View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
December 13, 1988
Sam Y. Cross
Negative sentiment towards the dollar was intense
during most of the intermeeting period.

Last week, however, the

dollar recovered partially from its lows of late November and its
The

decline for the period was pared back to about 2 percent.

Desk intervened in substantial amounts during the period, with
all operations split equally between the Federal Reserve and the
Treasury.
Selling pressures against the dollar broke through
around the beginning of November.

Although questions about U.S.

economic policies existed before that, and there were widespread
concerns that the international adjustment process was slowing
down, the markets generally believed that the U.S. authorities
would defend the dollar through the election so that market
pressures would not emerge as an issue in the Presidential
campaign.

As election day approached, however, the foreign

exchange markets began to test the dollar and by the time of your
last meeting on November 1, we had already started to intervene
to support the dollar.

Immediately after the election, dollar

selling intensified, much of it apparently speculative.

Market

participants were questioning whether adjustment was still
proceeding, and feared that the new Administration might not be
able to deal promptly and effectively with the twin deficit
problems, in the environment of a Congress controlled more
strongly than before by the opposition party.

From our first operations on October 31 through the
first two weeks of November, we intervened on 5 occasions to buy
about $1 billion, all against Japanese yen.

The market was aware

of our operations but not greatly impressed, with many believing
them aimed more at smoothing the dollar's decline so as to
prevent adverse effects on other financial markets rather than
reflecting a determination to halt the dollar's fall.

Despite

official statements to the contrary, market participants thought
that there may have been a shift in the U.S. view towards the
exchange rate.

For several months, some market observers had

suspected that any incoming Administration might tolerate or even
welcome a lower dollar, and took every opportunity to interpret
any actions or comments -- such as Martin Feldstein's statement
-- in that light.

The dollar continued to come under selling pressure
during much of the rest of November.

On November 17 and 18,

there was concerted intervention in both marks and yen that did
seem to give the market the impression, at least for a while,
that the Group of Seven (G-7) remained firmly committed to
maintaining stability in the exchange markets.

Selling pressures

against the dollar abated briefly after these coordinated
operations.

But when pressures reemerged, and we attempted to

counter them through intervention not coordinated with European
central banks, traders again began to express the belief that the
U.S. authorities might tolerate a gradual decline in the dollar.
On November 25, the dollar hit its lows of the intermeeting

period of Y 120.65 against the yen and DM 1.7085 against the
mark.
For the next ten days, in late November and early
December, market sentiment toward the dollar ebbed and flowed,
depending on evidence either that economic growth was moderating
and the Fed might not be ready to change its policy stance (a
conclusion drawn from the Beige Book) or that the economy was
really stronger than generally appreciated (a conclusion drawn
from employment data).

Also the cumulative effect of all the

dollar intervention support during the month was beginning to
leave a more favorable impression.

The sense of central bank

support was strengthened when, after the market saw the strong
labor market statistics and noted that they were not followed by
an immediate discount rate increase, the desk came into the
market visibly and aggressively to resist a renewed drop in the
exchange rate by buying dollars against both marks and yen.

In

addition, the efforts of President-elect Bush to put together a
team of pragmatic advisors, to reconcile differences with members
of Congress, and to attach priority to dealing with the deficit
problem gave some of the more pessimistic market observers reason
to pause.

In these circumstances, the dollar traded tentatively,

though above its lows of the period.
But confidence in the dollar remained uncertain, and
the market was still quite short of dollars when Gorbachev's
speech at the UN briefly tantalized market participants with
dreams of an early and significant cut in U.S. military
expenditures.

What was important about this latest episode was

not that, in the euphoria of the moment, the dollar briefly
rallied to DM 1.7730 or Y 124.25.

It was, rather, that the

market was reminded that speculators shorting the dollar could
get hurt.

Therefore, the period ended with the dollar still

shaky but on a somewhat better footing, bolstered by expectations
of higher interest rates, and with some renewed sense of two-way
risk in the market, a sense which we hope the major central banks
can preserve despite some differences in opinion about near-term
strategies for exchange rates and interest rates.
For the period as a whole, we sold far more yen -$1.77 billion equivalent -- than marks -- $630 million

equivalent.

Yet mark operations seem to have relatively greater

market impact.

The difference may reflect, partly, that the

mark, more than the yen, tends to be the speculative vehicle of
In

choice for foreign exchange market speculators worldwide.

addition, the market appears to hold different attitudes about
the fundamental strengths and prospects of the two currencies.
As for the yen, market participants have long been
impressed by the agility with which Japan has responded to its
currency's appreciation.

Recent economic reports from Japan

support the picture of strong domestic demand and continued
export growth, with market projections showing increases in both
Japan's trade and current account surpluses through 1990.

This

strong performance has continued without a pick-up in inflation,
suggesting to many that the yen should move even higher.

Also,

with so much of the global imbalance reflected directly in the
bilateral trade between the U.S. and Japan, there is a widespread

view that a large share of the total exchange rate adjustment
must come in the dollar/yen relationship.

Thus, the market still

sees a considerable upside potential for the yen over time.
For the mark, the picture was seen differently.
Although the market view of German economic performance has
improved recently, prospects for investment in Germany were less
than encouraging for much of the year, and both long-term and
short-term capital flowed out of mark assets on a large scale.
The Bundesbank is

concerned that the mark appears relatively weak

at a time when Germany has a strong and growing current account
surplus and may feel the need to demonstrate its commitment to
sound economic management when setting its monetary targets for
1989 next Thursday.
Mr. Chairman, I would like to recommend that the
Committee approve the Federal Reserve's share of the Desk's
dollar purchases during the period.

In other operations during

the period the Desk purchased a total of $25.2 million equivalent
of Japanese yen on behalf of the U.S. Treasury to augment
balances.

The Central Bank of the Argentine Republic, on

November 22, drew $79.5 million on a previously existing U.S.
Treasury short-term financing facility and subsequently repaid
$31.8 million on November 23.

The U.S. Treasury's short-term

financing facilities for Brazil and Yugoslavia matured on
November 30.

The Central Bank of Brazil had repaid their $232.5

million drawing on a $250.0 million facility on August 26.
remaining $17.5 million was not drawn.

The

The National Bank of

Yugoslavia had repaid the outstanding balance on its $50.0
million swap facility on September 30.

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
DECEMBER 13 -

PETER D.

14,

1988

STERNLIGHT

Domestic open market operations since the last
Committee meeting have been complicated by an uncertain and
elusive relationship between discount window borrowings and money
market rates, and by several wire system mishaps that led to
spikes in borrowing unrelated to general market pressures.

In

hindsight, the relationship of borrowing and funds rates was
already coming unglued in October or even earlier, but it

seemed

plausible as the new period began to expect things to "return to
normal."

They didn't.

Thus after starting the period with a

planned borrowing gap of $600 million, we found ourselves
continually battling to keep funds from rising appreciably above
the anticipated 8 to 8-1/4 percent range even while borrowing ran
noticeably below its planned level.

In effect, to avoid having

funds persistently trade well above the range envisioned by the
Committee, we provided some additional nonborrowed reserves.
This situation was drawn to the Committee's attention
in a conference call on November 22, and following that call we
used a $400 million path level of borrowing, anticipating-though still with considerable uncertainty--that funds might
range around 8-3/8 percent.

Primarily, this recognized an

apparent shift in the borrowing-Fed funds relationship, but it

was also noted at that call that recent news on the economy had
suggested continuing strength, with overtones of potential

inflationary pressure.

In this context,

a funds rate around

8-3/8 percent was considered acceptable where earlier in the

period this level had been resisted.

Actual funds rates didn't

change all that much--averaging about 8.30 percent in the
November 16 maintenance period and 8.38 in the November 30
period, but the more discerning market participants noticed the
difference.
Following the strong November employment report
released on December 2, market anticipation of System firming
tended to pull the funds rate still higher.

Without a deliberate

Desk change, funds edged up to around 8-1/2 - 8-5/8 percent, with
many market participants imminently expecting a discount rate
move.

Meantime, the Desk sought at least to keep pace with

projected reserve needs, especially when funds rates traded
significantly above the expected.

In this setting, funds have

averaged about 8.57 percent so far in the current reserve period
through yesterday; today, it's been a shade softer -- 8-7/16.
Several separate incidents involving computers and
funds transmission systems played hob with actual borrowing
levels during the period.

In the November 16 period, a problem

at a large midwest bank caused that institution to pile up
massive excess reserves, which it

couldn't work off over the rest

of the period, while some other banks that had expected to

receive funds had to use the discount window.

In response, we

allowed for higher excess reserves while borrowing averaged
higher than it would otherwise -- though still not above the path
level then in use.

In the November 30 period, a large New York

bank had technical problems that caused it to borrow in size on a
Friday, leading the Desk to make some allowance for special
situation borrowing rather than over-provide reserves.

And

finally, early in the current reserve period, a problem at a
Reserve Bank produced a massive one-day reserve deficiency that
forced several money center banks to borrow even though there
were later "as-of" reserve adjustments.

Once again it was deemed

appropriate to treat the special borrowing as more akin to
nonborrowed reserves.
On days free of these special problems, adjustment and
seasonal borrowing during the intermeeting period averaged about
$315 million, while inclusion of the problem days would produce
an average of about $535 million.
Money growth behaved reasonably well in the recent
period.

M2 increased at just under 4 percent in the 2 months

ended in November, somewhat ahead of the slow 2-1/2 percent
September-December pace contemplated at the last meeting, leaving
November M2 modestly below the mid-point of its annual growth
cone.

M3 growth of 5-1/2 percent for the 2 months ended November

tracked close to the indicated 6 percent September-December path,
leaving M3 somewhat over its annual cone mid-point.

M1 barely

grew over the most recent two months--edging up at just over a

1 percent rate, which placed November at a modest 4 percent
growth rate since the fourth quarter last year.
To meet seasonal reserve needs over the intermeeting
period, the Desk bought over $7-1/2 billion of Treasury issues,
making use of the temporarily enlarged leeway.

Market purchases

included $3 billion of bills at the start of the period and
$3.5 billion of Treasury coupon issues in late November, while
about $1.2 billion of bills and notes were purchased from foreign
accounts over the course of the interval.

On most days the Desk

arranged either System or customer repurchase agreements.
Incidentally, so far in 1988, with just a few weeks
remaining, our net outright purchases of Treasury issues come to
a little over $14 billion, including $5 billion in bills and
somewhat over $9 billion in coupon issues.

This year's rise, to

date, is well short of last year's $21 billion portfolio
increase.

Part of the reason for a lesser rise this year can be

traced to changes in foreign currency holdings this year and
last, and the meeting of some reserve needs this year through
extended credit borrowing.
Yields on Treasury issues generally rose during the
intermeeting period, but by widely varying amounts in a range of
about 25 to 95 basis points.

The smaller increases were posted

for longer maturities so that the yield curve flattened and even
inverted slightly.

The major force pushing yields higher was the

market's perception that the economy remains strong, or perhaps
has regained some strength after a summer lull.

Major price

moves came in the wake of the unexpectedly strong employment
reports for October and November.

A softening dollar and rising

oil prices also encouraged higher yields, though these factors
were erratic over the period.
Many market participants assumed that monetary policy
was already beginning to firm up a bit further after holding
steady in September and October, or soon would do so in response
to the inflationary potential implied by the economy's continuing
strength and absorption of available resources.

As the period

began, market observers seemed to expect that funds rates would
soon return to the 8-1/4 percent area prevalent earlier in the
fall.

By late November, most participants were reconciled to a

funds range around 8-3/8 percent, and this gave way in early
December, after another strong employment report, to anticipation
of 8-1/2 or 8-5/8 percent, quite likely to be followed by a
discount rate rise.
The largest rate increases in the Treasury list were in
the 1 to 2-year maturity range, sending 2-year yields somewhat
above the 30-year yield.

The peak in Treasury yields--if one can

so dignify the modest differentials in an essentially flat
curve--now seems to be in the 2 to 10-year range.

It may be

reading too much into the recent rate trends, but one view is
that the modest size of increases at the long end has reflected
market confidence that, while the economy is strong and inflation
a threat, the central bank will take appropriate action to keep
the situation in hand.

There could also be technical factors at

work, such as investor switching from corporate to Treasury bonds
and active stripping of long Treasury issues which reduces
available supplies.
The Treasury raised roughly $37 billion, net, over the
period, divided about evenly between bills and coupon issues.
Coupon issues included $9 billion of new 30-year bonds, the first
in 6 months, offered after the President signed legislation
removing the 4-1/4 percent ceiling on bonds that has long been a
thorn in the side of Treasury debt managers.

The new bonds were

auctioned at 9.10 percent on November 17 and with some net price
gains in the longer end over the latter part of the interval,
they closed to yield a little under 9 percent.

As the period

began the active long bond yielded about 8.72 percent.
Key bill rates rose about 75-90 basis points over the
interval, propelled by anticipations of policy firming, supply
increases, and some actual rise in funds and financing costs.
The latest 3-and 6-month issues were auctioned yesterday at 7.98
and 8.21 percent, respectively, up from 7.37 and 7.48 percent at
the end of October.
Private short-term rates also rose substantially over
the period--by 80-90 basis points or so in the 3-month area and
even more for shorter maturities.

In addition to policy firming

concerns, year-end factors and possibly preparations to fund
upcoming corporate buy-outs may have played a role in the rate
rise.

Banks raised their prime rates 1/2 percentage point to

10-1/2 percent in a widely anticipated move.

In the Federal agency market, FICO sold two issues,
each for $700 million, through competitive syndicate bidding for
the first time.

The yield spreads against Treasury bonds

narrowed despite the gloomy thrift industry outlook as it is
widely assumed that massive Federal help will be forthcoming for
this industry.
The corporate market, especially industrial issues,
remained under somewhat of a cloud in the wake of the RJR-Nabisco
buy-out plans, but light issuance actually permitted some
measures of yield spreads over Treasuries to narrow a bit.

A few

corporate issues have come to market with special features to
protect against downgradings in the event of take-overs.

High-

yield bonds fared relatively well vis-a-vis Treasury issues
despite prospective substantial enlargements to supply.
Meantime, a threat continues to hang over the Drexel
Burnham firm--a major financial market participant.

There should

be news quite soon either of a settlement with the Justice
Department, with admission to some serious charges, or of a
criminal indictment of the firm.

In either case the firm could

face rough going.
Finally, on a housekeeping note, the Desk has begun a
trading relationship with two additional firms in recent days-S.G. Warburg and Wertheim Schroeder.
dealers since last June.
primary dealers.

Both firms had been primary

We now trade with all but 5 of the 46

December 13, 1988
BORROWING BRIEFING
Donald L. Kohn

I have only a little
on this subject.

to add to the memos the FOMC has received

In summary, a substantial decrease in borrowing at the

discount window at given spreads of the funds rate over the discount rate
developed this fall. It was widespread by size of institution, with a
considerable amount accounted for by smaller institutions.
identified any convincing rationale for the shift.
involve a change in the way the window is

We have not

It does not seem to

administered.

As for the be-

havior of borrowing institutions, we have a number of hypotheses,

but

have not been able to confirm empirically any reasons for depository
institutions to draw back from the use of discount window credit when
they did.

The ongoing dimensions of the shift also are not clear; to

date, there have been few signs of reversal.

In the bluebook,

we posit

some increase in the willingness of large banks to come to the window

early next year.

These institutions may be trying to reduce discount

window usage at this time in anticipation of more profitable opportunities later owing to rising money market pressures associated with yearend, financing of large corporate restructurings, or tighter monetary

policy. In this respect, similar behavior was evident right before yearend last year, and was partly reversed in January, though some permanent
shift still remained as an aftermath of the financial turmoil of the
stock market collapse.

-2-

Given the emerging size of the disturbance to the borrowing
relation, open market operations were carried out with some extra flexibility over the intermeeting period, as Mr. Sternlight has already commented.

Initially, the Desk tolerated both some upward pressure on funds

relative to the Committee's expectations, and a shortfall in borrowing
relative to path.

Even after the formal adjustment to path, while

reserve provision has been fully consistent with making-the borrowing
objective a bit more attention than previously has been paid to the
federal funds rate.

This shift in emphasis has reflected both lingering

uncertainties about the new borrowing relation, and concerns about misleading market participants in a period of greater-than-usual speculation
about possible shifts in monetary policy.
The Committee has gone over the arguments for and against using
borrowing as an operating objective on several occasions.

The principal

arguments in favor involve the flexibility in the federal funds rate that
comes from avoiding a narrow focus on this rate in policy implementation.
A borrowing objective allows some limited scope for market forces, including expectations,

to show through, and in the process, may facilitate

needed policy adjustments.

The argument against is that the overnight

rate is the proximate variable through which policy actions affect the
economy,

and adhering to a borrowing target can allow that rate to devi-

ate for a time from the level consistent with the Committee's desired

policy.

Such deviations are all the more likely when the borrowing

function shifts permanently, given that it may take some time to
recognize and compensate for such shifts.

In that regard, the recent experience certainly does not
strengthen the case for a borrowing objective.

Even so, despite the

massive size of the current disturbance to the function, the outcome in
money markets probably did not differ very substantially or for very long
from interest rate levels consistent with the Committee's discussion and
understanding, given the slight firming deliberately sought on the basis
of incoming data.

This result was largely a consequence of the flexibil-

ity exercised by the Desk,

in consultation with the Chairman, the Reserve

Bank President on the call, and the Committee.

Michael J. Prell
December 13, 1988

FOMC

BRIEFING-ECONOMICOUTLOOK

As you know, with the current Greenbook the staff has taken its

first stab at portraying how 1990 might look.
presented isn't very pretty.

The picture we've

We have suggested that, if

it

is the aim

of the Comittee not merely to hold the line on inflation but, rather,
to restore a downward trend by 1990, then it

may be necessary to run the

risk of some financial stress and economic weakness.
There are three key premises behind this conclusion:

First,

that oil and food supply conditions will provide only a little help in
damping overall inflation in the next couple of years; second, that
current levels of resource utilization are not compatible with slowing
wage and price inflation; and third, that additional macropolicy
restraint will be needed to slow

economic growth enough to reduce

utilization rates to disinflationary levels.
As we see it,

the incoming information since the November

meeting is on balance supportive of these assertions.
Starting with the oil market, we believe that OPEC showed a bit
more resolution than might have been expected in reaching its accord on
production limits.

The adroit handling of the Iraq-Iran quota dispute

and the seeming intensification of pressures on the Arab Emirates to
stop their egregious violations lead us to think that OPEC output is
likely to be lower than we had assumed previously.

Consequently, we've

assumed a $2-1/2 per barrel increase in oil import prices over the next

year, from a low $12.50 in the current quarter.

Translating this into

consumer energy prices, we are looking for a 2 percent increase next
year, rather than the 1 percent decline in our last forecast.
On the food price front, we've seen a fairly rapid reversal of
the earlier run-up in fruit and vegetable prices, and meat supplies have
been ample of late.

Over the next year, we're likely to see some

softening of grain and oilseed prices if

harvests are normal, but with

beef supplies falling and labor costs rising, we are projecting consumer
food price inflation of about 3-1/2 percent.
In our projection, these comparatively moderate increases in
food and energy prices prevent a discernible deterioration in overall
price inflation next year.

But the underlying tendency is

perhaps most notably in compensation.

still

there,

This brings me to the second

assertion I mentioned earlier-namely, that the pressures on resources
are excessive.

While the recent evidence on this point is not

absolutely clearcut, we think it
rather markedly in one direction.

suggests that the risks are skewed
Apart from signs of softening in a

few materials markets, the picture--anecdotally and statistically--is
one of stable or rising wage- and price-inflation trends.
On the statistical side, the readings on wages have been
sparse.

The hourly earnings index for production and non-supervisory

workers jumped 0.7 percent in October and then was unchanged in
November; these movements,

on net, left intact the general uptrend in

the year-on-year increases that began in the middle of 1987.

Meanwhile,

recent monthly changes in the consumer and producer price indexes have

not indicated a clear ongoing acceleration or deceleration.

-3Given that there was no sign of a diminution in pressures prior
to the recent drop in the dollar and further increase in resource
utilization, we see no reason to expect that the underlying trend of
inflation will improve in the near term.

Indeed, in putting together

our forecast of wages and prices, we have continued to discount the
predictions of a variety of econometric models,
substantial acceleration.
monetarist models.

which point to a

Perhaps I should say a variety of non-

A monetarist formulation would suggest that

inflation should moderate before long,

in light of the slower money

expansion path we've been on; but, in most cases,

the models also would

look for a weakening in real activity.
This brings me to the third and final premise of the
projection-namely, that, in the absence of

additional policy

restraint, economic activity will be too strong to restore a downtrend
in wage and price increases within the next two years.

Under the

assumptions we've made about legislative action on the 1990 federal

budget, fiscal policy probably will be supplying some of this restraint.
But we still believe an appreciable burden will fall on the Fed, and
we've built into our forecast a rise in short-term interest rates of
about 2 percentage points over the next year to 18 months.

There is no

question that this is considerably more than the markets are
anticipating, and we would expect that it would put a noticeable dent in
stock and bond prices.

Perhaps, though, the policy issue today is not

so much how great a tightening of money market conditions may ultimately
be needed but simply whether any appreciable further rise in
required, given the increase that has already occurred.

rates is

-4-

answer to that question is

Obviously, the staff's

yes, .and we

perceive support for that proposition in the recent economic data.

The

most noteworthy news was contained in the employment reports for October
and November.

The payroll gain of 700,000 and the lower jobless rate

argue for expecting that real GNP growth in the current quarter will
roughly match the 3-1/2 percent drought-adjusted pace of the first nine
months of this year.

With factory jobs increasing another 70,000 last

month, we'll be publishing tomorrow morning a one-half percent increase
in November industrial production; the quarterly-average rise appears
likely to exceed 4 percent.

In manufacturing, the quarterly gain

probably will be around 5-1/2 percent.
At the time the Greenbook was completed, indicators on the
spending side of the ledger were quite skimpy.

We noted that, to that

point, they seemed a bit softer than the production side.

Implicitly,

we were looking for some stronger expenditure data in subsequent
releases.

This morning we received the advance reading on November

retail sales.

Total sales are estimated to have risen 1.1 percent last

month, and the increase for October was revised upward, from 0.9 percent
to 1.6 percent.

These are big numbers, but because we were anticipating

strength, they would cause us to raise the projection of real consumer

spending growth in the fourth quarter only marginally from the 2-1/2
percent rate in the Greenbook.
Indicators of other sectors of demand present a mixed picture.
The housing market has, if
previous forecast.

anything, been firmer than we expected in our

Starts surged in November to a 1.55 million unit

annual rate--the highest since the spring--and sales of new homes have

-5-

remained strong.

With mortgage rates having turned up in the past

month, we're not projecting that the recent strength in demand will be
sustained; however,

we have raised the near-term forecast of residential

investment somewhat.
In contrast, nonresidential fixed investment has appeared
surprisingly weak of late.

Again,

I must emphasize that we are working

here only with October data-and they are extremely volatile ones at
that.

Both shipments of nondefense capital goods and construction put-

in-place were sluggish in

October, and weak car sales indicate softness

in that category of business spending, too.

As a result, we've

projected essentially no change in real business fixed investment for
the quarter as a whole.
Clearly, one of the key factors in our assessment that a
further rise in interest rates is

needed is

the judgment that the

underlying tendencies in capital spending are stronger than the recent
spending data suggest.

To be sure, orders at domestic equipment

manufacturers were weak in the early fall, and construction contracts
are unimpressive.

On the other hand, though, we've seen continued

growth in backlogs,
industries.

as well as rising employment in the machinery

There are still many anecdotal reports of increasing

capital outlays,

and two private surveys of 1989 plans for plant and

equipment spending indicate nominal increases of between 5 and 6
percent.

We therefore expect that equipment outlays will revive in the

next few months, more than offsetting what we anticipate
downward drift in commercial construction.

will be a

The other component of business spending,

inventories, provides no

hint of an emerging overhang that would be a major drag on output
growth.
stocks,

Apart from auto dealers, firms mostly report comfortable
and as with fixed investment,

the chances of a recessionary

miscalculation seem to be minimized by the lack of ebullience in
business expectations.

In the auto sector, there has been some buildup

of stocks in the past couple of months, but a combination of enhanced
incentives and some trimming of assembly schedules should be able to
deal with that fairly quickly.

The slowing in nonfarm output growth

we've projected for the first quarter can be attributed arithmetically
to the anticipated decline in auto production.
In sum, as we see the situation, the rise in interest rates
this year has not been enough to severely depress domestic final demand.
At the same time, we believe that the tradable goods sector is still
benefiting from rising export demand.

The underlying improvement in

real net exports may be obscured in the current quarter by an influx of
cheap imported oil.

However,

the trend should reemerge next year,

accentuated initially by a drop-back in the oil flow.

The recent

depreciation of the dollar should help sustain the gains in trade, and
we've assumed a further moderate nominal depreciation as well-running
about 6 percent per annum.

In fact, it seems to us likely that, if the

trade adjustment is perceived to lag, the downward pressures on the
dollar will intensify-albeit with potentially discomforting
implications for domestic interest rates and inflation.
I have focused my remarks on the near-term outlook.

We did

attempt to lay out the fundamental logic of the projection through 1990

-7-

in the Greenbook, however,

and we shall be discussing that forecast and

the implications of alternative monetary and fiscal policies in the
February chart show.

Given what we've reported previously,

I suppose

that you can already predict the broad outlines of those implications:
in short, all other things equal, a lesser degree of monetary restraint
would produce greater inflation in 1990, while a more forceful effort to
reduce the federal budget deficit could substantially ease the domestic
financial pressures foreseen in the present projection.
attempt to refine and quantify this at the next meeting.

But we shall

E.M. Truman
December 14,

1988

Report on October Trade Data

This morning the Commerce Department issued its
on U.S.

For October, on a seasonally adjusted customs

trade data.

valuation basis --

latest release

that is,

excluding the cost of insurance and freight--

the trade deficit narrowed slightly to a preliminary level of $8.9
billion, from a upward revised level of $9.2 billion in

September; before

revision, the September deficit had been reported as $9.0 billion.
cif basis,

the deficit in October was $10.35 billion.

On a

As was indicated

at the meeting yesterday afternoon, exchange market participants
reportedly expected a deficit of about $10 billion on a cif basis.
exchange markets this morning,
currencies following

In

the dollar edged off against major

the release of the trade data.

The value of total imports,

fell 1.7 percent in October.

Imports

of oil fell slightly in value terms, as an unchanged volume was offset by
a decline in price. Non-oil imports fell 1-1/2 percent with declines
recorded in

imports of capital goods and consumer goods.

The value of non-oil imports was up only slightly from the
average monthly level in the third quarter.

We expect the value of non-

oil imports to rise moderately over the forecast period, although the
quantity of imports, other than computers,

should be pretty flat.

Exports declined 1.1 percent in October.
were somewhat lower.

Agricultural exports

Boosted by higher aircraft shipments, non-

agricultural exports apparently were unchanged from their September

level; they were up slightly (about 1-1/2 percent) from the average for

- 2 -

the third quarter and were about 23 percent above their level in October
of 1987.

The decline in nonagricultural exports was principally in

industrial supplies and materials; exports of capital goods were
essentially unchanged from the September level.

The staff expects a

somewhat slower rate of increase of nonagricultural exports over the
forecast horizon--about 13 percent in value terms--reflecting for awhile
the continuing effects of the strength of the dollar through much of 1988
and the slowing of foreign growth from the rapid rates seen this year.
The data released this morning were marginally worse than the
staff's expectations.

However,

given the volatility of these data, we

would not be inclined to alter our basic view of the outlook, described
in the current Greenbook,

either for the current quarter or for the

next two years.

today's data are likely to provide some support

However,

for the view that the expansion of U.S.

exports has stalled.

December 14, 1988
POLICY BRIEFING
Donald L. Kohn
As a number of people have already remarked,

the period since

the last FOMC meeting has seen a further flattening of the yield curve.
As can be seen in chart 1, this occurred with short-term rates rising
substantially, while long-term rates increased by considerably less--a
fairly typical pattern for 1988.

Long-term rates have risen by less than

half a percentage point since last winter, while short-term rates have
gone up about two percentage points.

Moreover, viewed in a slightly

longer context, Treasury bond rates have fluctuated mostly around 9 percent for more than a year and a half.
This behavior of long-term rates raises a question about the
degree to which monetary policy has applied effective restraint on the
economy this year.

A focus on long-term rates remains appropriate, even

with the spread of variable-rate financing in the 1980's.

Long-term

rates still directly affect a substantial volume of funding and spending
decisions.

In any case, these rates embody a set of expectations about

the path of future short-term rates that anyone contemplating a long-term
resource commitment would have to take into account.
The most obvious interpretation of the changes in the yield

curve and the lack of trend in long-term rates is that savers and
spenders do believe that the Federal Reserve has applied--or will soon
apply-sufficient restraint to forestall a major, sustained increase in
inflation rates.

The current configuration of rates suggests expecta-

tions of some additional firming of policy in the near term, but very
little subsequent increase in rates.

By contrast, as Mike has noted, the

greenbook forecast embodies a quite different outlook for rates.

A por-

tion of the difference lies in the staff's assumption of a policy that
will foster a reduction of inflation-an outcome the market does not seem
But the more important factor is

to be anticipating.

the notion in the

staff forecast that rates have not yet increased to levels that will
forestall additional pressures on resources and higher inflation.
The differences between the market and staff outlooks involve,
at least implicitly, some judgment about two, unfortunately, partly unobservable variables-the actual level of real interest rates and an equilibrium level consistent with the economy growing along a path that will
not cause inflation to increase or decrease.

The actual level requires a

measure of inflation expectations; the equilibrium level,

some notion of

the factors impinging on spending and saving decisions relative to the
economy's potential, taking into account developments abroad as well as
domestically.
One reading on long-term inflation expectations and of actual
long-term real rates is

from the Hoey survey of 10 year inflation expec-

tations, shown in chart 2.

The last column of this chart shows a drop in

inflation expectations from spring of 1987 when the Federal Reserve began
to tighten.

However,

the survey does tend to confirm the evidence of the

yield curve that inflation is

expected to remain near or a little above

the rates generally prevailing in recent years.
tion expectations implies an upward tilt
in the lower panel,

The decrease in infla-

to real long-term rates, shown

since the spring of 1987,

following the substantial

increase in this measure that occurred with the initial
in nominal rates in early 1987.

upward movement

-3-

One year ahead inflation expectations, shown in the first
column, have risen on balance since early 1987 or 1988.

These expecta-

tions are likely to be more confidently held than those looking ahead 10
years, and real rates derived from them, though not as relevant in
theory, may better indicate immediate influences on spending decisions.
The one-year expectations from the Hoey survey have been subtracted from 1-year treasury rates to produce one-year real rates in the
top panel of chart 3.

The middle panel uses the inflation expectations

in the Michigan consumer
the Hoey survey.

survey, which have roughly paralleled those in

The bottom panel uses recent actual inflation rates as

a proxy for inflation expectations.

In all three measures,

the inten-

sification of inflation expectations has damped the increase in real
rates associated with the System's firming since March.

As a consequence

the rise in real rates through most of 1987 and 1988 appears fairly moderate.

The most recent plot on the charts, connoted with a star, was

constructed using yesterday's nominal interest rate together with the
last available inflation expectations.

The apparent jump in real rates

shown by the star must be interpreted cautiously, since the measures of
inflation expectations have not had a chance to react to the recent
strength in the economic data, but nominal rates have; one-year rates
rose another 10 basis points yesterday following release of the retail
sales data.

Judging whether, taking account of these factors, real rates

have risen sufficiently to restrain growth to a more sustainable pace
over the next year or so and to avoid additional inflation requires as
well that they be compared to an equilibrium real rate level.

This equilibrium level has even less foundation in directly
To a considerable

observable market quotes or statistical measures.

extent it must be inferred from past observations of real rates and their
effect on the economy, together with an analysis of factors that might
have affected this relationship.

Real rates now are well above the late

1970s, when they were associated with excessive demands and accelerating
inflation.

But they are under levels earlier in the current expansion,

when the economy was growing rapidly, and in particular below the rate
needed to slow expansion in 1984.

Demand in that period, however,

was

boosted by substantial fiscal stimulus and catchup spending following the
recession, with some offset from expanding imports.
Real rates also are higher than they seem to have been in the
early 1960's, a period of sustained noninflationary growth.
make it

Two factors

likely that the equilibrium level of real rates has risen sub-

stantially from that earlier period.

First, deregulation of the finan-

cial system and innovations in financial instruments have reduced
liquidity and credit availability constraints on borrowers.

In the

absence of roadblocks to spending associated with difficulties in obtaining credit as a result, for example, of disintermediation and usury ceilings, real rates must now rise higher to exert the same restraint on
spending.

Second, partly as a consequence of the fiscal deficit, we are

a high consumption-low national saving economy.

The consequence of this

for interest rates was damped for a time by the flow of saving from
abroad.

But, the rapid improvement in our external balance in real terms

in 1988 in response to the earlier decline in the dollar, together with
the small size of the shift toward less fiscal stimulus probably has

-5-

worked to raise the appropriate level of real rates this year.

These

effects may have been offset to an extent by the effects of the decline
in the stock market in late 1987,
On balance it

which boosted saving to a degree.

would seem that relatively high real rates by

historical standards probably are needed now to keep spending in line
with the economy's potential.

These equilibrium real rates likely have

not changed very much this year, but if

they changed they probably rose a

bit, further limiting the additional monetary restraint implied by the
increase in measured real rates.
their trough in

However,

the rise in real rates from

1986 probably has contributed to taking some steam out of

the economic expansion in 1988 relative to 1987.

And the lagged effects

of further increases this fall should lead to additional slowing in the
nonfarm economy next year.

If

the slowing already in train were thought

to lead to a pace of expansion and level of demand no greater than the
economy's potential, then alternative B might be considered appropriate.
After year-end, short-term interest rates might edge down a little

under

this alternative, given that federal funds eventually might center a bit
below recent levels,
not materialize.
to discuss.

and that the firming expected by the market would

The implications for long-term rates are more difficult

The interest rates of this alternative would be likely to

keep M2 growth above the bottom of its

tentative 1989 range over the

first quarter, with growth of about 4 percent expected.
On the other hand, if,

in light of the continued expansion of

the economy at rates above potential and the moderate rise in

real rates

so far together with the current relatively high level of resource
utilization, the risks were still

seen to be asymmetrically on the side

-6-

of higher inflation, an additional tightening of policy,
porated in alternative C, might be considered.

such as incor-

Although some firming is

built into the existing structure of short-term rates, the size and immediacy of the alternative C action would raise short-term rates, though
by less than the size of the increase in the federal funds rate.

This

increase would be echoed in real as well as nominal rates, unless new
information caused an upward revision in inflation expectations.

With

interest rates and opportunity costs rising under this alternative,
demand for money would be restrained, and through March M2 might grow
around the lower end of its 3 to 7 percent tentative range.

Materialfor

FOMC Policy Briefing

December 14, 1988

Chart 1

30-year Treasury Bond
and Federal Funds Rates
Monthly

Funds

__Feeft

97

1960

Ins

13s"

II

Weeks Ending Friday

Pa-"

9

Noymbta w
30-year
Tomm"

I

Bond

I

I
roo,
I

OP

1Is

/s

V

I

Fedw

,""

Funds

-17

VtV

Ddy I III=Thmu 12313

I itfill 11111
i
.
1tit i I
Nov
es
Jm,
o
Fb
lwI

fill
Mo

if

D

f
May

Jm
l

111
fi
19 11
JIy
Aig
Sep

1t I
Oi

11333,
Now

Chart
2

(Hoey Survey)

12 months

Date

....

Second
5 years

First

Next

Survey

--

5 years
-a nnual rate,

10-year

average

percent------

1986: 01

3.5

4.9

5.7

5.3

Q2
03

3.4
3.5

4.8
4.8

5.7
5.5

5.3
5.1

Q4

3.6

4.7

5.5

5.1

1987: January

3.8

4.9

5.4

5.1

4.0

5.2

5.8

5.5

May

4.7

5.3

5.4

5.3

June

4.6

5.2

5.3

5.3

August
September
November

4.9
4.7
4.1

5.4
5.3
5.0

5.7
5.6
5.3

5.5
5.4
5.1

1988: January
March
April
June
August

4.5
4.3
4.7
5.1
5.3

5.2
5.0
5.1
5.1
5.1

5.5
5.3
5.0
4.9
4.8

5.3
5.2
5.1
5.0
4.9

October

4.9

4.7

4.9

4.8

March

ESTIMATED REAL INTEREST RATE
10-year Treasury bond yieldless 10-year
average inflation expectation (Hoey survey).

Montly
observationsforsurveymonths:

test
conversation
is

Pw

October 198.

Chart 3

One-Year Real Interest Rates
1-year T-Bill Minus 1-year Inflation Expectations (Hoey)
10

5

0

6

1977

1978

1-year T-Bill

1979

19W

1981

192

1983

1964

195

Minus 1-Year Inflation Expectations (Michigan)

19M

1967

1988

1

Percent

10

5

0

110
1-year T-BillMinus Change

inthe CPI From Three Months Prior

Percent

10

0

6

1111111111

1973
1980
1982
1984
Note:
T-Bill
is ona coup
on equivalent basis.
*Denotes t-bill
rate as of 12/13/88 less most recent inflation expectation.

1m

10