View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

August 8, 2006

1 of 158

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee 

August 8, 2006 

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in the offices of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D.C., starting at 8:30 a.m. on Tuesday,
August 8, 2006. Those present were the following:
Mr. Bernanke, Chairman 

Mr. Geithner, Vice Chairman 

Ms. Bies 

Mr. Guynn 

Mr. Kohn 

Mr. Kroszner 

Mr. Lacker 

Ms. Pianalto

Mr. Warsh 

Ms. Yellen

Mr. Hoenig, Ms. Minehan, Messrs. Moskow and Poole, Alternate Members of the
Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Fisher, Plosser, and Stern, Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks of
Dallas, Philadelphia, and Minneapolis, respectively
Mr. Reinhart, Secretary and Economist 

Ms. Smith, Assistant Secretary

Mr. Skidmore, Assistant Secretary

Mr. Alvarez, General Counsel 

Ms. Johnson, Economist 

Mr. Stockton, Economist 

Messrs. Connors, Eisenbeis, Kamin, Madigan, Sniderman, Struckmeyer, and
Wilcox, Associate Economists
Mr. Kos, Manager, System Open Market Account
Mr. English and Ms. Liang, Associate Directors, Divisions of Monetary Affairs
and Research and Statistics, respectively, Board of Governors
Mr. Reifschneider, Deputy Associate Director, Division of Research and 

Statistics, Board of Governors 

Messrs. Dale and Orphanides, Senior Advisers, Division of Monetary Affairs,
Board of Governors

August 8, 2006

Mr. Gross, Special Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of
Governors
Mr. Small, Project Manager, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Mr. Luecke, Senior Financial Analyst, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Ms. Beechey, Economist, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Ms. Low, Open Market Secretariat Specialist, Division of Monetary Affairs, 

Board of Governors 

Mr. Barron, First Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta 

Messrs. Fuhrer and Rosenblum, Executive Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve 

Banks of Boston and Dallas, respectively 

Mr. Hakkio, Ms. Mester, Messrs. Rasche and Williams, Senior Vice Presidents, 

Federal Reserve Banks of Kansas City, Philadelphia, St. Louis, and San
Francisco, respectively
Messrs. Peach and Krane, and Ms. Weir, Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks
of New York, Chicago, and New York, respectively
Mr. Weber, Senior Research Officer, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Mr. Hetzel, Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

2 of 158

August 8, 2006

3 of 158

Transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee Meeting on
August 8, 2006
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I’d like to welcome President Plosser to the table.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you very much.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Charlie, welcome aboard. Let’s start with the Desk
operations. Mr. Kos.
MR. KOS.1 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. At your last meeting I focused on the
higher level of volatility that was concentrated in specific and fairly narrow asset
classes, particularly emerging market currencies and equities. In the intermeeting
period, volatility declined in those asset classes while staying low in a broader set of
asset markets such as fixed income and the major currency pairs. Meanwhile, the
market’s focus turned even more acutely to the prospect that the Committee would
take a pass in raising rates at this meeting, even as many other central banks were
tightening policy further.
On the first page of the handout, the top panel graphs the historical volatility of
the MSCI equity indexes for the United States, Europe, Japan, and emerging markets.
These volatilities rose after your May meeting and peaked around the time of your
June meeting but have fallen back in recent weeks. Emerging market equity
volatilities (the blue line) declined sharply from more than 35 percent to below
20 percent. On balance, the value of emerging market equities and currencies
rebounded somewhat after the selloff in May and June. The middle left panel graphs
the VIX index. Although a tad higher than the very low levels observed earlier this
year, the VIX is well off its highs and below its long-term historical average.
Similarly, the middle right panel graphs an index of volatility in Treasury yields.
This index has been very tame for several quarters despite the widely reported
uncertainty about the future direction of monetary policy. Rounding out this benign
picture is the currency market, as reflected in the bottom panels, where volatility
briefly ticked up in the spring but since then has quickly fallen to earlier levels.
Even though volatilities on balance trended lower since the last meeting, trading
volumes—as measured by the primary electronic brokering services in fixed-income
and currency markets—declined more than can be explained by the summer
doldrums. Some market participants suggest that speculators reduced risk in May and
early June and are now sitting on their hands. In that scenario, risk appetite is still
ebbing even if that is not showing up in wider spreads or higher volatilities.
If investors and speculators are being more cautious, one reason for the caution
might be related to the tightening of monetary conditions globally. The table on
page 2 summarizes for a sample of central banks the net changes in their main policy
1

The materials used by Mr. Kos are appended to this transcript (appendix 1).

August 8, 2006

4 of 158

rates so far in 2006. Last Thursday the Bank of England surprised the market by
increasing rates 25 basis points, while the European Central Bank ratified
expectations by also tightening 25 basis points. Of particular note among central
banks that have recently raised interest rates is the Bank of Japan, which on July 14
moved the target overnight call rate from 0 to 25 basis points, as shown in the bottom
panel. The move had been well telegraphed. Nevertheless, the aggregate current
account balance at the BOJ is still higher than required reserves of 5 trillion to
6 trillion yen. The main reason seems to be that Japan Post continues to hold high
and variable balances, thus bumping up the aggregate.
While the backdrop globally is toward tighter monetary conditions, investors in
the United States have been looking forward to a plateauing of short-term interest
rates or even a decline over the medium term as housing and other indicators have
weakened. The prospect of a pause in the tightening cycle reportedly helped support
equity prices, shown in the top panel on page 3, which inched higher as this meeting
approached. Corporate profits on the S&P 500 for Q2 have risen 19 percent, higher
than analysts’ forecasts. In fact, profits have risen by double digits seventeen quarters
in a row. With the prospect of a pause and strong profits, one might wonder why the
price action in equities has been on the sloppy side. The most common answer is that
the outlook that companies are providing is cautious, perhaps suggesting that the
economy is softening more quickly than previously forecast. Continuing on that
theme, the middle panel graphs the two-year and ten-year Treasury yields and the
target fed funds rate. Two-year and ten-year Treasury yields are down about 30 basis
points, to about 4.9 percent, and roughly 35 basis points below the funds rate. Such
an inversion is common during an easing cycle but very rare during a tightening
cycle. As shown in the bottom panel, breakeven rates have barely budged since the
last FOMC meeting. The entire decline in nominal yields represents a fall in real
rates. Taken at face value, this suggests that investors may see lower real returns
ahead, perhaps reflecting a bearish view of the economy. However, that bearishness
on the economy is not spilling over to an expectation that inflation will necessarily
fall back.
The top panel on page 4 graphs the Libor fixing rate for three-month deposits (the
thick red line) and three-, six-, and nine-month forward rate agreements. In recent
days the nine-month forward traded through the cash rate, suggesting—if one takes
this literally—that the markets are beginning to contemplate an easing of policy in
early 2007. This pattern is similar but not identical to what we observed in 2000, as
shown in the middle panel. After the Committee raised the funds rate in May 2000—
in what turned out to be the last move in the cycle—forward rates began to decline
even though the Committee continued with an asymmetric bias to tighten. By
September the forward rates had pierced cash rates. Another similarity is seen with
Eurodollar futures calendar spreads. The bottom left panel graphs the difference
between the December 2007 and the December 2006 Eurodollar contracts. Late last
year that spread turned negative, implying that market participants expected interest
rates to be lower at the end of 2007 than at the end of 2006. After reversing
somewhat, the spread turned sharply downward in recent months. The bottom right

August 8, 2006

5 of 158

panel graphs the spread between the December 2001 and the December 2000 

contracts from late 1999 through September 2000. The spread turned negative only 

with anecdotal reports of a sharp drop in orders around September, which was 

roughly three months after the last tightening. 

Shifting gears, I want to mention briefly the transition on July 20 to the new PSR 

(payment system risk) policy. The first major P&I (principal and interest) date under 

the new rules was July 25. Fannie Mae had to fund $40 billion in MBS P&I 

payments (net of payments to itself), and the transition went very smoothly. One of 

the tools that GSEs developed to help fund their accounts on a timely basis on large 

P&I dates are term and overnight early returns of fed funds sales. Under these 

contracts, fed funds must be returned to them earlier than the end-of-day deadline 

associated with standard fed funds sales, usually between 9:30 a.m. and 11 a.m. 

Rates on overnight early-return fed funds have traded roughly 1 to 3 basis points 

below standard fed funds. Based on incomplete sampling, about 15 percent of the 

volume of brokered fed funds reported to the Desk and used to calculate the daily 

effective rate has been early returns. The Desk is collecting and monitoring early-

return fed funds data from the major brokers to assess how this market develops and 

how early-return fed funds may affect the overall fed funds market. 

There were no foreign operations in the period, and I will need a vote to approve 

domestic operations. 

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. The transition to the new PSR policy is good
news. Are there any questions for Mr. Kos? If not, we need a motion to approve operations. So
moved, without objection. We turn now to the economic situation. Mr. Wilcox.
MR. WILCOX. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Jack Brickhouse, the voice of the 

Chicago Cubs for more than thirty years, was more widely known for his knowledge 

of baseball than for his command of probability. When a Cub would step into the 

batter’s box after an especially long string of hitless trips to the plate, Brickhouse 

would invariably declare, “He’s due.” Even we kids knew in our minds that Jack 

didn’t have it quite right on the probability front, but in our hearts it was enough to 

keep us going. Some of you may remember that an employment report was released 

on the Friday after the June meeting, and that time, we pretty much nailed it. So I 

have to admit to having had a “Brickhouse moment” last Friday and wondering 

whether we were “due” this time for a real trainwreck. But for a second time in a 

row, fate smiled, as it so rarely seems to do on macro forecasters. So at the end of 

today’s meeting, I’ll be happy to pass the baton back to Dave Stockton but with a 

certain sense of guilt: He’s really due. [Laughter] 

In fact, as we reported to the Board yesterday, Friday’s labor market report came 

in very much as expected. Private nonfarm payrolls increased an estimated 113,000 

in July, virtually the same as the 100,000 we had been expecting, and the gains in 


August 8, 2006

6 of 158

each of the previous two months were revised up by a modest 20,000. The
unemployment rate rounded up to 4.8 percent, but unless we receive additional
evidence of a more-rapid slackening of conditions in the labor market, we’re inclined
to stick with our Greenbook trajectory for the unemployment rate as well. Overall,
we made no material adjustments to our macro forecast in light of this news on the
labor market. Indeed, I would argue that there was less news in the August
Greenbook than met the eye. The quick summary of the August projection is that the
pressures on resource utilization look roughly the same to us as they did at the time of
the June Greenbook, whereas the outlook for inflation looks just a shade worse.
Turning first to the issue of resource utilization, the clearest indication of our
thinking in this regard is that the unemployment rate in the August Greenbook never
deviates more than 0.1 percentage point from our forecast in the June Greenbook. To
put a very fine line on the matter, we nudged the path down ever so slightly over most
of the forecast period, and that call still looks about right to us, even in the wake of
Friday’s report. Given an unrevised estimate of the NAIRU, the slightly lower level
of the unemployment rate implies that the pressures on resource utilization are just a
little greater in this Greenbook than they were in the last one.
At the same time, we have become a bit more pessimistic about the outlook for
the growth of aggregate demand relative to potential over the next six quarters. This
slightly greater pessimism derives from several considerations. Most notably, starts
and especially permits for the construction of single-family homes came in below our
expectations in June, and we responded by taking our projection for residential
construction down over the entire projection period. In the June Greenbook, our
projection ran above the simulated trajectory from our preferred model for starts, in
recognition of the persistent upside errors that model had been making. Now, for
what it’s worth, our judgmental forecast happens to be in line with the simulation
from that model that jumps off from the last quarter of data. Parenthetically, I might
note that the simulations from that model did not revise greatly over the past six
weeks. We still see the contraction in residential construction as moderate by
historical standards but likely to be a little steeper than we anticipated in June. This
time, we forecast that single-family starts will bottom out at an annual rate of
1.43 million units, bringing the overall decline from last summer’s peak to 18 percent,
still well shy of the declines that were registered in the early 1980s and early 1990s
but starting to be in the same ballpark. We also took on board the growth
implications of the further run-up in oil prices since the June meeting, the somewhat
lower level of household wealth implied by the downward-revised trajectory for
house prices, and the likelihood that greater inventory investment in the second
quarter robbed a smidgen of growth from the future.
All that said, the adjustments to our forecast of resource utilization are pretty
marginal. More eye-catching were our revisions to top-line GDP growth, which
averaged 0.5 percentage point over the second half of this year and 0.4 percentage
point next year. But here, of course, the changes were driven by the adjustments we
made to the supply side of our projection. In its annual revision of the national

August 8, 2006

7 of 158

income and product accounts, the BEA trimmed the average pace of growth of real
GDP from 2003 through 2005 about 0.3 percentage point. Because our fundamental
views of the pressures on resource utilization and the rate of inflation were unchanged
by the NIPA revision, the simplest thing for us to do would have been to take
potential GDP down by a like-sized amount, thereby keeping the GDP gap the same
as before. As we often do, however, we made a further adjustment to potential in
order to bring the output gap into line with the unemployment rate gap at the end of
last year thereby eliminating a tension between those two “gap” variables that had
become more distracting than informative. As for the forecast, in line with our usual
practice, we overlaid the other factors that I discussed earlier with a 0.3 percentage
point adjustment for the reduction in the growth of potential, on the theory that
households and businesses anchor their spending plans around their longer-term
prospects for income.
A central issue that we wrestled with in this forecast round was whether the
slowdown in growth that we anticipate will materialize to the degree that we expect.
The dimensions of that slowdown are significant. Looking ahead six quarters and
behind by the same amount helps smooth through some of the quarter-to-quarter
wiggles. We estimate that, over the past six quarters, real GDP growth exceeded
potential growth, on average, about ¾ percentage point at an annual rate; we expect
real GDP growth over the next six quarters to fall short of potential by roughly the
same amount. One key factor driving this swing in our forecast is the combination of
a waning boost to consumption from household net worth and the higher level of
interest rates. The result is reflected in our forecast for the personal saving rate.
Again using the same six-quarter window, fore and aft, over the past six quarters, the
saving rate declined more than 2 percentage points; we expect that between now and
the end of 2007 the smaller gains in wealth and higher interest rates will bring the
saving rate back up to 2 percent. Another key factor, especially in the near term, is
the slowdown in residential investment. After chipping only about ¼ percentage
point from the growth of real GDP during the first half of this year, residential
investment is expected to slice about ¾ percentage point from the growth of real GDP
over the second half of this year. Next year, the drag from this sector should have
diminished but not halted altogether. Finally, we think that the sum of public and
private spending related to last year’s hurricanes will top out sometime this year and
will begin to drift down, accentuating the downdraft from the other factors weighing
on demand. We have assumed that, within the aggregate of total hurricane spending,
government spending and the replacement of destroyed equipment have been
relatively front-loaded, whereas construction activity, we presume, is still ramping up.
Turning to inflation, the news is relatively slight but not of the welcome variety.
As you know from the Greenbook, we marked up our projection for core PCE
inflation over the second half of this year about ¼ percentage point and nudged the
forecast for next year up a tenth. The largest single factor accounting for these
upward revisions was the further deterioration during the intermeeting period in the
outlook for energy prices; the pass-through of these prices adds about a tenth to our
projection of core inflation during the second half of this year and about half a tenth

August 8, 2006

8 of 158

next year. Owners’ equivalent rent surprised us once again to the upside in the most
recent CPI release, and we extended forward some of that unfavorable news. Other
sources of upward revision, each small but together big enough to generate just a little
upward nudge to our projection, included slightly higher near-term core import prices
and slightly weaker structural productivity growth.
As before, we continue to see core inflation stepping down next year compared
with this year, almost entirely because of the flattening out we have projected for
energy and other commodity prices: We have the increases in those prices adding
about 0.4 percentage point to our forecast of core PCE inflation this year, and we
have them adding just 0.1 percentage point next year. Provided that this year’s
shocks do not get built into inflation expectations going forward, this removal of
upward impetus should be enough to give core inflation a downward tilt. In closing, I
might briefly mention that “speed effects” do not play an important role in shaping
our outlook for inflation. The slowdown in growth operates first by bringing output
down from above potential to right in line with potential by sometime during the first
half of next year and then by moving output below potential over the remainder of
2007. For 2007 as a whole, output is so close to potential as to be roughly a neutral
factor for inflation. If growth were to proceed at a subpar pace into 2008, the
resulting gap in resource utilization could begin to place some downward pressure on
inflation. Karen will now continue our presentation.
MS. JOHNSON. From the perspective of the global economy, one of the
important revisions in this forecast from last time is the projected path for crude oil
prices. We have incorporated into the baseline forecast a path for both West Texas
intermediate (WTI) prices and the U.S. oil import price that is more than $5 per barrel
higher in the fourth quarter of this year and nearly $7 higher by the fourth quarter of
next year than was the case in the June Greenbook. It is still true, however, that the
projected path, based as usual on market futures prices at the time the forecast was
made final, is quite flat.
The sizable jump in oil prices this time reflects the volatility that we have seen in
market prices for oil since late June, when the previous Greenbook was being
finalized. Spot prices for WTI moved from below $70 per barrel at that time to a
recent peak of $77 in mid-July and again yesterday, following BP’s announcement
that pipeline repair in Alaska will shut in about 400,000 barrels per day of crude oil.
Price fluctuations during the intermeeting period reflected market concerns about the
potential effect on supply of ongoing events in the Middle East, some disruptions to
production in Nigeria, and a slight reduction in output by Saudi Arabia, as well as an
awareness that hurricane season has arrived. No doubt the underlying strength of the
global economy is contributing by maintaining overall demand as well. As of close
of business yesterday, the futures path for WTI oil prices during the remainder of this
year and next year was about $2 per barrel above the Greenbook baseline path.
Clearly, further moves in oil prices are a risk to the forecast.

August 8, 2006

9 of 158

Another important element in the foreign outlook is the continued elevated level
of nonfuel commodity prices, especially the industrial metals. Metals prices are down
from their highs in May, but they are also up from their near-term lows in June.
During the intermeeting period, spot prices for copper and zinc rose through mid-July
and then partially reversed their recent increases but since have moved up again. On
balance, metals prices are modestly higher since the time of the June Greenbook, but
prices of other primary commodities are somewhat lower. As a result, our projected
path for nonfuel commodity prices in this forecast is very similar to that of last time.
The elevated level of these prices means that they will continue to have lagged effects
on U.S. import and export price inflation for a time. The flatness of the path going
forward means that we anticipate that the implications for import price inflation will
abate noticeably in 2007, contributing to a sharp drop in the rate of inflation for core
imports. Further fluctuation in the prices for these global commodities is also a risk
to our baseline forecast.
These developments in global commodity prices, both fuel and nonfuel, along
with other data released over the intermeeting period, led us to revise up some our
forecast for inflation abroad through mid-2007. We expect that the upward pressures
on inflation in the industrial countries will be felt in the near term, particularly this
quarter, whereas those in the emerging market economies will be evident later this
year and into next. The revisions are small, in part because foreign industrial
countries have to date been very successful at containing the inflation consequences
of higher crude oil prices and several have tightened monetary policy and in part
because emerging market economies have continued to suppress domestic energy
prices, delaying their effects in the process. Some monetary policy tightening has
also been implemented by a number of Asian central banks.
We continue to read the evidence for foreign real GDP growth as indicating a
solid pace of expansion, with the possible exception of Canada, where output growth
slowed in the second quarter. We have fine-tuned our outlook for expansion abroad a
bit—strengthening last quarter and this quarter and lessening the pace just a little next
year; but the overall path for foreign real GDP is about the same as in June.
Indicators from most of our important trading partners—for example, from Japan, the
euro area, and China—suggest considerable momentum in foreign economic
expansion at the present time.
Global financial markets confirm a generally favorable climate for continued
strong growth, and many of the signs of increased risk concerns and heightened
volatility from earlier in the year have faded. Over the intermeeting period, stock
prices in many of our trading partners have risen. Equity price indexes in emerging
market countries, in particular, have rebounded from the lows of mid-June but
generally have not returned to the levels reached in early May. Other than in the
United Kingdom and Japan, yields on ten-year sovereign bonds have moved down
10 or more basis points in the major foreign industrial countries since your June
meeting, and spreads on dollar-denominated emerging market sovereign debt have
partially retraced previous increases and are not far above the lows observed in early

August 8, 2006

10 of 158

May, with the exception of spreads for Turkish debt. On balance, the dollar is down
just a little over the period.
The bottom line is that the staff’s picture of the global economy implies an 

essentially neutral effect of the external sector on U.S. GDP growth over the forecast 

period, although one must remember that there are risks on both sides to that picture. 

The arithmetic contribution of real net exports to GDP growth for the rest of this year 

and next year is essentially zero—with a small positive contribution over the second 

half of this year, unusual for us, followed by a small negative contribution in 2007 as 

a whole. Exports of both goods and services are expected to grow strongly, supported 

by steady expansion of real GDP growth abroad. The step-down in U.S. real GDP 

growth should restrain import growth somewhat over the next six quarters. 

The nominal trade deficit on goods and services is projected to widen about 

$75 billion from the estimated figure for the second quarter to that for the fourth 

quarter of 2007. The change in the non-oil nominal trade balance accounts for only 

one-third of that $75 billion. This change in the overall trade balance is sufficiently 

small that the projected ratio of the trade deficit to GDP is steady at about 6 percent. 

Nevertheless, the current account deficit is projected to exceed $1 trillion at the end 

of 2007, and the ratio of the current account deficit to GDP rises from 6.5 percent to 

7 percent next year. A growing net deficit in investment income flows largely 

explains the further deterioration in the current account balance. That change, in turn, 

is accounted for by a substantial widening of the deficit on portfolio income that more 

than offsets a gain in the balance of direct investment income. The financing 

requirements of our external deficit remain large and will continue to grow as long as

the level of the trade balance remains far from zero. David and I will be happy to 

answer any questions. 

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Are there questions for David or
Karen? President Poole.
MR. POOLE. I’d like to put a question to you, but I want to do it in the form of an
observation that I’d like you to comment on. It has to do with the inflation situation. Obviously,
we are not in a situation anything remotely like that of the 1970s, but I do believe that we have
very generalized inflation across sectors and across regions of the world. Let me support that
statement in the following way. In the overall numbers, the core PCE is at or above 2 percent—
or was in ’04 and ’05 and is projected for ’06 and ’07. So this number is for a four-year period—
it’s not a little flash in the pan. The inflation projections abroad have been shaded up. I think

August 8, 2006

11 of 158

you commented explicitly to that effect. Import and export prices are being revised up a bit. The
revisions are not huge, but they are all in the same direction. Dollar depreciation would tend to
promote higher prices.
I’ve looked at the disaggregated CPI for the twelve months ending in June of this year
versus the twelve months ending in June 2005—so it’s a year-over-year comparison. When we
look at the components—I won’t go through all of them—we know what’s happening to owners’
equivalent rent. We know what is happening to the energy part of it. Household furnishings and
operations are up; apparel is up. The major things going down are actually new vehicles and
used vehicles, which are tending to hold the CPI down. Public transportation is up; medical care
commodities are up; and there is a very small decline in medical care services. Other goods and
services, communications, and recreation are all up. Education is up just a bit. The upward
revision is very generalized across almost all sectors of the CPI. Then, on the cost side, we’re
going to have this big upward revision in unit labor costs. By the way, were the unit labor costs
released this morning?
DAVID WILCOX. They should have been released by 8:30, I think.
MR. POOLE. Maybe we’ll see what happened there during the break. My argument is
that we have very generalized inflation pressure across regions of the world and across
commodity and service sectors. The pressure is not isolated. Could you comment on that
observation?
MR. WILCOX. Broadly, I don’t disagree that the acceleration in consumer prices is
broadly based. It is sensitive to sample period. Michael Kiley’s briefing yesterday to the Board
touched on some of the same issues and presented an exhibit that displayed the median CPI as
constructed by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and the trimmed mean constructed by the

August 8, 2006

12 of 158

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Both of those measures, which are alternative attempts to
capture the central tendency of inflation rates, have also moved up notably, most of all from
2003. I guess I would remind you that we were a little puzzled as to why inflation was as low as
it was in 2003. It fell below our model simulations. We have never been able to come up with a
fully satisfactory explanation for why it got as low as it did. So if you use 2003 as your base for
comparison with the present, the trend looks very worrisome. If you smooth through that—I
don’t know that “anomaly” is the right word—unexplained dip in 2003, you are left with a trend
that by any of these measures has moved up. The particular comparison that we chose to
highlight yesterday in the briefing to the Board emphasized the acceleration in housing services,
but other components have played a role as well. We also think that the energy-price passthrough into core has played a broadly diffuse role in giving some upward impetus to core
inflation.
MS. JOHNSON. If I could just comment on the worldwide aspect of your point, I’d say
that the one piece that’s missing is that globally we have not seen this inflation pressure translate
into an acceleration in wages and labor compensation—not so much here in the United States
and not in rest of the world. Even in places where central banks are tightening monetary policy
in recognition of the inflation that they are experiencing in their consumer prices, one is not
hearing stories about an acceleration of wages.
So there’s truth in everything you’ve said, and I wouldn’t disagree that it’s worrisome,
but we’ve seen huge changes in the structure of global economic activity. Those changes may
have effected significant changes in relative prices, particularly of energy on the one hand and of
other kinds of primary commodities on the other. We keep saying that those price changes are
going to end, right? Every FOMC I come here, and I tell you that those prices are flattening out

August 8, 2006

13 of 158

starting this morning. [Laughter] Then I come back six weeks later, and I say it again—and
that’s not lost on me.
However, there is a question in my mind as to trend versus relative price effects here, and
I think there are surely some of both types of effects. It may be wrong to attribute the pressure
entirely to a relative price shock that’s going to go away immediately, but it’s certainly also
wrong to call it all inflation trend with no relative price component.
MR. WILCOX. Now that I’ve had a chance to take a breath—another factor that
obviously is critical is the behavior of inflation expectations. As you know, the Survey of
Professional Forecasters long-term measure has been flat, immovable, at 2½ percent. The
University of Michigan survey—which we show in the Greenbook table back to 2004—was at
2.8 percent, on the median measure, in the second half of 2004, and it is at 2.9 percent in June
and July of this year. So long-term inflation expectations have really been remarkably well
contained. Shorter-term inflation expectations have fluctuated more with changes in overall
consumer prices, and they are up a couple of tenths from the end of 2004. But there hasn’t been
a lot of upward drift in measures of inflation expectations.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. President Poole asked a significant part of my question, or he presented
a significant part of my question. [Laughter] But let me ask you about the markup part of this.
You know, we have always thought that there was a cushion for compensation to go higher, for
input costs to go higher, and for profit margins to shrink, and therefore we wouldn’t get any
pass-through into price increases. Those markups have remained incredibly high—I mean, profit
margins are very high. I was just wondering whether you think we should put less weight on this

August 8, 2006

14 of 158

factor going forward when we’re looking at our forecasts, given what we’ve seen in unit labor
costs, which you mentioned, and other changes in the forecast.
MR. WILCOX. So, they revised down. The implication of the NIPA revision is that,
according to the latest estimates, those markups are a little lower than they were before. They
are still noticeably above their historical averages. In the judgmental forecast, we have never
placed an enormous amount of weight on those markup measures, and perhaps the chain of
events during this intermeeting period illustrates why. Our FRB/US model does put a lot of
weight on those markups, and it revised up its inflation projection 0.6 percentage point,
something like that. Now it’s within spitting distance of the judgmental forecast.
First of all, we have had a hard time getting those markups to enter reliably or robustly
into an econometric equation. Second, we’ve been leery of the kind of revisions that took place
in this year’s NIPA revision. We’ve certainly regarded them with some nervousness and refer to
them as presenting a downside risk to inflation, if those profit margins should compress. But I’m
not entirely sure how to respond to your question as to whether we should put less weight on
them since we haven’t put an enormous amount of weight on them in our judgmental projection
to date. They are a secondary determinant of our inflation outlook in the judgmental projection.
As I say, to the extent that you were prepared to put some weight on them before and to see them
as high before, you would still see them as high now, though less so.
MR. MOSKOW. And the unit labor cost trend hasn’t caused you to change your outlook
for the future either?
MR. WILCOX. Again, the statistical analysis is very frustrating. It’s hard to get that
variable to enter reliably, particularly with real-time data that are susceptible to the kind of
revisions that we have seen. We do put a nod in our inflation forecast to the acceleration in

August 8, 2006

15 of 158

structural productivity, which is related to unit labor costs, but unit labor costs themselves have
likewise not played a prominent role in our judgmental forecast.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you. I have a question for David and Karen, and it picks up on
President Poole’s. My question has to do with what, if anything, we can learn about the role of
energy-price increases as a factor raising core inflation here from the experience of other
countries. Since we’re not the only country experiencing increases in energy and other
commodity prices, my question is whether or not there is some econometric or other evidence
that pertains to the degree of energy-price pass-through into core inflation in other developed
economies. I’m thinking particularly of economies in which inflation expectations are
reasonably well anchored—for example, the United Kingdom, Canada, and the euro area. What
do we know about energy-price pass-through into core inflation? Is there evidence of that?
MS. JOHNSON. I suspect that there is, but I confess that I’m not really able to give you
the details this morning. We have not attempted to do a major project of that sort. There are two
things that have to be immediately taken into account if you’re thinking about some kind of
cross-country, or at least non-U.S., look at this. First are the tax features. Many of the other
industrial countries have specific taxes, much higher specific taxes, on fuel products of one sort
or another, particularly on gasoline but also on other things. Those economies will experience a
much smaller percentage change in the wholesale and retail prices for any given change in the
crude oil price than we will. The shock is always damped by that on the upside but also on the
downside, of course. So that’s a factor that we point to often, and that is why ocular regression
kinds of pass-through would make you think that pass-through is less abroad.

August 8, 2006

16 of 158

Second is the exchange rate effect. If the dollar is trending down a bit, for a short time
anyway, it needs to be taken care of in the dynamics of the equation rather than in the structure
of the equation because we believe that the dollar oil price adjusts to global demand and supply.
But for short episodes in particular, if one thought the dollar was experiencing a spike or a this or
a that, then obviously the changes in the exchange value of the dollar look to other countries as a
piece of how much oil prices have gone up for them. In general, many countries—say, Japan
and, for that matter, even Europe—have a sense that overall the effect is less because their
energy intensity is less. They are constantly lecturing us that we consume too much energy.
Whether, ceteris paribus, the actual parameter in terms of the price shock really differs I can’t tell
you, but the specific taxes and the consequent reduction in energy intensity that they have helped
to produce, and other factors that have made them less energy-intensive, do make the problem
seem to be smaller in most of the other industrial countries.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. David, in your opening comments you said that the staff got the last
two employment numbers right. But they were below the market expectations of what the
employment numbers would be. In the Greenbook baseline projections, the employment growth
numbers going forward are even lower. They are 80,000 per month for the rest of this year and
40,000 per month in 2007. Those seem like very low numbers; I think that, if those numbers are
realized, they’re going to continue to surprise markets and to appear pretty weak. So I was
wondering how sensitive to those specific employment numbers the outlook is. I know that the
Greenbook has a lower NAIRU alternative simulation; is that supposed to be providing us with
some information about the uncertainty in that forecast? Given that lower NAIRU alternative in

August 8, 2006

17 of 158

the Greenbook, I am also curious about what kinds of employment numbers we are looking at
that would achieve those outcomes.
MR. WILCOX. The predominant factor in generating those strikingly low employment
gains is our projection for trend labor force participation over the projection period. With the
aging of the workforce, we think that the trend is now turning decidedly downward, not for
cyclical reasons, not because the labor market presents atypically unappealing job opportunities,
but because an increasing share of the population is shifting into age groups that have historically
exhibited lower labor force participation rates. My recollection is that the difference between a
flat participation rate and a declining participation rate—and I’ll look it up here if I can find it
fast enough for you—is on the order of about 40,000 jobs per month. We have a neutral private
payroll gain for the remainder of this year in the neighborhood of about 90,000 jobs. If the
participation rate were to remain flat, 20,000 to 25,000 jobs would be added to our trend
estimate. We think that the decline in labor force participation is taking about 0.3 percentage
point off the growth of hours over the projection period. Now, if that were to flatten out, if we
simply have the trend wrong, then that would play through the macro forecast—I’m going to do
something dangerous here and think out loud—a lot like the adjustment to potential GDP that we
just made following the NIPA revision. In essence, a flat participation rate would mean that
trend hours growth is that much faster and that trend aggregate demand 0.3 percentage point
faster could be sustained without generating additional inflation pressures.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Minehan.
MS. MINEHAN. I have a follow-on question to Sandy’s. I know how the benchmark
GDP revisions work into your forecast. But if you look just at the headline numbers, we seem to

August 8, 2006

18 of 158

have the worst of all circumstances for a central bank: a good deal slower growth for a number
of reasons—the benchmark being one of them—even though all the output gaps and everything
else remain relatively the same, slower headline growth in both GDP and consumption, and
higher inflation. This is not an easy set of circumstances by any means. One thing I am
concerned about, like Sandy, is the speed with which you have consumers reacting in their
consumption to potential GDP changes. You haven’t changed the saving rate that much from
your earlier forecast, but you do get the 0.3 percentage point out of GDP growth. I was just
wondering about your thoughts on that—the reaction seemed fast. Second, outside of a
recession, have we ever seen this kind of decline in real estate investment in a period of growth?
We were trying to find it, but it’s hard to sort through cause and effect here. The decline seemed
very large in terms of the negative real estate investment. Finally, Karen mentioned that we
haven’t seen wage inflation or wage growth outstrip productivity here or in major countries
anywhere else in the world. I’m wondering, given all the focus on the fact that median family
incomes are not growing on a real basis, whether there is at least some chance that we’re going
to start seeing an increasing return, particularly for skilled people, which everybody tells you
they can’t find.
MR. WILCOX. Let me take those concerns in turn. First, with regard to the speed of
adjustment of consumption to potential GDP—perhaps it is ironic, but our assumption is that we are
the most ignorant ones in this little morality play; that households and businesses have been aware
of the slower growth of potential GDP; and that, as far as households and businesses are concerned,
what goes on in the basement of the BEA is utterly without consequence. You can see that as well,
for example, in our leaving the stock market projection unrevised. Implicit in the way we have
reacted to the news from the BEA is that households and businesses knew of the slower trajectory.

August 8, 2006

19 of 158

Investors knew of the slower trajectory for potential GDP. It was we who were off in previously
assuming an erroneously steep upward trend for potential GDP. It does change the error pattern:
The pattern of errors over history is changed a bit, and at the margin, that sends us into the
projection period with slightly different dynamics; but those are very small effects. (Sandy is
alerting me that an important piece of news that we received was the weakness of disposable
income growth in the second quarter.)
MS. MINEHAN. But you still have it growing pretty fast over the forecast period—
4 percent or so.
MR. WILCOX. Yes; indeed, faster than spending, and that’s how we generate the upward
motion of the personal saving rate.
MS. MINEHAN. The way that changes is sort of speedy, too; but that was in your previous
forecast.
MR. WILCOX. Now, let’s see. I can’t read my own notes. The second question is?
MS. MINEHAN. Just a real estate investment question.
MR. WILCOX. Oh, have we seen anything like this outside of a recession? I don’t know
the answer to that. I would mention, however, how strong residential investment was through the
recession and how well sustained it was and how we all remarked on the strength with which that
sector persisted through that period of very low interest rates. Every business cycle is different from
every other one, but this one certainly has its unique feature, which is the uncharacteristic strength
of residential investment through the recession period, and we have that coming off now.
Third, you asked about growth in real compensation or real wages. We have some
acceleration in our projection. We expect it to occur. We expect it to be consistent with a
moderating profile of price inflation. We do see labor’s share of income as lower now than it will

August 8, 2006

20 of 158

be in some equilibrium point in the future, so we expect that aspect of national income to shift in its
composition.
MS. MINEHAN. Slowly.
MR. WILCOX. Slowly.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Just a quick question for Karen. Karen, looking at the global economy as a
whole, would you say that capacity utilization has increased since we last met, since the end of the
last quarter, or since the beginning of the year and, if so, to a significant degree?
MS. JOHNSON. I would say in a kind of notional sense that most especially China, for
example, has not slowed to the degree that we and everybody else had been expecting. There was a
significant positive surprise in the Q2 numbers for China. At the time we saw what we called the
“volatility” of May-June, when it looked as though some commodity prices were coming off and
the stories that they had been held up by speculators and so forth seemed true, and it looked as
though those prices might actually adjust downward and stay down. Well, that perception was very
short lived: The fundamental demand for some of these products seems to have reasserted itself,
and many of those prices are back up where they once were. So based on those kinds of indirect
signals, I would say that the strength of the global economy is at least what it was three months ago
and perhaps a tiny bit stronger.
MR. FISHER. Is that net of our weakness or our declining? This is just guess work, but I
am curious.
MS. JOHNSON. If the full trajectory going through the rest of this year that is in the
Greenbook takes place, then the United States is going to take the world back just a bit, and it will
bring Canada with it probably. At least that is what our forecast says will happen. We see China

August 8, 2006

21 of 158

stepping harder on the mechanisms that it uses to try to slow its economy. In some sense, I would
say that the Greenbook picture we’re painting is that global capacity utilization is perhaps at a peak
right about now and that we anticipate the slowing in the United States and the efforts in China
certainly to outweigh the continued strength, say, in Europe or Japan, which is probably going to
happen. Still in all, that may be the mean of our forecast, but there’s a distribution around that, and
it’s certainly possible that there are upside risks as well as downside risks in those capacity
pressures.
MR. FISHER. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any other questions?
MR. WILCOX. May I just briefly mention the staff view? Our research on structural labor
force participation is laid out in a Brookings paper that is just about due for release by folks who are
our labor specialists. That paper sets out in considerable detail our work in this area.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. We are ready for our economic outlook
go-round. For President Plosser’s benefit, I will say that we have two go-rounds. The first is on
the economic outlook, and the second is on policy issues. One hand means you want to be
recognized, and Michelle will put your name on the list. If you want to interject a question or a
comment, we have two-handed interventions. Who would like to go first? President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Economic conditions in the Seventh
District moderated in the second quarter in line with our expectations after a very strong first
quarter. Most of my directors and business contacts believe that added caution is taking hold in
the economy. Some think that growth will be noticeably slower in the second half of the year,
and some believe that slowing will continue into 2007. However, my contacts are unable to
point to explicit examples, apart from housing, showing that such a marked deceleration

August 8, 2006

22 of 158

currently is in train. Indeed, many of the reports that we get are quite upbeat. For instance, one
of our national temporary help contacts said his indicators were pointing to a bounceback from a
weak second quarter, and he was seeing strong conversions from temporary to permanent status.
One reason that some people were more pessimistic was that they believe the current
expansion is a bit, as they say, long in the tooth, and so the economy must be due for a period of
weakness. Of course, the economic literature finds that the probability of an expansion’s ending
does not depend on the expansion’s current length. However, these comments could reflect
imbalances in the economy that increase exposure to adverse shocks. But except for housing,
any references to such imbalances are vague at best. Although it is not certain, the mixture of
reports may simply be indicative of the normal process of the economy’s moderating to growth
averaging near or a bit below potential. On the inflation front, we continue to hear reports of
cost pass-through and other price increases similar to those we’ve received in recent months.
Turning to the national outlook, although growth moderated in the second quarter, GDP
growth for the first half was a solid 4 percent. The unemployment rate remains below 5 percent,
and the core PCE inflation rate has now been at or above 2 percent for more than two years. It
has to be said, in looking simply at the top-line data that form the basis of most Taylor rules, that
real activity is pretty good and inflation is too high. In this context, three related questions
guided my thinking on the outlook. First, are there important imbalances within particular
sectors that should concern us? Second, is the list of exogenous downside shocks accumulating
to a point that the risks to growth outweigh those from deteriorating inflation? Third, are the
current financial conditions restrictive or not?
Regarding sectoral imbalances, for some time we have assumed a marked slowdown in
residential investment, but other sectors do not seem to be outside normal ranges of variation

August 8, 2006

23 of 158

associated with an economy that is growing close to potential. Business fixed investment last
quarter was weaker than we had thought, but the weakness appeared to largely reflect transitory
developments in volatile categories—communication equipment and transportation.
Importantly, we don’t hear any stories of pulling back due to earlier overinvestment. On the
household side, the steady growth in the consumption of nondurables and services indicates that
households do not seem to be overly concerned about their longer-term prospects for income
growth. So for now, I do not see any sectoral imbalances that would pile on the housing
adjustment and cause a more fundamental downshift in economic growth over the forecast
period.
What about shocks? Well, the list of downside shocks is troublesome. Energy prices
continue to surprise us on the upside. Geopolitical risks have increased, particularly considering
developments in the Middle East. We now have some sense from businesses that animal spirits
may be making them more cautious. Currently, however, I think that this is more rhetoric than
action. Still I think that all these factors deserve careful monitoring.
Third, what about financial conditions? When I was preparing for this meeting, I talked
to no one who thought that conditions are restrictive. The modal response continues to be that
financing is readily available and is fueling a lot of dealmaking. Ten-year Treasury rates are
under 5 percent. Risk spreads are low. If we want to assess the constraining effects of past
increases in the federal funds rate, we need to take into account the level of interest rates. In all
likelihood, the real funds rate has only recently reached neutral. Furthermore, we need to
consider the accommodation that we had put in place in 2003 and 2004. The core PCE inflation
data we now have for that period are about ½ percentage point higher than what we saw in the
real-time initially announced inflation rates that guided our policy decisions back then. So the

August 8, 2006

24 of 158

unwelcome disinflation of 2003 was not as severe as we had feared at the time, and accordingly,
our policy was more accommodative than we thought at the time, which may have had
inflationary consequences. The incoming data make the current inflation situation seem much
more troublesome. First, as we all know, the latest reading on core PCE inflation is 2.4 percent.
That’s pretty high. Second, the revised NIPA data indicate that core PCE inflation has been at or
above 2 percent since April 2004, as President Poole mentioned. The combination of these two
facts makes me more concerned that inflation expectations may soon begin to drift up. Finally, I
don’t see the forces in play that would make the policy assumption in the Greenbook restrictive
enough to put core inflation on a downward trajectory over the next 18 months. If the passthrough was small on the way up, it seems likely to be small on the way down, and output gaps
that might be emerging will not alter inflation’s trajectories very much or very quickly with flat
estimates of Phillips curves.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. So far the economy has stuck pretty close to
the script of the soft landing sketched out in the June Greenbook. Real GDP growth slowed
markedly in the second quarter. Housing construction has declined sharply, and house prices
have decelerated; this situation suggests that our policy actions have taken hold in this
interest-sensitive sector. The recent sharp rise in oil prices should also put a damper on growth
of real income and consumer spending. Most forecasters now expect below-trend growth in the
current quarter. Nonfarm payroll employment has shifted down to a more-sustainable pace, and
the unemployment rate has risen to 4.8 percent, just a bit below standard estimates of the
NAIRU. Core inflation, although uncomfortably high, came in 0.2 percentage point below the
June Greenbook’s forecast in the second quarter. In addition, despite further large increases in

August 8, 2006

25 of 158

the price of oil, inflation expectations held firm. In light of these developments, a reasonable
forecast is for growth to continue to run slightly below its potential rate, the unemployment rate
to edge up, and core inflation to recede gradually.
At our last meeting, I laid out some of my concerns about downside risks to the outlook
for growth and upside risks to inflation. Quite honestly, I cannot say that the recent data have
done much to assuage my angst on either account. The recent falloff in housing activity and the
deceleration in house prices have been faster than expected. The current Greenbook has
residential investment falling at an annual rate of 14 percent in the second half of this year,
nearly twice as fast as projected in June. These surprises intensify the risk of a sharper
slowdown as the lagged effects of our past policy actions come fully into effect. For example,
the housing slowdown could become an unwelcome housing slump as envisioned in one of the
Greenbook alternative scenarios. A large homebuilder in our District summarized the views of
many of our contacts when he recently commented that “the housing market has not yet popped,
but a hissing sound is now clearly audible.” [Laughter] He pointed to rapidly rising
cancellations as a particularly ominous sign. I will be watching the incoming data closely for
signs as to whether the housing slowdown remains orderly as hoped or takes a steeper downward
slide, posing a greater risk to the economy.
My concerns about inflation have also been somewhat heightened by the recent data or,
more precisely, revisions to past data. Core measures of inflation continue to be well above my
comfort zone. Of course, after the experience of last year, when core inflation was revised up by
a considerable amount, I approached this year’s annual NIPA revision with some considerable
trepidation. I was relieved to see that the core PCE price inflation data came out of the revision
relatively unscathed, revised up just 0.1 percentage point for 2005; but other aspects of the report

August 8, 2006

26 of 158

were somewhat less reassuring for the inflation outlook. First, the rate of labor productivity
growth over the past three years has been a bit slower than we thought, primarily because of
downward revisions to the rate of capital accumulation, so that the Greenbook now projects
structural productivity growth of 2.7 percent, about ¼ percentage point slower than we thought
back in June. This revision suggests somewhat less downward pressure on inflation emanating
from cost reductions and, therefore, greater upside risks to inflation.
But that wasn’t the only surprise tucked away in the annual revision. The upward
revision to compensation growth over the past four quarters implies that growth in unit labor
costs over the past year has been more rapid than we had believed. I had thought that there was a
good chance that compensation per hour and unit labor costs would increase relatively
moderately going forward, helping to contain inflationary pressures. The data revision was thus
a bit of a wake-up call for me, and I have revised upward my views on the outlook for
compensation and unit labor costs. My reading of the report is that the revised data provide a
clearer and less sanguine picture of the trend in this measure of compensation. However, the
employment cost index was in line with expectations in June and continues to show moderate
growth. Moreover, even with revisions to productivity and compensation, the markup in the
nonfarm business sector remains very high by historical standards, suggesting that firms do have
room to absorb costs.
Overall, I view the inflation outlook as highly uncertain, with a pronounced upside risk.
As I mentioned at the last meeting, we just don’t have a good handle on why core inflation has
risen of late or how persistent this rise will be. While it is comforting to attribute the increase to
energy and commodity-price pass-through, empirical evidence suggests that pass-through effects

August 8, 2006

27 of 158

have been quite modest since the mid-1980s. If so, the door is open for other explanations that
may have a more lasting influence and require a more aggressive policy response.
Something that makes me even more uncertain about the inflation outlook is that standard
backward-looking Phillips curve models of inflation appear to be breaking down. It has been
widely noted that the estimated effect of resource utilization on inflation in such models has
become much smaller over time. But equally striking is the finding that the sum of coefficients
on lagged inflation when freely estimated appears to have fallen as well, suggesting that inflation
has become far less persistent. In fact, our staff finds that, in looking over the past ten years, it is
better to assume that core inflation will return to its sample average over the next four quarters
than that it will remain in its recent range or follow a standard Phillips curve model.
Interestingly, this decline in the persistence of core inflation has occurred at roughly the same
time that long-run inflation expectations, as measured by the Survey of Professional Forecasters,
appear to have become well anchored, and this may not be a coincidence. Economic models
with forward-looking inflation expectations tell us that, if the central bank has credibility and
holds to a fixed long-run inflation target, then inflation will be less persistent than is implied by
the standard backward-looking Phillips curve model. Indeed, the puzzle for macroeconomists
has been why we see so much inflation persistence. Perhaps we no longer do. If that is true,
inflation may decline faster than the Greenbook expects.
Admittedly, the past ten years form a relatively small sample from which to draw
definitive conclusions. But the inflation process may have changed in a fundamental way, and
we should be open to that possibility. I would like to stress that this evidence and the analysis
concern the simple correlations of the inflation data that are used for forecasting. The evidence
does not relate to structural relationships, and therefore it does not necessarily inform us about

August 8, 2006

28 of 158

how our policy decisions affect the economy or about the best course for policy. In summary,
although my modal forecast is relatively benign, I remain very concerned about risks to both
growth and inflation.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, at our last FOMC meeting in my now over one-year-long
attempt to stay away from any analogies referring to innings or baseball [laughter], I used the
analogy of Phil Mickelson at the U.S. Open to suggest an opposite strategy. What I suggested
was that we use the minutes we are about to release and especially your testimony, if you recall,
to center the ball on the fairway so that we could approach the green from the point of this
meeting. It appears now that we have done that, you have done that, and the minutes have done
that, and we are basically at a point where we are confident of either a hawkish pause or one
more tightening of the screw in terms of raising the federal funds rate.
The Greenbook and the Bluebook do a good job of presenting us with an analytical
framework for this meeting. I want to compliment them, with an “i,” but I also thought it might
be helpful to complement them, with an “e,” with some of the data and inputs from our business
contacts and the work of our own research staff on the issues we have been talking about.
Let me start with housing. I regularly talk to CEOs of two of the five big builders. They
like using analogies. In the words of the second largest builder in the country, “The pig is still in
the python.” That is, he expects the decline from peak to trough in home sales to exceed that
forecast in the Greenbook. I think we had 17½ percent; he is talking about a correction of
25 percent. To adhere to the convention of reporting on my District, which we are supposed to
do, I’m happy to say that only Texas, where our economy is on the verge of employing ten
million workers, is holding up in the books of these two homebuilders. Even the Carolinas are

August 8, 2006

29 of 158

starting to fold over, and the weakest area is California. The Big Five builders and other
homebuilders are reacting as you might expect. They are cutting staff. They are renegotiating
their prices and getting concessions from their subcontractors. They are walking away from their
planned land deals, and they are renegotiating existing contracts. This is what a macroeconomist
would expect in reaction. In answer to Cathy’s and David’s questions, one CEO, who has been
in the business since 1973, reports that this correction is the roughest and most sudden he has
seen, with one exception. That exception is that the industry is significantly consolidated, with
most of the big builders either supporting very strong balance sheets or having ready
accessibility to capital from a flush banking system and eager private equity groups. So the
reports I received from the Big Five are that, while they are wringing their hands, they’re also
licking their chops; they are plotting acquisitions of smaller, weaker builders when they reach the
depths of despair. This situation may signal the prospect of a shorter turnaround time for a
correction, or it may not, but I just throw it out for your contemplation.
Clearly, however, the housing downturn and the cumulative effect of energy and
electricity price increases are having an effect. One of my contacts is the CEO of a large “casual
dining” restaurant chain, which employs 110,000 out of the 4.8 million people employed in that
segment of the restaurant business. He reports that his utility costs this year have risen
30 percent and his materials costs have risen 15 percent. Although customers are moving
downscale in terms of the dining chain, guest counts for that segment of the market, which again
employs 4.8 million people, are down 5 percent in the last week, and he sees that trend
continuing.
The CEO of a national middle price point retailer reported that furniture sales in July
were down 21 percent. A low-end price point retailer—the low-end price point being Wal-Mart

August 8, 2006

30 of 158

to 7-Eleven—reports slowing traffic. In the words of the head of Wal-Mart USA, John Menzer,
“What we saw last month is getting worse.” So-called morning madness sales, which are
common in September, have been moved up to July and August.
The railroads report a significant slowdown over the past four weeks in the shipment of
forest products. So we do have a slowdown, although it is important to point out that the rails,
according to the companies themselves, expect to increase traffic 3 percent during the second
half because of industrial demand. UPS reports through its CFO that it is shipping 13.2 million
packages a day, which is down from about 13.5 in the first half but up from 12.7 in ’05.
Incidentally, their report last quarter proved to be remarkably accurate in terms of their expected
growth for the second quarter, if it, in turn, is revised upward toward 3 percent. So I want to
stick with what I reported at the June FOMC meeting—that our “roadster” economy has
downshifted in growth.
I also reported a sense that inflation pressure gauge needles were moving forward, and
my soundings this time indicate that they continue to do so. I thought that the briefing the staff
gave to the Board and circulated to us was very helpful, and I appreciate very much the
discussion we had earlier on inflation in answer to President Poole’s question. It is important to
point out that the monthly trimmed mean PCE inflation rate in June was 3.1 percent. On a
twelve-month basis, it picked up to 2.7 percent. But very importantly—if, as President Poole
suggested, you break down the PCE components, whether you trim it or you use it “fully garbed”
[laughter]—83 percent of the components are increasing in price. That is up from 73 percent in
April. What that means is that only 17 percent of prices are falling compared with 27 percent
two months ago.

August 8, 2006

31 of 158

We know that inflationary pressures are building abroad. Karen, our work in Dallas is
very much in its infancy; but to the extent that it helps, our measurement of industrial capacity
utilization in all the large member states of the European Union is up. Recent revisions to the
United Kingdom’s national accounts indicate that the Brits are operating closer to capacity; and
if you look at the Tankan survey, for the first time in more than a decade, Japan is reporting
capacity constraints. Like everybody else, we have no reliable data on China and India, but we
know that their economies are steaming along. As they grow, they cut into existing global
capacity available to U.S. businesses. Let me give you an example. Our shipping CEOs report
that a portion of the international fleet of large bulk carriers, although they estimate that this
portion is only about 2 percent, has now been rerouted and is being used for intracoastal,
intra-Chinese trade. So at a time of the year when usually the rates cave for these Panamax
ships, which are the largest bulk carriers, the daily rate has stiffened another $1,000. It is up to
$23,000 from the $22,000 that I reported at our last meeting, even though this is usually the soft
time of the year. Just for a reference point, last year at this time it was one-half that price.
At home our bankers report, in the words of the CEO of the largest bank in Texas, “more
talk about price increases and pass-throughs.” We are seeing the return in our District of the
term “air ball financing,” which is financing based on prospects not on hard reality. One
example that caught my interest, which is yet unreported in the public press, is that, according to
the CEO of a large corporation with a $30 billion market capitalization, they have been
approached by a single buyout group to take them private. So there is a lot of liquidity left in the
system.
The CEO of Wal-Mart USA reports that they are building in a price increase of 1 percent
this year. It is the first increase in a long, long time. Typically they built in minus 1 percent to

August 8, 2006

32 of 158

minus 2 percent. The increase was confirmed by the CEO of one of Wal-Mart’s largest suppliers
of nongrocery goods, who quoted Lee Scott as telling him last week, “We are reaching the limits
of productivity enhancement and may have to take it out in price increases.” Kimberly-Clark’s
CEO reports that he started the year planning for an inflation factor in their cost of goods sold of
$150 million. It has been ratcheted up in two intervals and is now at $350 million. He reports
that they are covering increases in the cost of goods sold through price increases. This is in
sharp contrast to what he has been telling me before every previous meeting.
Food processors report the same. It might be noteworthy that corn prices—even though
we don’t include them in the core PCE—are, because of ethanol production, up significantly.
That’s very unusual at this time of the year. Frito-Lay’s CEO reports an overall inflation shift—
in his own words, “the ability to pass through price increases and make them stick.”
Finally, Mr. Chairman, at a recent meeting you asked about my reports from Hewitt, the
consulting company, regarding the prospects for health care costs. According to one of my
sources, several of the largest insurers are focusing on a settlement range of roughly 7 percent to
8½ percent growth for next year. It is a little more than they had expected; it is roughly what it
was last year. I might point out that those companies cover a large number of people.
To supplement this input, I touched base with three people I consider to be the best
long-term practitioners in the fund-management business. Each one has been in the business for
more than thirty years. Besides reporting continued high appetites for risk and continued
elevated liquidity in the marketplace, these gnarly old-timers report a shift in the attitude of
businesses that they cover in investing. To quote one, “Before, the operators we deal with were
worried about getting their heads handed to them if they tried to pass through price increases;
now they’re trying to see what they can get away with.” In summary, the CEO of Cadbury

August 8, 2006

33 of 158

Schweppes—to kill the serpentine analogy—says that “we’re just not through the snake yet on
inflation.”
Mr. Chairman, this is a long and faithful report. For all the inherent risks, I pay close
attention to what I hear from my CEO contacts. According to them, in addition to the data that
we are seeing, the economy is slowing from its torrid pace of growth and downshifting to a more
normal range. Global capacity and utilization are not slowing apace from what we can see, or if
they are slowing, overall global capacity utilization is staying at an even level. It is also clear
that the business community has its finger poised on the trigger of price increases. It may well
be that the lagged effect of our de-accommodation has yet to temper the price equation. It may
be that energy prices and other cost-push factors are at a point of tapering off. It may be that
moderation in the domestic economy’s growth rate will remove demand-pull potential, and it
may be that tightening measures of our counterparts abroad will tamp down input prices for our
producers here, although it could have a counter-effect in terms of the exchange rate effect on the
costs of imports. But I do want to ask us to remember that inflation is—as stated in a paper that
was circulated previously—an inertial process. (The paper may have been from you, Bill.) We
must be very careful in word and in deed that we do not encourage impulses that will spur that
inertia and that will prove harder and more costly to rein in further down the road. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Minehan.
MS. MINEHAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Incoming data on the national
economy have been slightly lower on the growth side and slightly higher on the side of
continuing price escalation than at least we expected, and we have seen reflections of both these
trends in the New England economy. Overall, however, my sense is that growth for the region
and the nation remains relatively solid but that price pressures are a concern.

August 8, 2006

34 of 158

The region’s economy appears to continue to grow at a pace that will be sufficient to
keep local unemployment levels in the fours. The region has a slower pace of job growth than
the nation, but total personal income is growing at about the same pace. This suggests that per
capita income growth is relatively solid, which is reflected in rising retail sales and state income
tax collection. Indeed, local businesses continually comment on their inability to find skilled
labor so that at least some of the region’s slow job growth may be attributable to supply rather
than demand conditions.
New England’s residential housing correction is becoming more evident and, by some
measures, may be more significant than that for the nation as a whole. Home sales were
4 percent to 5 percent off their 2005 highs in the first quarter. That is similar to the nation, but
the Case-Shiller-Weiss repeat-sales index sees, at least for Q1, the nation’s home-price escalation
at about 10 percent year over year but Boston area prices up much less than that. More-recent
data from other surveys suggest that regional prices may be falling. Inventories of homes for
sale continue to grow, and the value of regional residential construction contracts fell more than
20 percent, compared with about 4½ percent for the nation. This number likely reflects the
relatively small amount of residential construction in the region, but the downturn is
eye-catching anyway. Despite this, consumer confidence rebounded a bit from earlier this
summer, and business contacts report relatively good performance.
Now, one thread in my recent conversations with businesses is not dissimilar to what
President Fisher just talked about. I found it a bit troubling that manufacturing and related
business services appear to believe that they have greater pricing power than before. They are
talking less about increasing competition and less about efforts to increase productivity. They
seem to be less worried about margin squeezes and more confident that rising input costs,

August 8, 2006

35 of 158

particularly those related to energy, can be passed on. Some even report that strong demand has
enabled them to raise prices or to avoid discounting even without major new input cost pressures.
In general, there was a disquieting tone of greater tolerance for inflation.
On the national scene, recent data on second-quarter growth, employment, and housing
market trends seem to indicate a general softening of the economy. This is not unexpected. All
of us have been forecasting a gradual slowdown to potential or slightly below over ’06 and ’07
as the economy makes a transition from consumer-led to business-led growth and the saving rate
climbs to a positive number. But has the evolving slowdown turned out to be a bigger soft patch
than expected, or are we simply suffering through the ups and downs of the transition process? I
am not sure of the answer to that question. I found the relatively low GDP and consumption
figures for late ’06 and ’07 in the Greenbook forecast a bit disquieting, even after recognizing the
effect of the benchmark revisions on potential GDP.
Our forecast in Boston had been in sync with the Greenbook’s and on the low side of the
range of forecasts around this table, but now we see growth of 0.6 to 0.7 percentage point above
the Greenbook in ’07. We’re not projecting as large a hit to residential investment over the
period, and we see solid disposable income offsetting high energy costs and lower housing
wealth to a greater degree than does the Greenbook. Moreover, although slow job growth is a
concern, at full employment or beyond how much of this is a supply rather than a demand
phenomenon, particularly when you take into account lower labor force participation?
Are firms hesitant to hire because they are fearful of the future or because they can’t find
the skills they need? They certainly are not constrained by a lack of resources. Thus, I am
inclined to the view that, although things seem slower than we expected and the Greenbook
forecast seems softer, not much has really changed since our last meeting. Consumer spending

August 8, 2006

36 of 158

has been relatively well maintained despite a weakness in Q2. Spending for equipment and
software appears to be in good shape. And net exports, given growth abroad, will be positive at
least for a time. Residential investment is waning, but how fast is hard to say, and there well
could be an offset to that from nonresidential investment. Financial markets remain
accommodative, and given the rise in inflation, real rates are down.
What is a bit different is the fact that inflation is growing at a faster pace in the short run
and is growing across most aspects of the core measure. Certainly it is faster and broader based
than I would like, and we continue to see leveling-off or falling price numbers only in the
forecast. I recognize that will continue to be the case for some time even in the best of
circumstances, but I am concerned that we may not face the best of circumstances. Geopolitical
events of all sorts and global demand continue to put pressure on input prices. Productivity
growth is likely slower, and economic activity may not wane enough to reduce resource
pressures. As time goes by and outsized inflation growth continues, one can imagine a sense of
inflation complacency growing. In that regard, as I noted earlier, I found the regional anecdotes
about making price increases stick of some concern.
I should note here that my own board of directors in a telephone meeting just yesterday
indicated concern about the ongoing strength of the economy and voted to maintain the current
primary credit rate. I myself worry about overdoing the tightening process, but as I told them, I
don’t think we’re at risk of that at present. Given the pace of inflation and given financial
market activity, real rates have, in fact, gone down not up, leaving policy and overall financial
conditions more accommodative than before our last increase. In sum, I continue to be a bit less
worried about variations in the cycle and more worried about the medium-term prospects for
inflation.

August 8, 2006

37 of 158

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Guynn.
MR. GUYNN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. In our last meeting I reported that, while our
Southeast economy still seemed reasonably solid, we were beginning to pick up anecdotal signs
that activity might be slowing. Well, that sluggishness is now gradually showing up in the data
as well. The slowing is perhaps most noticeable in our labor markets. Although we are still
hearing that businesses in some sectors are having problems finding workers, especially in areas
such as construction, accounting, and housekeeping, payroll employment figures for June in our
states were disappointing. They showed seasonally adjusted contraction with absolute declines
reported in Georgia, Tennessee, and Mississippi and less-than-expected job growth in Florida.
Employers seem to be trying their best to hold the line on staffing, given the sense that they have
of a slowing in the pace of growth and an uncertain outlook.
Manufacturing activity in our region is mixed. Consumer spending remains softer than
earlier in the year, and the tourism outlook is reported to be guardedly optimistic. The bright
spot in some ways is the Gulf Coast outside New Orleans, where the demand for most
construction materials and labor and for replacement household and personal goods is strong; but
that pocket of elevated spending is not enough to offset the sluggishness elsewhere. The big
semiannual apparel and gift mart show in Atlanta, where buyers just came to place their major
orders for expected year-end holiday sales, was reported to have been slow.
The regional bankers are reporting slowing in loan demand, particularly in the consumer
housing sectors. However, the experience in C&I lending is more mixed. At the same time,
credit quality, in the words of two bankers with whom we talked, was “unsustainably” or
“embarrassingly” good. Banks are also pulling back on their lending into the softening housing
market. Our data indicate that single-family construction remained relatively strong in the

August 8, 2006

38 of 158

District. Home sales have slowed, and there now have been sharp corrections in some markets,
especially coastal Florida.
Perhaps the most-talked-about new worry in our region, and something I mentioned for
the first time at our last meeting, is the growing problem of obtaining affordable wind, flood, and
related insurance in our coastal areas, resulting from the huge losses incurred by insurance
companies from hurricanes in recent years. Some carriers have quit offering coverage at any
price, and costs of policies that are available have increased at extraordinary rates. That problem
is affecting residential construction and sales and causing some businesses to pull up stakes and
move elsewhere. Together, the various developments that I have just ticked off have taken
considerable momentum out of the strong economic growth and outlook we were seeing in our
region earlier in the year.
Our sense of what’s happening at the national level is much the same. It now seems
reasonably clear that we have settled into a pattern of slower and probably subpar growth. We
saw evidence of that in the second-quarter GDP data and in the markedly slower employment
gains in recent months. The several models that our Atlanta staff now employs to forecast real
growth are suggesting somewhat slower growth in the 2½ percent to 3 percent range as being
most likely over the second half of this year and through 2007.
Getting a good handle on the inflation outlook is a bit harder. Our most recent Atlanta
modeling work produces a somewhat encouraging inflation path over the next 18 months, which
suggests that core inflation should stop its upward drift and gradually begin to move back toward
2 percent. That optimistic outlook is consistent with the most likely path laid out in the
Greenbook and with the central tendency of the forecasts we all submitted for the recent
congressional testimony. At the same time, even those optimistic forecasts do not seem to

August 8, 2006

39 of 158

indicate that core inflation is likely to move comfortably to within the ranges many of us have
indicated we would like eventually to see.
Of course, these encouraging longer-term or medium-term, as some have been calling it,
outlooks are very much at odds with the discouraging headline numbers and the increasingly
higher core inflation readings in recent months. There seems to be good reason to expect that
some of the coming near-term inflation data could well be disappointing before we begin to see
the expected improvement, and these current data help to shape inflation expectations. In one of
our recent briefings, an economist humbly observed that, despite all the work that has been done
and continues to be done in the profession, our models for forecasting inflation are still less than
stellar as judged by past experience. So we go into the policy discussion with some encouraging
inflation forecasts but having to acknowledge wide error bands and considerable uncertainty
around those forecasts. I look forward, I think, to an interesting but probably difficult policy
discussion. [Laughter] Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My outlook hasn’t changed very much
since last spring, when I was contemplating the not-so-welcome cycle of slowdown in economic
activity and some persistence in both headline and core inflation due to the lingering effects of
large energy-price increases. In fact, the Greenbook projections for real GDP now reflect
something close to the pessimistic end of where I thought things could be heading. The
difference is that I have been thinking more of a cyclical slowdown and not so much of a
slowdown in demand and supply, as reflected in the Greenbook baseline. The possibility that
slack might not be widening as economic growth moves down puts the recent inflation numbers
in a particularly bad light.

August 8, 2006

40 of 158

I have been especially concerned about how broadly based the inflationary pressures
appear to be. When you take energy components out of the CPI and you look at the median that
Richard was referring to earlier, about 67 percent of the expenditure-weighted items in the CPI
increased at an annual rate of 3 percent or more in June, which is about the same share that we
have seen since March. As Richard mentioned, the PCE statistics yield basically the same
results.
In Procter & Gamble’s most recent earnings report, the company attributed its good
earnings performance partly to the ability to pass on higher costs through to product prices, and I
am hearing similar remarks about pricing power from our directors and District business
contacts. Although my business contacts have been reporting some ability to pass on price
increases now at the retail level, where in the past they were saying that it was very difficult to
go beyond intermediate goods, they’re not so sure that they will get more than one-time catch-up
adjustments. Most of my business contacts have not expressed concerns about an elevation in
the long-term inflation trend.
Nevertheless, I think there are clearly reasons to be worried about the risk of inflationary
pressures intensifying over the balance of the projection period. I also think that there is a risk
that we’re not going to see as much slack as is embedded in the Greenbook baseline. As in many
other parts of the country, activity in the housing sector is slowing in the Midwest, particularly in
the Fourth District, and the housing situation in the Fourth District could never be characterized
as bubbly or frothy. Some of the veteran Realtors in my District with whom I have been talking
are saying that this housing market is the worst that they can recall. Comments like these,
although they are selected, do suggest some more uncertain prospects for the housing sector. My
directors and business contacts have also been sounding a bit more cautious about the outlook for

August 8, 2006

41 of 158

their sales, but at the same time their capital spending plans appear to be intact. They remain
vocal about the ability to get productivity gains, and they remain disciplined about their hiring
plans. So as I contemplate the weaker spending track that’s forecast in the Greenbook, I’m
inclined to attribute more of it to the demand side of the economy than to the supply side. That
is, I am expecting the Greenbook’s call for moderation in economic growth to result in a little
more slack than appears in the Greenbook’s baseline.
In a qualitative sense, my outlook carries lower inflationary pressure than the Greenbook
baseline and thus is similar in spirit to the “lower NAIRU” alternative scenario. Separating the
cyclical and structural performance of the economy, of course, is a real challenge, and it is
natural, I think, to feel unsure about the real-time estimates and projection of slack. If the slower
growth of potential output in the Greenbook baseline is accurate, it raises the possibility that the
equilibrium real interest rate may be lower than it was in the last half of the 1990s. In summary,
Mr. Chairman, I still think there are risks to both of our objectives. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Fifth District’s economy remains
generally strong, though overall growth appears to have moderated in recent weeks. Retail sales
have been lackluster, especially for big-ticket items. Manufacturing shipments and new orders
picked up in July, however, and our early readings for August are even stronger in suggesting
additional momentum going forward. District labor markets remain tight, with workers in some
skill categories hard to find in urban areas and temporary workers in demand. The housing
market continues to slow generally, although markets differ significantly across our District.
Current and expected price trend measures remain very elevated, according to our surveys, as
they have been for most of the year.

August 8, 2006

42 of 158

Turning to the national economy, I focused at our last two meetings on my concerns
about the deteriorating outlook for inflation, and the news over the intermeeting period has
heightened those concerns. But today I think it is important that we also assess carefully the
outlook for output and employment. I’m pretty sure that I can safely do so without danger of
being viewed as an output nutter. [Laughter]
GDP growth has been choppy in recent quarters; but over the past year and a half, output
has been growing at about 3½ percent. You get the same 3½ percent growth rate if you average
over the past three and a half years. We have substantially reduced the overhang of underutilized
resources over that period. Employment has grown about 1½ percent a year, and the labor force
has grown at just a little over 1 percent. I think the evidence is now fairly persuasive that
resources are approximately fully utilized in the sense that significant amounts of idle labor or
capital do not seem to be awaiting the return of better times.
What sorts of growth rates for output or employment are sustainable over the next two
years? The labor force appears likely to grow at about 1 percent—that is, about 110,000 jobs per
month. Labor productivity has been trending around 2½ percent over the past couple of years,
but I would be a bit more conservative going forward and expect about 2¼ percent per year,
closer to the long-run average. As a result, it seems reasonable to put the center point of an
estimate of a sustainable real growth rate at about 3¼ percent, with perhaps some extra above
that if you’re more optimistic about productivity growth.
Is this trend our best near-term forecast? Several factors could contribute to weaker real
growth. Residential investment will contract in the coming quarters as the housing market cools,
and lower average housing-price appreciation will reduce household wealth gains and damp
consumption growth. The upward sweep in energy prices has taken a bite out of real disposable

August 8, 2006

43 of 158

income as well, but I would expect real household spending to track real household income
going forward because both the housing-price adjustment and the energy-price run-up, so far at
least, look more like one-time reductions in household wealth and income and not like sources of
ongoing erosion extending out more than a year. So I think it is reasonable to expect
consumption to grow at close to 3 percent, down a bit from the average of 3½ percent over the
past several years.
Other factors seem likely to bolster growth. Business fixed investment spending has been
expanding quite strongly in this recovery. It is up at an annual rate of close to 7 percent since the
beginning of 2003, despite the sluggishness of structures until this year. In the second quarter,
BFI was up 6.8 percent year-over-year, and the most recent high-frequency indicators remain on
track. BFI spending as a share of GDP is still quite low by historical standards; and as the
Greenbook points out, the fundamentals—business balance sheets and output growth—look
quite solid. So it seems reasonable to expect business investment to continue to expand at a rate
close to 7 percent.
Putting everything together, I expect growth over the next year and a half to be just under
3 percent, or just more than ¼ percentage point below potential. The Greenbook forecast is
weaker—GDP growth at about 2¼ percent for the next six quarters—mainly because the Board
staff sees lower business investment spending and a pronounced reversal in the household saving
rate.
I think that a healthy respect for the uncertainty involved suggests that reasonable
confidence intervals around each of these forecasts—the Greenbook’s and my own and the
others I’ve heard today, for that matter—would include all the other point estimates and, more
important, would include the possibility that growth proceeds at potential over the forecast

August 8, 2006

44 of 158

period and beyond. So though it is reasonable to expect growth at or less than potential in the
near term, my sense is that it’s hard to be too certain that it will be much below for long.
As I said at the outset, the inflation picture has only worsened. The surge in core
inflation that began in March has continued into June. The monthly pattern—3.7 percent in
March at an annual rate, 2.7 in April, 2.8 in May, and 2.9 in June—makes this episode look less
and less like a temporary bulge and more and more like a sustained increase. It is worth noting
that the current acceleration in core inflation is broadly based, as the Greenbook emphasizes and
President Poole ably articulated, and not attributable to any narrow set of special factors.
The annual revisions to the national income and product accounts once again raised
inflation for past years, although not that much this time, as President Yellen noted. It now
appears that year-over-year core PCE inflation has exceeded 2 percent every month since April
2004. Perhaps the most striking change in the annual revisions, however, was in wages and
salaries. The puzzle of compensation growth bulging in 2005 and slowing in 2006 is now gone,
and it is now clear that compensation is on a broad upswing. The Board staff estimates that
nonfarm business compensation per hour accelerated from a trend around 4 percent to something
over 5½ percent. In fact, 5.4 percent was today’s release. Unit labor costs have deteriorated
accordingly and now show an annual rate of increase of 4.2 percent in the second quarter,
according to today’s release, and they are up 3.2 percent year over year. Before the NIPA
revisions, the behavior of unit labor costs suggested that the current increase in inflation was not
being incorporated into nominal wage compensation, but the labor cost data now show exactly
the opposite—that the acceleration of inflation in recent months has induced a broad acceleration
in nominal wages.

August 8, 2006

45 of 158

I find it hard to be confident that a surge in unit labor costs is likely to be absorbed by
falling markups. Measured markups have been trending up for some time, and I think they still
do after the revision. Our economic understanding of the determination of markups, especially at
the macroeconomic level, is still quite limited. In many models, the markup is entirely a real
phenomenon and thus would be invariant with respect to purely nominal accelerations in costs.
The main exceptions are the sticky-price models, but these don’t provide much comfort because
in them a high markup is a forecast of accelerating nominal marginal cost—that is to say, an
upswing in inflation. So I don’t take much comfort from the high level of markups.
Combining the growth and inflation outlooks, it is worth thinking carefully about the
extent to which we can expect slowing growth to bring inflation down. There have been a
number of skeptical comments about that hypothesis around the table today. The relationship
between output gaps and inflation is quite tenuous, as the staff rightly emphasizes whenever the
subject comes up. Empirically, the ability to discover this relationship relies heavily on
recessions and, thus, is much less reliable as an indicator of the effects on inflation of a small
widening of the gap. Indeed, at our last meeting and again today, David Wilcox characterized
the effect of the expected path of the output gap on inflation over the forecast period as tiny.
The combination of uncertainty about the relationship between output gaps and inflation and the
uncertainty about the degree to which growth is likely to fall short of potential should, I think,
leave us deeply skeptical about whether we can rely on expected moderation in growth to bring
inflation down. It is unfortunate that so many commentators placed so much weight on that in
response to our last statement.
Let me add a comment or two about President Yellen’s most excellent statement. I think
the insights she articulated about backward-looking inflation models breaking down and the

August 8, 2006

46 of 158

different inflation dynamics in forward-looking models is very important for our policy
deliberations. Her staff apparently has documented that inflation now looks more as though it’s
fluctuating around a sample average—I’ll say, a trend—and less as though it’s driven by output
gap measures. She concludes that we may see inflation fall faster than the Greenbook forecasts
do.
I want to register a couple of observations. The first is that, with forward-looking
expectations, inflation behavior is far more sensitive to changes in the public’s beliefs about our
behavior than in models in which inflation expectations formation is backward looking. I’d
register just the possibility that the long-run expected inflation that the public believes applies
has been drifting around and may, in fact, account for some of the swings of measured inflation
around sample averages. Finally, certainly taking the point of view that inflation expectations
are formed in a forward-looking manner makes more likely the possibility that inflation will
come down faster than the Greenbook states. But with inflation looking forward, it becomes our
responsibility to bring that about. So that happy outcome could require our action and our strong
communication, but I would welcome inspecting, if I could, the work of President Yellen’s staff,
and I welcome her contribution.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Good morning. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It’s a pleasure to be here
today at my first meeting. Many people around the table I’ve known for many, many years.
Others I don’t know so well, but I’m looking forward to getting to know you better. I realize that
as the new kid on the block, so to speak, I have a lot to learn. I’ve been on the job one week
today, and that realization has been driven home to me in the past week quite amply by the fact
that I’ve struggled to prepare for this meeting. I have to confess that it did occur to me at a

August 8, 2006

47 of 158

couple of points that maybe my start date should have been moved to August 15. [Laughter]
Maybe that was a failure of rational expectations or maybe just a simple forecast error—I’m not
sure yet. Nonetheless, I really am honored to be here and to be a part of this group, and I’m
looking forward to working with all of you.
Economic activity in the Third District continues to expand at a moderate pace, albeit
somewhat more slowly than earlier in the year. Of course, this was in line with expectations in
previous reports by Bill Stone to you. Regional manufacturing activity expanded in July. Our
business outlook survey’s index of general activity fell to 6 in July, down from 13 in June, and
the indexes of new orders and shipments also softened. But the levels of these indicators
continue to point to expansion in terms of manufacturing in the region and manufacturers’
expectations of future activity.
Conditions in our construction sector are similar to what other people have been
reporting. Nonresidential construction continues to strengthen in our District. Bankers are
reporting increased strength in commercial real estate lending. Office vacancy rates have been
edging down, and rents have been moving up. Our business contacts expect those trends to
continue. In contrast, as in much of the nation, residential construction and home sales are down.
Residential mortgage lending has slowed considerably, although home equity lending has been
quite strong. Realtors report that the inventory of homes for sale is at the highest level they’ve
seen in a number of years; they also report that prices are higher than they were last year, but the
rate of appreciation tends to be softening. Thus far the slowing in the region’s residential
housing sector seems to have been an orderly one.
Retailers report a firming of sales in general merchandise in June and July, with sales at
stores specializing in high-end merchandise being stronger than those at the lower end.

August 8, 2006

48 of 158

Manufacturers’ incentives have helped boost auto sales in July in the region, but dealers tell us
that inventories remain above their desired levels.
Payroll employment in our three states has been expanding at a somewhat slower pace
than in the nation as a whole, but that’s not atypical of the region. The unemployment rate has
edged down. In June, it was 4.7 percent. In most of the District’s labor markets, unemployment
is lower now than it was a year ago. Our business contacts continue to report difficulty in filling
positions. There has been some relief this summer with the influx of college students, but that
cushion is about to end. It has been particularly hard in the District for firms to fill professional
and managerial positions. Firms have received a good number of applications, but many of the
applicants are unqualified. Consequently, salaries for these positions have risen more than
others. Our manufacturers report that recent wage increases in the region are higher than they
were last year. This is consistent with the employment cost index, which shows stronger
compensation growth in the Northeast than in other parts of the nation. On balance, the regional
conditions and outlook continue to be positive. The rate of expansion in the second half of the
year is likely to be somewhat slower than in the first half; but, again, that was expected.
I’m more concerned about signs of continued and growing price pressures in the District.
Consumer prices appear to be rising at a faster pace in the Philadelphia region than in the nation
as a whole. One factor contributing to the faster pace has been the increase in housing costs in
metropolitan Philadelphia, but that may prove to be temporary as housing prices stabilize.
Nonetheless, broad-based cost pressures persist in most sectors of the region. The indexes of
both prices paid and prices received in our manufacturing survey have increased in July, and
both are at very high levels. Business contacts say that price pressures continue to be one of
their major concerns.

August 8, 2006

49 of 158

I would characterize the national economy in a somewhat similar way. That is, right now
I tend to be more concerned about inflation than I am about growth. I don’t view the
second-quarter slowdown as necessarily a precursor to a significant weakening of the economy
going forward. The below-trend growth in the second quarter was widely anticipated, and
averaging over the first two quarters, as several people have done, output still grew at over
4 percent in the first two quarters. The slowdown in residential investment was expected, and
much of the slowdown in consumer spending was due to auto sales, which are volatile and which
had grown very strongly in the first quarter and considerably less in the second.
One surprise, however, did occur in the second-quarter numbers. We expected business
investment in equipment and software to slow last quarter from its very robust pace in the first
quarter, but we didn’t expect an outright decline. About half that swing, it turns out, reflects the
timing of business purchases, particularly of transportation and autos, so the weakness in
investment may be more about timing than it is about trend. Indeed, as has been pointed out,
corporate profits remain high, and capacity utilization rates remain high, and these data continue
to point to the underlying strength in business investment.
The July employment numbers released on Friday did little to change my view of the
economy. Employment continues to grow at a reasonable pace, although somewhat slower than
earlier in the year. In July, employment in the private sector expanded at its fastest pace since
March. Although the number was not large, the trend was at least mildly encouraging.
Employment based on the household survey fell. The unemployment rate increased 0.2 percent,
but household employment has been volatile. The decline of 34,000 jobs in July followed a gain
of 387,000 jobs in the household survey in June. If we abstract from the month-to-month

August 8, 2006

50 of 158

volatility in these numbers, the unemployment rate remains low for the first half of the year at
about 4.7 percent.
At this point, I believe the economic indicators are consistent with sustained real growth
near trend, as many people have suggested. The benchmark GDP revisions suggest that trend
might be a tad lower than we thought, but nonetheless I think the risks to growth seem at least
roughly balanced.
The inflation picture, however, has not improved. Despite a slowing economy, price
increases have been accelerating. The increases have been broadly based, as has been pointed
out by Bill Poole and others. They are no longer confined to energy and other commodities.
Indeed, in June the CPI rose less than did the CPI excluding energy. Core inflation is above the
range I consider to be consistent with price stability, and to my mind, inflation risks remain tilted
to the upside. The Greenbook’s baseline forecast has core inflation decelerating over the next
year, but the staff has been marking up its forecasted path of inflation over time as the
acceleration in inflation has persisted. Even with the projected deceleration, the baseline forecast
has core PCE inflation remaining above 2 percent through 2007.
Given this persistence in inflation, unacceptably high inflation seems likely to be around
for a while. A year ago I wouldn’t have said that. In fact, I was in the camp that thought it was
mostly a relative price phenomenon, but that position has become less compelling to me over the
past year. The benchmark revisions to the GDP report show that both compensation per hour
and unit labor costs have been trending up, not down as earlier data suggested. Energy-price
increases have not abated, suggesting that we are likely to see continued pass-through to core
inflation, perhaps for some time. Although the Committee has brought the fed funds rate up
appreciably from historically low levels, real interest rates to my mind are not high. I don’t view

August 8, 2006

51 of 158

monetary policy as particularly restrictive at this point. Thus, I have to put some weight on the
Greenbook’s alternative scenario of persistently high inflation, and that leads to particularly poor
outcomes. Even if I accept the baseline forecast as my point forecast, the fact that inflation
remains at a level above the range consistent with price stability for a considerable period is
troubling.
I am comforted by the fact that medium- and longer-term inflation expectations have
remained relatively stable despite the acceleration in inflation. That’s a testament to the
credibility of the Fed in the marketplace—that it will keep inflation low. But how reasonable is
it to think that inflation expectations will remain unchanged? By allowing inflation to remain at
a high level for a time—we are, after all, as several people have pointed out, in the third year of
core inflation running above 2 percent—do we risk sending the message that we are willing to
tolerate higher inflation? If so, will expectations adjust accordingly? As the model simulations
of optimal policy paths and outcomes in chart 7 of the Bluebook indicate, it’s very costly to get
inflation back down once it has been above our objective, particularly if expectations are allowed
to increase. I believe that monetary policy has an important role to play in ensuring that the
recent high inflation readings do not raise longer-term inflation expectations. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As has been observed, growth moderated in
the second quarter largely as anticipated. The economy is perhaps returning to a sustainable pace
of growth—one, I would add, that may be above the Greenbook forecast for next year. As I
thought about the Greenbook, much of it seemed plausible to me; but our VAR models provide
somewhat more rapid growth next year. When I step back and think about various components
of aggregate demand, it seems to me that we might get a bit more out of business investment in

August 8, 2006

52 of 158

equipment and software and net exports, and I think the supply side of the economy is
sufficiently flexible to accommodate that.
With regard to inflation and its prospects, little has changed from the last meeting in my
opinion, and I doubt much will change in the near term, or at least not much will change for the
better in the near term. This suggests to me that we should be prepared to see core inflation
running on a year-over-year basis near or above 2½ percent for several more months, perhaps
several more quarters. I haven’t heard anything from the business people with whom I’ve been
in contact that suggests that a moderation of inflation is at hand or that aggregate demand,
demand for goods and services, is slowing in an unanticipated way, except for what is turning
out to be a pretty mediocre tourism season in our District.
One distinctly positive development—and I think Charlie just referred to this—has been
the stability of inflation expectations in the face of incoming information on inflation that might
have led to some upward revision in those expectations. The fact that expectations have
remained well anchored so far is something that looks positive to me.
Overall, as I try to assess the risks, it seems to me that the near-term inflation risks are
tilted to the upside even though I continue to expect core inflation to ease back down in the
longer term. As for the risks associated with growth, I think here uncertainty has increased.
However, against the background of the latest Greenbook forecast, I think maybe the risks to
growth are also tilted to the upside. Only I wouldn’t use the term “risks”—I would consider that
to be a positive development if in fact it occurred.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Mr. Chairman, thank you. Obviously we are dealing with a difficult set
of circumstances. We have information that the growth of the economy is slowing and inflation

August 8, 2006

53 of 158

is rising, not something we particularly like to see. We have seen slowing consumption
nationally, and certainly our District has seen some of it. The one exception is in some areas
where we have an energy boom going on, which is not necessarily advantageous to other parts of
the country. We also have slowing residential investment in our District. Inventories are
building up rapidly, both in the eastern side of the District and in the Denver western side, and
we have some pretty sharp increases in bankruptcy levels in the Denver area. The shocks of
energy costs have affected consumption, and I think that effect will carry through. We have been
more optimistic about manufacturing. Even though our surveys have shown some slowdown
recently, the six-months-ahead forecasts are still fairly optimistic.
There is no denying that the inflation level is up, and I think that increase reflects past
policy accommodation that is still in play. I also think that some of the supply shocks are having
their effects, and the shocks themselves are continuing forward. That situation is being
aggravated a bit for our District, and perhaps will be even more for the nation, by the drought
that we are experiencing, which is reducing some of the crop output in the area. The outlook,
therefore, is not particularly encouraging. I think consumption will show some further slowing
going forward, especially as we see further shocks in the economy related to energy. Some of
the wealth effects related to the housing industry will also affect consumption going forward.
The outlook in terms of business fixed investment is unclear. BFI has been pretty good. The
outlook seems fairly good right now, but it is slowing to some degree. Policy is moderately, not
significantly, restrictive, but it seems to be working its way through fairly slowly.
While these factors are in place, we worry about whether the real rate will decline, which
I think Mike Moskow mentioned. I also worry that the decline will affect inflation expectations
and cause them to shift—that is an upside risk to the economy in terms of the inflation that I do

August 8, 2006

54 of 158

worry about. Still, I suggest that we are moving as expected. We have some short-term
inflationary pressures that are going to continue, that are “baked in the cake,” as they say. And I
do worry that—as we move forward and if the economy slows, as I suspect it will—our big
challenge will be not to ease too soon. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Poole.
MR. POOLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to offer just a few anecdotes, starting
with Wal-Mart. At the beginning of the year, Wal-Mart’s plan for same-store sales was for
growth of 3 percent to 5 percent, but growth has run persistently below that since Easter. July
came in at 2.6 percent. They had expected a range of 1 to 3 percent. However, I think we have
to be a little careful in interpreting July data in general because it was unusually hot over much
of the country, and Wal-Mart says that they particularly sold a lot of what they call “hot weather
goods,” like air conditioners and fans. My contact says that higher-priced items with higher
margins are generally doing better than the lower-priced goods. He is still seeing pressures on
the lower-income shoppers at Wal-Mart. Food inflation is actually coming down a bit: It is now
below 1 percent. My contact observed that suppliers seem to have paused in taking price
increases, but he’s not sure whether that’s just part of a cycle during the year. He also noted that
the rate of price deflation is also less than it was for a number of items—particularly apparel and
standard electronics items—that have been deflating for quite a number of years. Those prices
are still declining but not as rapidly as before.
I had two readings from the transportation industry suggesting that July was surprisingly
weak. UPS Express volume in July came in 3 percent to 4 percent below plan, and a large
trucking company said that the July truck volume was flat year over year and the weakness was
pretty much spread over all parts of the country, although more pronounced in the upper

August 8, 2006

55 of 158

Midwest. It seems to be broadly based in terms of product category. He said that in the trucking
industry, or at least in his firm, they are increasingly nervous about recession.
UPS noted that there is potential for disruption. Their pilots’ union is currently in a
ratification vote, which is supposed to be complete by September 1. There’s a great deal of
opposition within the union and some genuine possibility that the contract will be voted down,
with associated job actions and disruption of various sorts. My FedEx contact said he really had
nothing new, and he didn’t even want to talk about that. [Laughter]
Let me make a comment about the national economy. I want to talk about it in terms of
the risks we face and to use a Phillips curve diagram as a device. We’ll center the axes on the
Greenbook forecast. One of the quadrants here has higher growth and lower inflation than
forecast. I think we’re not very likely to be in that quadrant—it’s not impossible, but I don’t
think it’s probable. So let’s talk about the other three quadrants. One of them has good growth
and higher inflation. We could end up in that quadrant, and that would just mean that we’re
going to have the problem of dealing with the inflation over the longer haul even though our
immediate future might not have a growth complication. Quite frankly, I think we’re most likely
going to be dealing with one of the other two quadrants. One of them has lower growth with
declining inflation. I think the inflation pressures are pretty persistent and sustained, so I think
we’re actually most likely going to end up in the very unfortunate quadrant where we have
sustained inflation pressures running at the Greenbook forecast rate or above and growth running
at that rate or lower. That situation is going to be very uncomfortable for us, but we’re going to
have to be ready to deal with it. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman Geithner.

August 8, 2006

56 of 158

VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Growth has moderated,
but the economy still seems, to us at least, likely to grow at a reasonably good pace over the
forecast period, somewhere in the vicinity of 3 percent. We expect core inflation to moderate
gradually from current levels, declining to around 2 percent in ’07. This forecast assumes that
monetary policy follows a path fairly close to what’s in the market and in the Greenbook.
The key difference between our view of the outlook and that of the Greenbook forecast is
in the strength of demand growth relative to potential next year. We have reduced a bit our
estimate of potential and also of actual growth, but we still expect the economy to expand at a
rate close to potential. This is a very favorable forecast, and we have to recognize, of course,
that the economy is going through a set of extremely complicated transitions, including a large,
adverse, sustained relative price shock of uncertain duration and a substantial adjustment in asset
prices that is now concentrated in housing. Our capacity to anticipate the evolution of these
forces and to assess their effect on growth and inflation is, of course, very limited. The forces
that now appear to be working on the economy still present the unpleasant combination of upside
risk to inflation and downside risk to growth; but for the moment we believe that the former, the
possibility that our forecast is too optimistic on inflation, remains the predominant risk.
I have a few points on the growth outlook. The economy has clearly slowed, and the
composition of growth within the United States and here relative to the rest of the world has
changed. These changes were inevitable, and if they continue to occur smoothly, they seem
desirable and necessary. As a share of aggregate demand within the United States, residential
investment had to contract and consumption had to slow. And U.S. domestic demand had to
slow relative to domestic demand growth in the rest of the world. The key issue we face is

August 8, 2006

57 of 158

judging whether we have significantly more weakness ahead of us than we are now expecting.
In our view, most signs at present point to fundamentally healthy economic conditions.
The survey-based measures of confidence are holding up okay. Real household income
growth seems likely to be good going forward. Businesses have the resources and the motivation
to sustain fairly strong rates of investment growth. Structural productivity growth, even postrevision, still seems strong. Inventory levels remain relatively thin, and the tentativeness that
characterized much of the expansion in terms of investment and hiring should be a source of
some comfort. Global demand is still quite strong, of course, and together these forces will
offset part, but not all, of the weakness coming from the adjustment in housing and consumption
growth. The principal risk to this outlook for growth lies in the possibility that households will
slow consumption more sharply because of rising energy costs, higher interest rates, greater
pessimism about future income gains, or the effect of the housing adjustment on perceived
wealth.
Financial markets are showing a little more concern about future growth, but not a lot.
This concern is most evident in the greater inversion in the yield curve that has emerged at the
one-year to two-year horizon. I think you can see in the market some moderation of exuberance
in credit markets, but just a little. Overall, the markets seem to reflect a reasonably favorable
view of future growth prospects.
On the inflation side, as I said, we expect core inflation to moderate, not quickly and not
dramatically but by enough and soon enough to bring core PCE inflation down to just below
2 percent over the next 18 months. The issue we face is not so much about the acceleration in
core inflation that occurred in late 2003 and 2004. After that acceleration, core inflation was sort
of trendless, in the vicinity of 2 percent for much of the two-year period, until the past six

August 8, 2006

58 of 158

months, when we saw this uptick. The real problem we face is assessing the extent to which the
very recent acceleration in core inflation reflects transitory factors, such as the indirect effects of
energy prices, and the extent to which it may reflect pressures from higher resource utilization
and other things less benign and less transitory. Energy pass-through, of course, seems part of it,
but probably not all of it. Shelter doesn’t account for all of it either. This judgment is critical for
us, and we need to be careful that we’re not assuming away the more uncomfortable explanation,
such as a broader inflationary impulse or a rise in pricing power that could reflect increasing
acceptance of higher inflation.
How confident can we be that the pressures that have induced this rise in core inflation
will moderate sufficiently to bring down the rate of increase in core PCE prices to the vicinity of
2 percent or below? Reasonably confident, I think. With the economy growing at or slightly
below trend, with growth of unit labor costs peaking and decelerating a bit as the Greenbook
forecast anticipates, with inflation expectations moderating at short horizons and pretty stable at
longer-run horizons, with energy prices flattening out, and with the dollar falling only a little,
this forecast seems reasonable. But note the number of assumptions and conditions this forecast
depends on. Also, the expected path for inflation implies only a very gradual moderation and a
period of sustained inflation above what is presumed to be consistent with this central bank’s
long-term preferences. The risks of this forecast, as I said, still seem to lie on the upside. It may
be some time before we can be confident that the forces are in place to produce the necessary
moderation.
More generally, however, we face the very difficult consequential challenge of trying to
figure out the longer-term consequences of having been in an exceptionally long period of
exceptionally low real interest rates—both real short rates and forward rates—that were induced

August 8, 2006

59 of 158

by monetary authorities here and around the world. Real short rates now look as though they
were perhaps lower relative to the estimates of equilibrium even than we thought. Perhaps more
remarkable was the low level of forward real rates during much of our tightening phase. These
financial conditions may have produced more inflation momentum than we thought, and this
may be the case even though there is some reassurance in the stability of long-term expectations.
Those expectations are substantially below the peak in ’04 at the long horizon.
However, the rise in asset prices and residential investment and the leverage caused by
this long period of very expansionary monetary policy may lead to a process of adjustment in
asset prices that could be more sustained and more damaging in terms of confidence and of
demand than we expect. This risk is greater if we end up allowing more inflation than our
forecast anticipates, for the required monetary policy response could induce an even sharper
adjustment in risk premiums and asset prices. This possibility argues for a lot of humility in
judging the appropriateness of the present stance of monetary policy and what will be
appropriate over time, and it argues mostly for having as much flexibility as we can going
forward, emphasizing that the inflation risks remain the predominant concern of the Committee.
Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As many of you have remarked, the inflation
news over the intermeeting period was not favorable. Core consumer prices continued to run at
an elevated level, and the CPI actually came in on the high side of expectations. The shortfall in
the PCE that President Yellen referenced was, I think, more of those mysterious nonmarket
components. Petroleum prices rose further, implying additional feed-through going forward.
Prices of other commodities, as Karen remarked, were on average unchanged to somewhat

August 8, 2006

60 of 158

higher, suggesting not only continuing cost pressures on producers but sustained strength in
global demand. Early estimates of unit labor costs for the second half of last year and the first
half of this year show a faster increase than had been estimated and anticipated. The
compensation data for the early part of this year, in particular, are subject to very large revisions.
Even the now-faster growth doesn’t necessarily indicate that the economy has been operating
beyond its sustainable potential, given the likelihood of some catch-up with past productivity
gains, the still quite elevated profit margins, and the moderate increase in the ECI. But at the
very least, the unit labor cost story doesn’t provide as much comfort about future inflation as it
did previously. Largely as a consequence, the staff revised up its inflation forecast for 2006 and
2007, and that response seems reasonable to me.
At the same time, some developments over the intermeeting period help me feel a touch
more comfortable, or perhaps a touch less uncomfortable, with the downward trajectory for
inflation after the bulge. One of them that a number of you have mentioned from surveys is that
the long-term inflation expectations in the market remained stable or even edged down a little
despite higher energy prices and, importantly, despite downward revisions to the expected path
of monetary policy. If I were forecasting today, I would forecast a slightly higher inflation rate,
but I would also forecast a slightly higher unemployment rate than I did before. To be sure,
output gaps, as you’ve mentioned, don’t play a large role in determining inflation, but certainly
the growth of demand relative to potential has some effect on the competitive conditions that
businesses are facing and on their ability to pass through costs.
From the information that we received over the intermeeting period, growth slightly
below the growth rate of the economy’s potential seems more likely than it seemed a month or so
ago, and this would inhibit the pass-through of higher energy and labor costs. Weakness in the

August 8, 2006

61 of 158

housing sector has deepened, and we have not yet seen the full implications of the rise in
long-term and short-term interest rates over the first half of the year. This weakness seems to be
having an effect on housing prices as well as on activity. The effects of a lower expected
trajectory for housing wealth and the increase in interest rates this year haven’t begun to show
through to consumption, judging from the minus 1½ percent saving rate. The energy-price
increases of recent weeks will take something more out of consumption.
Recent data are consistent with a below-trend track for the growth of economic activity:
Private domestic final purchases increased at a rate of only 2 percent in the second quarter. The
consumption and investment data for late months in the quarter don’t suggest an acceleration
going into the third quarter. The growth of employment has been running slightly below what
would be a steady-state pace if participation were to remain stable, and participation has edged
higher. The greater increase than had been anticipated in inventories in the second quarter
suggests little impetus or even a small drag from inventory accumulation in the third and fourth
quarters. The growth of federal government spending seems to be dropping back a bit as
Katrina-related expenditures top out. Moreover, the recent higher rates of core inflation, though
they are puzzling to a considerable extent, must reflect some influences that are unlikely to be
repeated indefinitely into the future. One of those is the rise in oil and energy prices. The recent
rise clearly has been associated with escalating tension in the Mideast and other producing areas,
as well as the recent cutback in supply from Alaska. At some point, the risks of supply
disruptions, while remaining very high, should level out. As a consequence, so, too, should
energy prices, which will reduce core inflation as the feed-through fades.
Another factor boosting inflation in recent months was related to rising rents and, in
particular, to an even greater increase in owners’ equivalent rent. The staff has assumed that

August 8, 2006

62 of 158

owners’ equivalent rent will rise in line with other rents and that both will continue to increase
fairly rapidly but less rapidly than they did. That seems reasonable to me, given the increased
availability of houses and apartments on the market that would, at some point, seem to limit the
rise in rents as well as house prices.
So my conclusion is that the staff forecast of a gradual moderation of core inflation after
the second quarter is a reasonable expectation, although I am very worried about upside risks to
inflation. The inflation rate looks as though it will end up a tad higher than either the staff or I
thought likely at the time of our June meeting. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Bies.
MS. BIES. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think our decision today is going to be a close
call because of the recent information we’ve gotten both on inflation and on the growth of the
economy. We know that, as President Poole and others have mentioned, wage and price
inflation has been accelerating and is fairly broadly based. The recent NIPA revisions also
concern me because of the faster growth in core PCE prices that those data show. The business
surveys, in fact, show that companies feel they have more pricing power than they have had in
the past. We know that we are going to have some continuing feed-through of the higher prices
of oil. After talking to some folks in the oil industry, I am concerned about the recent Alaska
situation. It clearly shows that maintenance of equipment and the efficiency of the operations of
some of these companies may be under stress with the high volumes of capacity at which they
have been running. We pray that it doesn’t extend much further in additional surprises.
What also concerns me about the NIPA revisions are the changes in the productivity
numbers. The fact that with the NIPA revisions we are seeing lower productivity and fasterrising labor costs has implications for our forward expectations on inflation. We also see that

August 8, 2006

63 of 158

business investment in equipment and software was much lower. That downward revision
worries me because it implies that less capital deepening has occurred, and that would have been
a strong base to support productivity going forward. Now we apparently cannot rely on it as a
base as much as we could before the revisions.
In terms of the housing markets, the rapid escalation of home sale cancellations clearly
has been very surprising. Again, the gross sales figures don’t show this, but the information
we’ve got on the cancellations indicates a much more pronounced slowdown than we might have
expected. In looking through other housing cycles and in talking to bankers and lenders, one of
the good things I find is that the industry learned in the 1980s. Because those in the industry are
more sophisticated in the way they manage their land costs and their inventory, I think the length
of the cycle is unlikely to be as long. In the 1980s, bankers made plenty of funds available for
companies to continue to develop land and to put in infrastructure. When the housing bubble
burst, all of a sudden we had unsold housing units. They had to be sold before builders could
start building on the developments that had already been laid out, and it took us several years to
work through that. This time we don’t have the unfinished inventory of developments that we
had in the ’80s. So I think that the cycle is likely to be much shorter than it was then and that it
will put some firmness in that market. At the same time, this is the sector, aside from energy and
commodities, that had a very rapid rise in prices, and it’s good that we’re seeing some correction
in those prices right now.
The other good trend that I take comfort in is the one that Dino mentioned earlier—that
we’re seeing central banks around the world raising rates. When we started raising our rates a
couple of years ago, there weren’t too many moving at the same time we did. We know that
today monetary policy has global effects: Excessive accommodation in some countries clearly

August 8, 2006

64 of 158

can affect investments in other countries. So I think we now have support in what we’re doing to
remove accommodation. We’re seeing that support more broadly across the world; and in the
aggregate, then, it will help to moderate inflation in the period going forward. Finally, I’m
reminded that we do have long lags in monetary policy, and we still have to see the full impact of
what we have already put in train. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. I see it’s 11:00, and I’m told that coffee is
ready outside. Why don’t we take a fifteen-minute break. Thank you.
[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. David Wilcox has a couple of comments on the productivity
data from this morning.
MR. WILCOX. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Just very briefly, these data came in, in most
respects, pretty close to our expectation. I would note that the productivity figures for the second
quarter are built on the output data that were incorporated in last week’s advance GDP number. We
expect nonfarm business productivity in the second quarter to be revised up. Based on information
available today, it would be revised up 0.8 percentage point, to 1.9 percent. Probably because of
some fluctuations in hours, the productivity number in Q1 is 0.3 percentage point stronger than we
had expected. In Q2, it’s 0.3 percentage point weaker. On balance, the profile there looks much as
we had expected. Compensation per hour is 0.5 percentage point stronger in Q1 than we had
projected and right on our Greenbook projection in Q2.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Let’s turn now to Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Treasury markets have convinced
themselves in recent days and weeks of the prospects of lower growth, lower rates, and some degree
of comfort with inflation, and they seem to have lurched to that on a somewhat accelerated basis in

August 8, 2006

65 of 158

the past several weeks. But with some degree of humility, I’ll say I’m not quite as convinced as
they are. I suspect that they may lose some of their conviction if some of the data that we’ve all
talked about this morning around this table come to pass. So we need to be keen in looking at
inflation expectations, at the shape of the curve, and at the prices of some of these Treasury
securities to evaluate the market reaction to what we do.
I have just a couple of other general comments. We’ll have readings on inflation soon, but
I’m not persuaded that we will have a good view of how persistent inflation will likely be. I suspect
it will continue to trend to the upside and will beg those markets for a further review of the state of
inflation expectations. Similarly, I am not sure we’re going to have definitive views on growth. I
had a lot of discussions with a whole host of folks in the consumer and business sectors. They are
hearing, much as we are, top-down estimates for lower growth in the second half, but their own
bottom-up analysis doesn’t seem to be bearing that out even here in the second quarter. The only
thing I’d note at the outset from the BEA revisions is that, though growth has come down somewhat
over the historical period, quarter-over-quarter variance seems to be at least as pronounced as it was
in the original dataset; so the data are likely to be rather volatile, I would suspect, as we look
through the forecast period.
With that in mind, I thought I’d take a couple of minutes looking at growth in the consumer
and business sectors and then spend a few moments on inflation. With respect to the consumer
sector, I am probably more convinced at this meeting than even before that great tumult is going on
below the surface. In discussions with some of the big credit card processors, I asked them to tell
me what they’re seeing. They’re seeing huge changes in categories of purchases and even in the
types of purchases if we exclude energy and gas products. In sum, however, consumer spending
looked quite strong to most of them through June and, importantly, through the first month of the

August 8, 2006

66 of 158

third quarter. Although they had talked to their boards about lower volume in the second half, they
have yet to see it in much of their data across a range of lower-income Americans as well as
Americans with higher net worth. They’re not seeing much softness at all. The other piece coming
out of those discussions is that they had expected to see a ramp-up in delinquencies—again, with
much vaunted news of a slowing housing sector, higher energy prices, and a slower second half—
and they have not. The news about delinquencies continues to be very encouraging going into the
third quarter. It also raises the question of whether or not we’re going to see an inflection point.
With all the discussions about the slower second half, we would have expected that personal
consumption would have shown some more-meaningful effect than the data suggest. So I’m not
persuaded that several meetings from now we’re going to have this “aha” moment and that we’re
going to see this inflection point. On the growth front, I still have the view that growth continues to
be above the Greenbook projection. But I am more concerned, of course, about inflation.
I have just a couple of other points of interest on the consumer front. The July index of
consumer sentiment does not suggest much of a slowdown in consumer confidence, and when I
looked at the surveys since our last meeting, I came to a couple of conclusions. When the surveys
ask questions such as “How are you doing?” and “What is your personal financial condition?” the
numbers tend to go in a rather positive direction. “I’m doing pretty well, not great” is the answer, if
you cut through the data. When the surveys ask other questions such as “How is your neighbor
doing? or “What is the state of the economy or the state of business conditions?” the answer we’re
getting is, “Well, my neighbor is having all sorts of troubles.” If we’re trying to judge the economy
by what folks know best of all, I guess I don’t see much of a reason to expect that some of the
worst-case scenarios will come to pass.

August 8, 2006

67 of 158

Federal tax receipts, which I mention at most of our meetings, for July showed year-over­
year growth of about 13 percent. The gains in wages and salaries implied by these increased tax
collections finally make some more sense in light of the recasting of the official data from last
week’s revisions, with real wages and salaries having risen 3.4 percent over the past year, which is
about a six-year high.
Turning now to the business sector, I put myself as probably as confident as most around the
table on the state of this sector, though I have heard some talk of a diminution in “animal spirits.”
But if you look at the data, you see that, as discussed this morning, the ratio of profits to GDP is at a
record high. Momentum continues to be quite strong, with credit spreads low, acceleration in
business sales, and low ratios of inventories to sales; all these factors seem to speak to some
underlying strength.
The manufacturing sector, despite some noisy data on jobs and employment, appears to be
in an incredibly strong position. The ISM manufacturing index, PMI, and industrial production,
which advanced at an annual rate of about 6.6 percent during the second quarter, are all very
positive indicators about the manufacturing sector. We also continue both to hear anecdotes and to
see data about real pricing power in that sector, which is good news on the growth front and
probably gives us a couple of questions on the inflation front.
Finally, Dino referred at the outset to some of the bottom-up analyst estimates for profits in
the second quarter and the second half, and I said a couple of meetings ago that we should really
take note of these to see whether they flatten out. They appear to be possibly flattening out a touch,
but you have to do quite a bit of work to get there. Second-quarter profits will end up above
15 percent once the S&P companies all report. Some lower earnings guidance is being given over
the forecast period; but throughout that period, earnings would still be up 11 percent or so compared

August 8, 2006

68 of 158

with similar quarters last year—all of which is quite encouraging and comes as surprisingly positive
news to boards of directors of these companies, who had heard about the slowdown but aren’t
seeing it so dramatically.
One area about which I spoke earlier was the capital expenditure number in the second
quarter. President Plosser probably summarized the point well in explaining that we should
probably look through that number because of some volatile transportation-related orders.
Moreover, when I look at the second half of this year and at 2007, other data on unfilled orders
appear very positive. Pent-up demand for cap-ex should be higher, given that the past three years
had growth rates of 6.4 percent rather than the 8.3 percent that we had earlier anticipated. The only
other thing I would note about cap-ex is that there seems to be greater dispersion by industry and by
sector. Technology and telecom do seem to be more disciplined in this cap-ex wave than maybe
many of us, including myself, would have anticipated. I suspect that, with continued talk about the
slowdown in the second half, spending on tech and telecom will be bumpy and may drag some of
the aggregate cap-ex numbers down substantially. As I look at the business sector, I find myself
asking the key question of whether this industrial economy, as robust as I think it is, will boost labor
demand and personal income. I suspect the answer to that question is “yes”; but again, it’s hard to
be too definitive at this point.
On the inflation front, I share the views expressed by most folks around the table of some
degree of calmness and pleasure about the stability of inflation expectations. But when I think
about what has happened to the bond market, particularly in the past couple of weeks, and the rather
robust moves that the bond market made at the end of last week, I could be easily persuaded that
those inflation expectations will move against us as data come in between this meeting and the next.

August 8, 2006

69 of 158

I would probably describe many of these inflation expectations as relatively calm; but if I had to
guess, I’d say that they’re probably a bit more wobbly than we would like.
Further on the bad news front, and I think President Fisher and President Poole made
reference to this, no matter how we slice some of the core PCE data and some of the CPI data, even
if we look at things like non-energy services, the trend is not our friend on a three-month or
six-month average. Most of us would not expect it to be our friend over the next six months.
Again, the question is how persistent the trend is, and I have genuine concerns on that front. As the
inflation data are likely to deteriorate, we obviously have to look at a broad range of GDP outcomes
for the balance of 2006. In particular, I took note of the Greenbook’s simulation of persistent
inflation to a 3 percent core, which I would consider a genuine risk, and although the Greenbook
simulation suggests that the fed funds rate would need to go only to 5.9 percent, I’m probably more
concerned that we might have more work to do if that series of events came to pass.
Finally, let me quickly note the labor compensation front. I believe that many of the gains
shown on that front have been quite surprising on the upside. They have been good news for most
workers over the past couple of years, and they help explain that conundrum, which we’ve heard as
each of us have sat before this table and been asked on Capitol Hill: How is it that productivity is so
remarkably high and compensation so remarkably low? Have the gains to trade and to capital and
labor changed? I think these data suggest that they haven’t. If, in fact, we do see continued
acceleration in compensation gains—even, as the Greenbook suggests, to 5½ percent—I suspect the
markets again will look to that and will take it at face value that those gains are likely to be more
inflationary than many of us around the table believe. I think that’s another concern.
On balance, I’d summarize my own position as being considerably more concerned about
the inflation picture than about the growth picture. As Vice Chairman Geithner said, there are

August 8, 2006

70 of 158

confidence intervals around all of these that are hard for us to bang the table in support of. The
work that we have from this meeting to the next will become particularly important. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kroszner.
MR. KROSZNER. Thank you very much. As the comments indicate, this is probably the
most challenging time that we have had before us in my long history here at the FOMC. [Laughter]
The mix of continuing inflation pressures and decelerating growth are providing more concerns on
both fronts than I have heard around the table and than I myself have had since I’ve been here.
First let’s think about some of the growth prospects. I broadly share the Vice Chairman’s
view that the fundamentals are in place for reasonable growth going forward. Certainly there are
some risks. But whether we are looking at survey-based measures, at orders and shipments, or at a
variety of different things, we don’t really see signs of very significant deceleration or contraction.
We see more a moderation that would be either in line with the Greenbook or a bit lower than the
Greenbook.
Certainly a key risk to growth that a lot of people have discussed is residential investment.
If you look at where we are in residential investment, we’re back only to mid-2003; 2004 and 2005
were incredibly strong years. So being in 2003 is not that bad. If you look at the graph, residential
investment falls off rather precipitously to get us back to 2003 with great rapidity. The question I
have is whether it will flatten out or whether it will go down further. The Greenbook forecasts have
gradually been moving down and now reflect more downward pressure going forward. I think that
we’re not seeing the full effects on house prices reflected in the numbers because in the housing
market, for reasons I don’t think we fully understand, there tend to be queuing rather than just price
changes. So it may take a while for the price data to actually reflect the lower effective prices that

August 8, 2006

71 of 158

people are seeing. Obviously house prices will have a potentially important effect on the wealth
effect and on consumption down the line, which I think the Greenbook does a good job of putting
into place.
Another challenge is elevated prices for energy and commodities. Energy prices,
particularly, may be taking a little bite out of people’s disposable income. On the other hand, we
have been seeing continued strong business fixed investment. A small concern I have is, if we
continue to hear about slowing consumption and reports from Wal-Mart and others that retailing is
really slowing, why are these businesses producing? Are they investing to produce goods that
people will want to buy, or will we see in nine months or a year that maybe some misallocation of
resources has occurred and that things aren’t as strong as we had thought? There’s no particular
sign of such misallocation of investment. It just seems that there is a bit of tension between the
discussions of continued strength of capital expenditures and the statements of business contacts
that they are going to continue to invest even though they see a slowing coming down the line. This
is a variation of what Governor Warsh was saying—it’s almost as though they are saying that some
other sector will have that slowing, not their sector.
In some sense, we should take very cold comfort from the fact that the economy may be
slowing. We had quite a discussion about how there’s not much of an inflation–output tradeoff, but
at least in this period there are real questions of whether you do get much benefit in terms of lower
inflation from slower growth. There may be some benefit, but it seems to be attenuated compared
with the past. Obviously some of the recent numbers on inflation continue to be worrisome, but
fortunately both the survey measures and the market-based measures seem to be reasonably
contained looking forward. Survey measures, whether of the man in the street or of the professional
forecaster, seem to be quite flat. The TIPS rates for both the near-term forwards and the

August 8, 2006

72 of 158

longer-term forwards have not moved up much. Some of the near-term forwards have moved up a
bit, but that doesn’t seem surprising given the rise in energy prices that we have seen both from the
Middle East and from issues in Alaska.
The real key is looking forward as to what is likely to occur. Are the things we’re seeing
now transitory factors or persistent factors? That’s a very, very difficult call. Reasonable
arguments have been made that a number of these factors, particularly with respect to shelter
services, are perhaps a bit more short-lived. Shelter services are about 19 percent of core PCE and
about 30 percent of core CPI, and obviously they have been leading the band up. As many people
have said, we have been seeing price increases in a lot of areas, but I don’t put quite as much stock
in that because many of the categories in both the PCE and the CPI are arbitrary. The issue is really
what the relative size and the relative importance are. Shelter services and owners’ equivalent rent,
which composes a vast majority of shelter services, are an important piece. I think that there’s a
reasonable chance that this factor is likely to be transitory, although it may last for several months
and possibly quarters. But that is the key question—whether these forces are likely to be transitory
or likely to be more persistent.
Coming back to inflation expectations, that’s really where I see the markets both registering
their view of persistence and telling us something about whether they believe that we will keep
inflation well contained. At least so far, those expectations are suggesting that we will. It’s
extremely important that we maintain those expectations. It’s very costly to try to regain credibility
if credibility is lost. I think the markets are willing to say, “Well, there may be some transitory
inflation, and we’re willing to wait and see whether to mark up our longer-term expectations.”
Certainly once longer-term expectations are marked up, the situation becomes highly problematic
because it’s very difficult to rein in the changes in expectations, particularly in behavior. So

August 8, 2006

73 of 158

basically I think we need to keep a very, very watchful eye on where expectations are going. I’m
heartened that they haven’t moved too far despite, as many people have said, high core PCE prices
for a number of years and elevated levels in the most recent numbers. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Let me briefly summarize what I’ve heard and
add a few comments. I think one thing we can conclude is that this is not getting any easier.
[Laughter] Starting with the data, which are not cooperating, the NIPA revisions show that
potential growth may be less than we thought and, therefore, we may have to have more of a
slowdown, if we believe in the Phillips curve, to begin to contain inflation. The small bit of comfort
I take is that the slowdown in potential and productivity appears to be coming from capital rather
than from multifactor productivity; so at least that technological component still seems to be with
us.
The question is whether we are, in fact, slowing to potential or to slightly below potential. I
agree with most of what I heard around the table, which is that there is evidence of slowing but,
except for the residential construction sector, it is not yet at all definitive that we are falling below
potential growth rates. For example, the staff estimated that GDP growth in the second quarter was
3 percent. The staff also estimated that the slower rate of job creation we saw in the second quarter
is still fairly close to what is needed to keep the unemployment rate constant.
We are certainly seeing areas of strength in the economy, as a number of people noted. That
includes the industrial sector—which will grow 0.7 or 0.8 percent, something like that, overall in
July—and nonresidential construction, which has been strong enough that so far there has not been
a net decline in construction jobs in the United States. So there certainly are some strong elements
of the economy.

August 8, 2006

74 of 158

I’d like to talk about the very important housing sector, in terms not of the expected level
but of the variance of our forecast, which I think we must think about given our risk-management
approach. At least three dimensions of the housing sector provide significant uncertainty as we look
forward. The first is the extent to which sales, starts, and permits will decline. The correction in the
housing market so far appears to be fairly substantial. In 2005, we had 1.72 million starts. For
June, the number of adjusted permits was 1.45 million. We already have a 15 percent decline in the
level of construction. As Governor Kroszner pointed out, the curve doesn’t look as though it’s
flattening out; it looks as though it’s heading directly south. We have heard anecdotally that
cancellations are up very sharply. Inventories are rising significantly, and I note that, just since the
last meeting, the GDP contribution estimated by the staff for housing construction went from
minus 0.3 percent to minus 0.6 percent. So there is, I think, a lot of uncertainty about where that
sector is going to level out.
Second, associated with that consideration is a lot of uncertainty about housing prices.
Again, as Governor Kroszner noted, we don’t really have much information on what the “true
price” of housing is at this point because of the way this market works: People leave things on the
market for a long time; they take them off the market; they provide incentives; and so on. So we
don’t really see the transaction prices in any kind of quality-adjusted or reliable way for some time
after the decline begins. The prices are significant, of course, both because they affect the
profitability of future construction and because they are, at this point, an important component of
household wealth; we know that these factors are likely to affect spending.
Finally, a third element of uncertainty as we look into the forecast is what I would call
parameter risk, which is that the staff assumes that the effect of housing wealth on consumption
spending is, through the standard wealth effect, about four cents on the dollar. I happen to think that

August 8, 2006

75 of 158

is a good estimate. I think the econometric calculations are persuasive. Nevertheless, there is the
possibility that the effect is somewhat greater, perhaps operating through liquidity effects. There
may be buffer stock effects. If people see their equity falling, they may become more cautious
about spending in order to avoid eliminating their buffer of reserves. Thus there is the possibility
that housing will have a stronger effect on consumption than we now expect.
I don’t know what the expected growth rate is. If I had to take a guess, I would say that
we’re going to be close to or slightly below potential going forward, but I simply want to point out
that our forecast may have a higher variance now than it does under normal circumstances.
Let me say just a few words about inflation. I heard a lot of concern about inflation around
the table. I certainly share that concern, and I don’t expect any near-term improvement, if for no
other reason than that these things tend to be highly inertial. I also agree with the general
observation that the pickup is fairly broad based, as I discussed in the meeting last time. One
indicator of that is the share of goods that have price increases or price increases above a certain
level.
I tried a somewhat different exercise, and I didn’t do it in any way as an apologist for
inflation—I want to be very clear. But I think it’s useful to look at inflation from a different
approach, which is to ask what share of the inflation acceleration is attributable to different
components. So I asked for a look at the past three months versus the past twelve months to
examine the acceleration between those two periods. In a sort of growth-accounting exercise, how
can we distribute that acceleration among different components?
I have just a few observations from that exercise. First, the shelter component really does
play a big role. For example, in this particular calculation, which is somewhat sensitive to sample
period, of the 71 basis point increase in the core CPI between twelve months and three months,

August 8, 2006

76 of 158

48 basis points were associated with the shelter increase. So that component is significant, and our
views on where it will go and how that relates to the developments in the housing market need to be
thought about. A second observation is that we are seeing energy pass-through, a good example
being air fares, which have jumped significantly and which by themselves contribute 19 basis points
to the acceleration. So energy pass-through is real. A somewhat more subtle point, which was
made in the Greenbook and which I think is interesting, is that there’s a little different behavior
between inflation in goods and inflation in non-energy, nonshelter services. Inflation in services has
been generally flat. In goods, however, we have seen a bit of acceleration, from a negative number
in ’05 to a slightly positive number in ’06. Examples would be the rise in prices in apparel and,
more recently, in used cars. In just examining clues, I think that acceleration might say something
about international competition, the effects of the declining dollar, and the possibility that import
competition has weakened to some extent and is allowing prices of tradable goods to rise a bit more
quickly.
One theme that is consistent regarding the energy pass-through and the perhaps slightly
greater inflation in tradable goods is that an important component of the inflation is product market
tightness as opposed to labor market tightness. That suggests that, as we go forward, we should pay
a lot of attention to final demand and consumption and see how they are affecting the product
markets. My own guess is that unit labor costs and wages will be somewhat lagging; and I think
that, if the product markets slow and the slowing reduces pricing power, as we call it, those effects
will ultimately have effects on the markup that will offset some of the wage effects.
So those are just a few observations about the economy. To summarize, I agree with the
sentiment around the table that there is a lot of uncertainty going forward, particularly in the housing
sector, but that the inflation risks at this point are still dominant and that our policy action and

August 8, 2006

77 of 158

statement should reflect the greater concern with inflation. On the subject of policy, let me now
turn to Brian, who will present the policy options.
MR. MADIGAN.2 As shown in the top panel of exhibit 1, the probability of a
25 basis point firming at this meeting implied by federal funds futures quotes trended
down over the intermeeting period. Policy expectations were boosted briefly by
higher-than-expected inflation readings, but those increases were more than offset by
Federal Reserve policy communications and several economic data releases—most
recently, the July employment report—that came in weaker than market participants
had anticipated. The pattern of declining expectations of firming at the upcoming
meeting stands in sharp contrast to the previous experience in this tightening cycle, in
which market expectations of firming generally rose over intermeeting periods,
converging to a level close to 100 percent by a day before the FOMC meeting. But
the current situation is similar to the previous episodes in that markets arrived at a
high degree of certainty about the outcome several days in advance of the meeting.
Still, as shown in the middle left panel, primary dealers responding to the Desk’s
survey have, since last November, evidenced both increased disagreement among
themselves (the light blue bars) and greater uncertainty individually (the dark blue
bars) about policy actions to be taken at the next meeting two weeks ahead of that
meeting. Presumably these developments reflect a realization that, with policy
accommodation essentially removed, policy actions have become less
pre-programmed and more dependent on the evolving outlook.
Regarding your statement today, as indicated in the right-hand panel, dealers
anticipate language that expresses more conviction that economic growth has
moderated, acknowledges the recent elevated inflation readings, expresses concern
about inflation risks, and indicates that future policy actions will be dependent on the
data. Although dealers expect your statement to cite inflation risks, implying a
likelihood of further policy firming, slightly less than half see any further tightening
in this cycle, and all of those anticipate at most ¼ point either today or in September.
As shown by the black line in the bottom left-hand panel, the peaking of rates implied
by fed funds futures at just 5.31 percent suggests that investors see only 1-in-4 odds
that you will take another firming step in this cycle. Indeed, looking further ahead,
the black line in the middle panel illustrates that market participants continue to
anticipate policy easing to commence before long, and their projected downward
trajectory for the federal funds rate steepened somewhat over the intermeeting period.
Investors seems to remain surprisingly assured in these views: As shown in the righthand panel, measures of market uncertainty about policy six and twelve months
ahead, the black and the blue lines, respectively, have crept higher of late but are
quite low by historical standards.
Reflecting our own sense of uncertainty about the Committee’s future actions, in
the August Bluebook we presented four, rather than the usual three, alternatives for
2

The materials used by Mr. Madigan are appended to this transcript (appendix 2).

August 8, 2006

78 of 158

Committee consideration, spanning a fairly wide range of policy approaches:
alternatives A and B, which would keep the stance of policy unchanged at this
meeting but are distinguished by different risk assessments; and alternatives C and D,
which would involve a 25 basis point firming today but are similarly differentiated by
their risk assessments.
A case for holding the federal funds rate unchanged today is summarized in the
top left-hand panel of exhibit 2. Based on an assumption of an unchanged federal
funds rate, the staff forecast is for economic growth to run slightly below the
expansion of the economy’s potential over the next six quarters. As shown in the top
right-hand panel, real GDP growth is projected to average about 2¼ percent over the
second half of 2006 and 2007, and the unemployment rate is forecast to creep up to
5¼ percent. The negative output gap that develops by the end of next year is small
and exerts only very modest restraint on inflation; but the leveling-out of energy
prices that was assumed in the staff forecast has a more noticeable effect, and core
PCE inflation in the Greenbook edges down slowly over the forecast period. Should
the Committee find this outlook likely and, in the circumstances, acceptable, it might
be inclined to maintain its current stance at this meeting.
The model-based estimates of the equilibrium real federal funds rate portrayed in
the middle left panel present another perspective that might be seen as arguing for
holding steady at this meeting. Over the past two years, seventeen consecutive policy
actions have brought the real federal funds rate from a quite low level to the middle of
the range of estimates of the equilibrium (shown in red). This configuration might
provide some comfort that leaving the stance of policy unchanged for six weeks is
unlikely to turn out to be a serious mistake—that is, unless the Committee is
particularly concerned that inflation expectations could become unmoored by further
bad news on inflation in circumstances in which policy evidently had gone on hold.
Moreover, some monetary policy rules reported in the Bluebook suggest holding
policy steady at this meeting. For example, the first-difference rule using an inflation
target of 2 percent, which is portrayed to the right, points to only ¼ point of
additional policy firming through the end of next year, based on the staff baseline
forecast. However, even if the Committee thought that leaving the stance of policy
unchanged was appropriate for this meeting, it might—as noted immediately below
the panel—continue to see several sources of upside risks to inflation: most notably,
high levels of resource utilization, which might be a larger concern now that labor
cost pressures look to be greater than previously perceived; elevated energy and other
commodity prices; and the potential for further increases in those factors—the latter
possibility highlighted by yesterday’s news from Alaska. In these circumstances, the
Committee might see the language of alternative B, communicating a judgment that
“some inflation risks remain” and referencing a potential need to address those risks,
as appropriate in conjunction with an unchanged stance of policy.
At the same time, the Committee might perceive emerging downside risks to the
economic outlook, as noted in the first bullet in the bottom left-hand panel. Output

August 8, 2006

79 of 158

and employment have decelerated substantially in recent months, and certainly a
sharper-than-expected further deceleration cannot be ruled out. In particular, housing
may be slowing more quickly than anticipated. The housing slump scenario
presented in the Greenbook illustrates the possible consequences of a realization of
that risk. Under that scenario, not illustrated in this exhibit, policymakers following
the Bluebook’s outcome-based rule respond to emerging slack by lowering the
federal funds rate to 4¾ percent by the end of next year. Even without particular
concerns about such risks, an outlook along the lines of the Greenbook baseline
forecast might be consistent with alternative A if policymakers judge such inflation
performance to be satisfactory in light of the below-trend projection for output
growth, as in the optimal control policy path with an inflation target of 2 percent.
Moreover, the Committee’s past behavior as captured in the estimated forecast-based
rule would, as shown in the bottom right-hand panel, suggest a slight easing of policy,
given the staff outlook. In these circumstances, the Committee might find it
reasonable to leave the stance of policy unchanged at this meeting and not have any
predilection for the likely direction of policy going forward, as in alternative A.
However, as discussed in the top panel of exhibit 3, even if the Committee
thought that downside risks to growth were becoming more palpable, it might still
wish to firm policy another notch at this meeting. If the Committee saw significant
potential for inflation to exceed expectations, it might believe that another 25 basis
point increase in the federal funds rate is necessary to balance the risks.
Alternatively, the Committee might feel, given the already relatively high level of
inflation, that a significant upside surprise to inflation could be quite damaging and
would exceed the cost of a downside surprise to growth. If so, the Committee might
be willing to tighten policy a bit further to provide more insurance against persistent
high inflation. The Committee might also believe that a rate increase today could be
a useful signal of its anti-inflationary resolve while, as under alternative C, suggesting
that it was not necessarily expecting to firm policy further.
All that said, members may have reservations in current circumstances about
suggesting that the risks are balanced, even after the 25 basis point firming of
alternative C. Such reservations may motivate the Committee to consider alternative
D, discussed in the remainder of your exhibit. Under this alternative, the Committee
would both raise the federal funds rate 25 basis points at this meeting and imply that
further increases may well be in store. As noted in the middle panel, members might
be inclined to adopt alternative D for several reasons. First, the Committee might
agree that the staff forecast presents the most likely outcome for the economy and
inflation should the federal funds rate be held at its current level over coming
quarters, but it may prefer a steeper decline in inflation than in that forecast and be
willing to tolerate a slower pace of economic growth to achieve it. Indeed, as
reproduced in the bottom left-hand panel, the optimal control simulations presented in
chart 7 of the Bluebook suggest that considerable policy firming lies ahead if the
Committee wanted to pursue a 1½ percent inflation objective—especially should it
seek to attain that rate within a few years. The Committee also might believe that
appreciable further policy firming could be in prospect because it does not expect

August 8, 2006

80 of 158

growth to slow as much as the staff expects or because it is concerned that inflation 

pressures could turn out to be more durable than forecast by the staff, a risk that is 

illustrated by the “persistent inflation” scenario. As shown by the black line in the 

bottom right-hand panel, if those incremental inflation pressures were fully 

anticipated, optimal policy would call for boosting the federal funds rate about 

75 basis points above baseline over the next year. In the optimal control case with 

gradual learning (the dashed red line) or with the empirically estimated rule that

reacts only to outcomes (the dashed blue line) the policy response is more drawn out 

but is eventually of similar dimensions. Should the Committee see a significant risk 

of persistent inflation pressures along these lines, it may wish to continue to point to 

upside risks in its announcement if it firms 25 basis points at this meeting, as in 

alternative D. 

Your final exhibit is the version of table 1 that was distributed on Friday. Thank
you. That concludes my prepared remarks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Any questions for Brian? President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. I have one question about the term “resource utilization.” It was in our
statement last time, and we took it out of many of the alternatives. I think David mentioned that
resource utilization was a bit tighter since our last meeting. I was wondering whether there was a
particular reason for taking it out of many of the options that we have to consider here.
MS. MINEHAN. It’s in alternative C.
MR. MADIGAN. It is in alternative C, as President Minehan mentions. I think it’s simply
a question of whether or not the Committee prefers to speak in those terms, whether it would like to
mention that factor at this meeting. I don’t think the staff has a strong view on whether or not it
should be included.
MR. MOSKOW. You do not have a strong view.
MR. MADIGAN. I do not.
MR. MOSKOW. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any other questions? Governor Kohn.

August 8, 2006

81 of 158

MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I found this a challenging meeting for arriving at a
policy conclusion. I certainly agree with many of you that inflation has been running higher than
we want for longer than we have wanted, and I actively debated whether we should continue on our
tightening path. But in the end, I think there are a number of advantages to keeping policy
unchanged but being very careful to talk about the upside risk to inflation that we see. One of those
advantages is that the staff may actually be right. [Laughter] Keeping policy at this rate may be
consistent with a moderation of inflation over coming quarters. Even if inflation doesn’t moderate
quite as fast as some of us might want it to, at least it’s on the right, downward, track. In my
previous remarks I cited a few things that lead me to think that that’s a nontrivial possibility. One is
that we have had some evidence that growth is slowing to at least the growth rate of potential and
maybe a little below. Second, I do think that some of the influences that we’ve seen on inflation are
transitory, as Governor Kroszner said, and will lessen over time. So I think that keeping the policy
rate where it is could well be consistent with making progress toward our objectives of stable prices
and maximum employment over time.
Because there’s a strong expectation in the market, not 100 percent but around 80 percent,
that we won’t do anything, I think that, if we keep policy unchanged but continue to express
considerable concern about inflation risk, there will be very little market reaction in terms of the
expected interest rates further out on the curve. That would imply to me that financial conditions
won’t be loosened by our keeping policy unchanged. Talking about inflation risks will also
preserve our flexibility for the future. We’ll let the market know what we’re most worried about,
and keeping policy unchanged while talking about inflation risks will give us some of that
flexibility, which would be very, very important given the uncertainties. There are downside risks
to growth as well as the risk that inflation will remain higher. Expressing the concerns about

August 8, 2006

82 of 158

inflation but keeping policy unchanged gets us off what Chairman Bernanke called “the escalator”
of 25 basis points a meeting. The situation is such that it would be a good idea to get off that
escalator and have that flexibility without signaling that we think we’re done but just that we’re
stopping for today.
In terms of the language of the statement, I’m not sure that alternative B fully expresses the
concerns that I heard around the table about inflation risk. President Moskow raised one of those
issues—that the alternative B language has nothing about high levels of resource utilization. I think
high resource utilization is a risk. One suggestion would be to take the language in alternative C
under section 3 and put it in alternative B as perhaps a better expression of what the Committee’s
concerns are, even while keeping policy unchanged. That would speak to President Moskow’s
point.
Another word that was dropped from the announcement was “productivity” as damping
inflation. I think that’s a close call as well. Productivity growth remains very strong. The staff has
marked down only a little its expected path of productivity, which remains pretty high compared
with history. At the same time, with compensation increasing, labor costs are not really holding
down inflation and aren’t expected to hold it down in the future. So I could go either way in terms
of including a reference to productivity. To me, deleting it would indicate that the unit labor cost
path that we had for holding down inflation, which we cited last time, isn’t there anymore. But it is
a fact that productivity continues to be strong. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Minehan.
MS. MINEHAN. Thank you very much. In my memory, this is about the toughest decision
I’ve ever been a part of at this table. Over the past twelve, thirteen, or so years that I’ve been here,
we haven’t faced the combination of potential for slower growth and rising inflation that is certainly

August 8, 2006

83 of 158

not optimal for a central bank, and I really do find this choice to be very difficult along the lines that
Don mentioned earlier. Not only do we have to figure out what to do, we have to figure out what to
say about it, and that’s another complicating factor that has just grown over the years. We began
raising interest rates more than two years and 425 basis points ago, but at some point we have to
stop or at least pause. What makes this particularly difficult is that price growth is on an uptick and
moderation occurs only in projections and not yet in the data.
I think you, Ben, anticipated in one of your earlier testimonies—perhaps in the first one you
gave—that we might have to pause in the midst of adverse incoming price data. The thought wasn’t
well received at the time, as I recall; and now that we’re faced with that decision, I find myself
uncomfortable. The logic is clear. Inflation data are backward looking, and if we continue to
increase rates until incoming information suggests that moderation has occurred, we will
undoubtedly overdo the tightening process. But knowing that doesn’t make choosing when to stop
or even to pause easier when you see, as I do, many risks that both growth and inflation pressures
may well be stronger than we now forecast.
In that regard, I think Don and I are probably just micromeasurements away from each
other, but I’m sort of on the other side of the line. At the margin I favor increasing the federal funds
rate 25 basis points. I believe inflation risks are on the upside and that we’re at risk that the current
higher rates of inflation will become embedded in business practices and, therefore, get reflected in
the market expectations and the expectations that we measure. I don’t think we’re way behind the
curve, but I do think we need to ensure that policy stays less rather than more accommodative. As I
noted earlier, if one looks at real interest rates, among other things, financial conditions are more
rather than less accommodative than earlier in the summer, and I personally don’t think that’s
consistent with the inflation risks that we face.

August 8, 2006

84 of 158

Now, Don pointed out that the market is not anticipating this. For some reason or another,
the market saw the minutes of our last meeting as very soft. I didn’t read them that way. As I recall
our discussion at the last meeting, we wanted to give ourselves some flexibility. We would be
happy if the market saw a 50-50 chance. Probably reflecting on growth in Q2 that was slower than
they expected and on some of the employment data, they’ve obviously tilted it the other way. I
recognize that surprising the market with an increase would be a surprise, [laughter] but I’m not at
all sure that’s a bad thing, particularly if we are as concerned about inflation around the table as I
have heard many of us say.
I recognize that I may be in the minority here. So I would strongly advocate that, if we do
talk about pausing, we not suggest to the markets that we think the risks in the economy are
balanced. We have to signal clearly that our concerns are on the upside with regard to inflation. If I
were a voting member, I’d vote to raise the fed funds rate 25 basis points and to use some form of
alternative C, possibly by adjusting the last line to indicate an ongoing concern about inflation but
probably not going all the way in the direction of alternative D. I recognize that’s not likely to be
the consensus here. So then I would strongly favor alternative B in terms of language, with the
change that Don just mentioned—taking section 3 and moving it into alternative B—to perhaps give
a stronger cast to the overall assessment.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I favor alternative B. It is a tough decision. I
personally consider this the wiser course of action, although I think there’s no question that a case
can be made for raising rates today. Alternative B has several advantages. First, a pause at this
meeting will give us a chance to review incoming data over the next six weeks, which isn’t that

August 8, 2006

85 of 158

long. We need a chance to better ascertain where the economy is headed and whether the elevated
levels of inflation we have seen are persisting.
I think there is significant downside risk to growth, as I mentioned, with housing being a
particularly acute example. I think our policies are taking a bite out of economic momentum, and I
agree with the analysis that our Chairman gave of at least the downside risk from that source.
I am also disturbed by the trajectory of core inflation over the first half of the year. We’ll see two
CPI reports and other data by the next meeting, and I think maybe they will help us sort out just how
sustained the rise in inflation is truly likely to be.
As I said, there’s no doubt in my mind that you can make a good case for raising rates today,
and frankly I probably would have ended up favoring that myself, despite the associated risk to
growth, if I thought there were an imminent danger of our losing our inflation-fighting credibility
with the markets and the general public. But that’s not the case at all in my view. The markets
don’t expect us to raise rates today. Yet inflation expectations are contained. President Lacker has
emphasized, and I agree with this, that we cannot take our credibility for granted. Economic models
that allow for imperfect credibility show that, when a central bank lacks full credibility, it should
respond somewhat more aggressively to inflation than would be optimal if it were completely
credible, which is President Lacker’s point. I agree with that. But such models don’t imply that the
central bank should act as if price stability were the sole objective. In the current context, that
suggests to me that our credibility is likely to be preserved as long as we continue to respond to
economic conditions in a manner that is basically consistent with the pattern that the Committee has
established over the past decade, which is similar to, say, a modified version of the Taylor rule. I
think that’s what we’ve been doing and essentially should continue to do.

August 8, 2006

86 of 158

An advantage of alternative B, and I think this is important, is that it does suggest concern
with inflation risks. I completely agree that we should express that concern. I expect and I hope
that inflation is going to edge down, but I don’t have a great deal of confidence in that forecast. I
would not want to see a statement suggesting that inflation risks are balanced at the present time; I
think it would be misleading. Our statement should, in effect, contain an asymmetric bias toward
tightening, and that’s true whether we actually raise rates or we don’t raise rates. So I would oppose
alternatives A and C, and I have no objection to substituting the language from alternative C for that
in B as Governor Kohn suggested.
I find it hard to predict what the market reaction is going to be, but the language could end
up raising the market’s expectations concerning future rates. I would consider that appropriate in
light of the fact that standard policy rules and optimal policies reported in the Bluebook do suggest
that some further increases in the fed funds rate are likely to be called for in coming months. Our
communications should be consistent with that analysis and not indicate that we think we’re
probably done.
So what’s the advantage of alternative B? We can get off the escalator of 25 basis points per
meeting, take a pause, and evaluate incoming data without saying that we think we’re done with the
tightening phase. I do worry that a market psychology has developed that suggests that the minute
we stop raising rates we’re absolutely finished. In contrast to the Greenbook’s trajectory, which is
that we’re going to stay here for a while and not quickly reverse, markets now apparently anticipate
a rather rapid policy reversal. The Greenbook assumption is a more sensible position—it would be
a more sensible set of market expectations than the idea that we will have a quick reversal. It would
not be unwelcome to me at all to see the market trajectory for the future bounce up.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Guynn.

August 8, 2006

87 of 158

MR. GUYNN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. With each speaker, this discussion gets more
and more interesting. I think it’s fair to say that anybody who has been involved in the
policymaking process for very long has made a speech or talked publicly about how you come to
the meeting with your own views and you’re always willing to listen to your colleagues and change
your mind. I come probably as close to that phenomenon today as I have in my ten years at the
table.
As I listened to the discussion that we had earlier, I guess I was a bit surprised at how great
the concern about inflation is. I share it certainly to a great extent. I think that one could, in fact,
make a very strong case for a further tightening move today. It seems to me, however, that a
tightening move today would have to come with an expression of continuing concern about
inflation. That, I think, would imply probably additional tightening moves. If combined with the
notion that we’re not satisfied that the path we’re on will get inflation down well within the range, a
tightening move today implies an even greater likelihood of further tightening. I think that kind of
path raises the probability that we’re going to do too much and stay too long at this. Not to “me
too” your comments, but perhaps because I come from the Southeast, where housing is such an
important factor—though I’m not sure I understand completely the slowdown in housing and how
important that may turn out to be—it is certainly a factor in my mind. I’m willing to give more
weight to the optimistic forecast on inflation than it sounds as though some are. I appreciate the
pricing power discussion that we’ve heard around the table, but we have been hearing that for years,
and I would hope that the same things that kept that from playing out would continue keeping it
from playing out.
Again, one could, in fact, make a very honorable case for a further tightening move today,
but that’s not where I came in, and that’s not where I end up after the discussion. I think in some

August 8, 2006

88 of 158

ways that’s a harder conclusion to come to, but I still favor something like alternative B. It would
be very good for us to demonstrate the willingness to pause and try to understand the things that are
going on a little better than we do. I am willing to trust, perhaps more than some are, that the
forecast inflation is going to work its way down. I am less obsessed than some with trying to push it
all the way down to 1½ percent in the very short term. I don’t think that the world would expect
and insist that we do that.
We have enough credibility that we should use a bit of it now to give ourselves time to see
where we are. If our forecast that things are going to be okay turns out to be wrong, we can change
our position rather quickly and regain whatever loss of credibility somebody thinks we may have
incurred. Again, all things considered, I favor no change in policy today and language similar to
what’s in alternative B. I do not intend to dissent today if the consensus is on the side of tightening,
but I have a reasonably strong preference for using this opportunity to take a break in the path we’ve
been on and to try to understand a bit better where we are. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Gee, what can I say? [Laughter] It’s a very difficult call, and indeed, I
consider myself really fortunate that I happen to be in on this discussion in my first time. Maybe
there are some advantages and disadvantages to that. Maybe I don’t carry some of the baggage of
what I’ve said in past meetings because I haven’t said anything in past meetings.
I certainly understand and respect the view expressed by those who think we should pause.
I think that most people around this table recognize that reasonable people at this stage doing sound
economic analysis could come down one way or the other on this. But at this point, my inclination
is to favor a 25 basis point increase. Economic growth has slowed from the rapid pace that we’ve
all been talking about. This was expected. I see little reason to think, at least based on what I’ve

August 8, 2006

89 of 158

heard around the table today, that growth will be considerably below trend in the second half of this
year or into ’07.
I don’t think that holding rates steady at this time will add much to real growth in the near
term, nor do I think it’s really buying us much insurance against possible future weakness. By the
same token, I don’t think raising rates 25 basis points is going to have a significant effect on the real
economy in the near term either, but it can help reinforce the public’s perception of our commitment
to price stability. I believe that the Committee has done an outstanding job in maintaining
credibility thus far, as evidenced by the fact that we’ve all noted that longer-term inflationary
expectations seem to be well anchored. But longer-term expectations remain contained because the
markets and people expect the FOMC to contain actual inflation. Thus, we have to be very careful
not to presume that expectations will remain stable independent of our actions today or in
subsequent meetings.
If the Committee chooses not to raise rates, does it risk sending the message that we are
willing to tolerate inflation above an acceptable level for a significant period of time? If we take the
Greenbook’s forecast as our point forecast, as has been repeatedly said, it will basically say that
we’re prepared to tolerate PCE core inflation in excess of 2 percent for four years or perhaps more.
Sending that message may generate increased uncertainty about our commitment to low inflation;
and if inflation expectations become unhinged as a result, that would lead to some very bad
outcomes given the costs imposed on the economy as we strive to regain our credibility. I recognize
that a rate increase may come as a surprise to the markets, but I’m less sure that, over a slightly
longer period, it won’t indeed be good news for the markets and for the economy as a whole.
Thus, as I see it, the argument for favoring another move today is based on a comparison of
the potential costs and benefits. Pausing is not free. In my view, pausing today would do little for

August 8, 2006

90 of 158

growth in the near term, nor does it help us on our credibility side. I believe the potential costs of
tightening a bit more in terms of bad outcomes for growth and employment are outweighed by the
potential costs of not doing so, given where inflation is and where we think it’s going. If the
economy’s growth prospects deteriorate significantly in the coming weeks and months, we clearly
have the opportunity to pause or even reduce rates if we think doing so is necessary.
In contrast, I ask myself, “How difficult will it be, if we pause today, to resume rate
increases if we need to do so?” This question leads to thinking about the language of the statement.
If we choose to pause today, it’s important that we send a clear and very strong signal with our
statement language that we are committed to price stability. Pointing out that inflation pressures are
likely to moderate over time is important if we believe that to be the case because we need to
explain why, despite inflation above our comfort zone, we aren’t acting. Pointing out that some
inflation risks remain would help convey the idea that we may need to act in the future to bring
inflation down if our forecasts turn out to be wrong.
So I’d like to close by suggesting that each of us needs to ask ourselves the following
questions: What information are we likely to see in the next six weeks that would cause us, if we
pause today, to initiate another rate increase in September? What might cause us to cut rates in
September? And in the event that data on the real economy are once again a bit muddled, as they
were in the past six weeks, and inflation continues unabated, will we find ourselves in the position
of inertia that would lead us to continue pausing and then would possibly put us further behind the
curve? Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. As I outlined earlier, my sense is that, after having largely eliminated
resource underutilization, the economy is now fluctuating around potential. It’s attractive in

August 8, 2006

91 of 158

circumstances like this to look back to similar periods for an independent gauge on the
appropriate level of real interest rates. From 1995 through 2000, another period of sustained real
growth around potential, the real federal funds rate relative to lagged core PCE inflation ranged
between 3¼ percent and 5 percent. Right now, the real federal funds rate measured the same
way is 2.9 percent. This is handily illustrated, by the way, by the black line in the Bluebook’s
chart 8. You can do this calculation yourself using any number of alternative methods of
estimating inflation expectations, and you always get the same result. The real federal funds rate
was never this low between 1995 and 2000.
As an aside, a deeper scientific analysis of the appropriate level of the real interest rate
would take into account the insight, dating back at least to Irving Fisher, that it ought to reflect
the relative balance of pressures on current versus future resources—intertemporal rates of
substitution, in other words. Clearly, any gauge of that is going to relate real rates to current
demand relative to the potential for the economy to supply it. So in any statistical relationship
estimated over historical data, one is going to uncover a relationship between real rates and
output. A monetary policy maker surely can’t ignore output, and I wouldn’t advocate doing that.
One important difference between now and the late 1990s is that inflation was better
behaved then. Inflation fell from just over 2 percent in 1995 to just below 2 percent in 1996, and
it stayed in the middle of the 1 to 2 percent range for the rest of that decade. Now, as many have
noted, inflation is going in the opposite direction. Briefly, it has been above 2 percent since early
’04 and has stepped up significantly since the beginning of the year. The Greenbook is
projecting that it will remain above 2¼ percent for a year and a half. It now appears as if an
acceleration of wage inflation has begun. Although one might characterize—as many around the

August 8, 2006

92 of 158

table have—inflation expectations as “well contained,” I think it’s worth questioning whether the
level at which expectation measures are contained is that reassuring.
I’ll note that the TIPS inflation compensation figures taken from last Friday afternoon
show that, adjusted for the carry effect, the ten-year spread is 2.65, the five-year spread five
years ahead is 2.7, and the one-year forward rate ending in ten years is 2.89. Adjusting that to
get back to core PCE, the first thing you do is take overall to core; the expected value of that is
surely around zero going forward. Then, there’s this CPI-to-PCE measurement error. If you
chart that, you see it has fluctuated a lot. Sure, the historical average is 0.3 percentage point, but
it has been negative for several quarters, and just now it has gotten back to 0.2 or 0.3 or so. So
let’s take 0.4, the Bluebook’s adjustment. If you expected long-run inflation expectations to
accord with the opinion of some around this table—that they would like to see inflation within a
comfort zone between 1 and 2 percent—you’d expect core inflation of 1.5 percent, and you’d
expect these inflation expectation measures to be 1.9 percent. If you look at the survey evidence,
they are at 2.5, 2.9, and 3.2 percent. So it’s not clear that inflation compensation and inflation
expectation measures are contained in a way that’s consistent with a long-run inflation objective
around 1.5 percent. In short, if you sum up all the inflation evidence, take the whole picture
together, to my mind it looks a lot as though inflation has become entrenched above 2 percent.
In my view, the longer we let it go on, as a previous Chairman and this Chairman have said, the
more difficult it will be to correct it.
The worse inflation outlook now indicates that, if anything, the real short rate should be
higher than otherwise warranted by real growth considerations. On top of that, there is the Fisher
relationship to take into account, as President Moskow pointed out. Since the June meeting, the

August 8, 2006

93 of 158

Greenbook’s one-year-ahead inflation forecast has risen 45 basis points, so a 5¼ percent fed
funds rate now corresponds to a 45 basis point lower real rate than it did in June.
As I said earlier, I think a fair scientific appraisal of the evidence should make us deeply
skeptical of the notion that moderating growth is going to bring core inflation down without
further action on our part to better anchor inflation expectations. Yet a popular perception now
is that this hypothesis is the centerpiece of our inflation strategy. I believe we need to take action
today to correct that misapprehension.
I do not believe we live in a world in which it is common knowledge that we follow a
fixed policy reaction function that includes among its arguments or determinants a single number
capturing a well-known long-run inflation objective for us—for example, the Taylor rule that has
a single number, π*, that captures where inflation returns and to which any impulse response
function you run is going to return in five or ten years. I believe, rather, that our recent
experience clearly demonstrates that there have been substantial swings in the public’s beliefs
about future inflation and monetary policy—in other words, about what kind of policymakers we
are. Moreover, I believe that the public is confused about how monetary policy and inflation
should respond to energy-price shocks. I think this confusion arose in the wake of Katrina, and I
think it has been exacerbated by our failure to explain that fact well enough to the public, even
though we have all tried. More energy shocks are likely in the years ahead, and we need to
condition markets to expect us to protect core inflation in response rather than attempt to protect
the unemployment rate as we did in the 1970s.
I think the first-order policy problem for us today is to influence the evolution of the
public’s beliefs in a way that helps bring inflation down more rapidly than the public and the
Greenbook are currently forecasting, rather than relying on subsiding special factors. In theory,

August 8, 2006

94 of 158

a forceful enough communication about our intentions to act in the future could be an effective
substitute for action today, but I am skeptical about this hypothesis as well. We have been quite
careful to say that, if we pause, we could resume rates shortly thereafter. But every time we say
that, the market reaction seems to be, “Did you say ‘pause’?” This has the market focused on the
possibility of our pausing and less focused on the possibility of our resuming afterward, and that
is clearly reflected in what the yield curve has done since the last meeting, as illustrated in the
Bluebook.
In sum, I acknowledge the case for below-potential growth over the next few quarters, as
low as the staff believes. If I expected significantly lower growth than I do, I would obviously
favor a lower real interest rate path than I otherwise would. But I think that the risk that the
housing contraction will have broader multiplier effects on personal consumption and other
sectors is still relatively small, and I do not think we should be satisfied with the path that
inflation is likely to take if we stay on the policy path that the market anticipates.
Communication is important, as we’ll discuss later today, but there are times when actions speak
louder than words. Therefore I favor a 25 basis point increase in the federal funds rate and a
statement something like alternative D, and I favor them enough to vote accordingly.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Thank you. Well, like others, I have asked myself whether this is the
appropriate time to pause. I think there are respectable and reasonable arguments on both sides
of that question, and so let me briefly make a couple of them.
In favor of the pause now is the observation, which I would reiterate, that I do believe
inflation expectations are well anchored and have remained well anchored despite developments
that we might have expected to have concerned people in the marketplace, namely higher

August 8, 2006

95 of 158

inflation numbers in reality and an apparent growing conviction among many market participants
that a pause in our policy tightening actions is likely to be forthcoming. The second argument
concerns the well-known lags between our policy actions and their effects. I wish I knew more
about those lags, to be precise, than I do, but it still seems to me it’s a good bet that we have not
seen the full effects of the actions we have already taken. The third argument is that market
participants are expecting a pause at this point, or at least many are.
On the other hand, inflation has been more rapid so far this year than I had expected, and
it is probably not a good bet that it will decelerate anytime soon. This persistence of inflation
could have deleterious consequences for inflation expectations unless we communicate
particularly effectively going forward, if we do pause. With hindsight, looking at the course of
policy over the past three or four years, I think that it’s at least possible that policy was too
accommodative for too long; thus, we have more work to do to counteract those effects.
When I weigh those arguments and think about some of the other arguments I have heard
around the table, I come down in favor of a pause at this meeting and in favor of something like
alternative B. It’s very important that we avoid giving the impression that we may be done, and I
think alternative B largely does that. I am reluctant to wade into the morass of editing on the
run; but if we wanted to strengthen that alternative, I think we could actually do it with one word
in section 3, third line, by just saying “owing only in part to the pass-through.” The thought I
have is that the “only” signals that we’re not simply suggesting this is all transitory and all due to
special factors. But that’s just a suggestion.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Poole.

August 8, 2006

96 of 158

MR. POOLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As others are, I am very torn about this
decision. I come out for holding the funds rate constant, and here is the problem that I have with
our situation. Part of it is the language that we used in the past.
If you look at the first exhibit that we were given, you see that the fed funds rate
responded to the second-quarter GDP report and the employment report. We have told the
market that we are going to be data dependent, and we have told the market that resource
utilization matters to us. It seems to me that the lesson from that is, first, we should come
through with what we told the market we were going to do and, second, we should get some of
those things out of the statement because we need to put a lot more emphasis on the inflation risk
that we face going forward. I am particularly unhappy, quite frankly, with leaving the reference
to housing in there. Housing is likely to continue to have some weak numbers, and it seems to
me that we don’t want the market to believe that policy is really being driven by one sector of the
economy. I offered some language for section 2. I think that is a statement about the past—“has
moderated from its quite strong pace.” If you just look at the second-quarter GDP report, there
was moderation pretty much across the board. That was the language I suggested. I think we
ought not to be referring to housing explicitly.
We should try to move toward a bare bones statement and not create expectations in the
market that we are going to be responding. Of course, between now and our next meeting we
may get some more measures that people would interpret as reflecting resource utilization. One
of the things that is peculiar about having that in the statement at this point is that the staff is not
forecasting any significant gap in resource utilization that would put downward pressure on
inflation. So how can we be referring to resource utilization as our primary reason for thinking

August 8, 2006

97 of 158

that inflation is going to moderate? It seems to me that there is some internal inconsistency
there.
The problem that I have with alternative B, as it is now worded, is this: If we believe that
we will want to increase the target funds rate at our next meeting—which I think is the
interpretation of that last section—then we should do it today. We shouldn’t signal it for the
future. Given that expectations seem to be well contained, I think that we have a chance to use
our language to get out from under some of the expectations we have created and that we should
come through on the expectations we have already created. You see that clearly in the way the
market set the fed funds rate in response to the incoming data. We’ve said we were going to be
data dependent, and I think we’d better come through and be data dependent.
I want to say one other thing about housing. I think that housing may be telling us that it
is really a good measure of consumer confidence. Housing obviously involves people looking
forward and deciding what commitments they’re willing to make. I would interpret housing as
being a combination measure of people’s attitudes toward the future, the security of their income
flows, and the commitments they’re willing to make—to include obviously not only the
households themselves but also the lenders that are responsible for making mortgage decisions.
So I would downplay housing as a direct component of GDP. Thank you.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Mr. Chairman? May I ask Mr. Poole a clarifying
question?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Certainly.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. So, Bill, you would want to do what to expectations?
How would you want expectations to evolve in response to your preferred version of the
language associated with a pause today? Do you want them to be flat going forward?

August 8, 2006

98 of 158

MR. POOLE. Well, in terms of what we know today, I think we ought to be
noncommittal. If we continue to get information that leads to extending the inflation risk or
maybe indicating that it is more severe even than we think today, then we ought to be responding
to that, and we ought to leave ourselves open to be responding to that. We shouldn’t write
ourselves into a box by focusing on resource utilization because those numbers are in many ways
the most visible ones to lots of people. Suppose we get another low number on the August
employment report, and we have pointed to resource utilization as one of the things that we’re
counting on? Are we then writing ourselves into a box in terms of the expectations we create by
emphasizing resource utilization? So that’s why I’m arguing for a very, very general and rather
vague statement.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Like others, I think the policy action at
this meeting is a very close call, but in the end I support a pause, even in light of the continuing
unfavorable inflation situation. I think that there is a real possibility that slack could be greater
during this projection period than the staff’s baseline projections expect because of weaker
demand, stronger potential, or some combination of the two. I am encouraged that inflation
expectations remain anchored. In light of all of the uncertainties attached to the current outlook,
I would just like to take a pause and see how things play out. Now, as many have said, there is a
chance that the data are going to reveal that this is not a good stopping point. If the data do
reveal that more rate hikes are in order because inflation may reaccelerate, because inflation
expectations begin to increase, or because economic activity appears to be more robust than our
current projections, then I think we will need to consider the possibility of a more aggressive
move. Unfortunately, I think it’s unrealistic to expect that some of these issues are going to be

August 8, 2006

99 of 158

resolved in one or two future meetings. But we have market-based measures of inflation
expectations that are available to us on a continuous basis, and for that reason, it seems important
to me to be especially focused on inflation expectations in the coming months.
I favor alternative B. I support Governor Kohn’s suggestion that we move language from
alternative C, section 3, to emphasize our concern about the inflation risks. I also want to add
that, like President Guynn, I am not going to dissent if the consensus is for a move of 25 basis
points. I came into the meeting leaning toward a pause. I have to say, after listening to many of
my colleagues’ statements today, that inclination is less pronounced. It’s just a very close call
today. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I don’t think I’ll surprise you. I agree with
Governor Kohn that a pause is appropriate. In terms of some of the comments, I do suggest that
we need to recognize that we often say that monetary policy operates with a lag. In fact, moves
that we have made have not yet worked their way through, and we ought to see how they
develop. A pause is appropriate to do that—it’s not shutting off further moves but letting us look
at the facts that are in play.
With that, I am bothered that the markets are already projecting that, sometime in the
future, we will reverse and begin to lower rates, which I think is not something I would like to
see. Also, because I recognize that there are genuine and serious inflation risks, we need to be—
and to express that we are—very sensitive in watching inflation expectations. Part of our
judgment will be not just on real economic data but on these expectations and on what inflation
does, since that is our business. If I could say something in this language, it would be to the

August 8, 2006

100 of 158

effect that I think we are restrictive, maybe moderately restrictive, and that we’re going to stay
that way until we see systematic declines in inflation. I think that would do a lot for us.
Having said that, in terms of the language, I would then be comfortable with
alternative B, with the modifications that Governor Kohn has suggested, as we try to clarify our
intentions, if that’s what we want to do with this statement, moving forward.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I think it was in March that I referred to Pascal’s famous
wager about the existence of God. Pascal’s view was basically that if you look far out in the
future from a risk-management standpoint, the answer was in the affirmative. [Laughter] I
happen to accept the existence of inflation, and I admire President Lacker, President Minehan,
and others who have made very strong arguments.
I take note of one thing that is very different at this meeting from what I have heard in my
year-plus at this table. This is the first time that many people have said—and I certainly have
heard this from the people I have talked to in the field—that they are moving on prices instead of
being tamped down in terms of their desire. In other words, they have pricing power, and it is
being realized. This is the first time we’ve heard that in the discussion, and it worries me.
It’s very, very important that we signal our anti-inflationary resolve. I generally always
agree with President Poole. I happen to be a minimalist as far as the statement is concerned. But
if we pause here, it is very important that we use the kind of language that Governor Kohn
suggested and that we make it very clear that this may not be the end of the process. Even more
important, Mr. Chairman, is that we agree at this table that we’ll be fearless in moving if we have
to.

August 8, 2006

101 of 158

As to the market, I think President Minehan made a very good comment. Having been a
market operator for thirty years of my career, I have found that markets are usually wrong. Our
job is not to satisfy the markets. Our job is to get the economy right—that’s our mission.
So I would accept a pause, Mr. Chairman, under the conditions I just mentioned. I like
Governor Kohn’s suggestion on language although, like a broken record, I would put the word
“global” in front of “resource utilization” because I think that reflects reality. Having said what I
just said, I would also say that, if the group decides to raise the rate 25 basis points, I won’t
dissent because I don’t have a vote. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Excellent reason. President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The incoming data have heightened my
concerns about inflation. I think it’s true, as a number of people have mentioned around the
table, that inflation expectations have not moved up. The markets seem pretty confident that
we’re going to be successful in fighting inflation. But as Kevin Warsh said, the markets can be
pretty fickle. We’re going to get some further bad news on inflation in the coming months, and I
hope the markets will maintain their confidence in the Federal Reserve. But their confidence in
us could change as the news continues to be bad in the coming months. Also, I think we have to
ask whether our failure for two years now to keep inflation inside what many of us have said is
our comfort zone—1 to 2 percent—is going to weigh eventually on the assessment of the
markets and their confidence in the Federal Reserve. I’m concerned that the public’s confidence
in us may begin to waver if we don’t express our readiness to tighten if inflation doesn’t head
down soon. It’s not clear to me that we’ve put restrictive-enough financial conditions in place to
put inflation on much of a downward path. According to the Bluebook, the fed funds rate is
close to neutral. In the Bluebook’s longer-run simulation, the optimum policy requires further

August 8, 2006

102 of 158

rate increases to put us on the path to 1½ percent. We won’t get there just staying where we are
now.
I realize it’s a very close call, and everyone has mentioned that; but on balance, I would
prefer to raise rates 25 basis points at this meeting. I won’t repeat all the comments that Cathy,
Charlie, and Jeff made. I think they were very persuasive. It would surprise the markets, but we
shouldn’t be doing what the markets expect us to do. We should be doing, as someone said,
what’s right for the economy and for the American people. It doesn’t appear that an increase
will be the consensus coming out of this meeting. I’d just add that, if we do pause, it’s not going
to be easy for us to start again. I don’t think we should kid ourselves about that. We’re going to
be accused of whipsawing by the markets, and we’ll take a lot of criticism. So we’re going to
have to take a very tough stand if we decide to raise rates again. It’s not going to be easy, and
we should just be prepared to do that. Looking ahead, I’d say that if we determine that factors
are not reducing growth too much and if inflation does not appear to be moderating, then we’re
going to need to increase rates further to coax inflation back toward price stability. We have to
make it clear in our public statements that we’re prepared to do that.
If we do go with the pause, then I certainly agree with Don Kohn’s recommendation that
we should use the language from section 3 of alternative C and move it to section 2 of
alternative B. To omit the reference to high levels of resource utilization, when we’ve had it in
our past statements, would be a serious error.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Bies.
MS. BIES. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Well, I’m like everybody else around the table—
I have found the decision about which way to go to be a very tough call. I’m coming down on
the side of a pause right now, partly because I’m more pessimistic than the staff forecast on the

August 8, 2006

103 of 158

second-order effects of the slowdown in housing. We’re hearing from some bankers that
subprime borrowers especially are having more difficulties and that delinquencies in that sector
are going up. Although I don’t see a prolonged problem, as housing slows, the effects are going
to bleed into other sectors, and whether into home furnishings or other things, I think there will
be wider implications. I also think the optimism about the housing sector is so important to
people because it’s a big chunk of their net worth. So I’m just not as positive about the outlook
here.
Another concern I have is what is really happening with the disruption of oil supply
around the world. I think that situation is potentially more disruptive. We don’t put political
things in our forecasts. A good friend in the oil industry is very concerned, aside from the
political risk, about the operating risk in the industry right now, as I mentioned awhile ago. So I
think there is enough uncertainty out there that I’m on the edge, and it’s that uncertainty that
leads me to say, “Let’s take time out and pause.”
I like Governor Kohn’s suggestion for the change in alternative B. It’s important that we
signal resource utilization. It’s also important to signal that this is a pause and not a permanent
stop because, when you look at the futures curve, it’s as though the market figures that once we
stop we’re going to stop forever. It’s also important that we signal that we are pausing to see
what the lagged effects will be.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. From a capital markets perspective, as I think
about this decision, what matters more than the pricing of this issuance—that is, the decision on
25 basis points—is really what the after-market effects are. How is this security going to trade
over the next weeks and months? When I think about the decision in that context, it puts the

August 8, 2006

104 of 158

burden on the communications, which are only in small part in the message of our statement
today. At the end of the day, I am willing to agree to a pause. But, again, I think that puts the
burden on laying the predicate that we are in fact poised and prepared to act as necessary. That
begins with our statement, but it doesn’t end there. Given the data that are likely to come in
between this meeting and the next (a couple of CPIs, a couple of PPIs, maybe a revised PCE) and
what’s likely to happen to some of the forward-looking market indicators (TIPS spreads, some of
the commodity prices), I think it is very important that the markets understand, before the trading
in the security gets very significant, the depth of our thinking on the subject and of the discussion
around this meeting. The minutes can be part of that communication. Such communication is
important so that they don’t perceive us when we meet next to be reacting to one or two pieces of
data, the way they seem to have overreacted to one or two pieces of data last week, but really
recognize the depth of our thinking on this subject.
To be consistent with that view, I think Governor Kohn’s suggestion of indicating a
pause as powerfully as we can is critical. The markets, in the first days, are going to take our
pause to be a stop, as reflected currently in the Eurodollar futures contracts and the fed fund
futures contracts. But we need to disabuse them of that view as quickly, as frequently, and as
consistently as we can so that the pause does not become read as a stop. We will then have set
out the conditions for the ways in which we might react if different data arise. Again, I think that
the decision today is not an easy one. It’s important that the markets recognize that it is unlikely
that our work here is done. With all that said, I’m prepared to support Governor Kohn’s
suggestion.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kroszner.

August 8, 2006

105 of 158

MR. KROSZNER. As I said before, obviously this is an extremely difficult decision, and
I agree with many people around the table who have said that very respectable arguments could
be made on both sides. So I would say that, on net, there are some advantages to keeping policy
unchanged but communicating very, very strongly our wariness about inflation.
I think there is value in pausing to see what is going to happen with growth. Around the
table, we certainly expressed different views about what is happening to growth. We know that
we’re likely to continue getting somewhat unfavorable numbers on inflation, but I think the
markets are well primed for that. We’ve gotten some numbers that have been worrisome or
unwelcome and not particularly favorable on inflation, but we haven’t seen inflation expectations
become unanchored. Also, we’ve been seeing that the markets have apparently been assuming
that we are not going to move now and that we’re not going to move in the future, if you look to
the fed funds futures markets; but that assumption hasn’t manifested itself in any increase in the
short-term or longer-term inflation prospects.
That’s very heartening to me. If that weren’t the case, I would not feel comfortable in
moving toward supporting a pause because, as many of us have discussed, the expectational
context and credibility are very important. Credibility is an easy thing to lose and a difficult
thing to recapture, but I don’t think having a pause now would lead us to lose credibility. I think
also that it’s important that we see a pause as not being just until the next meeting but as possibly
going over multiple meetings because a lot of information, particularly with respect to inflation,
will come out over time. I expressed my view that we may be seeing some transitory effects on
inflation that are due primarily to shelter services. Within two or three meetings we’ll have a
better feeling for whether or not those effects are likely to be transitory, and I think keeping our
powder dry is very valuable.

August 8, 2006

106 of 158

We’ve been emphasizing not just that we are data dependent but that we are forecast
dependent. What do the data say about what is likely to happen in the future? Saying that we
are forecast dependent helps to underscore that, even though the current data or the recent
backward-looking data are not favorable, we are looking to the future to what the evolution of
inflation and growth is likely to be—exactly what the last line of alternative B emphasizes. I
think, one, it’s what we should be doing and, two, it’s important for people to see that. So I
would favor going with alternative B or having the language in alternative C. I’m not sure the
alternative C language adds all that much more, given the fairly strong statement that we have in
the assessment of risks, because I think that is likely to lead to a somewhat changed expected
feds funds futures curve—to leave some probability that we may move and that this is not a stop.
Certainly, if our pausing is interpreted as a stop, we need to pursue a communication strategy to
convey that it is not a stop and that a pause does not mean just one meeting but possibly multiple
meetings as we are gathering more information, particularly about the transitory versus persistent
effects of inflation, and are keeping a very careful eye on the effect of both short-term and longrun inflation expectations.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman Geithner.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We could obviously
justify moving today, but we don’t need to move today. We don’t need to move today
principally because we have an economy that has already slowed to what we think is trend and
because we have inflation expectations at the long horizon staying relatively stable despite
adverse inflation news and a fair amount of uncertainty about the path of inflation going forward.
That has happened, as many of you have said, in the context of substantial downward revisions

August 8, 2006

107 of 158

of the expected terminal fed funds rate. That’s a bit of an experiment in credibility. We don’t
want to take too much reassurance from that, but it’s positive.
I think we have to signal that inflation remains the predominant risk and that we may
have more tightening to do. We have to make it clear that, if expectations deteriorate or if our
forecast for inflation changes materially, we are prepared to tighten further. Many of the prisms
we look through to judge the appropriate path of policy going forward suggest we may have
more to do. They don’t tell us with any certainty that we have a lot more to do; they suggest that
we may have more to do. If you choose the 1.5 percent target for core PCE and take out the
inertial preference in the optimal policy rules, the case for going significantly above 5.25 on the
funds rate is pretty strong.
We need to look for the combination of action and message in the statement that gives us
the most flexibility going forward. It’s hard to know with confidence what that combination is.
My own view is that, if we don’t move today but we have a strong statement about the
asymmetry around the risks, we preserve the possibility of tightening further. If we move today
and the world unfolds as we expect, I think in some ways it’s harder at the margin to tighten
further. But none of us knows that with total confidence because we don’t know how the market
is going to interpret the statement.
Credibility is a very complicated thing. If we look as though we’re moving out of fear
that we’ve lost it, you could say that might be more damaging to perceptions about our
credibility. You can think about the dominant option on the table as a pause coming from a
position of strength and confidence and a move in these circumstances coming from a position of
greater tentativeness and weakness. I don’t think that would be desirable—it is something we
should try to avoid.

August 8, 2006

108 of 158

Looking at market expectations today, I see three things that make me uneasy. One is the
high degree of confidence that we’re pretty close to being done. The second is the inversion—
the speed with which they have us removing a bunch of policy tightening ahead. The third is the
degree of certainty or confidence in the path for interest rates. I don’t know why they have that
degree of confidence and certainty; [laughter] I don’t think we have it. It’s hard to know,
however, how to get us out of that mix. I think that, as several of you have suggested, it would
be nice if we made the market a little less confident that we’re going to be taking out the last
move or two of tightening pretty quickly. How to do that is difficult.
Alternative B, as modified by Don Kohn, comes the closest to doing so. I would also
favor a second suggestion, which is putting back in the reference to ongoing productivity gains,
for the following reason. We revised down our estimate of structural productivity growth a bit,
and that’s a material change in our view about productivity. But the basic forecast, as we best
judge it, is still a pretty good one for productivity growth. We don’t want to look as though
we’ve lost conviction about that basic positive outlook for productivity growth. Its omission
would be very conspicuous, and I don’t think we’ve learned enough to justify the risk of creating
the signal that we’ve lost confidence that we’re going to have productivity growing in the
vicinity of 2, 2½, 2¼ percent. For those reasons, I’d favor putting that back in.
Just to summarize, I’m reasonably comfortable not moving today, but I think we should
send a strong signal that the risks are still predominantly to the upside on inflation. I also think
that alternative B, as modified by Don, does the best job of communicating that message.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. First of all, I’d like to thank
everyone for a really helpful and thoughtful discussion. It was very useful. Let me just make a
few comments.

August 8, 2006

109 of 158

First, we do need to be careful to think about what the optimal policy looks like. It
doesn’t take the form that we keep raising rates until we’re happy with the inflation rate.
Instead, what we need to look for is the rate that, if maintained, will ultimately give us a good
trajectory in the economy. I would submit that we don’t really know where that is yet.
President Lacker made some very interesting arguments about the real rate of interest in
the late ’90s. Those are good arguments, but I would reply to him, first, that we’ve seen very
low real rates in the past decade, a global savings glut and all of that, and, second, we have at the
moment an IS shock of very significant and unknown size—the housing market, which is
declining very sharply. So I agree that we may well want to go up from where we are. I think
that’s, in fact, a more likely outcome. But we really can’t be sure at this point where we
ultimately want to stop, and we need to be a bit cautious and try to learn about exactly where that
level is going to be. For those reasons, I’m not comfortable with alternatives A or C because
they basically say that we’re done, either at 5.25 or 5.50, and so the choices then are between
alternative B and alternative D.
I’m concerned with alternative D because, besides raising the rate to 5.50, it signals
further increases. After seventeen consecutive moves, we would be tightening into a housing
decline. We don’t have that much confidence that we need to be so strong at this point.
Signaling a strong concern about inflation but being more cautious in groping for the optimal
level of the interest rate is probably a wiser course. I remind you that the Fed has not been
terribly successful with soft landings. We have a chance to get one. All else being equal, I think
it would be good if we could achieve that.
So I’d recommend alternative B. I’ll come back to the language in just a moment. I
characterize this as a hawkish pause. I think it has several advantages: The first is to gather

August 8, 2006

110 of 158

information. With respect to some of the points President Poole raised, I think the key
information we want to look at is, first, activity; we want to look at employment, housing, and
consumption, in particular, which will give us some indications about growth going forward.
But we also want to look at inflation data and inflation expectations data. Inflation expectations,
specifically, are mentioned in the statement, and an untethering of inflation expectations would
be, on its own, grounds for us to respond. The risk of our falling behind the curve by pausing is
relatively small. Again, I think that we’re not more than a couple of moves away from the
optimal level. Therefore, if we miss a meeting or two and then move again in November or
December, we will still be able to reach this optimal level within a reasonable period of time.
Moreover, we have a degree of freedom on the other end, so to speak. If the markets expect us
to begin to cut, we can always maintain the rate at the level for a longer period than expected to
get some further restriction. So on the substance I think there are grounds, after seventeen moves
and with the housing market in an indeterminate situation, to pause and to get more information.
I’d like to say a word about the tactics as well. President Minehan was correct that my
introduction of the idea of a pause was not particularly well received. But we have now, at least
reading the commentary, explained the difference between a pause and a stop. It’s useful for us
to get the flexibility that will allow us not necessarily to move at every meeting but to move as
the data require. A demonstration of that flexibility has some value in terms of creating some
more optionality for us in the future. Also, we have been talking about data dependence. By
creating this flexibility, we’ll be able to increase the relationship between what we do and what
the data say, and I think that’s already working. For example, I would note the wide dispersion
of views among the dealers about where we’re eventually going to stop. That dispersion of
views comes from differences about where they think the economy and inflation are going. It is

August 8, 2006

111 of 158

very encouraging to me that they are now not looking to us for forward guidance but rather
looking at the state of the economy and trying to judge where the Fed will have to go to achieve
its objectives. So recognizing the concerns that have been raised and taking them very seriously,
I think that our best option, of perhaps not very many great options, is a hawkish pause, which I
associate with alternative B.
With respect to the language, I think it is an improvement to take at least the first
sentence of section 3 in alternative C, which includes high resource utilization, and use it in place
of the first sentence of section 3 in alternative B. I have two questions for the group. One, do we
want to reintroduce or go back to our old language of including productivity gains? If so, that
would require the second sentence of alternative A, section 3. If not, we just use the whole
section 3 of alternative C. That’s question one. Two, President Poole has expressed concern
about the housing reference. We could simply say “reflecting the lagged effects” and leave out
the housing part. I would take suggestions on that. I would note that we have used this housing
phrase in the past few meetings, and so it would be a change. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. The unit labor cost figures suggest leaving productivity gains out of this.
That’s just my opinion.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Other comments? President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. If we were to keep productivity gains in, I would suggest striking the
word “ongoing.”
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any others?
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. May I say something on the mention of housing?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Certainly.

August 8, 2006

112 of 158

VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. I think Bill’s reservations about it are right. Of
course, they would have applied the last time we used it, too. I guess I would argue for keeping
housing in on the grounds that it’s happening. It is the principal area in which we see some
weakness going on in the economy, and not to make reference to that reality seems a little
awkward. It would be like having a statement that didn’t mention what’s happening in either
energy prices or housing, and that would be hard to justify. So I would keep it, on the simple
grounds that it is happening and it’s an accurate description of reality. I don’t think it’s a
problem.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Poole.
MR. POOLE. Section 2 can reasonably be interpreted as referring to second-quarter
GDP. That’s the news that we have, and there has been a slowing in a wide range of sectors. So
I think that that’s a sensible interpretation. There are continuing concerns about housing going
forward. I understand that. But it seems to me that section 2 is really a statement about what has
already happened in the economy—that’s the essential element of it—and housing is just not the
biggest thing that has happened. I would also agree with Jeff that we should keep productivity
out because people logically say, “Well, unit labor costs are what are really important here,” and
we don’t have a great story to tell on unit labor costs.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Kroszner.
MR. KROSZNER. I think it would be odd to take out the reference to housing, given
that we have mentioned it a number of times in the past. The rationale clearly says that it’s
“partly reflecting” and then gives a number of factors. It is not saying that those factors are the
only ones. Also, I don’t interpret this language as being simply about what happened in the past;
“has moderated” is also talking about where we are—that growth is not as strong as it was. I see

August 8, 2006

113 of 158

that language as having a forward-looking aspect to it. I think it would be very odd to take
housing out, partly because it’s factually accurate, even if you take the historical view, and partly
because, given our discussions around the table, we are concerned about “gradual cooling.” It is
appropriate to leave the reference in.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. I agree with Randy on this. It would be very strange to take housing
out now because it was in last time and because it is so important to the future of the economy.
The productivity question is a close call. On balance, I’d leave it out because it does raise the
whole question about unit labor costs.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any other views? President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I’m new to these language nuances about housing. It occurs to me,
however, that one question you ought to ask is whether by including housing or continuing to
include housing the Committee is putting itself in a position where it can’t raise rates until
housing comes back. Are we unfairly locking ourselves in, or at least are the markets going to
interpret it that way? That’s just another question to think about in deciding how to include it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Minehan.
MS. MINEHAN. I think that President Plosser has a good point there and President
Poole did as well. Section 2 is aimed at explaining what has happened with growth in the past.
Everything moderated. To me, the most surprising thing was how slow business fixed
investment was. It was not so surprising that housing was slow because we expected housing to
be slow, so I think you could easily take housing out of there. You have the lagged effects of
increases in interest rates, which affect housing as well as a whole range of other things. I also
think that Charlie has a good point. We don’t want to hang our action on one piece of data

August 8, 2006

114 of 158

versus another piece of data going forward. I’m agnostic about productivity, to tell you the truth.
I think the unit labor cost numbers are not good news—we have some problems there—and to
hang it out as a saving factor again and again may not be what we want to do.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. All right. I think we need to come to resolution. Oh, sorry.
Governor Bies.
MS. BIES. I would prefer to leave housing in because housing resources aren’t readily
substitutable for other parts of the economy. If we leave resource utilization in, we’re sort of
acknowledging that, although housing is soft, there are still resource pressures in other parts of
the economy. I think the picture is better balanced that way.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. Let me just say that I think this
language is purely descriptive. I don’t think it’s conditioning our action on anything having to
do with housing. I don’t think the market will tie our move to housing. Let’s just take a straw
vote. How many would like to keep the statement as it is with housing included? One, two,
three, four, five, six, seven, eight, nine, ten, eleven. Okay. I think that’s a majority. So we’ll
leave section 2 as it is. Is there any sentiment for going back to alternative A, section 3, second
sentence, which includes ongoing productivity gains? Are any of you in favor of that?
[Laughter] All right. The statement, then, will be exactly alternative B, except that the third
section of alternative C will be substituted for the third section of alternative B. Would you
please call the roll?
MS. SMITH. Yes. The directive would be, “The Federal Open Market Committee seeks
monetary and financial conditions that will foster price stability and promote sustainable growth
in output. To further its long-run objectives, the Committee in the immediate future seeks

August 8, 2006

115 of 158

conditions in reserve markets consistent with maintaining the federal funds rate at an average of
around 5¼ percent.”
Then the risk assessment is, “Nonetheless, the Committee judges that some inflation risks
remain. The extent and timing of any additional firming that may be needed to address these
risks will depend on the evolution of the outlook for both inflation and economic growth as
implied by incoming information.”
Chairman Bernanke
Vice Chairman Geithner
Governor Bies
President Guynn
Governor Kohn
Governor Kroszner
President Lacker
President Pianalto
Governor Warsh
President Yellen

Yes 

Yes 

Yes 

Yes 

Yes 

Yes 

No 

Yes 

Yes 

Yes 


CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. We have a lunch break now for
about half an hour, and then we’ll reconvene to discuss communications.
[Lunch break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I know some people have flights and so on, so why don’t
we continue eating here. If you’re still eating, we can just reconvene. Before we get going, I
just want to recognize Barbara Driggins over here. Barbara is retiring. [Applause] Thank you,
Barbara, for thirty-six years of service, and we hope this display of affection will cause you to
reconsider. [Laughter]
MS. DRIGGINS. I don’t think so. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Best of luck. Our afternoon session is on communications.
I’d like to turn it over to Governor Kohn.

August 8, 2006

116 of 158

MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We are in a hurry, and I don’t have anything
really in the way of introduction. I just want to say that we sent a list of questions, but we didn’t
expect answers to every question. We hope that the questions helped to spark thinking about
some of the broad issues related to communications—what we’re trying to do and the broad
strategy of how we should go about it. I remind you that, as the memo says, this is an initial
discussion. Time is limited, so we’d prefer not to get into the details of various proposals but to
think about broad issues of strategy and goals.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. We’re just going to have a go-round. Please raise
your hand, and Brian will take your name.
MR. KOHN. If no one wants to start, [laughter] I can start. I actually have just a couple
of things to say. We need to keep in mind that communication is not an end in and of itself. It’s
a means to an end. Where we rank on some professor’s table of transparency isn’t really what
it’s about. It’s about meeting our legislative objectives for stable prices and maximum
employment. As we think about our communication, we ought to concentrate on that—what our
goals and objectives are and where inflation and activity are going relative to those objectives,
given the shocks and dynamics of the economy, and the broad policy outlines for strategy to
foster those objectives. If we do that well, we’ll help achieve those objectives, both by building
public understanding of, confidence in, and support for a politically independent central bank
and by giving private agents, in financial markets and in labor and product markets, information
that should help them act in ways that will promote achieving our goals.
I think we’ve done a good job of this. Certainly, this institution for the past twenty-five
years has been pretty darn successful at achieving our congressional mandates, and our
communication has contributed to that. At least around the edges it certainly has helped, in both

August 8, 2006

117 of 158

the political and the economic dimensions. So I don’t think we have a communication strategy
that’s seriously broken, that needs radical surgery. But I do think it has grown in an ad hoc way,
separately in each area of communication—the announcement and the minutes, for example.
This is a good time to step back and see how things are fitting together—whether we can tailor
some things to some audiences and other things to other audiences that we want to attract and
whether anything is missing from the strategy.
The discussion this morning reinforced my view that we do need to talk about goals and
about whether we should be numerically defining price stability. There’s a presumption around
the table that we have already done this to a certain extent, but we haven’t as a committee.
We’re in a kind of untenable position right now in which the outside world doesn’t know how
we look at our objectives and how we would act. So we need to have that discussion, and I’m
glad that we’ve scheduled it for the first part of the discussion in October.
How the economy is doing relative to our goals, objectives, and strategy does require
forward-looking language. We tried to indicate in this memo that the forward-looking language
has pitfalls that we need to keep in mind as we go forward. What we know is limited. That
certainly was a theme this morning about our uncertainty, and conveying that uncertainty is
really, really hard. How we indicate the risks, which are almost as important as the central
tendency forecast, is something we’re going to need to work on.
There are issues about the market’s putting too much weight on what we say. I was
surprised, Mr. Chairman, by the reaction to your testimony and how much emphasis they seemed
to put on our projections, indicating where they thought things would be going forward. In
retrospect, I wonder whether there are ways of indicating our degrees of uncertainty around those

August 8, 2006

118 of 158

projections, and I think we need to honor and encourage the diversity and exchange of views in
the Committee.
All those issues are hard with respect to the outlook for inflation and economic activity,
and they are even harder with respect to the outlook for interest rates and our policy path in
particular. The issues of conditionality, overweighting, and flexibility become even more acute
when we start talking about our own policy path.
There are times, and the summer of 2003 was one of those, in which the market’s
interpretation of where our policy path might be has the potential for impeding our ability to
meet our objectives. In 2003 and the subsequent year or two years, I think we were right to put
some emphasis on that because, if we hadn’t, it would have been harder to meet our goals. But
for the most part, I think the markets should be able to infer what we’re going to do from how we
talk about our goals and our assessment of the economic developments, and we don’t need to
discuss the immediate outlook for policy. It would be nice to think about ways of getting away
from this business of signaling what we’re going to do exactly at the next meeting, partly
because we don’t know but also because it does sometimes build in expectations that affect our
decisions and dynamics. Those are some broad thoughts I had.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Minehan.
MS. MINEHAN. Oh, dear. So you didn’t want answers to all of these questions? This
homework assignment was significant. [Laughter] I agree with a lot of what Governor Kohn
has said. In my view, anyway, the principal goal behind central banks’ communicating what
they’re doing and why is that they need to be accountable for their actions in a democratic
society. I see that as the primary goal of all forms of central bank communication—that is, the
preservation of the legitimacy of the central bank. We’re not elected officials. We’re appointed

August 8, 2006

119 of 158

officials. We’re doing something that’s critical as far as the economy’s performance is
concerned, and we need to be accountable for it.
A secondary goal is to facilitate the transmission of monetary policy by better shaping the
market’s understanding of what we’ve done so that their actions can help the direction of policy.
But in that regard, in terms of the market’s facilitating the direction of policy, what we do really
ought to be more important—and I think Don was saying this—than what we say about what
we’ve done. Communication can help, but it can also hinder short-term market perceptions.
Over the longer run, what we actually do will create or destroy our credibility.
We also need—and I think this is consistent with what Don was saying—to think about
constraints. I would be very concerned if we ended up trying to convey the future course of
policy with certainty except in very unusual circumstances, like those that began in mid-2003. In
that regard, I took a measure of confidence in some of the Chairman’s discussion in the policy
round with regard to being encouraged that major market participants weren’t unanimous in what
they thought we were going to do, that there was a range of thought out there. I think we can
learn from that. If we force everyone to have a certain view about what we’re doing and then
they just feed back to us what we’ve told them, we’re losing a lot in terms of understanding
what’s going on in the market.
About some of the other questions here, I’ll just try to hit the highlights. On quantity—
we ought to think not about how much we communicate or how many instruments we have or
how different they are but about their effectiveness. It seems to me that we ought to try to
convey the uncertainties in the policy process in the most flexible and expansive of our
communication instruments—our minutes, the semiannual reports, the Chairman’s testimony,
and the speeches that we give. The least flexible and least expansive forms of communication, in

August 8, 2006

120 of 158

particular the statement, ought to be used to convey less-subtle information. Thus, as I’ve often
said in the past—and I think President Poole’s recommendations have been in the same
direction—we ought to focus more in our meeting statements on what we did and why and leave
the longer, more-nuanced discussion to the minutes or the semiannual reports.
If I had had a vote at this meeting, I wouldn’t have dissented on the pause, and I was in
favor of alternative B with the enhanced section to make it more hawkish. But when you step
back and you think about a hawkish pause, you wonder whether you’re asking your statement to
do a lot of work for you, particularly if you think you’re going to have to fill in exactly what you
meant by that statement in subsequent communications over the following weeks. So I think
some of that is a little tough.
On content—I don’t want to get into inflation targeting. Yes, we have to talk about it,
and we’ll get into that later in the year, I suppose. On forward-looking information—that goes
back to uncertainty. I would not like to get into the process, like some central banks, of giving a
future policy path. There are ways of facilitating the market’s understanding of what our
forecasts are and where we see the risks. Maybe we can do a better or more complete job with
our semiannual information, but I wouldn’t like to get into communicating a policy path.
Finally, on the subject of individuals versus a committee—I don’t think the Committee
should constrain individuals. That’s what the committee process is about—that we ought to feel
free to express our opinions here as well as outside the Committee. However, I also think that, at
times, circumstances are such that a number of us are speaking around the same time, which
creates the impression of committing the Committee. I would want all of us to think hard and
long about how we shape our public statements. Even though we all are very careful about not
committing the Committee by saying that these are our views and not the Committee’s views,

August 8, 2006

121 of 158

there are lots of ways of saying things within our various statements that can act more or less to
bind our hands going forward, and I’d like us all to be sensitive to that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Don, I appreciate the outline that you gave in
terms of raising the questions. I’ll be straightforward. As far as goals—what we are doing and
why is the important part of communication. That’s our obligation. That is part of transparency,
and it serves us well. Regarding our view of the future—I think we should outline that in terms
of the balance of risks. What we’re doing now is just about right, frankly. We need to get away
from the idea of trying to signal or giving a policy path. I think that gets us into some
difficulties. In addition, it binds Committee members who may not agree into the future, and
that’s a disadvantage to the Committee in the long run.
Having said that, I still think what we’re doing right now is pretty darn good. Having the
statement to say here’s what we did and why and the minutes to show the nuances of the views
gives further information to the markets and serves us well. Speeches may sometimes raise the
media’s attention, but I think they have served us well; I don’t think that we’ve gotten ourselves
into too many problems with them. Once we get through the discussion in October in terms of
the price goals and that sort of thing, how we communicate may change. So we may need to
have another discussion of this. But for the moment, with those comments, I’m pretty satisfied
with where we are.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll comment on just three areas, in the
spirit of being general here. First, on the goals—I thought the goals that you put into the
document you distributed were very good. They were very well stated and had an appropriate

August 8, 2006

122 of 158

balance. I didn’t think that they constrain open discussion at the meetings. The communication
of uncertainty and conditionality is difficult, but part of our goal should be to do it better.
Second, on the quantity of information and the forward-looking content—that whole
series of questions that you asked—I’d divide my comments into two parts. One, if we do go
with some type of quantitative guideline, we will need to release more information. We’d need
something like an inflation report, maybe quarterly, such as other central banks have, just to
explain and elaborate on the guideline and how the economy was doing versus that quantitative
guideline. I don’t think we could just stay with the twice-a-year report that we give now in
detail.
Third, we should talk about longer-term forecasts than we do now. That’s an important
part of this. In fact, if this Committee decides not to go with quantitative guidelines, we could
accomplish many of the objectives by just having longer-term forecasts for the economy. If we
did these longer-term forecasts, we’d have to address many of the issues that are discussed in the
sections here—the policy assumption question, for example. We now do that based on
appropriate policy, but we could do that in different ways. But the longer forecasts would allow
us to convey policy goals, to discuss expected paths to achieving those goals, and to take into
account the range of opinions regarding the paths and goals without necessarily having us agree
to a quantitative guideline. At this point, I’m agnostic on the question of whether we should
have a quantitative guideline. I should say that I really haven’t decided yet and that the topic is
for further discussion. In any case, longer-term forecasts would be one option to consider if we
did not go with a quantitative guideline. Of course, if we did go with a quantitative guideline,
we could also have longer-term forecasts. But I think the longer-term forecasts would help us
improve our formulation of monetary policy, either with or without a quantitative guideline.

August 8, 2006

123 of 158

I want to mention just one other point about the policy conditioning. I hope someone
could do research on the Bank of England approach. Don, I know you’ve been there. They
present a forecast conditioned on the market expectations for policy interest rates. They also do
an alternative based on an unchanged rate path. They’ve given us an example of one case in
which the forecast based on the market showed that inflation would be outside the guideline
when they published it, and the market immediately reversed its view as to what the Bank of
England was able to do on policy without the Bank’s saying anything. Just the publication of
that forecast itself accomplished a lot of their objective. Of course, we’d have to be explicit
about the technical details underlying the market expectations of the forecast, but that’s sort of a
technical part of this.
We’re off to a good start, and I particularly like the goals that you set forth.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me make just a few comments. I, too, like
the goals. To me, the overarching objective of our communication policy should be to enhance
the effectiveness of monetary policy. The goals that have been identified in this latest paper—
which I take to mean making sure that, insofar as possible, we build public support for our
policies and we work toward anchoring expectations—both work in that direction. It’s very
important that the public broadly defined understands what we’re doing and why.
One implication of that thought is that we don’t want to make the statements too terse.
Now, I agree that they are supplemented by the minutes, testimony, speeches, and so on and so
forth, but many people are wedded to the 2:15 p.m. announcement and the interpretations of that
announcement, both immediately in the afternoon on CNBC and so forth and the next morning in
the newspapers. If we make the statement too terse, we’re going to leave people sitting around

August 8, 2006

124 of 158

saying, “Well, we know what they did, but we don’t have much of an understanding of why, how
they view the world, where they think the risks lie,” et cetera. So I would be careful about
working really hard to shorten the statement.
One place we’ve had a lot of success, in my opinion, is in articulating our price stability
goal, why that’s the appropriate goal, and how it relates to the dual mandate. We’ve had more
success than I would have predicted, quite honestly, when we started to articulate that more
forcefully a good number of years ago. There might be something to be learned from that
approach because I think we have been pretty consistent about that message and even some of its
nuances.
We are going to get to the question about a numerical objective for inflation. When we
do, we’re going to have to think long and hard—I suspect this doesn’t come as any surprise to
anybody—about how that is going to play out in policysetting, in decisionmaking. We may need
to provide some sort of background paper to the public at large if we adopt it—in other words,
here is what we’re doing, here’s what we think the implications are, here’s how it’s going to play
out in a policy role, as best we can see it. That’s just something to think about for the future. I
think I’ll stop there.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think this Committee has made huge strides
over the past decade toward greater transparency and more-effective communication, an example
being that—it was in 1994, I guess—we actually started issuing post-meeting statements. I think
we’ve seen significant dividends from those innovations. They have advanced the goals of both
policy effectiveness and accountability. Our communication strategy at this point, in my view, is

August 8, 2006

125 of 158

not fundamentally broken, and so I hope that what we can accomplish in the coming months is to
produce some improvements in current practice without going for wholesale changes.
I thought today I would just touch on a couple of points that I’ve been thinking about
relating to communications, without getting into specifics. Frankly, I think the goals are fairly
noncontroversial. I regard them as pretty much motherhood and apple pie issues. What’s
challenging is figuring out exactly how to use communications better both internally in the
Committee and externally to serve our policy goals.
A couple of cautionary notes: First, I want to endorse the point that Don made that we
should not put in our list of goals that our objective is to maximize transparency for the sake of
greater transparency. The research in this area provides very ambiguous advice about how much
transparency is optimal. Second, we need to be careful that our communications don’t actually
impede the process of making appropriate policy decisions or our ability to do so. In contrast to
some of you, I have generally favored the inclusion of forward-looking language in post-meeting
statements, at least when the Committee has a reasonably clear idea of where policy is going, as
it has until quite recently. But including such guidance does have the potential for building false
expectations that can constrain our actions. I hope that we will continue to provide forwardlooking guidance to the public because I think it does enhance the effectiveness of our policy
actions. But I think we will need to be very clear that those kinds of policy pronouncements are
not unconditional commitments to future actions, and we need to continue to emphasize data
dependence.
I want also to emphasize a point that Cathy made, which is that communication is a
two-way street by which we communicate with markets and the public but we also receive
feedback from markets and the public concerning economic conditions and expectations

August 8, 2006

126 of 158

concerning the future. We benefit from that feedback perhaps as much as or more than the
public benefits from the utterances that we make. That is a kind of independent reality check on
our forecast and analysis. Therefore, we have to be careful to ensure that these outside voices
aren’t drowned out by people who parrot back what we say. There are times when I have very
much worried that our communications have turned the markets into a mirror in which we see
little more than our own reflection.
Now I’d like to spend just a couple of minutes on what to me is the most critical
challenge that we face as we go forward with our communication strategy. It relates to the
apparent dichotomy between speaking with one voice and speaking as nineteen individuals. The
question is how to provide the public with the clearest and most coherent description of our
collective goals, strategies, and policies while continuing to promote an environment in which
diverse opinions among the nineteen FOMC participants are not only tolerated but encouraged.
In the past we have managed this balancing act in different ways depending on the
circumstances, and we’re going to need that kind of flexibility as we go forward. On the one
hand, there are settings in which the Committee provides a reasonably unified view to the public;
that occurs in our post-meeting statements and also in the Chairman’s testimony to the Congress.
On the other hand, we have a number of outlets for the expression of members’ diverse views—
the FOMC meeting minutes, participants’ speeches, and the ranges of FOMC forecasts that are
published in the Monetary Policy Report. I think that type of approach, of having some unified
statements and many opportunities for expression of diverse opinions, is useful. First, it gives
the public a reasonably accurate sense of both the areas of consensus in the FOMC and the range
of opinion. Second, taking an “agree to disagree” approach lessens the likelihood that the
FOMC will become trapped in a kind of group-think mentality, in which we end up conforming

August 8, 2006

127 of 158

for conformity’s sake. Of course, with the freedom to disagree, we do have a responsibility,
when we make statements, to be careful that those statements are not interpreted as representing
the views of the Committee as a whole. Finally, an approach that tries to limit the range of
issues on which a committee as big as ours attempts to speak with a united voice will end up
enhancing the sense of collegiality and cooperation in the Committee.
The post-meeting statement provides a concrete example of the tricky balancing act that
we confront. We all know it’s often easier to agree on a decision concerning the federal funds
rate than it is to agree in every detail about why we came to that decision, let alone about what
we expect going forward. It’s impractical for the statement to convey the full range of our
opinions and to attempt to give very detailed explanations of the Committee’s thinking—again,
it tends to ignite disagreements about which specifics to include or to exclude and about even the
precise phrasing of each and every line. So in thinking about that, I find myself wondering if a
better approach might be to recognize the intrinsic limits of the statement and to focus on
communicating only necessary elements that clearly lie within the consensus view, leaving fuller
discussion to the minutes and other things.
The same issue about unity versus diversity is going to arise when we come to discussing
our longer-term inflation objective. I do greatly favor increasing clarity concerning the
Committee’s long-term inflation objective, but frankly I’m uncertain which approach is going to
be the most attractive to accomplish that. There is a range of possibilities. One possibility is that
the Committee could provide that type of information through the publication of the range and
central tendency of participants’ longer-term inflation projections, which presumably reflect
ultimately their inflation objective. Another possibility is that the Committee could try to agree
on the specific numerical objective to communicate to the public, assuming that a sufficient

August 8, 2006

128 of 158

consensus does exist in the Committee. Certainly, the benefit of the latter approach would be a
clearer signal to the public, which would be beneficial. But the tradeoff here is that we have to
be careful not to straitjacket participants into a particular view that they don’t fully endorse. So
as we go forward, I think we’re going to have to approach these issues case by case. In general,
as I think about the question of unity versus diversity in our communications, I am moving to the
conclusion that it’s probably better to err on the side of preserving the advantages of the diversity
of views at the cost of somewhat less of the clarity and coherence that would come if we could
provide a unified voice to the public.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The first set of questions from the
subcommittee had to do with goals and principles. The first principle I’d bring to this is that
money is intrinsically worthless and has value only because people expect it to have value in the
future. So, to be a little provocative, I’ll say that monetary policy is about people’s expectations,
and everything else is just commentary. Therefore, I fully support the first goal—helping people
form expectations regarding our future policy actions is a reasonable goal for communication
policy. The second goal seems clear, too—ensuring accountability to the people who have
granted us this monopoly on policy actions.
It’s important to be clear about what’s meant by communication regarding future policy
actions. It may mean saying something about the future path of interest rates—and we’ve done
that several times—but it doesn’t have to. An alternative approach is to articulate what
objectives will determine our interest rate choices in the future, and in principle, someone who
understands our objectives and the constraints we’re under will be able to figure out what we’ll
choose in any given circumstance. I think this offers really good prospects for overcoming some

August 8, 2006

129 of 158

of the problems that the Committee has encountered with the forward-looking guidance
language, when we essentially tell the public what interest rate settings we think will likely be
required to achieve our objectives. It seems as though communicating that would be enhanced
by telling them what our objectives are. In a sense, that would aid efficiency.
The subcommittee asked what constraints affect our communications. The obvious one
that comes to mind is time consistency—essentially, the idea that our claims about our future
actions are credible. People have to think that our future selves, be they us or our successors,
will actually want to follow through on the actions that we’ve implied by our communications—
we are selecting what our future selves are going to select. The question of whether our
communications will constrain our future selves immediately arises. Now, one can make some
stark assumptions about this question. In the literature, you typically see just two polar cases
analyzed: One is “yes, totally”—the perfect commitment case; the other is “no, not at all”—the
complete discretion case. But for the purposes of our discussion, I think it makes sense to adopt
the intermediate view that our future selves are likely to view it as costly to be perceived as
taking actions that contradict what we had previously communicated. So I’m happy to assume
that our statements are not cheap talk, to use game theory language. At the same time, I don’t
think the credibility of our communications is perfect or costless. At all junctures we need to
think through whether we will want to follow through on what we’re implying by our
communications.
That idea is related to a separate issue that often arises in discussions of inflation
targeting and communications, and that is whether communication will reduce our future
flexibility. At this point, let me just say that to stabilize the value of money we have already
sacrificed a great deal of flexibility. I’d claim that we’ve given up the flexibility to inflate or

August 8, 2006

130 of 158

deflate at 10 percent in any given year, in the near future. We’ve given up a lot of things to
convince people that money should have about the value it has now. So it really isn’t a question
of giving up flexibility; it’s a question of what flexibility we want to give up. Here I’d make
another point as well. If communication is going to have any value at all, it’s going to persuade
some people to change their minds about what actions we would take in the future. Well, if
that’s true, then in some sense it has to involve our giving up some of the flexibility that the
public has perceived us to have. So while there are flexibilities we would like to preserve, there
are flexibilities we’d like to give up. I don’t think flexibility per se is a trump card in this
situation.
The subcommittee asked about what information should be communicated. I’ll just focus
on one thing that I talked about earlier today, and that’s our long-run inflation objective. Let me
be precise about what I mean here. Averaging across all possible futures, taking into account
how we are expected to react in each possible future, what is the inflation rate n periods from
now? It may not be perfectly certain, but what is the average across all of those futures, taking
into account how we’re going to react? Let me define that average as long-run expected
inflation, at least the long-run expected inflation associated with the public’s beliefs about our
reactions that are built into that thought experiment I just described. In most of the standard
models (except for those in which some learning about the policymaker is occurring)—models
with Taylor rules or some other fixed reaction function plopped in—if you take n out long
enough, like five years or so, long-run expected inflation is a single number that never varies. As
I mentioned earlier this year, I don’t think that’s the world we live in now. Personally, I think
that we ought to try to agree on a value for where we want inflation to be on average and
communicate it to the public. I don’t see the benefit in terms of short-run flexibility of letting

August 8, 2006

131 of 158

expected inflation n years ahead have a big, wide, and disperse probability distribution around it
or having the mean of that distribution fluctuate a lot. I can see the value of being flexible about
how fast—a couple of years or a couple of quarters—we return inflation to target or about how
far from target we let it drift; but I just don’t see the value of allowing fluctuation in our inflation
objective years out.
Whenever I encounter one of those software programs for calculating your retirement
income and they ask for a lot of assumptions—such as your age, your salary, your age at
retirement, and how fast your wages will go up, and all—and they get to a box where they ask
what the inflation rate is going to be, I think to myself, I don’t know what to put in there.
[Laughter] And I think—that’s exactly right. I know what I’d like to put in there, but at this
point that’s just wishful thinking on my part, and I’m hesitant to do that. I’m certainly not going
to do that for my brother-in-law when he asks. [Laughter]
I think it’s a real tragedy that we don’t have anything to tell the country for circumstances
like that. It’s the one thing that we ought to be able to pin down in the long run; it’s the one
thing we know we can deliver. We can’t deliver a predicted average real growth rate; we know
we can’t deliver a predicted average unemployment rate; but we all agree we have a fair amount
of latitude about the long-run inflation forecast. Anyway, that’s what I have to say about this
subject.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Guynn.
MR. GUYNN. Mr. Chairman, since I’m not going to be here in October, I probably
should sit quietly; but I can’t resist. I think almost everything has been said. I want just to
comment quickly on a couple of things. I’m not sure we really talked about a very fundamental

August 8, 2006

132 of 158

question—that is, who it is we are trying to communicate with. That deserves a bit of discussion,
it seems to me.
Building on the whole notion of trying to quantify our objectives, I think we’ve seen what
a box we can get ourselves in. In the absence of something, we all start offering our own
quantitative whatever. At the current time, we’re in a position in which many of us have
specified what we think our comfort zone is. We haven’t explained how we’re going to measure
it; we haven’t reconciled the differences across people; we haven’t explained what we’re going
to do when we’re not there; so we’ve gotten ourselves in this kind of halfway house. Whether
we’d like to talk about inflation targeting and all the things that go with it or not, we’re going to
have to stop and deal with it.
We haven’t really talked very much about the role of the forecasts—and I hope
policymaking has always been based on forecasts—but we have been much more explicit about
that role in recent times. That opens up the whole question of whose forecast and how we talk
about forecasts at all the different stages.
Finally—and I can’t resist commenting—I think the greatest short-term tension regards
the issue of what to do with the four-paragraph post-meeting statement and what to do with the
minutes. I’ve more and more come to the view of Bill Poole that less is more. We simply can’t
get very much of the different ways of thinking into that four-paragraph statement. I think that’s
an impossible task. We all think about it very differently. We’ve heard it today. The statement
is simplistic. I would hope when you get around to talking about the issue that it would be clear
that the minutes offer a much better way of trying to help people understand not only the
uncertainty but the range of views that go with the policymaking and not let that little simplistic
statement after a meeting become the most important communication. End of story. Thank you.

August 8, 2006

133 of 158

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Poole.
MR. POOLE. Let me concentrate on the forward-looking information on the federal funds
path or something associated with it. One of the problems I have with Janet’s position is that, every
time we put that information in, we need to have an exit strategy of how we’re going to get it out.
As soon as you stop putting it in, you get yourself tangled up. In fact, I think that’s where we are
today and one of the reasons that we have the language in the statement that we do today. I would
put it in only under very special circumstances with a clear understanding of the strategy of how to
get it out.
The argument of this whole bias/tilt language goes back to Volcker, I believe; it was used as
a device to try to produce more agreement within the Committee. Then it was continued under
Greenspan. It wasn’t announced to the public. So the idea was that you would get some people to
go along with what the Chairman wanted by saying that we’ll have a tilt toward X or Y, up or
down; it was meant to produce a larger vote for the consensus. Once we started to announce it
publicly, it started to affect the markets. I was part of that decision. I was in favor of it at the time,
and I have since had very strong second thoughts about it—in part because of the experience of
trying to get out from under it once we started down that road.
We need to put more thought into explaining in our statement the decision that was reached,
which we don’t do very much of really. We don’t put much text around the reason for the decision,
compared with the risks or the foreshadowing of what we might do in the future. So that’s where I
would put my effort in drafting the statement.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I agree that the goals listed in the
subcommittee’s memo are the right goals. However, in thinking about the next few questions

August 8, 2006

134 of 158

concerning the quantity and the content of the information and the nature of any forward-looking
information that we provide, I find it difficult to make judgments without knowing where we’re
going to emerge from our discussion about what policy approach we take, especially the discussion
about whether we’re going to adopt a numerical inflation objective. As others have said, I think that
our communication practices need to reinforce our policy strategy. In fact, we should consider our
communication practices to be a part of our policy strategy.
So, for example, if we move down the path of adopting a numerical objective for inflation,
then the appropriate communication strategy may simply be to provide the explicit inflation
objective with little guidance about specific policy moves beyond reference to our performance
against that objective. In that case, I think there would be less need for information in the statement
that follows our meeting. However, it might require more information in our semiannual report to
the Congress.
Then regarding the forward-looking language, again I think it depends on whether or not we
adopt a numerical objective for inflation. A successful communication strategy should first and
foremost give the public confidence that we’re going to produce low inflation over the long run. I
don’t think that a good communication policy strategy, as others have already said, necessarily
means that we have to make sure the public can anticipate our next policy move. If we have a
numerical objective helping us to anchor long-term inflation expectations, then that forward-looking
guidance might be reserved for those times when the Committee has a great deal of certainty in the
course of its near-term policy moves or when it perceives that the cost of being misunderstood is
just exceptionally great.
Regarding the last set of questions from the subcommittee involving the individual
communications or the Committee communications, I believe that whatever communication

August 8, 2006

135 of 158

strategy we adopt, it is important to preserve our ability to give and express independent views,
especially about forecasts, policy strategies, actions, and so forth. It’s clear that each of us
formulates our own independent opinions about policy actions, and we form those opinions from a
sense of how we think economic conditions will evolve. I’d like to preserve the ability that we
enjoy today of sharing our independent thinking and the climate that I sense we have today of a
Committee that’s very skilled at building consensus around different perspectives but yet sees the
benefit of respectful dissent. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Well, Mr. Chairman, we do have responsibility for a fiat currency, and my
straightforward and undiplomatic way of describing what we do for a living is that we are
performing a great confidence game. I think that’s important to bear in mind. As President Yellen
said, this is apple pie and motherhood. The answer is “yes” to the first questions, but there are
questions about which agents we are talking about and, when we talk about generating wellinformed expectations, how we do so.
I mentioned earlier, to Governor Kohn’s embarrassment, “full frontal exposure,” and I think
that’s not an unimportant point. To maintain the confidence game that we have to maintain and—if
you’ll permit me to say this having experienced the other side—to maintain the last bastion of
integrity in Washington—and I feel very strongly about that—we have to be very careful that we
preserve a bit of modesty and mystery to accomplish our goals. The really tough part is how far we
go, and that’s what we’re going to have to talk about going down the path. For example, I’m
somewhat uncomfortable, even though I have great respect for President Moskow, about making
long-term forecasts. The further out you forecast, the more probable error is. I am wary of

August 8, 2006

136 of 158

exposing our vulnerabilities, and I think we should be mindful of that as we go through time. That’s
just one thought.
Another thought is about the statement. I may have forgotten my logic here, but I think we
should be as straight as Occam’s razor—that is, we should take as few variables as possible to
explain what we decide to do. I do think the minutes are very important for illumination. I don’t
want to manipulate the minutes, but I think we can use them quite effectively. In my statement
earlier in the meeting, when we were discussing our view of the economy, I said that I think we did
that very effectively the last time around.
Then a third point—I’m a strong believer in partnerships. I mentioned this at a dinner with
the Presidents last night. I’m also a very strong believer in a strong managing-partner model,
having worked all my life in the private sector in partnerships. But I do think it’s very, very
important to have a diversity of views, and so I second what has been said at the table on that front
as well. Those are my three comments, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Bies.
MS. BIES. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, support the broad goals that are laid out here.
In thinking about communication, I see that one challenge we will have relates to some of the
dialogue we had today. We set some long-term goals. How do we link those to what we do in
individual meeting actions and decisions? We already talked about how inflation has been above
our 2 percent top goal for two years, and it is likely to be so for two years more. How would we
explain that when we were trying to go forward? This is the sort of problem that corporations have
every year, when they set goals for shareholder returns, but then the earnings jump around like
crazy quarter to quarter. Well, we’re going to have the same kind of issue. It raises the question of
whether we want to talk about how we’re going to get from one place to another. In other words, a

August 8, 2006

137 of 158

company can say that they took these big chargeoffs, but that will reduce the cost base, or that they
are making an acquisition. We need to have some real dialogue about what a set goal is going to
mean for our short-run communications after each meeting and for the policy path. It’s the
difference between setting the goal and implementing and executing it effectively. If we can’t
communicate how we intend to implement effectively, then we ought to have second thoughts about
the goals that we’re setting. Since I’ve been here we really haven’t talked a lot about how to tie
those two together.
On the forward-looking information—it might have been appropriate back when we started
this 25 basis point step-up each meeting. I’m glad we’re now taking the position that we’re trying
to push the risk back to the market. The market has to make its own forecast of what’s likely to
happen. We need to be clear as to what the key drivers are and pick the few vital elements that we
really all can agree on. We need to communicate that well but make the market judge where those
variables are likely to go in the outlook. I don’t think we do a service to ourselves or to the market
if they feel they can sit back and let us make the call. The moral hazard and other issues there are
simply too great.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Just a few brief comments. First, with respect
to the concision of our statement and the minutes, I guess in a perfect world the minutes would
come out much sooner after our statement, but I recognize all the work that needs to get done to get
consensus and understanding on those.
I have a modest suggestion, which we can take back up in October. The minutes could end
up being released somewhat sooner but also be more corporate in nature. It strikes me that a lot of
the communication that we do through the minutes is useful for history and for an understanding of

August 8, 2006

138 of 158

many of the nuances that we’ve talked about but is probably not that useful for some of the other
communication purposes discussed here. It would certainly be useful if the crucial arguments in the
discussion we had today were available in the minutes before three weeks have elapsed. That
would take some of the burden off figuring out what goes into the statement. Without burdening the
staff by getting the same product done sooner, we could think rather about what should be part of a
corporate-style set of minutes. We’ve taught the market that a full set of the minutes would come
out, but my own suggestion is that the full set could be somewhat delayed. That’s just a sort of
provocative suggestion without as much discussion and thought as we’d want, but I think it partly
addresses the statement issue.
Second, on striking the right balance between individuals and the Committee, I’m more
convinced than ever, now that I have gone through four FOMC meetings, that the diverse views that
people express on monetary policy outside this meeting are important and are critically independent.
What I’m going to say is not an attempt to break that divergence of views or dissuade people from
sharing them. I think it’s actually more problematic when FOMC participants say similar things
between meetings. For example, Mr. Chairman, let’s say that you said X and that 18 of us went out
and repeated X more or less identically after the meeting. The market understanding of that is no
longer X or 2X but perhaps 10X or 12X, and I think that does prove problematic. A burden should
be on each of us, when we take our messages to different places between meetings, to be thinking
about the consequences, in particular, when we’re saying similar things. None of that means to say
that if you believe Y instead of X you should not be able to go scream that from the hills; but if you
believe a nuance of X, you really have to consider how the markets are going to understand the
repetition that they’ve heard.

August 8, 2006

139 of 158

Third, just a brief point about market discipline—I think President Yellen and President
Minehan made reference to this. We’ve been fairly cognizant over the past several meetings about
getting the markets to do their own work and not to rely on us. That market discipline is very
important. Governor Kohn said at the outset that the purpose of this discussion is not to have
transparency for transparency’s sake but to try to get to the right monetary policy objectives. It
strikes me as though we could well test the limits of transparency by sharing too much information
and getting the markets in a position where they stop doing much of the homework we’ve only
started getting them to do at this point. The right place to come to that judgment is somewhere
around where that transparency ends up making them more lemmings than we’d ideally like. I must
admit that I’m not exactly sure how to pull that off, but it strikes me that’s the way to structure or to
think about that discussion. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The goals are pretty clearly stated, and I have
no real problems with them. I agree that communication and transparency are really a key part of
maintaining and enhancing our own credibility. I also understand, as I listen to people around the
table and other conversations, that some of these issues have no easy or clear answers to them, and I
should note in advance that my own views are evolving as I think about and understand the nuances
of the issues. I agree with President Yellen. I’d like to applaud the Committee because in the past
ten years there have really been great strides in both transparency and communication.
Part of the challenge, it seems to me, is how we meet these goals. I think it’s true that
putting some limits on what information is released is probably necessary over certain periods of
time. For example, I wouldn’t advocate opening the FOMC meetings to the public; I think that
would not be terribly useful. On the other hand, Governor Warsh was just talking about perhaps

August 8, 2006

140 of 158

releasing minutes earlier or faster or some version of them, maybe with incomplete detail, but
including the tone and nature of the discussion. I think it could be fairly useful and informative,
particularly if it noted disagreements or discussions in terms of where the tension happened to be
within the meeting. I spent several months at the Bank of England a couple of years ago and
watched the give and take among committee members at the MPC and also watched them go out in
public and discuss their different views and why they disagreed with each other. That was very
instructive to me because they did it without apparently adding to volatility in the marketplace. The
market had come to accept the notion that these people disagreed on some things.
The information released might differ depending on the type of monetary regime we think
we’re in—whether in a regime of inflation targeting or one of full discretion. However, regardless
of the regime, the need for policymakers to clearly communicate what their goals are, their
understanding of the economy’s current economic conditions and expected future conditions, and
then the reasons for their decisions is an important part of communication.
As to the quantity of information, quantity and quality to me are intertwined, so I’m going to
talk about both of them together. Again, I applaud the expedited release of the minutes. Instituting
that was a tremendous step forward, and I think it’s a very good idea. However, I would favor the
Committee’s releasing some additional pieces of information. I obviously favor stating an explicit
definition of price stability because doing so would help clarify our goals. The current practice of
citing the range and central tendency of members’ forecasts is fine, but I would favor our releasing
more information, perhaps in a quarterly forecast or in something like an inflation report, to help
convey to the marketplace and the public what our range of views is and where the Committee
stands on the state of the economy.

August 8, 2006

141 of 158

It might help the public’s assessment of our views if we based our forecasts on some
underlying policy assumptions rather than on what one might call appropriate policy, which might
differ from member to member obviously and would likely not be well understood by the public
anyway. One suggestion that has already been mentioned is conditioning the forecasts on the
market’s expected funds rate path, for example. But in some way stating our assumptions or
projections about potential GDP would be important as well because that information, again, will
help the markets and market participants understand where the Committee is coming from.
In regard to forward-looking information, I think there are a number of things that the
FOMC could and should communicate, but its current expectation about the future path of the fed
funds rate is not one of them. I don’t think that’s a very good practice in general. However, I do
think that what we need to do is talk more about what our goals are, what our forecasts of those
goals are, and even more in a qualitative sense the process by which we think we’re going to get
there. That is to say, talking about how monetary policy will respond to various events—I hesitate
to use the phrase “decision rule”—wouldn’t necessarily say anything about the future path of the fed
funds rate, but it would be very informative.
It’s critical, as has already been mentioned, that the FOMC members agree on what the
goals are. The members don’t need to agree on the model of the economy or the channel by which
they think monetary policy actually operates. Indeed, given the state of economic science, the
differences in models and channels can aid in policy formation. Similarly, since dissents at this
meeting are public, dissenters should feel free to explain the reasons for their dissent. We shouldn’t
discourage presidents and other members from expressing their views about the state of the
economy and the process. Committee members should be free to indicate how their views on the

August 8, 2006

142 of 158

economy are evolving. In fact, I think that doing so supports our goal of helping the public form
sound expectations of what policy is actually going to be.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman Geithner.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Thank you. I want to start by saying that I think we’re
confronted with a set of issues that really aren’t principally about communication and transparency.
I think they’re fundamentally about how we conduct monetary policy and the monetary policy
regime we’re going to operate under.
I want to say a little about what I see as the hierarchy of challenges or decisions we have to
make in that context. We have to have a discussion about what objectives, particularly in terms of
inflation, will guide this Committee’s decisions going forward, and I think it’s hard to do that
without a discussion in quantitative terms. We also need to get in the position of thinking and
talking through more directly and candidly at these meetings how we make decisions about the most
appropriate path for inflation and output, especially at times when we’re way off our basic
objectives. We don’t really do that now. We’ve been living with a lot of ambiguity about whether
we’re operating with, in effect, an objective of getting core PCE down to some particular level at a
certain time or not, and I don’t think we can be comfortable living with that degree of ambiguity
much longer. In some ways, that set of issues is the first we have to confront. We may not get
consensus or resolution, but we have to talk through those issues.
We also have to decide what we want to disclose in terms of our objectives, our forecast, the
policy consistent with that forecast, and uncertainty. We face a lot of choices in terms of what we
do and how we do it regarding quantitative versus qualitative and explicit versus implicit
approaches to communications. Several of you said that in our statements we should simply say
what we decided and why, but I don’t think it’s quite that simple. The “why” has a lot to do with

August 8, 2006

143 of 158

the forecast, and to say nothing about the forecast in the statement would be communicating little
about the reasons for our policy decisions. But the “what” is also not simple: It is certainly not
principally about whether or not we move the fed funds rate. The “what” we’re deciding has to do a
lot with whether we take a view about or try to change or validate the market expectations going
forward over some period. So I don’t think we can get through the choices about communication
and transparency by just agreeing that we want to limit ourselves to the more-minimalist objectives
of communicating what we did and why. It feels to me a little more complicated than that.
The third point is a general point. If we are going to change the regime, we can’t do it
piecemeal. We can’t decide that we want to announce a quantitative definition of long-term price
stability without confronting the kind of disclosure regime that we have to adopt in support of that.
Also, we can’t think sensibly about the evolution of our disclosure regime around the forecast, for
example, without coming to some greater understanding about whether we disclose a quantitative
objective for inflation. So I think they need to be viewed as a package. For a similar reason, I think
we can’t approach this set of changes by saying let’s move on the things that are easy or less
contentious or have more of a consensus without having a better sense of where we really want to
go. That doesn’t mean that we should change all at once or, if we decide to change things, we do
them all together. We can still decide to have a graduated approach to introducing the changes in
the regime, but before we make an incremental move, we need to have a better sense about where
we want ultimately to go. If we don’t have consensus about where we want to go, then it’s harder to
decide what the incremental move should be. It doesn’t mean we should be inert.
It’s very healthy to have a candid discussion about what we think is wrong with our current
regime. I used to work with somebody who said to me, “Don’t bring me problems without
solutions.” Therefore, discomfort with a set of attributes of our regime relative to the experience of

August 8, 2006

144 of 158

other countries is really not enough to justify change. We have to be able to look at the proposals
for change and be very comfortable that they’re going to respond to the problem without leaving us
with a set of other collateral risks or disadvantages. It’s also good to have a direct and open
discussion about what we do not want to try to achieve through communications. I’m very
uncomfortable with what I think it would be fair to say is a substantial faction in the academic
profession now, which says that the optimal communication policy of central banks should be to
seek very close alignment between the market’s expectations about future policy and the central
bank’s and to achieve that alignment in real time and not have long periods of wide divergence
between what the market thinks and what we think is appropriate. That position strikes me as
highly unrealistic and complicated and maybe difficult to achieve, but we should talk through that
issue. I think it’s also unrealistic to say that we should avoid clarity about our views on the future
course of the economy and policy. That pure fog alternative seems unsatisfying and uncomfortable
to me.
I have nothing to add to the discussion about diversity. There are great benefits to diversity.
I do think we should try to avoid having, because of scheduling, many members of the Committee
talking in the same period. It is difficult to achieve but worth thinking about.
Finally I just want to compliment the subcommittee. The way you have laid out the issues is
very nicely done. I also want to compliment the Chairman for approaching this subject very openly,
having us try to think through all the difficult choices involved together, and allowing some
analysis, debate, and a little competition for ideas help inform choices about how we go forward. I
think that approach is admirable, and I commend you for it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kroszner.

August 8, 2006

145 of 158

MR. KROSZNER. I’ll be very brief. I think a number of the points that Vice Chairman
Geithner made are excellent, in particular his emphasizing that we have to think about this as a
package but not as necessarily meaning that we must implement everything at once. We may want
to see how the pieces are working before we do that, but we do have to have the ultimate goals in
mind. We need to have the whole thing together before we can start moving forward because it
could be quite dangerous to change some aspects of communication policy but then realize that, if
we want to do something else different down the line, we’ll have to change them again. So I think
that approach is exactly the right one.
Also because what we’re doing relates to any changes, we have to think about the dynamics.
We see this now in the persistence of certain words in our statements. We use the word once, but
then do we use it again or do we not use it again? Individual words take on an incredible amount of
importance. Now, one way to solve that problem is perhaps to put out more and more words so that
each one is diluted. [Laughter] An awful lot of private-sector resources were devoted to the
three-letter word “yet” that came out of one of the statements, when I believe that not a single
member of the FOMC even noticed it. I think that is problematic. I’m not quite sure of the best
way to solve that problem, but I think we have to be very sensitive to that.
On the issue of the one versus the whole, the markets have a very strong perception of
coordination among us. The notion that the Governors are independent and that the Federal Reserve
Bank Presidents are independent is considered laughable. When people ask me about that, they say,
“Well, doesn’t he tell you what to do?” I say, “No, no one tells anyone what to do.” Maybe you’d
like to, [laughter] but that’s not how it operates. Part of that notion is just a perception, and so
having people speak at the same time may not be much of a problem. But the perception is that it’s
a coordinated effort rather than a series of individuals who are expressing their views, and I think

August 8, 2006

146 of 158

communicating the extent of our independence or the extent of our coordination is something that
would actually go a long way toward things. I was one of those academics that Don referred to as
putting up those tables and trying to figure out whether we were independent or not, sort of rating
us. But that is not what we’re supposed to be doing, and I hope my comments will not be taken in
that context.
One final remark is that we have to be modest about what we’re trying to do. Part of this
discussion is the way of conveying our uncertainty. I would close my class on money and banking,
and I’ll close my remarks here, by presenting a fantastic New Yorker cartoon. It relates to the
former Chairman and shows someone praying, just before going to bed, about the former Chairman,
that he knows what he knows, he knows what he doesn’t know, and he knows the difference. It’s
important for us to be able to try to convey to the markets that we know what we know, we know
what we don’t know, and we do know the difference.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. What if we don’t know what we don’t know? [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Let me add just a couple of very general comments. I hope
that in our discussions about communication we’ll be aiming to make policy work better. I think
that involves trying to make the markets and the public form expectations that are at least broadly
consistent with our goals and our strategy and trying to anchor long-term inflation expectations to
the extent possible. Even if you are skeptical about our ability to do this, you may still agree that we
want to avoid miscommunication and unnecessary volatility to the extent possible.
I agree also that in general we don’t want to provide the future funds rate path. I see a lot of
problems with that. One of the reasons not to do it is that, if the market is forced to infer the funds
rate path from economic information, that inference provides information to us. Otherwise, they’re

August 8, 2006

147 of 158

simply repeating what we tell them. In an ideal world, how would we get the market to infer our
expected path? Well, we would provide them with a conditional forecast with error bands and all
kinds of conditioning assumptions, and we would tell them about our objective function, which
would include not only the long-term objectives but also the relative weights on inflation and output
and the shape of the risk aversion coefficients and the like.
Now, of course, we can’t do that. Besides the technical difficulties, as has already been
pointed out, we have nineteen very distinct points of view around the table. But I do think there are
ways to communicate this kind of information to the public. As an example, in my monetary policy
testimony I very consciously—whether it was successful or not I leave it to you to judge—talked
about our Committee projections, which gave the public not only some insight into what our general
views were but also information about our preferences because it showed a relatively gradual
decline in inflation. This removed the fear that at least some market participants had that we were
going to try to bring inflation down extremely quickly and extremely far. In that respect, it was very
useful, and I generally agree with President Moskow and others that more-detailed and morefrequent projections might be a very useful way for us to go in the future.
Finally, since we don’t have the budget to hire a semiotician, I do want to express some
frustration with the coded language that we rely on so heavily—I have been exposed to some of the
pitfalls that it can create. I think that we are reaching the limits of what codes can provide, and I’d
like to encourage us to think about ways to use quantitative information, like forecasts, to provide
more information and thereby reduce the weight that’s placed on any single words in statements and
the like. So those are just a few comments.
I want to thank everybody for an excellent discussion and for a lot of patience. I appreciate
it very much. Our next meeting is on Wednesday, September 20, and we are adjourned.
END OF MEETING