1.8
2.7

2.7

2.2

2.2

1.8

1.6 - 3.2
0.9 • 3.7

Notes: The figures In the "Previous Bluebook" column indicate the esti mates for the current quarter as of the previous
Bluebook that would have been reported using the new procedures. Confidence intervals and bands reflect uncerta inties
about model specification, coefficients, and the level of potential output.