View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC BRIEFING - P.R. FISHER

AUGUST 22, 1995
Mr. Chairman:
Point-to-point comparisons of interest rates and exchange
rates since your last meeting reflect, to a great extent, the
changed outlook for the U.S. economy.

However, the dollar has

also benefitted from shifting perceptions about Japan and Germany
and a number of uncertainties hang over the bond market.

In early July, most market participants thought the economy
was likely entering a period of pronounced weakness and,
following the Committee's July action, they thought the Committee
would be easing rates repeatedly.

Now, following the more upbeat

economic reports of the past weeks, few see pronounced economic
weakness ahead and both bond yields and the dollar have backed up
off of their recent lows.

Prices on the near-term interest rate futures contracts
continue to imply a further 25 basis point ease by the Committee
before year-end.

The October Fed Funds contract can be read as

implying around a 30 percent probability of a 25 basis point cut
in rates at the Committee's September meeting and, in the absence
of any such move in September, the November contract suggests a
similar 30 percent probability of a 25 basis point reduction at

-

2

the Committee's November meeting.

-

However, I think the growing

view in the market is one of outright uncertainty as to whether
and when the Committee might ease again, with a small, but
notable, minority who think that the Committee's next move will
be to raise rates sometime next year.

The scaling back of expectations for further easing moves,
which occurred over the summer, made it harder for the Street to
digest the Treasury's recent refunding.

Many dealers also

appeared to reduce their risk exposures during the period,
contributing to somewhat greater intra-day volatility.

The debate over fiscal policy has provided an additional
reason for uncertainty in the bond market, with the extent,
timing, and impact of any significant deficit reduction hard for
market participants to assess -- particularly in the context of
uncertain expectations for the economy.

I should note that I do not think that the market has yet
priced in the risks of a disruption to the auction calendar, or
the unthinkable risks of a default by the Treasury, which might
occur in October or November as a result of Congressional
unwillingness to increase the debt ceiling.

The dollar's gains since your last meeting -- 14 percent

against the yen and 7 percent against the mark -- reflect more

- 3

-

than the changed perception of the U.S. economy and the backup in
interest rates here.

The dollar has particularly benefitted from

the weakening of the yen as well as from changed perceptions of
the German economy.

At the time of your last meeting, there was a growing
concern in the market that the Bank of Japan and the Ministry of
Finance were
deterioration in the Japanese
financial system.

But the combination of policy actions taken

over the last two months -- the reduction in the call money rate
below the Official Discount Rate, the handling of the Cosmo
Credit Union failure, and the measures announced to stimulate
capital outflows -- were well received by the market as
deliberate steps to stimulate the Japanese economy and weaken the
yen.

There have been on-again-off-again expectations for further
reductions in official rates in Germany since the Bundesbank last
reduced its discount rate on March 30th.

During June,

expectations for further easing were in the off-again part of the
cycle.

But over the course of July and August, the German

economy came to be seen as slowing down a bit and expectations
grew for a further ease in rates by the Bundesbank.

On August

9th, the Bundesbank lowered the rates accepted in its repo
operations by 5 basis points, to 4.45 percent, and a reduction in

- 4 -

official rates is now seen as increasingly likely, especially
following this morning's announcement of a modest contraction in
German M3 in July.

The dollar also appeared to benefit from the improved market
perception of the commitment of the Treasury to strengthening the
dollar.

Each of the three intervention operations conducted during
the period were intended to underscore that commitment while
demonstrating the vitality of coordination among the major, G-7
countries.

The first and second interventions were coordinated

with the Bank of Japan and timed to support and underscore the
actions of the Japanese authorities: on July 7th to lower the
call money rate and on August 2nd to stimulate outward
investment.

The third operation, on August 15th, was coordinated with
both the Bank of Japan and the Bundesbank and was intended to
generalize the Treasury's interest in a stronger dollar to
include dollar-mark while also demonstrating the support of the
Bundesbank.

If there is a weakness in the underpinnings of the dollar's
recent rally, I think it is probably in market participants'
exuberant reaction to the Japanese authorities' policy moves in

- 5 July and August.

The initial, modest measures announced this

summer may simply have helped propel a technical rally in dollaryen, as the Japanese exporters' paused their dollar sales after
they completed hedging fourth-quarter receivables.

Moreover,

market participants have come to place great importance on the
package of fiscal, regulatory and monetary policy measures
expected from the Japanese authorities this autumn and, thus,
there is a risk that the package will fall short of expectations.

In domestic operations, we faced relatively modest,
alternating needs both to drain and add reserves over the period.
There were more episodes of discount window borrowing by large
money center banks than we have seen for some time.

These appear

to have reflected mis-estimates of banks' own reserve positions
going into the end of the maintenance periods, but it also does
reflect some reduction in the stigma that has been associated
with discount window borrowing.

Mr. Chairman, I will be pleased to answer questions on my
report.

I will need separate votes of the Committee to ratify

the Desk's foreign and domestic operations.

David J. Stockton
August 22, 1995
FOMC BRIEFING
With only a few notable exceptions, the data that we
have received since the July FOMC meeting have been on the
positive side of our expectations.

Employment and hours worked,

consumer spending, housing activity, and business fixed
investment all have been stronger than we had anticipated seven
weeks ago.

At the same time, inventory investment has come in

weaker.
Putting the pieces together, we now expect little
revision to the BEA's advance estimate of second-quarter growth
in real GDP, which was a percentage point stronger than our July
Greenbook forecast.

More important, the composition of second-

quarter activity--with stronger final sales and fewer
inventories--suggests that the inventory correction may have
progressed further last quarter and will be less of a drag on
production in the current quarter than we had anticipated.

And,

with the spending indicators for early in the current quarter
suggesting more momentum to final demand, we have raised our
current quarter projection by about a percentage point to a bit
above 2 percent.
Although our outlook has not changed materially, there
are two related reasons why we are now projecting a briefer and
shallower dip in output growth.

First, we have been impressed by

the promptness with which production was shifted down in response
to the emergence of inventory problems.

With the exception of

motor vehicles, considerable progress already appears to have

FOMC Briefing: David J. Stockton

August 22,

1995:

Page 2

been made in working off inventories in a number of troublesome
areas.

The second reason is that final sales have held up well

in recent months, helping to speed the inventory correction and
suggesting somewhat greater underlying strength in aggregate
demand than we previously thought.

As we see it,

the economy,

thus far, has avoided the more pronounced inventory-productionspending feedbacks that often separate recessions from slowdowns.
The major exception to this brighter picture has been
in the auto industry, where continuing lackluster sales are
likely to result in substantial reductions in scheduled
assemblies and more generous incentive programs in the months
ahead to work down the inventory overhang.
We expect that these efforts will be successful, and
that growth of fourth-quarter GDP will receive a small lift as
motor vehicle production moves closer to trend.

Next year,

growth in real output is projected to settle in a touch below its
potential, with the unemployment rate edging up to just under 6
percent.
Tighter fiscal policy and a pronounced slowing of
investment spending are expected to be important factors working
to restrain domestic demands over the next year and a half.
Although there have been few concrete signs to date of any
slowing in fixed investment, the deceleration in output and sales
that already has occurred should leave a clearer mark on capital
spending not too far in the future.

The boom psychology that was

evident in many industries at the turn of the year has faded
considerably.

Even in many of those businesses that have escaped

relatively unscathed to date, the slowdown in activity seems

FOMC Briefing: David J. Stockton

August 22,

1995:

Page 3

likely to have restored a sense of two-way risk to the economic
outlook.

Under these circumstances, firms may be marking down

investment plans and are likely to be hesitant to engage in a
rapid restocking of either inventories or workers.
Working as something of a counter weight, the rallies
in bond and equity markets that have occurred this year should
provide a considerable cushion to the deceleration of demand.
Moreover, the projected recovery abroad and the noticeable cost
advantage U.S. producers enjoy on world markets are expected to
shift demand to domestic production.
Although we think the risks in our forecast are
balanced, I suspect that we would all agree that the virtually
perfect soft landing that we have presented in the Greenbook will
occur with a probability approaching zero.

Thus, it might be

useful to review briefly some of the major risks to the
projection.
Let me start with the downside risks.

Although the

string of recent surprises has been, for the most part, to the
upside, I would not want to exaggerate how much we have learned
since the last meeting.

Most of the data we have received

pertain to the ancient history of the second quarter.

Our

current-quarter projection is still more forecast than
arithmetic.

And, not all that we have learned about this

quarter's activity has been good.

The sharp drop in auto sales

last month might give one pause about the state of underlying
consumer demand, and contrasts with the more upbeat picture
painted by July's advance retail sales report.

Moreover,

manufacturers have been trimming payrolls at a steady clip in

FOMC Briefing: David J. Stockton

August 22,

recent months, a pattern that continued in July.

1995:

Page 4

And finally, we

have yet to see much evidence that the external sector is moving
into the plus column for the economic expansion.

Taken together,

these observations at least raise the possibility that we are not
out of the woods yet with respect

to a more protracted period of

sluggish growth.
But there are risks to the other side of the forecast
as well.

One could build a reasonable case that the economy

could exit this period with greater upward momentum than we have
projected in the Greenbook.

Private domestic final demands--that

is, consumption, housing and business fixed investment--grew at
about a 3-3/4 percent annual pace in the first half of the year
and entered the third quarter on a solid note.

This is below

last year's 5 percent growth, but it is still quite strong by
historical standards.

And, this performance occurred in the

context of a sag in the growth in income and employment that
accompanied the inventory correction, the drop in construction,
and the substantial hit on demand from the trade adjustment with
Mexico.

With these problems largely behind us, with income

growth picking up in recent months, and with generally supportive
financial conditions, domestic demands and production could
rebound more strongly than we have forecast.

In that regard, the

plunge in initial claims over the past couple of weeks, if it
persists, could be pointing to a stronger labor market than we
have factored into our forecast.
All told, the downside and upside risks to our
projection remain considerable, but for now, we see moderate
growth as at least a reasonably good bet.

FOMC Briefing: David J. Stockton

August 22,

1995:

Page 5

For the most part, price inflation has been unfolding
close to our expectations.

The bulge in prices that occurred

earlier this year is fading, in part, as a variety of special
factors such as airfares and auto finance charges partially
reverse earlier run-ups.

Moreover, the pressures generated by

rapidly rising prices of materials and imports are subsiding.
The principal surprise that we have had on the
inflation front since the last forecast was the second-quarter
reading on hourly compensation in the ECI, which came in at a 3
percent annual rate--about 1/2 percentage point below our
expectations.

That reading led us to mark down our compensation

projection, in the face of tighter projected labor markets.

The

growth in benefits, particularly health insurance, has dropped
substantially over the past year.

And, given reports that

efforts by employers to trim health costs are ongoing and
widespread, we have assumed that benefits growth will remain
subdued over the projection period.
But wages also have been running somewhat below
expectation, and, in total, growth in compensation per hour has
slowed over the past year at a time when the unemployment rate
averaged about 5-3/4 percent.

Although such an outcome is well

within our confidence band, these events raise the possibility
that the natural rate--or NAIRU--may be below our working point
estimate of 5.9 percent.

Given the volatility of the data and

the fact that our models have often seen deviations of similar
magnitude and duration in the past, we did not see a sound
statistical basis for lowering our estimate of the NAIRU.

But we

can't rule out the possibility that our models would be too slow

FOMC Briefing: David J. Stockton

August 22,

Page 6

1995:

to pick up structural changes that may be under way in labor
markets.

In recognition of that risk, we included in the

Greenbook some alternative simulations using the Board staff's
quarterly econometric model that assume a lower and higher
natural rate than embodied in the staff forecast.
I wouldn't want to leave the impression that we felt
the risks to our inflation forecast were one sided.

Our CPI

projection remains well below the Blue Chip consensus--even
making due allowance for our slightly weaker output path.

And,

almost all survey measures of inflation expectations for the year
ahead are higher than our forecast.

Furthermore, the good news

on benefits may prove shorter lived than we are now projecting.
But, on balance, we are comfortable with our relatively
optimistic outlook for inflation given the subdued pace of labor
costs and signs that the price pressures evident earlier this
year are waning.
Mr. Chairman, that concludes my prepared remarks.
Charlie Siegman and I would be happy to answer any questions the
Committee might have.

August 22,

1995

FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

I thought I would organize my comments this morning
around the real federal funds rate.

At the last FOMC meet-

ing, a number of you characterized current policy as restrictive, in part because the real funds rate was above its
historical average.

This comparison has also been prominent

in press and financial market assessments

of monetary

policy, with the presumption that as a consequence, the next
moves by the Committee are more likely to be toward lower
than higher rates.

Market and press attention to this

concept is not surprising;

the Federal Reserve found it a

useful construct for thinking about and explaining policy
when the real funds rate was well away from its
norm.

longer-term

The question is its utility when the gap between

actual and the long-run average is much smaller.
The chart

that was distributed this morning puts

the current level of the real funds rate in historical
context.

The series plotted with the solid line uses one-

year ahead projections from the Philadelphia Fed survey of
professional forecasters as a proxy for expected inflation;
the dotted line uses CPI

months.

inflation over the previous twelve

The horizontal line--at 2.36 percent--is the

average of the dotted line since 1967;

I chose this interval

-2-

because

inflation as the

it is today,
as

period began was about the same as

so that monetary policy could be characterized

having been neither tight nor easy on average.

to note

One point

right away is that the historical average is sensi-

tive to the period chosen.

For example, as can be seen in

the table at the bottom of the page, the average back to
1954--or

roughly the post-Accord period--is somewhat lower.

The table also shows the wide range of averages over the
decades.
The chart suggests that in a very rough way the
real funds

rate compared with its average may be a useful

method of characterizing the stance of monetary policy.
real

rate was low in the

The

1970s and inflation trended higher;

it was high through the first half of the 1980s and
inflation trended lower.

But there are anomalies as well.

Relatively elevated real rates didn't
accelerating in the

stop prices from

late 1980s, and low rates through most

of the 1990s were associated with stable to falling inflation.
Clearly, historical averages do not always

provide

a reliable estimate of the natural rate of interest--the
rate that if held would eventually keep inflation from
rising or falling.

As you are aware, many factors can cause

the natural rate to vary over time.
policy probably raised it

in the

For example, fiscal

1980s, and the credit

crunch lowered it temporarily in the early 1990s.
of secular forces may be at work as well.
markets, deregulation--especially the

A

number

In financial

removal of regulation

Q--and innovation probably have changed the relationship of
interest rates to spending--possibly raising the natural
rate.

Changes in long-term trends in private saving and

productivity would also affect the level

of interest rates

consistent with the economy producing at its potential.

Not

only does the natural rate move around over time, but any
estimate of its level

is just the middle of a fairly wide

confidence band.
Moreover, by definition, the natural real rate is
generally a long-run concept.

As such it abstracts from

the short-run and cyclical dynamics that are central to
the conduct of monetary policy.

Thus, it shouldn't come

as a surprise that using the level of the real rate relative
to some notion of the natural rate--a long-run average or
otherwise--does not consistently help in forecasting
economic activity or inflation over the next few years.
At any point in time, past spending patterns--such as the
multiplier and accelerator effects of inventory corrections--past policy actions, and new exogenous shocks are
exerting powerful effects on the economy, possibly causing
it to deviate for extended periods from the path the
Committee would like to see.

Setting policy only with an

eye to a long-run equilibrium--to the exclusion of short-run
considerations--is likely to exacerbate, rather than damp,
economic cycles.
In addition, the federal funds rate may not always
be a good proxy for other financial variables that are even
more important for economic performance--intermediate- and
long-term interest rates,
tions.

exchange rates, and credit condi-

A particular federal funds

rate may be associated

with a wide range of values taken on by these other financial variables, with significant differential effects on
spending.

For example, at the last Committee meeting Mr.

Simpson demonstrated the powerful impact a forward-looking
bond market can have on the appropriate monetary policy
response to a change in fiscal policy.
pattern of the funds

And, the cyclical

rate and its relationships to other

rates and hence to spending can change over time;

I suspect,

for example, that this has happened over recent years

in

response to the Committee's attempts to be more forwardlooking in its policy actions.
Given the complex relationship of the funds rate to
the economy, even simple policy rules, such as the nominal
income targeting exercises of the San Francisco Fed or the
Taylor rule, don't just put the funds rate at its natural
level.

Rather, they use data on where the economy is rela-

tive to assumed Committee objectives to adjust the funds

rate in order to achieve these objectives more effectively.
Your own forecasts and those of the staff take into account
all available information of what the

economy has been

doing, some knowledge of the implications of economic

re-

lationships for behavior going forward, and information
about future movements of exogenous variables, such as
government spending.
For all these reasons,
funds

comparing the level of the

rate relative to a historical average, especially when

the two are fairly close, may not be all that helpful a
short cut or adjunct to your usual inclusive process of
forming expectations about the outlook under various policy
alternatives and then modifying your assessment in response
to incoming information.
at times

Nonetheless,

such a comparison may

serve as a useful crosscheck on forecasts and a way

of framing questions about the underpinnings
cast.

of the fore-

We have occasionally utilized it this way in examin-

ing the policy options in the bluebook.
Applying this approach to the current circumstances,

the staff forecast has the

economy coming in around

or just below the level of its potential next year with the
real federal funds rate staying around its current level of
2-3/4 percent.

Given the uncertainties, this may well be

the natural level of this measure.

But it is slightly to

the high side of history, and this might be seen as

raising

questions about the outlook, especially when fiscal policy
is assumed to be tilted toward restraint.
The answers in the staff forecast can be found in
part in a number of factors in financial markets that are
working to offset any restraint on aggregate demand that
might be coming from short-term rates.
close to

its all-time lows

One is the dollar--

in real terms--which, in conjunc-

tion with expansion abroad, is expected to stop the decline
in net exports.

Another

term real interest

is the apparent level of longer-

rates.

While they are difficult to

measure, and have ticked up a bit in recent weeks,
real

long-term

rates seem still to be close to their lows since 1980,

except for the credit crunch period.

Moreover, they are

considerably below the level of last fall, and the somewhat
stronger tenor of the incoming data may suggest that even
those higher levels weren't quite as
have thought a little while ago.

restraining as we might

In any event,

rates seem
constrain

low enough to avoid having debt service burdens
borrowing and lending.
demand

Indeed, a further factor

supporting

is the generally ample credit availability:

Quality

spreads in securities markets remain quite low, and banks
continue to ease lending terms to businesses.
prices

High equity

also are holding down the cost of capital and boost-

ing wealth.
returns to

Moreover,

businesses

apparently perceive the

investment as elevated relative to the cost

of

capital, at least for high-tech equipment,

imparting con-

tinuing momentum to capital spending.
This was not intended to be a complete list of the
influences the staff looked at in making its

forecast.

Dave

has listed a number of risks to growth and inflation on both
sides.

And, the funds rate, real and nominal, may have to

come down at some point,

especially if there is more fiscal

contraction and inflation comes in below market expectations.

In any case, as you consider policy, you may have a

different assessment of the outlook.
to illustrate

My point was primarily

the use of the real funds

rate as a

starting point, but only a starting point,
thorough examination of the key variables
look.

for a more
shaping the out-