View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

Notes for FOMC Meeting
August 21, 1990
Sam Y. Cross
Sentiment toward the dollar has turned decidedly negative
since your last meeting with growing pessimism about the outlook both
for the economy and for inflation.

As a result, the dollar has come

under fairly persistent downward pressure against most currencies, and
in recent days has established new historic lows against the mark. On
balance, the dollar is trading 5 to 7 percent lower against the mark
and other European currencies, though only about 3 percent lower
against the yen, than it was in early July.
Sentiment toward the dollar had already begun to turn
negative around the time of your last meeting.

You may recall, the

dollar began to soften in late June-early July after President Bush
raised the possibility of tax increases to reduce the budget deficit.
The market was well aware of Administration pressure on the Fed to
ease monetary policy, and believed that the Fed would act quickly to
offset the contractionary impact of any fiscal tightening.

With

dollar interest rate differentials against both the mark and yen
already very low, even negative in some cases--dealers believed
investors would continue to diversify into non-dollar holdings.
Then after the last FOMC meeting, a number of developments
made dollar investments seem even less attractive.

First, market

participants were taken unaware by the Chairman's comments on July 12
that the Federal Reserve was poised to offset a tightening in the
credit markets and by the following day's 1/4 percentage point decline
in the federal funds rate.

Initially, the market's interpretation of

these developments was negative for the dollar--seeing it as increased
Fed willingness to tolerate inflation in order to counter further

economic slowdown--although some of that concern was moderated by the
Chairman's subsequent Humphrey-Hawkins testimony.
Sentiment toward the dollar received another setback
following the release of data in late July/August which raised
concerns both about the softness of the economy and the persistence of
inflationary pressures.

The report on second-quarter GNP released on

July 27 was followed by a period of dollar weakness.

Then, on August

3, the July employment report was seen as evidence that the pace of
economic growth had slowed dramatically.

These signs of weakness were

seen in the exchange market as consistent with the mid-July decline in
the federal funds rate, and prompted expectations of further easing of
U.S. monetary policy in the near future.
Attitudes toward the economy and the dollar soured further
because of the increasingly large estimates of the cost of the savings
and loan bailout and the related rising projections of the fiscal 1991
budget deficit.

As the period progressed, hopes for avoiding a Gramm-

Rudman sequester faded.

But given the worsening news about the

economy, fading prospects of a budget agreement did not reverse
expectations of a decline in dollar interest rates.

Instead, it was

viewed as evidence that political leaders were still not committed to
addressing U.S. fiscal and financial problems.
The dollar's decline showed through most clearly against the
European currencies.

Developments peculiar to Japan cushioned the

dollar/yen exchange rate from the full effects of the change in
investor sentiment.

In mid-July, the Japanese stock markets came

under renewed strong selling pressures, following rumors of a new
political scandal, and in an environment of growing expectations of

further tightening by the Bank of Japan.

Once the declines in

Japanese stock prices got underway, market participants were reminded
of the situation earlier in the year when policy-makers appeared
stymied by the fragility of the domestic financial markets.

In

addition, the rise in oil prices reinforced inflationary concerns in
Japan and added to selling pressures in the Japanese bond and stock
markets.

Against this background, the yen resumed its decline against

all major currencies other than the dollar.
Following the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait on August 1, the
dollar initially strengthened as dealers bid aggressively,
anticipating increased transactions demand and safe-haven demand for
the U.S. currency.

The dollar immediately rose by as much as 4

percent against the yen, and by a lesser amount against the other
currencies, although it just as quickly gave up much of its gains.
Thereafter, the dollar on occasion received some support on rumors of
heightened tensions in the Persian Gulf, but the support tended to
diminish as the period progressed.

Safe-haven considerations seemed

to have a much bigger impact on gold and on the Swiss franc than on
the dollar.
Instead, the dollar once again began a slow but steady
decline as market participants focused on the implications for the
U.S. economy of a sharp rise in oil prices.

There was concern that,

unlike the robust economies of Germany and other European countries,
the U.S. economy would be unable to withstand the policy tightening
necessary to counter the effects of higher oil prices.

Also, many

were wondering whether the Fed might feel compelled to accept a

relatively high rate of inflation in order to prevent recession.

As a

result, during the final two weeks of the period, the dollar continued
to move lower against the major currencies, declining through postWWII lows against the mark and reaching 9-year lows against several
other European currencies.
Late last week, the market's reaction to the U.S. June
merchandise trade report provided another example of the market's
negative bias toward the dollar.

Despite an impressive narrowing of

the trade deficit, dealers continued to sell dollars, either ignoring
the report or interpreting the lower deficit simply as further
evidence of an economic slowdown.
The dollar's decline over the past several weeks, while
persistent, has not been sharp or erratic.

There has been no serious

consideration of market intervention as yet, and the market does not
seem to expect any.

But in the present rather precarious

circumstances, there is the risk that developments could quite
suddenly bring on a very difficult and even dangerous exchange market
situation which could also disrupt other financial markets.
Mr. Chairman, since the last FOMC meeting, the Desk has not
intervened to influence the exchange rate, but as reported earlier has
undertaken certain transactions on behalf of the U.S. Treasury to
adjust ESF balances.

Since the last FOMC meeting, the Desk has

acquired a total of $427.4 million against marks in the market and
also exchanged $1 billion equivalent of marks for dollars directly
with the Bundesbank.

Then on July 20, the ESF reversed $2 billion of

the $9 billion of outstanding warehousing with the Federal Reserve,

using dollars acquired over the past several months through these
transactions.

The transactions have not yet been publicly reported or

explicitly identified, although the financial effect has been
reflected in releases regularly issued by the Treasury, the Federal
Reserve and the Bundesbank.

We plan to report the transactions in the

Federal Reserve Bank of New York's next quarterly foreign exchange
report, which will be released on September 7.
In a separate program, the Treasury has also been exchanging
ESF holdings of SDRs for dollars.

The SDRs are sold to IMF member

nations who require SDRs to pay Fund charges.

Since July 12, a total

of SDR 290.7 million, equivalent to $407.8 million, have been sold,
out of a total sales of 500 million SDRs contemplated.
In other operations, the Bank of Mexico on July 5 and 31 made
payments totaling $736.4 million on a $1.3 billion facility
established with the Federal Reserve and Treasury in late March.
latter payment effectively closed the facility.

The

The Central Bank of

Honduras on July 5 and August 1 made payments totaling $43.3 million
on a $82.3 million special swap facility established with the U.S.
Treasury to enable that country to clear its arrears with
international financial institutions.

The National Bank of Hungary,

on July 16, drew $80 million in its second drawing on a multilateral
financing facility; the U.S. Treasury's share amounted to $8.9
million.

On August 1, Hungary made principal payments totaling $42.5

million, $4.8 million of which was credited to the U.S. Treasury.

The

Bank of Guyana on July 31 made a principal repayment of $102.6 million
on a multilateral facility, of which $18.3 million was credited to the
U.S. Treasury.

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
AUGUST 21, 1990
PETER D. STERNLIGHT

Domestic Desk operations
Committee in
turbulent

since the last meeting of the

early July were conducted against a sometimes

background

that overshadowed

in

the small adjustment

reserve pressures undertaken in mid-July.

The turbulence stemmed

chiefly from markets roiled by Iraq's takeover of Kuwait and
subsequent political

and military reactions around the world,

given the concerns over oil

supplies and inflation generally.

Added anxieties stemmed from uncertainties about Congressional
action on the debt ceiling,
approached.
final

as a major Treasury financing

Unsettlement of a different kind developed in

week of the period due to an extended power outage in

New York financial district

the
the

that impeded New York Fed operations

and had widespread effects on many other market participants.
For about the first

week of the period,

the Desk sought

to maintain reserve pressures of about the same degree that
prevailed through the first

six months of this year,

with an expected Federal funds rate in
8 1/4 percent.

On July 13,

in

associated

the neighborhood

of

response to indications that a

greater degree of restraint had developed

in

the financial system

than had been anticipated or was deemed appropriate,
moved to a slightly more accommodative

the Desk

reserve stance.

The

borrowing allowance was pared by $50 million to $400 million and
it

was anticipated

that funds would trade around 8 percent.

borrowing allowance was subsequently raised in

The

two $50 million

steps to $500 million, as technical adjustments to keep pace with
the rise in seasonal borrowing, while leaving the expected funds
rate at 8 percent.
The Desk's July 13 move was ingested quickly by the
market and funds moved down to trade around 8 percent or a shade
over

from mid-July through early August.

During last week,

funds

traded a little above the expected range, primarily due to
uncertainties and distortions growing out of

the New York power

outage, and also to some extent due to the Treasury's large
refunding settlement on August 15.

Nonetheless, market

participants continued to anticipate an equilibrium rate

in the

8 percent area, and by yesterday trading was predominantly back at
that rate.
Actual borrowing levels were fairly close to path on a
statement period average basis, being made up largely of seasonal
borrowing.

Adjustment borrowing was very low most of the time,

although it bulged on the July 25 reserve period settlement date
and also rose last week when power problems disrupted computers
and communication links.

For

the whole period, through the past

weekend, adjustment credit averaged about $100 million and
seasonal borrowing about $400 million.
The Desk faced moderate reserve needs throughout the
period which were met through buying about $1.5 billion of bills
from foreign accounts and a combination of System and customer
repurchase agreements.

Needs were enlarged by virtue of the

Treasury's unwinding of a $2 billion warehousing of D-marks with
the Fed on July 20.

For a time following

the July 13 move to a

slightly easier degree of reserve pressure, the Desk exercised
special caution in meeting ongoing reserve needs to ensure that
the market did not jump to conclude that greater than
easing was under

way.

intended

Market participants were keenly alert to

the possibility of further moves, especially as some weaker
economic data were published and the
financing approached.

Treasury's mid-quarter

A further complicating

factor was the

market's heightened skittishness following the Middle East
eruption.
Last week, Desk operations were affected somewhat by the
power outages in New York.

We

sought to provide reserves a bit

more generously, although repeated reserve shortfalls partly
frustrated our efforts.

Also, because of potential constraints on

our ability to process a heavy volume of activity we set a larger
minimum transaction size for our repurchase agreements and
temporarily discontinued the lending of securities.

On one

occasion, the System Account accommodated foreign central bank
demand by selling a few bills outright rather than burden the
funds and securities networks with additional transactions late
the day.

On the whole,

it can be said that the contingency

back-up plans worked well and at no point did we feel that the
essential thrust of System Open Market operations was being
compromised.

in

Markets were pulled in different directions during the
intermeeting period, with the net result a significant steepening
of

the yield curve.

At the short end, yields on Treasury bills

and other money market instruments maturing within a year
about 15-25 basis points.

fell by

The decline in the perceived expected

Federal funds rate from 8 1/4

to 8 percent in mid-July was

the

main influence here, with some added downward pressure at times
when weak reports on the economy made it appear
could ease further.

likely that policy

Bills and perhaps other money market paper

also enjoyed some flight-to-quality demand in the turbulent
markets following

the

invasion of Kuwait.

The decline in

short-term rates occurred despite heavy

demands on the bill market.
the period was about $33
cash management bills.
its 3- and 6-month

Net cash raised in that sector during

billion, including some $14
In yesterday's auctions

the Treasury sold

issues at 7.55 and 7.45 percent, respectively,

down from 7.73 and 7.60 percent just before the
At the same time,
higher.

billion of

longer

last meeting.

term rates pushed sharply

The main factor here was the inflationary concerns

growing out of events

in the Middle East, but even before those

developments investors were becoming more jittery over

inflation.

The System's move to reduce reserve pressures in mid-July caused
some observers to question the central bank's resolve to combat
inflation.

These commentators recognized that the economy was

sluggish but they did not see significant evidence of greater

weakness than had been observable in other recent months.
Moreover there was suspicion about succumbing to Administration
pressure or perhaps premature acquiescence to a policy move in
connection with a budget deficit reduction package.

Economic

reports coming out after mid-July tended to put the System's
July action in a better light--notably the report on GNP for the
second quarter and the revisions for earlier quarters,

the

Purchasing Managers report for July, and the weak July employment
numbers.

These reports even brought anticipations of further

easing--although

the employment report,

coinciding as it

did with

the news from Kuwait, led to mixed expectations of both greater
economic weakness and stronger inflation.

Further complicating

and heightening the market's reactions to news from the Middle
East was the fact that a major Treasury financing was about to be
undertaken,

calling on dealers and investors to absorb

record-sized additions to supply and with a shortened period of
trading because of delays in

the debt-ceiling

only that,

for curbing

but the prospects

legislation.

the Treasury's

Not

future

appetite looked shakier as events seemed to cloud the outlook for
deficit reduction negotiations.
interest

in

A final straw was that overseas

the Treasury's offerings looked dimmer as rates had

been rising significantly in foreign markets.
In the turbulent days of early August, the Treasury sold
its

new issues,

but only after sharp upward yield adjustments and

some considerable

anxiety.

Over the full

period,

Treasury yields

in

issues

the 10-year area rose about 40 basis points and 30-year

This puts the yield on the new 30-year

about 55 basis points.

bond at about 8.95 percent.

Yields on 30-year bonds had pushed

just above 9 percent last spring in

the wake of heightened

inflationary concerns after the bad first

quarter price numbers,

but the yield had come down to around 8.35 percent at the start
August,
the

amid sluggish reports on the economy,

inflaton numbers,

deficit

of

and apparently improved prospects for a

reduction given the Administration's

about taxes.

some abatement

of

willingness to talk

Including the nearly $14 billion raised in

the

quarterly refunding, the Treasury borrowed about $20 billion in
the coupon market during
Refcorp borrowed $5
period,

the intermeeting period.

billion through a 30-year

In

addition,

issue early in

the

which elicited much better interest than their earlier

40-year offerings.
Whether in

bills

or coupons,

the relentless pace of

Treasury borrowing shows little prospect of abating.
fiscal year deficit

is

begins to hear private
year--assuming
absent a deficit

pushing

to the $220 billion

The current

area,

and one

sector estimates for the next fiscal

a soft economy,

large thrift

bail-out costs,

reduction package--approaching

and

$300 billion.

Market sentiment on near-term monetary policy prospects
has tended to ebb and flow with information on the economy,

and

evaluations of the Middle East situation and budget deficit
reduction possibilities.

As recently as a few weeks ago,

the

preponderance of information emphasizing the weakness of the
economy,

and

some fair

prospect of budget

action,

tilted

sentiment

rather clearly toward anticipations of an easier policy early on.
The combination of Middle East events,

dimmed hopes on the budget,

and evidence of greater inflationary force even before the Iraqi
invasion, has now left most observers looking
policy change.

for no immediate

Still, the view remains that the economy is quite

soft and that somewhere further down the road an easing

is in

store.
Finally, I should mention that once again there has been
a decline in the ranks of primary dealers.

The Bank of New York

relinquished its primary dealer role earlier this month after an
extended period of disappointing profitability.
fourth firm to drop out this year,
1989.

following four

that dropped in

In the meantime, three firms were added in that 20 month

period, so the net decline was five,
that have dropped out

from 46 to 41.

Of the eight

since the start of 1989, half were foreign

owned and half were domestic.
owned.

This was the

All three new entrants are foreign

Of the present 41 dealers, we consider 15 to be

foreign-owned, including 8 Japanese.

The dropouts have resulted

essentially from the poor profit experience of
the dealer group as a whole

the first

recent years.

several months of

this

For
year

showed better results than a year earlier--though still not an
attractive

long

run return on capital.

David J. Stockton
August 21, 1990
FOMC BRIEFING

As you know, the economic outlook for activity and inflation
has been altered by the steep rise in oil prices that has occurred since
early July.

However, the uncertainties associated with developments in

the Middle East are so large that, at this point, any economic projection should be taken only with an even larger-than-usual grain of salt.
Our strategy in the Greenbook was to take a reasonable scenario for the
evolution of oil prices as a conditioning assumption for the projection.
But, the Greenbook projection is only one reasonable scenario among
many.
This morning, I'll lay out the rationale underlying the
baseline Greenbook projection.

Ted then will discuss some of the

international implications of recent events and present some model-based
results that highlight the sensitivity of the outlook to some of the key
assumptions that we have made.
However, before dealing with the tremendous uncertainties
surrounding the question of where the economy may be headed, I would
like to touch on the merely significant uncertainties associated with
assessing where the economy has been.

A considerable amount of

information has become available since the July FOMC meeting, and, on
the whole, this information appears supportive of our view that activity
has been expanding gradually, but with no abatement of inflation.
Let me begin with a bit of ancient history and comment briefly
on the downward adjustment to the growth in real GNP in 1989 that was

reported in the annual revisions.

One question raised by the revisions

is whether monetary policy has been exerting greater restraint on
aggregate demand than we previously realized.

While there is no

absolutely clear cut answer to this question, it is of interest to note
that the downward revision occurred in consumption of services, most
notably medical services--not an area of spending normally thought of as
interest sensitive.
A second question raised by the revisions is whether the lower
estimated growth of the economy implies that we are facing less
inflation pressures, than we previously thought.
appear to be no.

The answer would

Broad measures of inflation and the unemployment rate

were not affected by the revision.

As a consequence, the data suggest

that both actual and potential output have been growing at a slower
pace--implying no greater slack exists.

In our view, it appears that

the economy must grow a little more slowly than we had previously
thought to generate the same amount of slack in labor markets.
The most recent readings on the labor market suggest that
activity is, in fact, growing at less than its potential rate.
payroll employment dropped 45,000 in July.

Private

Employment as measured by

the household survey also dropped last month and the unemployment rate
rose 1/4 percentage point to 5-1/2 percent.

Other evidence, however,

suggests that a major contraction in labor demand is not underway.
Aggregate hours worked in July were 1-1/2 percent at an annual rate
above their second-quarter average.

And, initial claims for

unemployment insurance have been virtually flat since the turn of the

-3-

year, giving no hint that layoffs are becoming deeper or more
widespread.
A similar picture of slow growth emerges from the industrial
sector.

The index of industrial production has been buffeted by monthly

swings in motor vehicle production and the output of utilities.
Abstracting from these factors, production has been rising at about a 2
percent pace since late last year.

Industrial materials prices have had

a firmer tone of late, and although they may have been boosted in part
by the drop in the foreign exchange value of the dollar, these activitysensitive prices are not pointing to any significant weakening in the
industrial sector.
Turning to the spending indicators, the BEA's advance estimate
of real GNP, at 1-1/4 percent for the second quarter, was quite close to
the June Greenbook estimate.

However, in contrast to our June

projection, the BEA showed a sharp drop in final sales offset by
considerable stockbuilding.

The data we have received in recent weeks

now make it appear that real GNP is likely to be revised up--perhaps on
the order of 1/2 percentage point--with a more favorable mix.
Although retail sales posted only a small rise in July,
substantial upward revisions to May and June suggest that spending in
the second quarter was not so weak as previously had been suggested and
that consumer outlays are entering the current quarter on a slight
uptrend.

Ted will discuss later the recent trade figures, but those

data also point to stronger final sales than estimated earlier.

In contrast, inventory investment now looks considerably weaker
than had been assumed by the BEA.

Stock-to-sales ratios in most sectors

ended the second quarter at or below levels seen earlier in the year.
Elsewhere, incoming information on spending seems to have
extended recent trends.

Orders for nondefense capital goods remained

sluggish through June and point to a continuation of the sideways trend
in equipment outlays that has been evident for some time now.
starts moved lower in July.

Housing

And although nonresidential construction

activity apparently spurted in June, advance indicators remain negative.
The news on inflation has been disappointing, even apart from
the large increases in energy prices that already are underway.

The

July CPI, which we received after the Greenbook was published, showed an
increase of 0.4 percent, after increasing 0.5 percent in June.

The CPI

excluding food and energy was up about 1/2 percent in both months.
These increases are especially troubling in light of the steep rise that
occurred earlier in the year.

In particular, discounting of apparel

prices failed to materialize to any appreciable extent after the sharp
price runups this spring.
distinct uptrend.

And service price inflation has remained on a

On balance, the CPI ex food and energy increased at

close to a 6 percent annual rate over the first seven months of the
year.
Labor cost measures also have provided little encouragement
that inflation pressures are easing.

Over the twelve months ended in

June, the employment cost index for hourly compensation increased 5-1/4
percent, 3/4 percentage point above the increase in the preceding year.
This acceleration is consistent with the view that the labor market has

been tight over the past year.

At this point, information on the

current quarter is limited to average hourly earnings for July, which
increased 0.6 percent.
All told, the information that has become available over the
past seven weeks suggests that activity has been expanding at a slow
rate.

And, apart from any consideration of higher oil prices, real

growth seems to have been poised to proceed in the second half of the
year at a pace comparable to that over the first half.

Meanwhile,

inflation was not likely to have departed from recent trends.

It is

this view of the economy that served as the point of departure for our
Greenbook forecast and for the assessment of the economic consequences
of the increases in oil prices.
As you know, crude oil prices had begun to rise even prior to
the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait, as it became clear that the major OPEC
players would reach an agreement to scale back production.

In the wake

of the invasion, spot prices for West Texas Intermediate crude oil
jumped up and have been fluctuating in about a $25 to $30 per barrel
range.

Our scenario calls for the price of West Texas Intermediate to

average around $26.50 through year-end, with an associated average
import price reaching $25 per barrel in the fourth quarter--about $8
above our June forecast.

Such a path would be consistent with the loss

of roughly 4-1/4 million barrels per day from Iraq and Kuwait relative
to production rates in June and July and an offset from other OPEC
producers of 2-1/4 million barrels per day.
The forecast assumes a resolution to the current turmoil by
early next year.

At that time, oil production is assumed to move up to

the levels targeted in the July OPEC accord.

Thus, by mid-year 1991,

crude oil prices fall to roughly $3 per barrel above our June forecast.
One could hypothesize much less favorable circumstances, but
even under those we have assumed in the Greenbook the Committee would be
confronted with considerably less favorable sets of outcomes with
respect to output and inflation.

We conditioned our projection on the

assumption that interest rates and the foreign exchange value of the
dollar remain near current levels.

In our view, under this assumption

even our optimistic oil price pattern would lead to both relatively high
inflation and very slow growth of output over the next few quarters.
The oil price disturbance also complicates the fiscal policy
picture.

Budget summit talks had stalled even before the invasion, and

the turmoil in the Middle East cannot be a positive factor.

At this

point, we are inclined to stick with our $35 billion deficit reduction
package for fiscal year 1991.

But our unease may have shifted from

feeling a shade too pessimistic, to feeling perhaps a bit too optimistic
about the outcome of the negotiations.

For fiscal year 1992, we have

assumed an additional $35 billion in deficit reduction actions.
The direct effects of the jump in oil prices are expected to
show up quickly in the prices of gasoline and fuel oil.

Indeed,

available survey evidence suggests that more than half of the rise in
crude oil costs had been passed through at the pump by mid-August.

By

September, we expect the bulk of the direct effects to be complete,
having added roughly 1/2 percent to the level of the CPI.

The indirect

effects on prices of goods and services that use energy as an input and
on competing energy products are likely to begin immediately and extend,

with waning influence, into early next year.

All told, the rise in the

CPI is expected to average close to 6 percent in the second half of the
year.
On the spending side, we have assumed that households and
businesses are as uncertain about the outlook for oil prices as we are.
We expect that households will curtail their real consumption in the
second half, but not quite by the full extent of the erosion in their
real incomes.

And, facing the prospect of weaker sales and confronted

with greater uncertainty, businesses seem likely to trim or defer
capital outlays over the next several quarters.

Moreover, efforts to

hold inventories in check, in light of expectations of softening sales,
are expected to exert a modest drag on output later this year.
Construction activity drops further in the second half, but less in
reaction to higher energy prices than in response to the overhang of
unsold homes, high vacancy rates, and continuing problems of credit
availability.

The only bright spot seems to be the likelihood of a

small lift to oil drilling activity.
The greater near-term weakness that is contemplated in this
forecast pushes up the unemployment rate more rapidly late this year and
early next year than in our previous projection.

We now anticipate a

rise in the unemployment rate to around 6 percent by the end of this
year, rather than by the middle of 1991.
Given our baseline assumption that oil prices begin to move
lower by early next year, some of the depressing effects on demand and
activity begin to unwind.

Declines in energy prices add to real incomes

and allow some rebound in consumer spending.

And, with inventory

accumulation having been brought quickly into line with weaker sales,
stockbuilding provides no further impediment to growth in production.
Later in 1991, the acceleration of output encourages some recovery in
business equipment spending.

Exports continue to provide a healthy

boost to domestic activity throughout the projection period, but some of
the growth in domestic demands in 1991 takes the form of increased
imports from abroad.
In addition, the slump in real estate markets and problems of
credit availability are assumed to begin to ease somewhat next year,
leading to a very mild recovery in housing starts.

However,

nonresidential construction activity continues its contraction.

With

growth in output projected to move back close to its potential late next
year, the unemployment rate stabilizes at a bit above 6 percent.
The inflation outlook is appreciably worse in the near-term
than we projected in June, owing for the most part to the rise in energy
prices.

But the residual effect of the oil price shock on inflation

diminishes over the projection period.

In part, this reflects the

effects of the partial reversal of the energy price increases.

However,

the rapid rise in the unemployment rate in the second half of this year
also acts to limit the persistence of the energy price shock by holding
down nominal wage demands.
The behavior of wages will be an important determinant of the
persistence of inflation resulting from the oil shock.

If workers

attempt to resist the reduction in real wages that is made necessary by
an increase in the price of imported oil by raising their nominal wage
demands, the momentum imparted to inflation by the oil shock will be

greater.

If, on the other hand, workers immediately acquiesce to the

reduction in real incomes brought on by the oil shock, the inflation
consequences could be limited to a one-shot jump in the price level
associated with the rise in petroleum prices.
In our projection, we have assumed that the rise in energy
prices does have an adverse effect on nominal wage demands, though we
have not assumed workers are successful in offsetting all of the higher
prices in wages, in part because of the margin of slack that emerges in
labor markets.

With the unemployment rate remaining at a bit above 6

percent, gradual reductions in inflation occur in late 1991 and in 1992.
However, the starting point for this progress is a notch higher than we
had assumed in the June Greenbook.

Ted now will continue our presentation.

E.M. Truman
August 21, 1990
FOMC Presentation -- International Developments

The staff outlook for the external sector of the economy
has been affected by five principal developments since the July
FOMC meeting:
First, as has been described by Dave, are the changes in
the outlook for the U.S. economy largely as a consequence of the
higher oil prices.

The lower growth of real income over the next

few quarters tends to depress imports.

Although in our forecast

the growth of imports picks up next year, the lower level of
economic activity continues to hold down imports.
Second, most of the 4-1/2 percent decline of the dollar
on average against the other G-10 currencies over the
intermeeting period has been incorporated into our forecast;
everything else equal, this tends to boost inflation as well as
the contribution of real net exports to U.S. growth over the
forecast period.
Third, we received the merchandise trade data for May,
and they were remarkably close to our expectations; only
agricultural exports were slightly weaker than what we had
implicitly incorporated in our last forecast.
Fourth, last Friday, after the August Greenbook forecast
was completed, we received the preliminary merchandise trade
results for June.
expected.

These data on the whole were better than we

Accordingly, we estimate that real net exports of

-

2 -

goods and services in the GNP accounts for the second quarter
will be revised up by $9 to $10 billion.
The quantity and price of imports of crude petroleum and
products in June were lower than we had anticipated.

On the

quantity side, it is likely that some of the shortfall of imports
in June relative to our expectations will be made up in the data
for July.

The average price in June was $14.64 per barrel.

We

estimate that it rose about one dollar in July, and by a further
four dollars in August to about $19.50.

As Dave described

earlier, we are assuming that oil import prices will rise further
and average $25 per barrel in the fourth quarter before turning
down next year.

At $25 per barrel, the cost of our oil imports

will be about $75 billion at an annual rate in the fourth quarter
of this year, compared with less than $50 billion in the second
quarter.
The biggest surprise in the June data was in the area of
nonagricultural exports.

We expected the pickup in shipments of

large aircraft and the rebound in exports of computers and
accessories.

The unexpected elements were substantial increases

in exports of other capital goods and consumer goods.

Exports of

consumer goods have increased by 20 percent over the past year.
We would be inclined at this point to accept the June data as
confirmation of the strong underlying trend in nonagricultural
exports, and not to raise that trend further.

In the Greenbook

forecast, the growth of real nonagricultural merchandise exports
over the next six quarters is a bit more than 10 percent at an
annual rate.

-

3

-

The effects of higher oil prices on economic activity,
prices, and policies in the foreign industrial countries are the
fifth and final development that has affected our outlook for the
external sector of the U.S. economy since the last forecast.
With respect to output abroad, absent the increase in
oil prices, our outlook would have been for somewhat lower growth
in the second half of this year than we had earlier expected,
largely as a consequence of new information suggesting slower
growth in Europe -- on the continent as well as in the United
Kingdom.

In addition, oil prices are higher.

Our rule of thumb

is that growth on average in the foreign industrial countries
would be reduced by about 1/3 of a percentage point over a year
as a consequence of an increase in oil prices by $5 per barrel.
The smaller effect than in the United States reflects the lower
oil and energy intensiveness of output in other major industrial
countries.
Largely for the same reason, our rule of thumb is that a
five dollar increase in oil prices will increase inflation abroad
in the first year by about 2/3 of a percentage point -- somewhat
less than for the U. S. economy.

In our forecast, we have raised

inflation on average over the next four quarters, but the
appreciation against the dollar of these countries' currencies
over the past seven weeks provides a partial offset.
With respect to policy abroad, we do not have any rules
of thumb.

Moreover, we are faced not only with uncertainty about

the size and persistence of the rise in oil prices but also with
uncertainty about the effects on the economies of the foreign

-

4 -

industrial countries of the increases in nominal interest rates
that have taken place over the past six quarters -- increases on
average of about 300 basis points since the fourth quarter of
1988.
This second factor is relevant to our interpretation of
policies in connection with the 1973 and 1979 oil shocks.

Our

sense is that differences in policy responses were largely a
function of differences in conditions of the individual economies
at the time.
Against this background, we have reached the following
tentative judgments:
In Japan, with its high real growth and its capacity and
inflation concerns, we expect policy will be relatively
nonaccommodative.

Short-term interest rates, which have already

risen more than 60 basis points since the middle of June, are
likely to rise by another 25 basis points or so by the end of
this year.
In Germany, capacity constraints are probably as tight
as in Japan, but inflation is not rising, the growth of M3 is
subdued, and the political situation implies that policy-induced
increases in interest rates will not be well received.
Consequently, we expect the Bundesbank to lean against the
additional inflation induced by higher oil prices, but not as
vigorously as the Bank of Japan.

Short-term interest rates have

not been pushed up by policy recently.

They are expected to rise

by about 50 basis points in the first half of 1991, but this
increase is smaller than what we assumed in our June forecast,

-

5 -

and it is largely caused by the macroeconomic consequences of
German unification, not higher oil prices per se.
In the other major European countries, France and Italy,
capacity pressures are not as intense, and growth prospects are
not as robust.

We would, therefore, expect these countries to

follow more accommodative policies if EMS considerations permit.
The United Kingdom and Canada are countries where
inflation is a problem, but economic activity is clearly weak,
and they are net oil exporters.

Our judgment is that the

authorities of these countries would be reluctant to respond
aggressively in the short run to higher oil prices.
Pulling together these various developments, we are
continuing to project strong growth of real nonagricultural
exports.

The rate of expansion is slowed in the near term by the

effects of higher oil prices on growth abroad.

However, the

effects of the lower dollar kick in by the middle of next year to
push up such exports more rapidly than in the June forecast.
Meanwhile, non-oil imports are held down in real terms over the
next several quarters by slower domestic demand and, later in the
forecast period, by the lower dollar.

On balance, real net

exports of goods and services are a more positive factor in each
quarter of our current forecast than in the previous forecast.
The nominal trade and current account deficits widen over the
balance of 1990 because of the rise in oil prices.

However,

given our assumption about oil prices, the deficits narrow
substantially in 1991 and early 1992.

The current account

-

6 -

deficit averages about $60 billion in 1992 while the trade
deficit averages about $85 billion.
In the handout that you have just received, we have
summarized and extended through 1993 the two forecast scenarios
presented in the Greenbook, and we have provided a variation on
the second scenario that incorporates a different assumption
about monetary policy.
In extending the baseline, we retained the assumption
that U.S. nominal short-term interest rates will be essentially
unchanged through 1993, though rates are assumed to edge off a
bit in 1993.

The foreign exchange value of the dollar is

unchanged throughout.

Oil prices, after declining through the

middle of 1991, are assumed to be roughly constant in real terms
thereafter, rising to $22.75 per barrel in the fourth quarter of
1993.
Real GNP, while depressed in 1990 and 1991, expands at
about the rate of its potential in 1992 and 1993.

With the

decline of oil prices in 1991, consumer price inflation declines
sharply in 1991 to about 4-1/2 percent; it remains at that rate
in 1992 before edging off further in 1993.

Excluding food and

energy, the decline in the CPI is more gradual.
In the alternative oil price scenario, the price of oil
imports remains at $25 per barrel through 1993.

However, the

difference between this price path and that underlying the
baseline narrows after the middle of 1991.
The estimated additional impact of this alternative
scenario on the growth of real GNP in 1991 is about 1/3 of a

-

7 -

percentage point, but further effects on growth in 1992 and 1993
are estimated to be negligible.

Overall consumer price inflation

does not decline as much in 1991 as in the baseline scenario
because the temporary benefit from the drop in oil prices is
absent.

As in the baseline, the decline in the CPI excluding

food and energy is more gradual.
Growth of M2 -- the bottom panel -- is essentially the

same in the alternative as in the baseline.

This reflects the

fact that in our model changes in oil prices have essentially a
neutral effect on nominal GNP.
Finally, the table presents a variation on the
alternative oil price scenario in which the price of imported oil
remains at $25 per barrel and monetary policy is targeted on the
path of real GNP that would have prevailed under the oil price
assumption that was used in the June Greenbook forecast.

The

third line in the top panel of the table presents the path for
real GNP that was used in the model simulation.

To achieve that

path, the federal funds rate was reduced by 50 basis points in
the third quarter of 1990 relative to the Greenbook assumption.
By the fourth quarter of 1991, half of that reduction is
eliminated, and it is entirely eliminated by the end of 1992.
Compared with the alternative scenario, with the real
GNP target, consumer price inflation, including or excluding food
and energy, is only slightly greater in 1990 and 1991, but a gap
opens up in 1992 and 1993.

However, given our oil price

assumptions, the downward inflation trajectory is maintained,
albeit from a higher starting point, because of the slack that is

- 8 -

introduced into the economy in 1990 and 1991 in the underlying
projection.
Mr. Chairman, that concludes our report.

Alternative Forecast Scenarios
August 21, 1990

Alternative Forecast Scenarios
Greenbook forecast extended through 1993, with essentially
unchanged nominal short-term interest rates and an unchanged
value of the dollar.

Baseline:

Alternative Oil Price Scenario:
Price of oil imports remains at $25 per barrel through 1993.
Monetary policy assumption same as in Baseline.
Real GNP Target:

Price of oil imports remains at $25 per barrel. Monetary
policy targets the real GNP path that would have prevailed with
the oil price assumption in the June Greenbook.

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

1990

1991

1992

1993

1.1
1.1
1.3

2.0
1.7
2.3

2.4
2.4
2.4

2.5
2.5
2.5

5.8
5.8
5.9

4.4
5.0
5.1

4.4
4.4
4.6

4.2
4.0
4.4

Baseline
Alternative
Real GNP Target

5.3
5.3
5.4

4.8
5.0
5.2

4.5
4.6
4.8

4.3
4.1
4.5

Baseline
Alternative
Real GNP Target

4.0
4.0
4.3

4.5
4.6
5.6

5.0
4.8
4.8

6.0
6.1
6.4

Real GNP
Baseline
Alternative
Real GNP Target

Consumer Prices
Baseline
Alternative
Real GNP Target

CPI excluding Food and Energy

M2

August 17, 1990
FOMC BRIEFING
Donald L. Kohn
Like the other briefers this morning, I will be devoting at least
part of my remarks to the implications of the oil price increases.

My

focus will be less on broad consequences of alternative scenarios for oil
and monetary policy, and more on the difficulties of choosing a policy and
implementing it under these circumstances.
In the staff forecast, outlined by Dave and Ted, the oil shock
under either oil price assumption is taken about half in GNP prices and
half in reduced output.

This is achieved following the same monetary

policy as would have been followed without the oil price increase.

That

policy is one in which the federal funds rate is assumed to be flat, just
below the level assumed for the June Greenbook, and money growth on a path
just above the one thought likely in June.
As a number of members have remarked, this result, or something
shaded to one or another side of it, may be a reasonable outcome, given
the choices facing the economy and the FOMC.

The problem facing the FOMC

in implementing policy over coming months and quarters is that the situation is not likely to work out this neatly.

The results in the forecast

are a product of assumptions not only about the shock but also about the
particular values assigned to a whole host of relationships in the
economy; these produced the approximate equality between upward price
effects and downward output adjustments in response to the assumed oil
price increase.

Especially when these relationships involve responses to

an infrequent phenomenon, such as a supply shock, their specification is

subject to great uncertainty.

In these circumstances, the chances of

policy mistakes, leading to unintended output shortfalls or accelerations
in prices are amplified.
The bluebook noted some attractiveness to paying attention to a
path for nominal GNP in the presence of a supply shock.

A given path for

nominal GNP when prices are going one way and quantities another enforces
a discipline of taking equal deviations from a baseline in both prices and
output.

Focusing on nominal GNP imparts a self-correcting aspect to

policy--that is, it limits the possibility of cumulating shortfalls in
output or sustained accelerations in inflation.

A tendency, for example,

toward cumulating weakness in the economy would depress nominal GNP, both
directly itself and indirectly by holding down prices, spurring an easier
monetary policy.

A limit on the ease would be reached if it began to

produce such a sharp turnaround in prices that nominal GNP started to
overshoot its mark, eliciting an automatic tightening of policy.

In

short, nominal GNP objectives, if they can be pursued successfully, protect against the possibility of major policy miscalculations, which might
be especially important in situations of unusual uncertainties in the
economic outlook.
The Committee has chosen over the years not to specify a target
for nominal GNP, despite some academic urgings to do so.

There are a

number of reasons for this, but one is the desire not to be accountable
for an objective that is difficult to achieve.

We don't know what nominal

GNP is until after the period is over--often over for a considerable

time--and the relationships between policy instruments of interest rates
or reserves and nominal GNP are loose at best.
Of course, these relationships are loose for any objective the
Committee might wish to pursue.

In practice, when deciding on its stance

in open market operations, the Committee has looked at a wide variety of
indicators, encompassing incoming data on the economy and prices, money
and credit, auction market prices, et al.

It is an error-prone process in

the most normal of times, and a supply shock only compounds the problems
by changing many of the relationships among these variables.

Often policy

moves have been made by deducing the course of the economy from the direct
observation of price and output data.

As Dave and Ted have emphasized,

the supply shock implies both more inflation in the short run and lower
output.

As a consequence, data suggesting a particular level of economic

activity will be associated with a higher path for prices and nominal
spending than in the absence of a supply shock, and comparable adjustments
will need to be made for expectations about output and spending associated
with particular price data.
This situation does imply the need for restraint in responding to
data that previously might have provoked a policy adjustment.

A somewhat

lower path for output and reduction in real income is a necessary consequence of the adverse movement in our terms of trade and decline in potential output.

In the short or intermediate run, the path for output might

have to dip even lower if there is a danger of a flare up of inflationary
expectations that would have to be reversed later through even greater

restraint on the economy.

On the other side, it may be necessary to tole-

rate a spike in prices if it can be seen not to have lasting consequences
because a margin of slack in resource utilization is developing at the
same time.
The relationship between money or nominal interest rates and
ultimate outcomes is also subject to considerable uncertainty.

The

felicitous property of the staff forecast, that a given monetary policy-specified using either M2 or the federal funds rate--would yield the same
nominal GNP both before and after the oil shock, was a property of the
particular quantitative specifications assumed.
stead were to

If the supply shock in-

produce larger increases in prices than decreases in out-

put, policy would have to be tightened relative to baseline to get the
same result for nominal GNP.

Similarly, if there were in fact a bigger

hit to output than bulge in prices, policy might have to be eased to get
the same nominal spending, with higher money growth and lower interest
rates than in the baseline.
Indeed, it may be particularly difficult to determine the association of nominal interest rates with spending and prices in the context of a supply shock.

Judging which nominal interest rate is most

likely to further policy objectives requires knowledge both of inflation
expectations--so that real rates may be determined--and of the correct
real rate to produce the desired level of spending.

Both of these vari-

ables are likely to be greatly affected, and by unknowable amounts, by the
oil price movements.

Choosing the wrong nominal interest rate and moving

too slowly in changing it over an extended period raise the odds on
cumulative economic weakness or accelerating inflation.
In circumstances of unusual uncertainty about the relationship of
interest rates to income, the conventional prescription for monetary
policy has been to pay more attention to money supplies.

To be sure,

money supply growth has not been tied particularly closely to nominal GNP
in recent years.

The wide variations in velocity, however, have occurred

in the context of a monetary policy that has moved interest rates largely
in anticipation of economic and price developments.

The concern at this

time would be that it will be much more difficult to "stay ahead of the
curve" when the shape of the curve will be hard to determine.

If policy

tends to lag events, that delay would tend to be reflected in stronger or
weaker money supply growth as spending accelerates or decelerates.
Attention to the money supply would not avoid variations in nominal GNP,
given the considerable interest elasticity to money demand, but it could
limit some of the most egregious swings.
However, increased reliance on monetary indicators requires that
their movements relative to income and interest rates be relatively predictable.

The "unexplained" movements in monetary aggregates was a topic

of considerable discussion in July.

There was a tendency at that meeting

to interpret the miss in M2 relative to expectations as a signal that
perhaps policy had been more restrictive than had been thought.

Since

that meeting downward revisions to GNP for past quarters have trimmed the
size of the miss relative to our standard money demand equations by a full
percentage point.

However, even after the revisions, there remains a

substantial shortfall in the quantity of money in the second quarter relative to historical relations among money, income and opportunity costs.
And GNP growth in the second quarter, when the mysterious slowdown in
money occurred, does not now seem to have come in much different than had
been expected.

That raises the possibility of a shift in asset prefer-

ences, or a downward shift in money demand.

Ordinarily, slow money growth

that occurred for this reason should be discounted in policymaking--that
is, it would not be reflective of restraint on the economy and would have
little import for future spending.

In the current situation, one might

want to be more careful in discounting the full extent of the money shortfall.

Some of it could well reflect an underlying disruption to the in-

termediation process that is not embodied in the opportunity cost variables included in our equations but will show up in future GNP.

Thus, it

is likely that the slow growth in M2 relative to income reflects both some
monetary restraint and some rearrangement of asset portfolios without much
macroeconomic effect.

While uncertainties on the nonfinancial side would

seem to reinforce the Committee's recent additional emphasis on money and
credit data in making policy, fresh questions about the stability of money
demand tend to weaken arguments for giving it even more prominence in
guiding open market operations.
Even the signals of the forward-looking indicators in auction
markets are not immune from disruption.

For example, a heightened pre-

ference for safety and liquidity can distort yield curves, commodity
prices, and exchange rates.

And those prices embody the guesses of inves-

tors about the reactions of the policy authorities here and abroad as well

-7-

as about the effects of the oil price increase.

This suggests that these

too need to be interpreted with particular care as we go through the
period ahead.
The Committee will need to continue its eclectic policy, but
perhaps with some modifications over coming quarters, should the supply
shock persist.

Relationships previously relied on for guiding policy will

be disturbed, but by unknown amounts.

Consequently, the room for error is

higher, especially since short-term nominal interest rates inevitably will
remain at the center of policy implementation.

In these circumstances,

fairly prompt changes in policy stance may be called for if the situation
clearly begins to unfold in ways that were not anticipated.

Although

strict nominal GNP targeting is not possible, some attention not only to
price and output data separately, but also to their interaction may be
useful in avoiding cumulative policy errors when supply shocks send prices
one way and quantities another.
None of this offers particular guidance for the decision today.
That requires some sense of the situation coming into the oil shock, and
also a judgment about the risks of leaning one or another direction in the
face of the disturbance.

As Dave explained, the greenbook forecast was

predicated on a judgment that the economy was on a trajectory that encompassed continued slow expansion, but also price pressures that had shown
no signs of abatement.

That forecast included a flat pattern of interest

rates into the future, and slightly faster money growth over the next few
months than we have seen on average since the first quarter, and faster
than we expected at the last meeting.

Some of this strengthening in money

reflects a lagged reaction to the narrowing of opportunity costs since
short-term rates peaked in April, and some a flight toward M2 assets in
the wake of the turmoil in bond and stock markets.

Additional growth for

the latter reason, of course, might be a sign of weakness, not of
Even with the stronger demand for M2, its

strength, in the economy.

growth is projected to remain substantially below that consistent with
what would be expected from standard money demand models using greenbook
spending and interest rates.
Credit conditions and their effect on spending continue to be a
major uncertainty in the outlook.

The greenbook projection does incor-

porate restraint from an ongoing constriction of credit supplies.

Our

senior loan officer survey seemed to confirm that a tightening of credit
conditions had in fact been continuing at least through the date of the
survey in early August.

Banks reported greater selectivity in making

loans, and they had raised rates on loans relative to benchmark rates and
had tightened nonprice terms, including collateral requirements, loan
size, and loan covenants.

The results can not be parsed with any con-

fidence between a natural response to deteriorating credit quality, and a
tighter leash on supply for borrowers of a given credit quality.

Weaker

economic conditions and concerns about credit quality were cited most
frequently as reasons for tightening, but banks also mentioned capital
standards and regulatory pressure.

To some extent, these results can be

seen as confirming the sense of a deterioration that underlay the easing
of reserve conditions in July.
evaluate.

Whether they go further is difficult to

Credit flow data do suggest some drop off in July.

Business,

consumer, and real estate lending at banks all were relatively weak last
month, and show no signs of significant strength in early August.

But

this is a pattern that was evident early this year, and borrowing by private nonfinancial sectors continued to about keep pace with income growth
through June, the last month for which we have estimates.

Lenders likely

are even more cautious than they were earlier this year, especially for
marginal borrowers who are more vulnerable to a prolonged period of slow
growth, and this caution may have increased further with the uncertainties
over the effects of the oil price increase.

Investment grade borrowers,

on the other hand, seem to continue to find funds available.

Although

banks reported some tightening of terms to large borrowers, spreads in
credit markets for investment grade issues remain narrow.
A view that credit conditions were tightening beyond that allowed
for by the previous easing in reserve conditions and might contribute to,
and feed on, an economy that was already deteriorating might argue for
consideration of an additional easing move at this meeting--or at least a
leaning in that direction in the language governing intermeeting adjustments.

Such an action need not contribute to a longer-run worsening of

the inflation situation, even after the oil shock, though to avoid this
consequence it should not prevent some weakening in economic activity
relative to the economy's now lower potential.
Any policy move also would need to be considered in light of the
sensitive state of market expectations, however, with implications for the
course of output and inflation over time.

In the wake of the oil shock,

the Federal Reserve's next policy action is likely to be scrutinized

-10-

especially carefully for signals about how the Committee assesses the
risks and weighs the outcomes in terms of leaning against the price or
output consequences of the oil price increase.

The market already seems

to anticipate both lower output--as seen in the stock market decline--and
higher inflation--as reflected in part in movements of the dollar, bonds
At the same time markets do not now appear to expect a near-

and gold.

term monetary policy move.

Volatile markets and sensitive expectations,

along with uncertainty about both the extent and duration of the oil price
increase and the response to it of spending and wage and price developments, might argue for a cautious approach to any monetary policy moves,
at least initially, perhaps implying some bias toward no immediate change
in policy.
Such an approach should not be allowed to paralyze policy over
time, however.

Indeed, as was noted earlier, the greater chance

for

error in the current situation strengthens the case for making adjustments
promptly should incoming information, interpreted in light of changed
circumstances, begin to indicate that policy is not calibrated appropriately.