View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held
in the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System in Washington, D. C., on Tuesday, August 21, 1973, at
9:30 a.m.

PRESENT:

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Mr.
Mr.

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Burns, Chairman
Hayes, Vice Chairman
Balles
Brimmer
Bucher
Daane
Francis
Holland
Mayo
Morris
Sheehan

Messrs. Clay, Eastburn, Kimbrel, and Winn,
Alternate Members of the Federal Open

Market Committee
Messrs. Black, MacLaury, and Coldwell, Presidents

of the Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond,
Minneapolis and Dallas, respectively
Mr. Broida, Secretary
Messrs. Altmann and Bernard, Assistant

Secretaries
Mr. O'Connell, General Counsel
Mr. Partee, Senior Economist
Mr. Axilrod, Economist (Domestic Finance)
Messrs. Bryant, Gramley, Reynolds, Scheld,
and Sims, Associate Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market Account
Mr. Coombs, Special Manager, System Open Market
Account

8/21/73

Mr. Melnicoff, Deputy Executive Director,
Board of Governors
Mr. Coyne, Assistant to the Board of Governors
Mr. O'Brien, Special Assistant to the Board
of Governors
Messrs. Wernick and Williams, Advisers,
Division of Research and Statistics,
Board of Governors
Messrs. Gemmill and Pizer, Advisers, Division
of International Finance, Board of Governors
Mr. Ettin, Assistant Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Mr. Wendel, Chief, Government Finance Section,
Division of Research and Statistics,
Board of Governors
Miss Pruitt, Economist, Office of the Secretary,
Board of Governors
Mr. Crow, Staff Assistant, Board Members' Offices,
Board of Governors
Mrs. Peters, Secretary, Office of the

Secretary, Board of Governors
Mrs. Stanier, Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Board of Governors
Messrs. Parthemos and Doll, Senior Vice
Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of

Richmond and Kansas
Messrs. Hocter, Brandt,
Presidents, Federal
Cleveland, Atlanta,

City, respectively
and Green, Vice
Reserve Banks of
and Dallas, respectively

Messrs. Kaminow and Kareken, Economic Advisers,
Federal Reserve Banks of Philadelphia and
Minneapolis, respectively
Miss Greenwald and Messrs. Cooper, Thunberg, and
Balbach, Assistant Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of Boston, New York, New York,
and St. Louis, respectively

8/21/73

Chairman Burns welcomed Mr. Black, who was attending his
first Committee meeting since being named President of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond, and on behalf of the Committee he wished
Mr. Black well as he undertook his new responsibilities.
By unanimous vote, the minutes
of actions taken at the meetings of
the Federal Open Market Committee
on June 18-19 and July 9, 1973, were
approved.
The memoranda of discussion for
the meetings of the Federal Open Market
Committee held on June 18-19 and July 9,
1973, were accepted.
Chairman Burns called for a staff report on international
monetary and trade developments, and Mr. Reynolds made the
following statement:
Since late July, there has been a marked reversal
of tendencies and attitudes in foreign exchange markets,
as Mr. Coombs will be reporting in more detail. The
dollar has strengthened pretty steadily, and major
foreign central banks have sold off about $1 billion
of their dollar reserves in just the past 3 weeks.
This reversal seems to have been triggered by
changes in interest rate relationships--by the easing
of an unintended late-July liquidity squeeze in
Germany, and by the sharp further advance in U.S.
interest rates, including the administered rates to
which Europeans pay more attention than we do, namely,
the prime rate and the discount rate. But more
fundamentally, the strengthening of the dollar has
been based on a growing recognition that the U.S. trade
balance and over-all payments position are improving
rapidly.

8/21/73

The improvement is clear from recently published
statistics. The trade deficit in the second quarter

of 1973 was at an annual rate of only $1.2 billion,
compared with $6.9 billion for the year 1972, an

improvement of nearly $6 billion. The balance on
goods and services showed a surplus in the second
quarter of nearly $3 billion at an annual rate,
compared with a deficit of $4-1/2 billion in the
year 1972, an improvement of nearly $7-1/2 billion.
We do not yet have the second-quarter figures for
the balance on current and long-term capital trans
actions; the so-called "basic" balance will be pub
lished in mid-September. But we do have an estimate
and we think that that balance may have been a deficit

at an annual rate of less than $3 billion, compared
with nearly $10 billion for the year 1972, representing

an improvement of $7 billion.
Our most recent assessment of the outlook suggests
that the improvement in our payments position will con
tinue through 1974, and at an even more rapid rate
than we had earlier supposed. We now think the trade
balance may be about zero for the second half of 1973,
and may show a surplus of as much as $4 billion in
1974. On goods and services combined, we expect that
the surplus may rise to a rate of nearly $4 billion
in the second half of 1973, and to as much as $9
billion in 1974. We are hesitant to project the basic
balance so far ahead because of the great uncertainties
attaching to capital flows during a period when U.S.
controls are scheduled to be relaxed. But there does
seem to be a good possibility that the basic balance
could even be in surplus next year for the first time
since 1957.
While the fact that the U.S. payments position
is improving, and will continue to improve, is now
increasingly recognized, the nature of the improve
ment seems to me to be somewhat misunderstood. I
would like this morning to try to clarify it a little,
and also to comment on some related developments in
international commodity markets.
As we pointed out in the June chart show, there
are three main forces currently working to improve
the U.S. trade balance. The most fundamental is the

8/21/73

exchange rate changes that have taken place since

1970.

These work persistently and powerfully, but

only slowly and with a very considerable lag.

Evidence that they are indeed working is found in
the recent leveling off in the volume of U.S.

imports, despite the domestic boom, and in the
increasing U.S. share in world exports of manufac
tures. But nothing startlingly new is happening
here. Just as it seemed to me wrong in 1972 to
say that the adjustment to exchange rate changes
was coming much more slowly than should have been
anticipated, so it seems incorrect now to say that
the adjustment is now coming faster than had been
anticipated. I think the adjustment to exchange

rate changes is about on schedule, and much of it is
still to come, in 1974 and on into 1975.

What does seem to be coming somewhat faster
than we earlier anticipated is the change in relative
business cycle conditions here and abroad. Whereas
in 1972 much of the deterioration in our trade
balance was attributable to a worsening cyclical
position, with strong recovery at home and delayed
recovery abroad, much of the recent improvement is
attributable to an improving cyclical position,
with the boom abroad still gathering steam while
ours is beginning to slacken. We would expect
cyclical conditions to be favorable to us over the
next year or so, with the expansion of activity
slowing much less abroad than at home.
Finally, the third factor--and the factor
that at the moment is quantitatively most important
in improving our trade balance and outlook--is what
we used to refer to as the temporary bulge in agri
cultural exports, which is related more to acts of
God than to policy actions, although prosperity abroad
and dollar devaluation have certainly contributed to
it. That bulge in agricultural exports now shows
signs of being prolonged until at least mid-1974,
whereas earlier we had expected it to subside in
late 1973. Large--perhaps record--crops are still
in prospect around the world for the crop year that
has just begun, but crop prospects are not quite so
good as earlier expected, and carryovers are danger
ously low, so that total supplies are both lower than
had been hoped and low in relation to prospective
demand even at current high prices.

8/21/73

It is a close question whether world supplies
will prove to be just adequate to meet demands for
current consumption or whether they will fall somewhat
short. In this uncertain setting, with low carryovers,
market prices have recently been bid up to dizzy
heights, and it seems clear that even if they later
fall off a good deal, the average prices for U.S.
agricultural exports will remain much higher than
they were last year, while export volumes will remain
at about the past year's high levels.
Possibly the United States will find it necessary
to reimpose controls on agricultural exports. But
such controls should not greatly affect our projections,
since their purpose would be to hold down U.S. prices
while permitting export volumes of just about the
levels projected. We are currently projecting the

value of agricultural exports to hold at a $16 to $17
billion annual rate range through mid-1974, whereas
last June we had been projecting a $13 to $14 billion
rate. Even our latest estimates may be too low; we
have assumed average export prices well below recent
market prices, though, of course, above the export
prices of last year. The figure of $16 to $17 billion
may be compared with $9-1/2 billion for calendar 1972,
which we then thought of as a pretty good year.
Incidentally, if further export controls are
judged to be necessary, I would hope we might make
international efforts of some sort to share the
shortages as equitably as possible.
It looks as
if any world shortages will be only marginal, and
it does great damage to our long-run export promotion
effort to keep harping on our desire to put U.S.
consumers' interests ahead of everyone else's.
In summary, because of crop shortfalls abroad and
our own good fortune in having supplies available for
export, we have recently been getting a much more
rapid balance of payments improvement than would
have resulted from exchange rate changes alone. Later,
when agricultural exports subside, as they surely will,
the exchange rate changes will be working their full
effects, and with prudent domestic management we ought
to be able to sustain the better payments position
that we expect will be achieved in 1974. Thus, both

8/21/73

the short-term and medium-term outlooks for our
balance of payments seem to me to be very strong.
There may still be occasional setbacks, but the
trends are encouraging.
The enormous rise in agricultural prices has,
of course, done great damage to domestic price
stability, and we would not have needed anything
like the large price increases that occurred to
achieve an acceptable rate of balance of payments
improvement. Similarly, the boom in world market
prices of nonfood commodities has also contributed
greatly to domestic inflation, and has somewhat
damped the payments improvement by the added cost
of imports.
Commodity price increases--both for foods and
for raw materials--have reflected, I believe, not
only genuine supply shortages, but also a good deal
of speculative activity. The latter has included
not only speculation on the possibility of shortages
but also more generally an effort to beat inflation
by getting out of financial assets into goods. This
speculative bubble on top of the commodity boom may
now, it seems to me, be on the verge of bursting.
That would be helped by the recent strengthening of
the dollar and by the very high cost of borrowing
money to maintain speculative positions. We have in
recent days seen some hesitation in the market prices
of cocoa, copper, and rubber, as well as in prices of
grains and soybeans. And wool prices peaked as long
ago as last March.
Since earlier increases in the prices of raw
materials have not yet been fully reflected in the
prices of finished products, it may be some months
before any decline in spot commodity prices will be
reflected in slower increases in broad price indexes.
But by the end of the year, we may well be getting
some relief on the price front from declining commodity
prices as well as from the improving foreign exchange
value of the U.S. dollar compared with the lows reached
in July.
Over the past year, the rapid expansion of U.S.
exports put added pressure on an already buoyant domestic
economy and thus intensified somewhat our domestic

8/21/73

problems. But over the year ahead, if our pro
jections of flagging domestic demand are realized,
the stimulus of further advances in exports will
be a more welcome, sustaining influence.
Chairman Burns then invited Mr. Daane to report on develop
ments at the meeting of the Ministers of the Committee of Twenty,
which had been held in Washington on July 30-31.
Mr. Daane observed that the meeting had been billed in
advance as a working meeting designed to permit an exchange of
views on the key issues and not intended to produce a communique.
He thought

an excellent summary of the major issues had been

prepared for the Finance Ministers and Governors by the C-20
Deputies prior to the meeting.
good one in his judgment.

The meeting itself was a very

The prevailing atmosphere was one of

forward motion and of willingness and desire to cooperate in
finding solutions to complex issues.

Mr. Wardhana, chairman of

the meeting, in both his public and private remarks at the end
of the meeting rightly praised the constructive spirit in which
the participants had faced the difficult issues before them.
Mr. Daane reported that three major sessions were devoted
to substantive issues.

One half-day session was concerned with

the adjustment process and convertibility, and in his opinion,
it was the most significant.

It seemed to develop a greater

narrowing of differences with a general recognition of the need

-9-

8/21/73

for symmetry in the burden of the adjustment process.

Secretary

Shultz made clear the United States' position in favor of a system
with strong enforcement features.

The ensuing discussion helped

to clarify differences which still remained regarding the desir
ability of a system involving more of a presumption of action or
one relying more on an assessment or appraisal process by a
revamped Executive Board of the International Monetary Fund.

There appeared to be general agreement on the need for some sort
of graduated pressures but the nature and degree of the pressures
were still unresolved issues.
The second substantive session dealt with primary reserve
assets, Mr. Daane said, and he thought there was less narrowing
of differences on this issue.

The Ministers and Governors seemed

to take the position that SDR's should be the primary reserve
asset, but they were uncertain about the characteristics that SDR's
should have in a reformed system.

Those characteristics involved

technical questions which required some further study.

One, for

example, concerned maintenance of the value of the SDR--whether
it should be tied to an average market basket of currencies or
to something else.

Another question was the appropriate rate

of interest on SDR's.
resolved.

All those questions were far from being

On the issue of gold, there was really no pressure

8/21/73

-10-

to increase its price except from one or two representatives.
Secretary Shultz expressed the U.S. position that gold should be
phased out.

The thrust of the European position, as he (Mr. Daane)

interpreted it, was that there was no need for an official
price of gold and that nations should have the freedom to
buy and sell gold and to settle their accounts in gold at
market-related prices.

The U.S. view was that it might be

desirable to amend the March 1968 agreement to permit selling
but that the United States was skeptical about the usefulness,
and was unsure about the implications, of a complete severing
of the official link.
Mr. Daane indicated that the third major substantive
session was concerned with development assistance.

As expected,

the developing countries wanted to be exempted from any con
straints in the adjustment process and they were very much in
favor of a link between development assistance and SDR creation.
Chairman Burns spoke with a single but very strong voice in
opposition to the link.

He gave a stirring defense of the U.S.

view that neither development assistance nor the SDR would be
helped by such a link.

It was his (Mr. Daane's) impression

that the Chairman's remarks, while perhaps not convincing to the
developing countries, were received with a great deal of sympathy
outside the meeting by a number of his European counterparts.

-11-

8/21/73

Mr. Daane said he felt that progress at the recent meeting
had been greater than had been anticipated.

The C-20 Deputies

were scheduled to hold a meeting in Paris on September 5 to 7.
They would try to develop further the draft outline that the
Ministers and Governors would consider at their meeting in
Nairobi now scheduled for Sunday, September 23.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of
the System Open Market Account on foreign exchange market con
ditions and on Open Market Account and Treasury operations in
foreign currencies for the period July 17 through August 15,
1973, and a supplemental report covering the period August 16
through 20, 1973.

Copies of these reports have been placed in

the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr.

Coombs

made the following statement:
Between July 10 and 31 we intervened fairly
frequently to restrain a declining tendency in the
dollar rate. During this period we did a total of
$273 million equivalent in German marks, French
francs,and Belgian francs, all financed by drawings
on the swap line. Of this total, $220 million was
in marks and I am glad to say our intervention was
strongly supported by coordinated purchases of
dollars in the market totaling $355 million by the
German Federal Bank. More or less concurrently
the British Government became thoroughly alarmed

8/21/73

-12-

over the inflationary risk of a further depreciation
of sterling and authorized the Bank of England to
intervene forcefully, which they did to the extent
of $635 million, while the Common Market central
banks spent $245 million in defending their parities
vis-a-vis each other.
The Bank of Italy intervened
even more strongly for a total of roughly $1 billion.
This intervention added up in my view to a fairly
convincing demonstration of central bank determination
to restore orderly conditions in the exchange markets,
although the scale and forcefulness of our own operations
were, comparatively speaking, fairly constrained.
Towards the end of July, I requested and secured
Chairman Burns' approval to switch, if we got a
favorable opportunity, from purely defensive tactics
to a more aggressive approach, designed to push the
dollar rate up toward more realistic levels. After
some delay, the Treasury also concurred. We were
hoping to exploit through such operations the favorable
trade figures for June, released on July 26. Unfor
tunately, this operation was totally frustrated by
a credit crunch that developed in the German money
market. As a result we ended up that day, instead
of undertaking an aggressive operation, spending
$53 million in purely defensive operations despite
the good news on the trade side. Together with other
central bank representatives in Europe, Governor Daane
and I appealed to the German Federal Bank to temper
their credit squeeze, and they responded in a very
cooperative way. As the German money market sub
sequently eased, we began to nudge the dollar up gently.
But just as we were about to operate more forcefully,
the dollar suffered a new setback on the news that

some Congressman had filed a resolution to impeach
the President.

Early in August, however, the situation turned
completely the other way and the dollar was suddenly
favored by a whole series of events--in particular
a sharp decline in the London gold price, unusually
stringent conditions in our own money market, and

the development of abnormally easy conditions in the
German and French markets. We were naturally tempted
to seize this opportunity to drive the dollar rate up,

8/21/73

-13-

but we concluded that too much of its buoyancy at
that moment was probably attributable to temporary

factors, and that if we did go into the market with
aggressive tactics, we could get more results than
we really wanted in the sense of generating an
unduly sharp rise in the rate which might subsequently
prove costly to sustain. The German Federal Bank
agreed fully with our analysis of the situation.
Accordingly, we decided that it was best to take
advantage of the temporary factors pushing up the
dollar to reduce our outstanding debt as much as
we could. As the dollar continued to rise strongly
each day, we succeeded by August 15th in completely
covering the $273 million of swap drawings made in
July, with an over-all profit on the operation of
nearly $8-1/2 million.
I think it was just as well that we got this
debt cleaned up when we did, because yesterday the
market suddenly turned sour. The weekend European

press put out a lot of dire warnings about the
resurgence of inflation in the United States; rumors
began to circulate that the German trade surplus
for July would move up to record levels; and, finally,
the Secret Service revealed knowledge of a plot against
President Nixon and cancelled the presidential motorcade
in New Orleans. We let the dollar rate gradually fall
back by about 2 per cent from Friday's close, and
then as the Secret Service report began to attract
wide attention, we went back into the market and began
to operate fairly forcefully--more forcefully than
before--by repeatedly hitting bids for marks. By
mid-afternoon, the demand for marks seemed to be
tapering off and we then proceeded to try to restore
a little buoyancy to the dollar rate by placing offers
in the market. We finished the day with the rate
significantly above the low point at a cost of
$45.5 million equivalent in the way of intervention.
We appealed to the German Federal Bank to follow
through in Frankfurt this morning, and they did, with
secret intervention of $30 million. The rate has
now moved up by another 1/2 per cent or so. We hope
that the market is now stabilizing but much will
depend upon the German trade figures for July as well
as our own, both of which are due to be published at
the end of this week.

8/21/73

-14-

Reviewing our market experience since July 10,
I am inclined to think that our operations, in con
junction with those of other central banks, have
done quite a bit to restore a fairly orderly market,
although the market remains pretty jumpy and I don't
like the sharpness of rate movements in response to
whatever is the latest item on the ticker. We have,
I think, introduced to some extent a feeling of
risk in the market that the dollar can go up as
well as down. But most market traders still remain
persuaded, I'm afraid, that we will probably tend
to back off as soon as selling pressure develops
against the dollar, and on balance the market still
remains more fearful of a decline than of a rise
in the dollar rate. As a result I am more than ever
inclined to the judgment that when we do operate,
we should operate on a larger scale and in a more
forceful and visible manner than we have hitherto,
if we want to change market psychology for the better.
If Mr. Reynolds' forecast holds up, the risks inherent
in more forceful operations should be much reduced.
The second point I would like to stress is the
importance, at the earliest possible moment, of
getting clearance to operate in the London gold
market in conjunction with one or two other central
banks. For better or worse, sharp increases or
declines in the London gold price exert an important
influence on market confidence or lack of confidence
in the dollar. We urgently need to reinforce our
exchange operations with periodic operations in the
gold market, where the Treasury would, incidentally,
realize profits of around 200 per cent on any gold
sold.
Finally, our experience of the past month has
demonstrated the abnormally strong influence on
the external value of the dollar of relative changes
in credit conditions here and abroad. All of the
major money markets, including our own, are now so
tight that any further intensification of stringency
in one of them or easing in another tends to set off
big movements of short-term funds with inevitable
effects on exchange rates.

8/21/73

-15-

Chairman Burns commended Mr. Coombs on the skill with
which he had conducted the System's foreign currency operations
in recent weeks.
Mr. Mayo noted that Mr. Reynolds had not commented on
the problem of growing fuel imports.

He asked whether the staff

anticipated serious balance of payments repercussions only over
the longer run or whether intermediate-term difficulties were
also foreseen.
Mr. Reynolds replied that the staff had allowed for a
very large increase in fuel imports in the projection period,
but since other imports were expected to level off, total imports
did not rise as fast as exports.

The problem of fuel imports

would require more attention in projections of 5 or 10 years
ahead, but it needed to be kept in mind that oil exporting countries
would have very large dollar earnings to invest and some of those
funds might well be channeled back to the United States.
such investments were already occurring.

In fact,

The question, therefore,

was how the two flows would balance out, and it was not clear that
the over-all balance of payments would be worsened by rising oil
imports.
Mr. Brimmer asked Mr. Coombs whether current conditions
in international financial markets made it advisable in his
judgment to drop the reference to international developments

-16-

8/21/73

in the operational paragraph of the directive, as the staff
had suggested.

1/

Mr. Coombs replied that such developments could have a
significant influence on the System's operations and on that
basis it might be desirable to retain the reference.
Mr. Brimmer referred to Mr. Coombs' suggestion that the
System participate in the London gold market for the purpose of
fostering greater stability in that market and indirectly in
the external value of the dollar.

He (Mr. Brimmer) had thought

that the direction of causality ran the other way, that the gold
market was a barometer of expectations for the dollar and that
a strengthening in the dollar would have a tranquilizing effect
on the gold market.
Mr. Coombs replied that the two markets tended to interact.
A strengthening in the dollar tended to weaken the market for gold.
On the other hand, a sudden rise in gold prices, as had occurred
the day before, tended to be construed as an indication of developing
weakness in the dollar.

What concerned him was that speculators

in the gold market were in a position to influence the behavior
of the dollar in the exchange markets.

He believed it would be

helpful if the System were in a position to counter the activities
of the speculators.
1/ The alternative draft directives submitted by the staff for
Committee consideration are appended to this memorandum as Attachment A.

8/21/73

-17-

Mr. Francis said he had found Mr. Reynold's report
useful and realistic.

In view of that report and of the success

of relatively modest transactions in the exchange markets, he
did not understand why Mr. Coombs was recommending larger
operations.
Mr. Coombs remarked that although there was a fair
chance that the projections made by Mr. Reynolds would materialize,
setbacks to confidence in the dollar could be expected from time
to time under current circumstances.

It would be unfortunate,

in his view, if the improvement in the fundamental position of
the dollar were to be frustrated by speculative sprees generated
by temporary influences.

He had the feeling that to date the Desk

could not intervene by much more than $50 million on any given
day without weakening the Treasury's willingness to support
the System's operations.

On certain days it would have been

helpful if operations could have been larger.

The scale he

had in mind would involve transactions ranging up to $100 million
or $125 million.

Such intervention would be closer to the tactics

employed by European central banks when they encountered temporary
difficulties.
By unanimous vote, the System open
market transactions in foreign currencies
during the period July 17 through August 20,
1973, were approved, ratified, and confirmed.

8/21/73

-18-

Chairman Burns then called for the staff report on
the domestic economic and financial situation, supplementing
the written reports that had been distributed prior to the

meeting.

Copies of the written reports have been placed in

the files of the Committee.
Mr. Partee made the following statement:
Fairly firm figures now indicate that the expansion
in economic activity slowed more sharply during the
second quarter than we had been expecting. Real
GNP rose at only a 2-1/2 per cent annual rate, while
the pace of inflation quickened further, to an 8 per
cent rate in terms of the fixed-weight private
deflator. The reported slowing in real output
growth may have overstated the underlying adjustment
that has been taking place, however, because of
measurement problems associated with farm output,
rapid price inflation, and seasonal factors. Thus,
gross private nonfarm output increased in real
terms at a 4 per cent annual rate--considerably
better than for over-all GNP. And the industrial
production index, which avoids the problems of
making adjustment for price change, rose at a 5-1/2
per cent annual rate--down markedly from the first
a respectable showing.
quarter but still
Moderation in real growth, of course, is a
desirable development in the current economic
setting. Output has been pressing against capacity
in many lines, and there is undoubtedly a good deal
of upward price pressure stemming from the strength
and intensity of market demands, as well as from
special supply constraints in foodstuffs and basic
commodities and from the inexorable upward march
in unit labor costs. If some of these pressures
can be relieved, so much to the good, as long as
the adjustment doesn't go too far. And at present,
there is no evidence I know of that the slowdown is
beginning to cumulate. Industrial production is

8/21/73

-19-

estimated to have risen at a 7 per cent rate over
the past 2 months; retail sales rebounded in July,
following the relatively weak second-quarter showing;
and new orders for durable goods have remained at
peak levels with backlogs continuing to rise.
Looking ahead, we continue to expect that
growth will be moderate for the remainder of the
year and that it is likely to slacken further in
1974. As before, the main elements in this pattern
of slower growth are the expected sharp decline in
housing starts and continued moderation in real con
sumer demands. Indeed, we have reduced our projections
in both areas somewhat since the last meeting of the
Committee. In the case of housing, the recent con
striction in the availability of mortgage credit
seems likely to cut somewhat further into housing
starts than we had been projecting, particularly in
the first half of next year. And in the case of
consumption, sharply higher prices--especially for
food--are likely to squeeze the budgets of many
urban families, thus tending to force reductions
in outlays for consumer durables and other post
ponable items. Higher prices will have the effect
of transferring income to farmers, businesses andthrough tax revenues--to governments, where the
stimulus to current spending is apt to be much less
than the purchasing power impact of lower real
incomes on urban families.
Despite the clear prospect of additional weakness
in these major sectors, it is important to recognize
that the economy still has in it the potential for
a substantial further rise. Capital spending, inventory
investment, and export demand, in particular, could
all increase markedly further in the period to come.
And, in each instance, it is difficult to know how

far the expansion might go or how long it might last.
First, as to capital spending, we have already
witnessed a major upsurge over the past 2 years.
Physical output of business equipment is up by nearly

30 per cent from the lows of early 1971 and fully 10
per cent above the pre-recession peak, while non

residential construction expenditures in real terms
have also been tending upward. Nevertheless, new

8/21/73

-20-

orders for capital goods continue very strong, and
there seems to be no prospect of a slackening in
the months immediately ahead. Capacity limitations
in many industries, opportunities for profitable

substitution of equipment for high-cost labor, and
an ample internal cash flow all suggest a further
uptrend in capital spending, probably extending
well into 1974 and possibly of major dimensions.
The fall surveys of spending intentions for 1974 will
tell us more about prospects in this area.
The situation with respect to inventory invest
ment seems to point even more dramatically in the
direction of expansion. Stocks are currently very
low relative to sales and order backlogs, and many
business firms complain of shortages and delivery
delays. There is every evidence that business
desires to rebuild inventory positions to more
comfortable levels, and as the pressure eases from
expanding final demands, they should have the
opportunity to do so. Production facilities might
remain under considerable pressure for some time
as a result of this restocking process, and we
would expect that inventory accumulation will
take up most of the available slack well into the
winter and perhaps beyond.
Finally, there is the prospect that export
markets may remain much stronger than we have been
accustomed to in recent years. Mr. Reynolds has
discussed the marked improvement in the foreign
trade outlook that appears to be taking place,
and we have incorporated the new numbers in our
GNP projections. Suffice it for me to say that this
is an entirely new factor affecting the strength and
character of demand for U.S. production. If, at
something like current exchange rates, we have in
fact become the cheapest source in the world for a
wide array of basic commodities--both agricultural
and industrial--then demands for our output could be
much better sustained than in past periods when there
has been some domestic slack. Not only would foreign
buyers be available as a source of demand external
to our domestic environment, but those U.S. buyers
who in recent years have obtained supplies from abroad

8/21/73

-21-

would tend to shift back as domestic production of
such materials as steel, chemicals, textiles and
paper became available. This might mean a considerably
longer run of capacity operations for the basic
materials industries, relative to the remainder of
the economy, than has been typical in past cyclical
episodes.
It is not my intention, by emphasizing these
potential sources of strength, to depart from the
staff GNP projection presented in the green book.1/
That projection represents our view as to the most
probable course of economic developments, and it points
to a very moderate expansion in real demands, fading
next year to the point where unemployment begins to
move appreciably upward. What I do mean to underscore
is the fact that there is a good deal of uncertainty
surrounding that "highest probability" projection.
Substantially higher capital spending, inventory invest
ment, and foreign demand than we now anticipate would
not only raise the expenditure figures directly, but
would also tend to lift employment and consumer incomes
and expenditures, and would increase pressures on
employers for more liberal wage settlements. The
dilemma that the Committee faces, in my view, is in
deciding how to weigh the very real prospect that
growth in the economy will be slowing to minimal levels
against the very real risk that there may be enough
remaining strength to keep unacceptable pressure on
critical resources and hence on our structure of costs
and prices. The way that difficult question is decided
will have an important bearing on whether the Committee
maintains the pressure on credit markets for a while
longer or whether it should be prepared to slacken off
a bit as the long-sought objective of achieving much
slower growth in the money supply comes into view.
In response to a question by Mr. Francis, Mr. Partee
indicated that the staff was projecting a relatively small
increase in real product of 1.2 per cent from the fourth quarter

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

-22-

8/21/73

of 1973 to the fourth quarter of 1974.

That increase was about

3 percentage points below the normal potential growth rate of
the economy over the longer run.

On the basis of that projection

the staff anticipated some rise in unemployment after the fourth
quarter of this year.
Mr. Black observed that inventories had remained unusually
low in relation to sales and other pertinent measures, partly because
of the increased use of computers in inventory management and partly
because of supply shortages.

Recently, however, the Richmond Bank

had been getting the impression from businessmen in the District that
the rising cost of carrying inventories was contributing to consider
able reluctance to build up their stocks.

He noted that the Board

staff was projecting a large pickup in inventories and he wondered
whether Mr. Partee was inclined to modify the projection in light
of the rise in short-term interest rates.
Mr. Partee remarked that the current high cost of money
was in itself a restraining influence on the accumulation of
inventories.

However, he had been impressed by the many references

in the red book1 / to shortages of materials and component parts,
and his own observations suggested that the selection of many
items available in retail stores was poor.

Those impressions of

1/ The report, "Current Economic Comment by District," prepared
for the Committee by the staff.

-23-

8/21/73

shortages were consistent with the available statistics, which
showed that the inventory-to-sales ratio was lower than it had
Accordingly, he still anticipated a

been in a long time.

strong burst of inventory restocking as supplies became avail
able, but he believed high interest rates would be a moderating
influence.
Mr.

Black referred to a table in the supplement to the

green book which contained calculations of before-tax profit
margins in manufacturing industries.

The table suggested that

only a few industries--including primary metals, motor vehicles,
and petroleum--would have much opportunity to raise prices under
the Phase IV ceilings.

In that situation he wondered if those

ceilings might have a greater dampening effect on price increases
than might otherwise be expected.
Mr. Partee replied that the data referred to were very
hard to interpret.

They did indicate that a large number of

industries were at or above their Phase IV profit margin ceilings
in

the second quarter and those industries did not seem to be

in a good position to pass on increased costs.
not sure what would happen in practice.

However, he was

One consideration to

bear in mind was that nearly all industrial prices had been
frozen since mid-June.

Since costs could be assumed to have

-24-

8/21/73

continued to rise in

the interim, many firms might well report

lower third-quarter margins.

In that event they would have

more leeway to raise prices after the freeze was lifted.
Mr.

Hayes commented that the staff at the New York Bank

viewed the economic outlook in
Board staff.

much the same way as did the

He was impressed by the intensity of current

demand pressures in

the economy and by the pervasive shortages

of materials and skilled labor.

On the other hand, he saw

evidence that aggregate demand might be moderating,

in

part

because of a slackening in over-all consumer demands--despite
the recent spurt in
stimulated in

retail sales, which apparently was

part by the temporary freeze on prices.

no evidence, however,

There was

that business demands were cooling off.

Continuing, Mr. Hayes observed that the Phase IV
stabilization program was subject to a number of uncertainties.
He wondered,

for example, whether the controls would be admin

istered flexibly enough to correct existing distortions, and
if

the latter

were corrected,

whether price advances would be

so large as to worsen inflationary expectations and provoke
excessive wage demands.

In

the financial area, he did not see

much evidence that high interest rates were in themselves
bringing demand pressures under control thus far.

At some level,

presumably, interest rates would have a retarding impact, and
he hoped it

would be felt soon.

-25-

8/21/73

Mr. Hayes added that the most certain aspect of the
economic outlook was the inevitability of continued high rates
of inflation for some time to come.

As Chairman Burns had

pointed out on a number of recent occasions, the current
inflation had been greatly aggravated by factors beyond the
direct influence of domestic monetary policy.

Nevertheless,

he believed that if the System could help restore moderate
demand conditions before the recent price increases had begun
to work themselves fully into the wage-cost process, monetary
policy could make a major contribution in the fight against
inflation.
Mr. Coldwell asked Mr. Partee whether there was much
evidence that consumers were presently buying heavily in
anticipation of future price increases, especially in the
food area.
Mr. Partee observed that the July retail sales figures
were based on the advance report and therefore had to be inter
preted with caution.

However, he believed the data showed some

evidence of speculative buying.

There was a major increase in

food store sales during the month, and auto sales also were
surprisingly strong.

Ford and General Motors had held major

sales contests, which might have helped to account for the
spurt in auto sales, but it was also clear that buyers were

-26-

8/21/73

anticipating higher prices on 1974 models.

More generally, the

indexes of consumer confidence were now at their lowest point in
quite some time.

Consumers were cautious and were particularly

concerned about the outlook for food prices.

In the period

ahead, the character of markets for consumer goods would be
influenced by those concerns as well as by the speculative
buying that had occurred.
With respect to the projections, Mr. Partee noted that
the staff expected relatively little increase in retail sales
in the remaining months of 1973.

The stockpiling of foods

that might have occurred in July probably would have only short
run effects and would be followed by reduced buying for a month
or two.

However, the outlook for sales of durable goods was

distinctly weaker than it had appeared a month or two ago.

In

fact, there had not been much growth in sales of durable goods
since the surge in the first quarter.
Mr. Coldwell remarked that his contacts in the Dallas
District suggested that anticipatory buying of both foods and
other goods was substantial.

Consequently, some decline in

retail sales volume in September was expected. On the other
hand, shortages of inventories were delaying the receipt of
goods already ordered and deliveries in the period ahead would
help to maintain sales volume.

-27-

8/21/73

Mr. Winn inquired whether the recent reports of business
profits might not be misleading because of both profits on foreign
exchange dealings of multinational firms and inventory profits in
a period of rapid advances in prices.

If his suspicions about the

quality of earnings were correct, one could expect price increases
in the period ahead that would be approved under the controls.
Capital spending might also be affected.

One large manufacturing

company in the Cleveland District was reported to be operating with
marginal facilities, and because of the resulting squeeze on profit
margins, the company planned a major capital expenditure program
despite the high cost of money.
Mr. Winn added that capital spending would also be stim
ulated by political and social forces.

An obvious example was the

petroleum industry where capital spending for refining facilities
had fallen noticeably behind growing needs in the last 2 or 3
years.

Executives in the steel industry had maintained that

they would not undertake major capital spending programs despite
capacity operations, but their attitudes now seemed to be changing
rapidly.

One company alone was reported to be contemplating a

capital spending program of $3/4 billion, and other companies
were likely to follow, culminating in a major capital expenditure
boom in the industry.

-28-

8/21/73

Mr. Partee remarked that the staff report on corporate

profits in the second quarter, contained in the green book supple
ment, indicated a considerable increase in foreign dividends and
branch profits, presumably due in part to foreign exchange profits.

More importantly, the elimination of inventory profits would
serve

to reduce the year-over-year gains rather substantially.

With respect to the question that Mr. Black had raised earlier,
companies might argue before the Cost of Living Council that

after adjustment for inventory profits, profit margins were low
enough to justify increases in prices.

With regard to capital

spending, some staff members saw a potential for a major expansion
in several basic industries.

The current projections suggested

only a rather moderate increase next year, but actual expenditures
could be substantially higher.
Mr. Kimbrel commented that shortages of materials in the
Atlanta District were leading to delays in the completion of
both residential and industrial construction projects that were
pushing some construction firms close to bankruptcy because of
the high costs of funds.
were hard pressed;

Steel producers in the District also

demands for domestic steel were especially

strong--because imports from Europe had fallen off--at the same
time that supplies of steel scrap were being diverted to other
markets.

8/21/73

-29-

Mr. Kimbrel added that the staff at the Atlanta Bank
had studied the relationship between rates of capacity utilization
and price changes over the past 15 years.

They had found a

significant relationship between the level of unused capacity and
the behavior of prices.
Mr. Partee remarked that various other studies had shown a
strong relationship between the degree of capacity utilization
and the degree of pressure on prices.
Mr. Eastburn, noting that the staff projections suggested
a substantial decline in residential construction, inquired about
the staff's assumptions concerning interest rates.

He also asked

how Mr. Partee would assess the probabilities that the staff pro
jections for real GNP would prove to be too low rather than too
high.
In response, Mr. Partee noted that growth in the money
supply was assumed to be relatively low throughout the projection
period, and consequently, short-term interest rates were assumed
to drift upward in the remainder of 1973 and then to level off.
However, those assumptions did not have much effect on the pro
jections for residential construction because of the relatively
long lag in the impact of mortgage availability on housing
starts.

The staff had reduced somewhat its projections of housing

-30-

8/21/73

starts in 1974 in view of the unfavorable prospects for flows of
funds through the specialized mortgage lenders, given the current
high level of interest rates.
With respect to the over-all projections of real growth,
Mr. Partee said he believed the probabilities were greater that
they would prove to be too low for the period through the second
quarter of 1974.

The economy might well get more support than was

now expected from capital spending, inventory investment, and exports.
Beyond that, in the second half of 1974, those sectors would tend
to lose their momentum, and he was inclined to believe that the
projections were too high.

Personally, he found it difficult to

believe that an actual recession would not develop around the end
of 1974.
Mr, Morris indicated that he had been a little disturbed
by the apparent upsurge in retail sales in July.

A resurgence in

consumer spending could obviously upset the scenario of a slowdown
in real economic growth.

Accordingly, he had asked his staff to

do some research on recent developments in retail sales, and with
the help of the Cleveland and Chicago Federal Reserve Banks, a
number of major nonfood retailers had been contacted.

Interest

ingly, none reported an acceleration in the growth of their sales
in July and early August, and one nationwide firm reported a decline
from the April-May pace.

8/21/73

-31-

Chairman Burns commented that such evidence had to be
interpreted with caution; retailers invariably made comparisons
with year-earlier developments and did not make use of seasonally
adjusted movements, which would be much more revealing.
Mr. Morris said he agreed, but there was other evidence
to be considered.

For example, one reason for the sharp upturn in

retail sales in July was the downturn in June, on a seasonally
adjusted basis.

Reports now suggested that the June figures would

be revised upward owing to a revision in the data for sales by
automobile dealers.
be eliminated.

In that event, part of the July gain would

Moreover, about one-fourth of the total increase

in sales in July was due to foods, which at least in part reflected
price increases and anticipatory buying.

The conclusion from his

staff's review of the evidence was that no general upsurge in
consumer buying had occurred.
Mr. Partee said he agreed with the thrust, if not all the
specifics, of that evaluation.

The general merchandise category,

which included the retailers that had been contacted in the survey,
had not shown much increase in July following poor sales in June.
Over the 2 months combined sales probably had grown little after
adjustment for price increases.

More generally, he did not feel

that over-all consumer spending had rebounded in recent weeks and
he therefore was fairly confident that consumer demand would be
relatively slack in the autumn months.

-32-

8/21/73

Mr. Brimmer asked whether the staff had made any allowance
in the projection for the possibilities of strikes and other dis
turbances.

The green book indicated that some 2-1/2 million workers

would be affected by contract negotiations later this year, including
workers in the automobile and farm machinery industries.

A major

strike and its attendant disruptions could have a significant
influence on the course of economic activity.
Mr. Partee replied that the staff had assumed that there
would be no major strike.

Prospects appeared good for a settle

ment in the automobile industry, and if one was reached there,
settlements in the farm machinery and other industries were likely
to follow.
Mr. Brimmer commented that an important question before
the Committee was the likely course of economic activity 6 to 9
months ahead.

As he looked at the underlying forces, he saw

strength in State and local government expenditures and in business
investment.

The outlook for housing was clearly weak.

There was

greater uncertainty about the course of net exports and consumer
expenditures for durable goods.

In his view that combination of

developments was very likely to lead to a downturn before the last
quarter of 1974; he concluded that the economy was close to an
actual turning point, not just an inflection point.

Given the lags

-33-

8/21/73

with which monetary policy exerted its influence, he believed the
time was approaching when the issue before the Committee would
be not whether but how soon monetary policy should be eased.
Mr. Partee noted that the staff projections suggested
that real GNP would grow at a moderate rate in the second half of
1973 and a slow rate in the first half of 1974.

As he had indicated,

he was inclined to believe that growth over that period would be
somewhat higher, and he did not believe that a recession was an
early prospect.

He was particularly impressed by the major change

taking place in the foreign trade situation in part because of
the shifts in exchange rate relationships;

it was a factor in the

economic situation without precedent in the postwar period.

It

had implications not only for the over-all level of activity but
for the structure of output.

Thus, within the context of slow

growth in the economy next year, operations in certain basic
industries might be at capacity and demands for foods might
remain very strong, generating price pressures in particular
sectors.

With respect to business fixed investment, major expan

sion programs might be getting underway in the chemical, paper,
cement, steel,and petroleum industries--industries which had not
had major expansion programs since the mid-1950's and were now ex
periencing pressures on their facilities.

If such expansion pro

grams developed, the capital spending boom would be larger and would

-34-

8/21/73

last longer than suggested by the recent surveys and by the staff
projections.
Chairman Burns observed that there also was a clear poten
tial for a large expansion in inventory investment over the next
6 to 9 months.
Mr. Axilrod remarked that the expected rate of inflation
generally was higher now than it had been not very long ago, and
that might influence many business decisions in favor of making
capital expenditures without delay; not only would the cost be
lower than later on, interest rates in real terms were not high.
Chairman Burns observed that increases in wage rates had
accelerated in the non-unionized industries, and the probabilities
were high that they would accelerate in the unionized industries as
well, especially because of the sharp advances in the consumer
price index that had already occurred and those that were in pros
pect.

From the first quarter to the second quarter of the year,

wage rates in wholesale and retail trade rose at an annual rate
of 7.2 per cent, a far larger increase than in any other quarter
over the past 2-1/2 years.

The annual rate of increase in the

service trades was 7.3 per cent--a significantly higher rate than
in most other quarters since 1970.

The annual rate of increase in

wage rates for farm labor--which was a very sensitive measurewas 17.5 per cent from April to July; over the year from July 1972

8/21/73

-35-

to July 1973, the increase was 9.2 per cent, which was substan
tially higher than the rate of increase over the preceding 18 months.
Concerning fiscal policy, the Chairman remarked that the
reported figures did not tell the full story because the unified
budget excluded the activities of governmentally sponsored cor
porations.

In fiscal 1973--the year ending last June--the unified

budget showed a much smaller deficit than had been anticipated,
but during that fiscal year net borrowing by such corporations was
almost $8 billion.

If the corporations were included, the recorded

deficit would be $22.2 billion--not much smaller than the deficits
of $28.2 billion and $24.1 billion in fiscal years 1972 and 1971,
respectively, calculated on the same basis.

For calendar year 1973,

the deficit was estimated to be $27.5 billion--with deficits of $9.1
billion in the first half and $18.4 billion in the second half,
not seasonally adjusted.

Therefore, the frequently heard conclu

sion that the impact of the Federal budget was neutral did not take
into account the large expansion in net borrowing by those corpor
ations.

Over the four fiscal years 1970 through 1973, the cumu

lative deficit in the unified budget was $63.4 billion, but with
the governmentally sponsored corporations taken into account, the
deficit was $88.1 billion.

It was clear that fiscal policy had played

and would continue to play an important part in the inflationary
developments of the period.

-36-

8/21/73

In response to a question by Mr. Brimmer, Mr. Partee noted
that the Federal government sector in the national income accountswhich, on the high employment basis, was projected to move from
deficit in the second half of 1973 into progressively larger surpluses
in 1974--also did not include the activities of such corporations.
Mr. Brimmer remarked that he agreed with the Chairman's
assessment of wage rate developments.

In his own earlier remarks,

he had meant to call attention to the lags with which monetary policy
affected economic activity.

His own view--although he was not fully

persuaded of it--was that the pace of economic activity would slow
sooner rather than later, resulting in increased amounts of unused
resources.

Nevertheless, the Committee might decide to accept that

cost and retain a restrictive policy for a time in order to make
a further contribution to checking the rate of inflation.

That,

however, depended on a value judgment rather than an analytical
conclusion.
Mr. Hayes commented that he agreed that there were lags in
the effects of monetary policy, but if one thought that real weak
ness in the economy was as far in the future as the last quarter
of 1974 or the first quarter of 1975, the clear and present pressures
on prices and wages would rate a higher priority.
Chairman Burns remarked that forecasting difficulties should
never be underestimated, but on the basis of the evidence at hand,
a judgment of an early recession would be premature.

8/21/73

-37-

Mr. Sheehan noted that the staff projections in the green
book suggested that real GNP would grow only 1.2 per cent from the
fourth quarter of 1973 to the fourth quarter of 1974.

The staff

projection might prove to be too high and a mild recession might
develop, but he questioned whether a mild recession would have much
impact on the rate of inflation.

It seemed to him that only a deep

recession for a protracted period would have a significant effect
on inflation.

Therefore, he suggested that the Committee should

focus on what it might do to help bring about a higher rate of
real growth in 1974.
In response, Mr. Partee commented that the staff had said
a number of times that it would take a long period of slack in the
economy to have an enduring effect on price developments, chiefly
because sizable increases in wages tended to persist for a time and
the rate of advance in productivity slowed in a period of little
growth in output.

His own preference would be for the Committee

to aim at a moderate rate of economic growth--around 2 to 3 per
cent--for a protracted period.

It was highly important that

pressures not be increased in those industries that were already
operating at capacity.

In his view, therefore, the difference

between 3 per cent and 5 per cent growth in real output was large
in terms of the inflationary impact whereas the difference between
3 per cent and 1 per cent was relatively small.
was a threshhold that should not be crossed.

In effect, there

8/21/73

-38-

Mr. Sheehan remarked that growth of 1.2 per cent in real
GNP from the fourth quarter of 1973 to the fourth quarter of 1974
would be too low, that it was projected to result in an increase

in the unemployment rate from 4.9 per cent to 5.5 per cent over
the same period.

Although that was not a dramatic increase and a

rate over 5 per cent was not as worrisome as it had been some years
ago, because of structural changes in the economy, he would prefer
to aim for growth of 3 per cent in real GNP in 1974.

As far as

inflation was concerned, the Committee ought not to feel too respon
sible in view of the international developments that had contributed
to it.

He wondered what the rates of increase in the GNP deflator

and the consumer price index would be if foods and petroleum products
were removed.
Concerning capacity expansion in basic industries, Mr. Sheehan
agreed with Mr. Partee that it was getting started, but he observed
that it was a long-range development--extending, perhaps, over 2
to 5 years.

Construction of new plants in the cement and chemical

industries required a minimum of 2 years; in the steel industry,
where expansion was already under way, it took as much as 5 years.
Mr. Partee commented that removal of foods and petroleum
products from the price measures surely would lower their rates
of increase.

He would judge, however, that even after allowance

for special influences, the rate of inflation was on the order of

8/21/73

-39-

4 to 5 per cent.

Moreover, the rise in prices of nonfood commodi

ties, excluding the petroleum products, had accelerated sharply in
the first half of 1973, and the rise in service prices was showing
some tendency to accelerate.
Chairman Burns said he thought the rate of inflation after
allowance for special influences was at least 5 per cent.

Average

hourly compensation in the private nonfarm economy rose 7.4 per cent
in the year ending in June.

If growth in output slowed as projected,

the advance in productivity would be relatively low.

Assuming that

the advance in wage rates did not become even more rapid and that
profit margins were constant, he would estimate that the rate of
increase built into the consumer price index was 5 to 5-1/2 per
cent.

Reduction in the rate of inflation would require an environ

ment of tighter budgets and a relatively restrictive monetary
policy, and it would take time.

An attempt to deal with the problem

quickly would probably not be successful and could do permanent
damage to the economy.
Mr. Francis observed that in his judgment the recent weak
ness in retail sales and consumer spending was overemphasized.
If capital spending continued to expand as had been suggested, some
easing in consumer spending and residential construction would not
be an unfavorable development.
the near future.

He did not foresee a recession in

-40-

8/21/73

Mr. Mayo remarked that the figures the Chairman had cited
concerning the role of fiscal policy were very revealing.

Con

sidering the implications for Treasury borrowing, he would remind
Committee members that financing the deficit was facilitated in
1971-72 by acquisitions of Treasury securities by foreign monetary
authorities in association with the large outflows of funds from
the United States.

Projections of the U.S. payments balance

suggested that foreign monetary authorities were more likely to be
sellers than buyers of Treasury securities in the period ahead,
so that the Treasury would have more difficulty in financing
deficits of the size in prospect.
Mr. Daane, with reference to Mr. Sheehan's remarks, observed
that there was an expectational dimension to the current policy
Over the years he had

problem that had to be taken into account.

been with the System, there had been times when policy actions had
more of an impact on expectations in the short run than on the
course of economic activity over the longer run.

Perhaps Mr. Partee

would disagree, but he believed this was one of those times when
the Committee needed to be especially concerned about the impact
of its policy decisions on expectations.

While he did not think

that System policies could quickly slow the inflation, an overt
easing could intensify inflationary expectations.

8/21/73

-41-

Mr. Partee observed that the country was experiencing a
runaway inflation that was a source of widespread concern.

Any

thing that could be done to suggest that inflation would be brought
under control would be beneficial.

Of greater benefit than anything

else, perhaps, would be a halt to the rise in food prices.

Although

he could not say whether inflationary expectations of the public in
general would be affected much by the sorts of gradations in monetary
policy that the Committee contemplated, an apparent easing in policy
would have a significant impact on participants in financial markets
and on businessmen and bankers.

The unfavorable effect on attitudes

could spread and become an important factor in the economic situation.
Mr. Sheehan remarked that he would like to see growth in real
GNP from the fourth quarter of 1973 raised to about 3 per cent from
the 1.2 per cent projected by the staff, if that could be done with
out significantly affecting inflationary expectations.
Mr. Brimmer commented that in the late 1950's the Committee
had been deeply concerned about inflationary expectations and it
had pursued policies that were still a source of controversy.

One

view was that monetary policy had been too restrictive for too long

and thus had brought on the stagnation of the early 1960's.
Chairman Burns observed that there was another interpretation
of developments in that period which was just as partial as the first:
precisely because of the restrictive policies pursued in the late

8/21/73

-42-

1950's, the price level was stable from 1958 until mid-1965.

With

reference to Mr. Sheehan's remarks, he noted that in light of the
margins of error in projections of real GNP and the uncertainties
about the effects of policies, the two figures of 1.2 per cent and
3 per cent were not very far apart.

Given the choice between the

two, all other things being equal, he would prefer the higher
However, no one could say what policies would be needed

figure.

to achieve precisely 3 per cent.
Mr. Partee remarked that the staff projections for the
second half of 1974 were not very firm and that it would be better
to focus on the four quarters through the second quarter of next
year.

Growth of 2.3 per cent was projected for that period, and as

he had indicated, any deviation was likely to be on the high side.
Thus, growth might prove to be in the 3 to 3.5 per cent range.
Mr. Black noted that he shared Chairman Burns' view regard
ing the outlook for labor costs and prices.

Considering that the

cost-push element in the inflation was likely to continue, with or
without demand pull, he asked whether some kind of wage board was
likely to be created to deal with the problem after the end of
Phase IV.
The Chairman replied that such an approach to the problem
was likely to develop sooner or later.

However, he could not say

whether it would be early next year or in 1974 at all.

-43-

8/21/73

Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System
Open Market Account covering domestic open market operations for
the period July 17 through August 15, 1973, and a supplemental report
covering the period August 16 through 20, 1973.

Copies of both

reports have been placed in the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Holmes
made the following statement:
The period since the Committee last met was one of
frantic movement in the securities markets on both the down
and up sides as market expectations shifted wildly. It was
a period of near disaster for Treasury financing as the
bond offering in the August refunding failed and the
Treasury had to borrow directly from the Reserve Banks on
August 15. And it was a period in which the monetary
aggregates behaved in a widely disparate fashion, with
M1 for the July-August period coming in below the lower
limit of the Committee's range of tolerance and M2 and
RPDs coming in at or above the upper limit of their respec
tive ranges. Bank credit was very strong.
Interest rates rose sharply in all sectors of the
capital markets as market expectations shifted from a view
that interest rates would peak in late summer to a view
that the Federal Reserve really meant business and would
sustain and perhaps intensify its efforts to restrain
monetary expansion. As a result, we had one of the sharp
est rises in interest rates in history. Treasury bill rates
moved up by a full percentage point and yields on long-term
securities rose by 1/2 to 3/4 of a percentage point. Last
week a strong rally took place, with the market as near
to being disorderly on the up side as I can recall.
Illustrative of the wild gyrations in interest rates
over the period was the behavior of the two issues offered
in the Treasury's August refunding. The 4-year, 7-3/4 per
cent notes--reopened in the financing--were trading at
about a 7-3/8 per cent yield around the time of the last
Committee meeting. By the time of the auction on July 31,

8/21/73

-44-

when the issue was just barely covered in the auction,
the average issuing rate was set at 8 per cent. During
last Friday's frenetic trading the yield sank as low as
7-1/8 per cent; it then bounced back to just under 7-1/2
per cent; and today it is just about where it was when the
Committee last met. The 7-1/2 per cent bond seemed very
fairly priced at the time of the financing, and as you
know, that issue was only about half covered by public
subscriptions--with the price established in the Dutch
auction at 95.05, a yield of 8 per cent. On Friday, that
issue closed at about par, a 5-point premium over issue
price and a full 1/2 percentage point lower in yield.
Short-term interest rates, while subject to similar
gyrations, were generally substantially higher over the
period, spurred particularly by aggressive bank demand for
CD's to replace declining Treasury tax and loan accounts
and heavy short-term financing by the Home Loan Banks. In
yesterday's auction, average rates of 8.91 and 8.86 per cent
were established for three- and six-month Treasury bills, up
about 95 and 85 basis points from the auction just before
the last meeting.
Open market operations over the period were devoted
to a firm restraint on reserve availability, resulting in
an increase in the Federal funds rate to around the 10-1/2
per cent level. Early in the period, we were supplying
reserves to keep the funds rate from staying up above 11
per cent. Later in the period--when market factors,
particularly the decline in the Treasury's balance at the
Reserve Banks, were supplying reserves--the Desk had to
absorb reserves in considerable volume, setting volume
records on both the last two Wednesdays for outstanding
matched sale-purchase contracts. On August 3, as you know,
a majority of the Committee concurred in a recommendation
to increase the upper limit of the Federal funds rate to
11 per cent from 10-1/2 per cent. But with M1 apparently
growing at a rate well below the Committee's range of
tolerance and the securities markets in considerable dis
array, we have been trying to manage reserve availability
so as to produce a steady funds rate at around the 10-1/2
per cent level. Last Friday, I might add, the Federal
funds rate was the only rate in the market to display any
sort of stability.
As you can well imagine, this has been a hard period
for the Treasury. During the financing period, it felt
obliged to support its new issues with market purchases
by the Desk for trust accounts. All in all, we purchased

8/21/73

-45-

about $350 million in securities; trust accounts also had
to take down $240 million of the $500 million bond issue.

It was an amazing coincidence that the trust accounts
placed subscriptions for that exact amount in the auction
just before the 1:30 p.m. closing time. As a result of this
cash drain--and a tendency for cash receipts to fall short
of expectations--the Treasury has been short of cash and
on August 15 had to borrow $351 million from the Reserve
Banks. Fortunately, Congress had passed a temporary exten
sion of the authority for such borrowing.
The Treasury had been expecting a low point in cash
on September 6, but it had hoped that passage of the gold
bill, which would have permitted monetization of about
$1 billion of gold, would help it to squeeze through;
that hope never materialized. It appeared late last week
that in early September the Treasury could be running an
overdraft at the Reserve Banks of around $2 billion.
Consequently, the Treasury announced yesterday that it
would raise $2 billion in cash with the auction of a
September 30, 1975 note on Friday, August 24. This Treasury
decision, while it may have been painful, will be a major
help for open market operations since it will obviate the
need for substantial reserve absorption that would have
occurred had the Treasury been forced to borrow such an
amount from the System. Some borrowing may be necessary
in any case, but present cash projections suggest that it
should be quite moderate.
The sharp rally in the bond market last week had a
number of causes. First of all, the technical position
of the market, with dealers and many banks and institutional
investors having short positions, was highly conducive to
a rally in light of the large recent rise in interest rates
and the relatively light calendar in the corporate and muni
cipal markets. In addition, the good performance of the

dollar in the exchange market and better news on the
trade and payments deficit were generally encouraging. More
over, there was growing sentiment among some market participants
that the Federal Reserve had gotten the monetary aggregates
under control and that this would lead to stability, or
even a decline, in the Federal funds rate after the sharp
rise of recent weeks. And finally, on Friday there were
all sorts of rumors about an extremely large order received
by one or more New York banks to buy Government securities
with funds arising out of Middle East oil operations. By
yesterday, a somewhat better sense of balance had been achieved

-46-

8/21/73

after Friday's frenetic trading, and the announcement of
the Treasury's cash financing tended to cool things off
further; in fact virtually all of Friday's gains were lost.
The experience of the last 4 weeks demonstrates
how sensitive the markets have become under a prolonged
period of monetary restraint. You can be sure that the
market will be following the weekly M1 data with hawklike
intensity and watching the Federal funds rate minute by
minute for clues to the System's policy posture. I am
afraid that we will have to live with erratic markets
until the course of the economy and the outlook for infla
tion--which are of course the basic factors--become more
clear.
1/
indicates that under
Looking ahead, the blue book
alternative B the Federal funds rate might show some
decline from its current 10-1/2 per cent level, given the
forecasts of M1 in August-September. Even a minor decline
would almost certainly be interpreted in the market as a
shift in System posture, and it would be most helpful to
have the Committee's views on the importance it wants to
attach to the Federal funds rate in this sensitive period.
While growth in M1 for August-September is expected to be
very moderate, growth in M2 and the credit proxy is ex
pected to be far above the Committee's long-run targets
for the third and fourth quarters. In light of the dis
parate forecasts for the aggregates, it would be helpful
if Committee members indicated what weight they would
like to put on the individual series.
By unanimous vote, the open
market transactions in Government
securities, agency obligations,
and bankers' acceptances during

the period July 17 through August 20,
1973, were approved, ratified, and
confirmed.
Mr. Axilrod made the following statement on prospective

financial relationships:

1/ The report, "Monetary Aggregates and Money Market Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

8/21/73

-47-

The background material presented to the Committee
indicates that progress has been made in securing control
of growth in the narrowly defined money supply (M1). But
growth in the more broadly defined money supply (M2 ) has
been running above the Committee's range of tolerance,
and the bank credit proxy has been expanding faster than
expected.
M1 behavior is probably beginning to reflect the
cumulative impact of monetary restraint, but recently, as
explained in the blue book, the growth of M1 may also have
been dampened to some extent by one-time readjustments of
asset holdings by the public to the new regulations on
interest rates payable by banks and thrift institutions.
Thus, there may have been some shifts out of demand deposits
to time deposits at banks.
However--and perhaps more
importantly--there also seem to have been shifts from thrift
institutions to banks.
To help the Committee evaluate past and prospective
trends in money growth in a transition period involving
substantial shifts among money-like assets, we have included
projections of M3, along with M1 and M 2 , in the blue book.
The weak experience of the thrift institutions in late
July and early August will hold growth of M3 in August to
a rate below that for M2, and we estimate the gap at about
2-1/2 percentage points at an annual rate. As the public's
one-time stock adjustment wears off, we expect the gap to
close somewhat in September. This would be likely to reflect
both a more moderate growth in consumer-type time deposits
at banks and a somewhat more favorable experience for thrift
institutions.
A further point to keep in mind in evaluating this
complex of money supply measures is that M2 and M 3 now in
clude a growing amount of quite long-term certificates.
I am referring of course to the 4-year and over savings
certificates that are not subject to interest rate ceilings.
These certificates do have a money quality because the
principal is not subject to capital loss and is readily
obtainable. On the other hand, the holder has determined
that he is willing to make a 4-year or more commitment
and is subject to a substantial interest penalty for with
drawal before maturity. On these grounds, a movement of
demand deposits or savings deposit funds into the certifi
cates would reflect a reduction in liquidity in somewhat
the same sense as do movements out of cash into market
securities in a period of rising interest rates.

8/21/73

-48-

Certificates maturing in 4 years or more increased
by $1.3 billion at weekly reporting banks between mid-year
and August 8, and increased by about $1.4 billion at a
sample of savings and loan associations between mid-year and
July 31. Comparable information is not yet available for
nonweekly reporting banks and for mutual savings banks.
On the basis of a conservative extrapolation of this frag
mentary information, it looks as if the increase in these
certificates would contribute at the least 3 percentage
points, at an annual rate, to the 9 per cent rate in M
projected for August. It also appears that the long-term
certificates issued by both banks and thrift institutions
would contribute at least 4 percentage points to the slower
5-1/2 per cent rate in M3. In judging M2 and M 3 growth,
I would not subtract the whole 3 or 4 percentage points
because of the money-like qualities of the certificates,
but I would keep in mind that in both July and August
there is some considerable overstatement in both M2 and

M3.
While the precise relationship of longer-term time
certificates to money is debatable, both assuredly pro
vide a source of lendable funds to banks. The good experi
ence of banks with consumer-type time deposits and con
tinued aggressiveness in the large CD market are leading
to a very sharp expansion of the bank credit proxy in
August; in September growth in the proxy is expected to
be more moderate, though still very sizable.
There is no need for me to repeat the pro and con
arguments well known to Committee members with regard to
the role that might be assigned bank credit as a policy
guide in comparison with other monetary aggregates. I
would point out, though, that the current expansion in

bank credit is being accompanied by restraint in other
areas--in particular at nonbank savings institutions.
Any credit growth at thrift institutions to meet out
standing commitments in recent weeks would have been

based entirely on advances from the Home Loan Bank
System; and in consequence of stringent credit avail

ability, thrift institutions are reportedly cutting
back sharply on their mortgage commitments.
Under existing institutional circumstances, a sub
stantial cutback in the pace of bank credit expansion

8/21/73

-49-

in August-September would require sharply higher costs
of liabilities to banks--sufficiently high to stiffen
bank lending terms further and thereby discourage
borrowers, and sufficiently high to persuade banks to
cut back further on their participation in securities
markets. This would, of course, mean further advances
in market interest rates on a broad front.
On balance, the developments of the past few weeks
do not seem to me to have seriously reduced the role of
M1 as one important guide to policy, although they may
have at the same time brought other aggregates more
into prominence. The recent large-scale shifts in
financial flows have probably involved some movement
out of demand deposits, but I believe that for the most
part shifts have occurred among time and savings deposits
at banks and other institutions and between time and
savings deposits and market instruments. Thus, I would
argue that no substantial readjustment is needed in the
Committee's longer-run M1 path as a result of recent
financial experience. However, because higher time
deposit rates do lower the demand for M1 in some degree
and because recent experience is not inconsistent with
a view that the impact could have been underestimated,
a quite slow growth in M1--even one somewhat below
path--might be acceptable to the Committee for a few
months for this reason alone, provided that M 2 growth
does not also become unduly low.
While reasonable men may disagree on the weight
they wish to assign to the various M's or bank credit,
I believe most would agree that the latest figures do
reflect an uneven impact of monetary restraint on
institutions and types of borrowers. This is an almost
perennial problem that is not easily handled by open
market policy. At the moment, however, the Committee
may wish to consider its policy stance for the next few
weeks against the background both of large-scale shifts
in fund flows that have not fully worked themselves out
and of highly sensitive credit markets prone to large
interest rate swings. In particular, the Committee
may wish to consider modifications in the fairly wide
funds rate ranges shown in the blue book; specifically,
it may wish to consider narrowing the range while the
current institutional and market situation settles
down.

-50-

8/21/73

Mr. Black noted that--as had been reported--a substantial
portion of growth in thrift deposits recently was accounted
for by certificates with maturities of 4 years or more and that
staff projections in the blue book suggested that in the August

September period growth in M2 and in M 3 would be at higher rates
than that in M1.

At the same time, according to staff assumptions

in the green book, market interest rates would rise further in the
months ahead.

He wondered, therefore, whether disintermediation

might not become an increasing problem as banks and other insti
tutions approached the limit set on the issuance of the longer-term
certificates--or if an interest rate ceiling should be imposed on
them--and whether, consequently, the projected ranges of growth for
RPD's were not too high.

If over-all growth in time and savings

deposits at commercial banks proved to be lower than projected,
more of the reserves supplied would be available to support expan
sion in M1 at rates higher than those projected.
In reply, Mr. Axilrod observed that, arithmetically, if
the reserves were supplied and time and savings deposits did
not expand as much as projected, demand deposits would expand
more rapidly than projected.

However, that would not be the

actual result because the Committee specified a Federal funds rate
constraint as well as a range of tolerance for growth in RPD's.

Thus,

if time and savings deposits grew at rates much lower than projected,

-51-

8/21/73

the provision of the reserves would bring about a sharp decline
in interest rates--unless the demand for money were much stronger
than he thought it was.

In practice, reserve-supplying operations

would be constrained by the lower limit set for the funds rate, and
growth in RPD's would fall below the specified range.
Mr. Daane, noting that both Mr. Holmes and Mr. Axilrod had
commented on the sensitive state of the financial markets, asked whether
market participants were not assuming that the System had carried its
policy of restraint about as far as it would--although it might
maintain that restrictive posture--so that any overt policy move in
either direction would have a major impact on interest rates,
particularly long-term rates.
Mr. Holmes responded that some market participants had
thought last Friday that System policy was beginning to ease, but
developments on Monday disabused them of that idea, and at present
some market participants thought that the System would maintain its
current posture of restraint while others believed that the System
would tighten further.

In his view, market reactions to an overt

policy action would depend on what action was taken.

Considering

that over the past 4 weeks markets had adjusted to the substantial
rise that had occurred in the Federal funds rate, a small further
rise in the rate probably would not have a major impact on long
term rates.

However, a substantial increase in the funds rate--say,

to around 12 per cent--probably would have a major impact.

-52-

8/21/73

Mr. Brimmer asked what the Committee might do if it wished
to assure that growth in RPD's in the August-September period did

not exceed whatever range was adopted, as it frequently had.
In response, Mr. Holmes observed that in the past the
Committee had given the greatest weight to M

among its targets and

that RPD's had been the operating handle used in the pursuit of the
M1 target.

Therefore, when M1 had tended to move outside the speci

fied range of tolerance, he had given major weight to M1 in the
conduct of operations and had tended to ignore RPD's.

In the latter

part of the period since the last meeting, for example, the data had
indicated that M1 would grow at a rate below the range specified for
the July-August period, and operations had been influenced more by
that development than by indications that RPD's and M2 were growing
at rates above their ranges of tolerance.

If the Committee wished

to place greater emphasis on achieving a rate of growth in RPD's
within the specified range, he would not then look through RPD's
to M1 and the other aggregates.

In that event, however, operations

might very quickly run into the funds rate constraint.

With respect

to the recent period, the unsettled state of the securities markets
also had made him hesitant to push the funds rate all the way to the
upper end of the range.
Chairman Burns commented that the Committee's focus on M1
had been unfortunate in the most recent period because its meaning
had been altered by the changes that had been made in Regulation Q.

8/21/73

-53-

The Chairman then said that the Committee was ready for
its general discussion of monetary policy and the directive.
way of introduction, he would make two brief observations.

By
First,

the Board was considering the desirability of raising the marginal
reserve requirement on large-denomination CD's, and any views
the Presidents wished to express would be helpful to the Board in
reaching its decision.
Secondly, the Chairman continued, the Committee had to
recognize that its failure to bring the monetary aggregates under
control in recent months fundamentally resulted from a failure to
control RPD's; in most recent periods, RPD's had grown at rates
close to or above the specified ranges as the Desk had acted in
accordance with the Committee's over-all instructions and had
given more weight to M

than to RPD's and the other aggregates.

However, the meaning of the several targets of policy had changed
recently.

It was his view that for the next month or two, the

Committee would need to pay more attention to RPD's, bank credit,
and M 3 and less attention to M1.

Mr. Eastburn observed that he had come to the meeting
prepared to argue for a small increase in the longer-run target
for M1--which would place it between the targets specified under
alternatives A and B in the blue book--and there were some arguments
to be made for that course of action.

First, inflation was a

-54-

8/21/73

difficult and persistent problem requiring a considerable period
of time to overcome, and monetary policy could not be expected to
have quick and decisive effects.

Secondly, the projections sug

gested that the economy would move very close to an actual recession,
even though the expected rates of inflation had been raised.

And

finally, experience indicated that not only were there lags in the
effects of monetary policy, there were delays in recognizing turning
points in economic activity and in taking appropriate policy actions.
However, the reports presented by Messrs. Partee and Reynolds
inclined him to favor the longer-run target of alternative Bwhich was consistent with a rate of growth in M1 of 5-1/4 per
cent from the March level estimated at the time of the March
meeting.
Continuing, Mr. Eastburn remarked that there were dangers
of severe effects in the credit markets in the short run if the
Committee attempted to get back onto that longer-term growth path
too rapidly.

He would hope to avoid major increases in interest

rates, and he would not attempt to get back on the path by the end
of the year if doing so entailed such increases in rates.

Achieving

the longer-run targets without excessive effects on the money markets
would require a great deal of agility and discretion on the part
of the Manager.

-55-

8/21/73

Concerning the marginal reserve requirement, Mr. Eastburn
said he thought an increase would help banks in rationing credit.
From conversations with bankers, he had the impression that the
larger banks found it difficult to ration credit, particularly
when they had commitments to good customers.

As an approach to

additional restraint, the marginal reserve requirement was more
like a rifle than a shotgun and was appropriate to the current
situation.
Mr. Hayes said the problem of formulating appropriate
monetary policy had been getting more complex in recent weeks
because of increasing evidence of possible weakening in the
current boom and also because of the risk that the lagged effect
of the very sharp rise in interest rates could be an excessive
slowing of money growth.

Those considerations suggested to him

that the Committee should be cautious about further tightening
moves, recognizing that it had already established a posture of
rather severe restraint.

However, he hastened to add that in his

judgment it was even more important that the System avoid any move
that might suggest it was backing away from its firmly restric
tive policy.

The most important goal was still to contribute to

cooling the overheated economy, given a record of excessive credit
demands and too rapid money growth over a considerable period of

months.

The improvement in the dollar's international position,

-56-

8/21/73

which was certainly encouraging, could be rapidly eroded if the
inflation were to continue unchecked, and a firm interest rate
structure in itself was, of course, a real help.
Mr. Hayes observed that it looked as if the System was
beginning to make progress in slowing the growth of the monetary
aggregates--or at least M1 --but it was well worth maintaining the
present degree of restraint until the improvement had clearly
persisted for 2 or 3 months.

Certainly, bank credit continued

to expand rapidly, and it demanded close attention.

For that

reason, he found it hard to try to set a meaningful 2-month range
of tolerance for M1, since he would be willing to see the rate
drop to zero or even to a negative number for a month before delib
erately moving to drop back from a Federal funds level of around
10-1/2 per cent.

Thus, for the period between now and the next

meeting he could see a very strong case for a directive couched in
terms of continuing to restrain reserve availability in such a way
as to keep money market conditions about where they were, perhaps
with a proviso that unexpectedly rapid growth of the aggregates
might justify slightly firmer conditions.

To reflect that approach,

he proposed that the operational paragraph of the directive say,
"To implement this policy, the Committee seeks to restrain the
growth of bank reserves and to maintain the firm money market

8/21/73

-57-

conditions achieved in the preceding interval in the expectation
that this will result in a significantly slower growth in the
monetary aggregates than has occurred thus far this year."
With respect to specifications for the aggregates,

Mr. Hayes

favored the longer-run targets and the short-run ranges of tolerance
shown under alternative B. For the funds rate, he preferred the 10
per cent lower limit shown under alternative C but would not set
the upper limit as high as 12-1/2 per cent.
Mr. Hayes remarked that the directors of the New York Bank
probably would have voted for a 1 percentage point increase in the
discount rate, instead of 1/2 of a point, had it not been for the
extremely sensitive state of the market following the Treasury's
disappointing refunding operation.

Although market conditions had

improved greatly in the past week or so, he was inclined to think
that it was still too soon to raise the discount rate another
notch to 8 per cent.

However, such a move--as well as an increase

in marginal reserve requirements on certificates of depositmight well become desirable in the next few weeks if the aggregates
should appear to be getting out of control again on the upside.

An

increase in the reserve requirement might be desirable in any case,
and as he had indicated in a letter to the Board, he would suggest
that any increase be accompanied by a modification in the base.

-58-

8/21/73

Mr. Coldwell observed that conversations with both bankers
and borrowers in recent weeks had convinced him that increases
in interest rates had not yet been effective in restraining expan
sion in business loans; probably because of inflationary expecta
tions and rising costs, businesses continued to be willing to
borrow.

In addition, there was a disturbing report that some busi

ness borrowers were engaging in interest rate arbitrage--borrowing
at one bank and depositing the funds at another.

The availability

of bank credit was still relatively high, and as he had said in a
recent letter to Chairman Burns, he was concerned about the avail
ability of credit and about growth in RPD's at rates in excess of
the ranges of tolerance specified by the Committee.
With respect to the policy decision, Mr. Coldwell said he
would virtually ignore M1 , which had become subject to a number
of difficulties of interpretation, and would concentrate on
achieving a reduction in the rate of growth in RPD's.

To reflect

that objective, he would have the operational paragraph of the
directive say, "...the Committee seeks to achieve bank reserves
and money market conditions consistent with a significantly
slower rate of growth in RPD's than has occurred on average thus
far this year."

He could accept Mr. Hayes' formulation of the

operational paragraph, but if the Committee wished to concentrate
its efforts on an RPD target, it would be desirable to say that
in the directive.

-59-

8/21/73

Mr. Coldwell remarked that an increase in the marginal reserve
requirement on large-denomination CD's would be accepcable, assuming
that it was intended to lead to a reduction in the availability
of bank credit and would not be offset by open market operations.
As he had indicated, higher interest rates had not been effective
in discouraging borrowing and reducing inflationary pressures, and
it was necessary to limit the availability of bank credit.
Mr. Bucher noted that at the preceding meeting he had
expressed his concern about the danger of overreacting to the
current economic situation with monetary tools that would have their
major impact in a future period about which there was considerable
uncertainty.

Strong arguments could be made both for strength

and for weakne:s in the ec .omy in the period ahead.

However, he

was influenced by the staff projections, which caused him to be
concerned about a slowing in economic growth into next year.

In

similar periods in the past, it seemed to him, the Federal Reserve
had overreacted
the economy.

and its actions had led to undesirable shocks in

His concern was reinforced by current problems in some

segments of the credit market and the resulting effect on housing
in particular.
Continuing, Mr. Bucher observed that the effects of the
degree of restraint already achieved were not yet known.

As

Mr. Holmes had said, the rise in interest rates that had occurred

-60-

8/21/73

in the period since the last meeting was one of the sharpest on
record.

Treasury bill rates, commercial paper, and large

denomination CD's had risen 100, 115, and 125 basis points,
respectively.

Consequently, he would want to hold the current

position, being sure that the market understood that the System
was not easing.

Although a difficult task, it could be done, and

the Committee might assist the Desk in the effort by narrowing
somewhat the range for the Federal funds rate.
Concerning the aggregates, Mr. Bucher said he still had
a fair amount of confidence in M

as a target of policy; current

problems of interpretation were transitory.

There were reasons

to pay attention to additional aggregates, especially M3, but he
would not discard M1.

Like Mr. Eastburn, he would tolerate a

temporary departure of M1 growth from the longer-term path of
5-1/4 per cent in order to avoid increases in the Federal funds
rate and in interest rates generally of a sort that would be harmful
in the longer run.
Mr. Francis remarked that the boom was continuing and
that a slowing in growth was to be expected when capacity limits
were reached; real GNP could not continue to grow at annual rates
of 6 and 8 per cent.

Following such high rates, a falling off

in growth to a rate of 2 or 3 per cent could hardly be characterized
as a recession.

-61-

8/21/73

Concerning policy, Mr. Francis said he favored the general
outlines of alternative B.

He would continue to place primary

emphasis on M1 among the aggregates.

Since the last meeting, a

great deal had been accomplished in slowing growth in the aggre
gates, and he would interpret alternative B as continuing that
progress.

If the alternative B projections of M1 for the rest of

1973 were realized, growth from December 1972 to December 1973
would be 4.9 per cent; from the average in the fourth quarter of
1972 to the average in the fourth quarter of 1973, growth would be
5.6 per cent--only slightly above the longer-run target of 5-1/4
per cent--and that rate was acceptable in view of the danger of
overkill.

He continued to believe that the Committee could dispense

with the specification of a range for the Federal funds rate.

In

any event, he would not favor a range any lower or any narrower
than that of alternative B.

With respect to the marginal reserve

requirement on large-denomination CD's, there was no need for an

increase if the Committee accomplished its goal of limiting growth
in the monetary aggregates.
Mr. Holland observed that on the basis of his review of
the economic and financial situation he believed that the current
position of monetary policy was just about as it should be to make
what constructive contribution it could to an orderly cooling of the
economy.

With respect to the operation of monetary restraint in the

-62-

8/21/73

current period, he differed somewhat with Mr. Coldwell; it was both
inevitable and desirable to think in terms of monetary restraint
being executed to a greater degree than in the past through interest
rates and to a lesser degree through nonprice restraints.

The way

the financial system was evolving made such a program inevitable,
and having put its hand to that plow, the System would be wise to
try to avoid looking backward.

Continuing, Mr. Holland remarked that the greater emphasis
on interest rates was a little better tailored to deal with the
current kind of inflation problem.

A fairly long period would be

required to try to bring price increases down within an acceptable
range, and a policy that worked more through interest rates could
be held and adjusted better over a longer period of time than
could a policy that relied more on nonprice restraints.

By their

nature, the latter tended to have a kind of stop-go effect.
Moreover, the review of the economic situation today suggested
that business inventories and plant and equipment were the principal
spending categories that could be favorably influenced by the appli
cation of more monetary restraint.

Therefore, if the System wished

to move toward more restraint, he would prefer to use an increase
in the marginal reserve requirements on large-denomination CD's
than the more general policy instruments.

The impact on interest

rates generally might be somewhat less, and in addition, there
would be some structural effects.

-63-

8/21/73

Mr. Holland noted that there were analytical problems
currently arising from stock adjustments affecting rates of growth
in the various monetary aggregates, but the nature--although not
the degree--of the shifts among the various forms of deposits had
been foreseen.

That suggested that the disturbance was temporary

and that for a time projections of the aggregates would be subject
to wider-than-usual margins of error.

In the circumstances, he

would continue to use the Committee's existing framework for formu
lating policy and would adjust it to reflect the analytical problems
and the concerns of the moment.

Starting with alternative B, which

he generally favored, he would add M3 to the longer-run targets,
not only because of the shifts taking place among the various types
of deposits but also because the System ought to be concerned about
changes in flows into the savings and loan associations and the
mutual savings banks.

Although deposits at those institutions were

not subject to the System's reserve requirements, they were as
relevant for monetary policy as were time and savings deposits at

nonmember commercial banks.

The greater-than-usual uncertainty

about the projections could be dealt with by widening the 2-month

ranges of tolerance for M1 and M2.

He could accept a range for M1

that stretched from the low end of alternative C to the upper end
of alternative A and a range for M2 from the bottom of alternative
C up to about 10 per cent.

Thus, the ranges for M1 and M2 would be

8/21/73

-64-

1-1/2 to 4-1/2 per cent and 7 to 10 per cent, respectively.

He

would retain a narrower range for RPD's and would narrow the range
for the Federal funds rate, specifying a range of 10 to 11 per
cent. The wider ranges for M1 and M2 would help the Committee

to deal with shifts taking place in deposit flows while the
narrower range for the funds rate would guard against giving any
undesired signals to the market.

In the circumstances, the Manager

might need to consult with the Chairman and some form of communi
cation with the Committee might be required before the next meeting.
He fully expected that Committee members would be willing to author
ize a movement of the funds rate above or below the narrow range
in the event that the evidence becoming available suggested either
course.

Mr. Daane remarked that at this juncture he was more con
cerned about the System's posture showing through to the market,
because of its impact on expectations, than about trying to choose
specifications for the aggregates.

The specifications probably

could not be achieved in any case. At the last meeting, he had
been unhappy despite his agreement with the restrictive stance
of the policy adopted because of the emphasis placed on M1 and
the effort to use it as a guide to operations; he had had a strong
desire to play down M1 and to lay stress on bank reserves and
money market and credit conditions in order to give the Manager

-65-

8/21/73

the latitude to hold back on the provision of reserves.
he held that position even more strongly.

Now,

He could accept Mr. Hayes'

proposal for the language of the operational paragraph of the
directive, although he would add a reference to international develop
ments and might suggest some minor modifications.

Altogether, he

would direct operations toward holding steady and letting the market
know that the System was maintaining a restrictive posture.
Mr. Mayo remarked that Messrs. Daane and Holland had ex
pressed some of his views, which he might characterize as "don't

rock the boat."

He would retain the longer-term target for M

the Committee had adopted.

that

He favored alternative B, except that he

would retain the existing 9 to 11 per cent range for the Federal funds
rate.

Such a policy stance would let the market know that the System was

allowing adjustments to occur without attempting to tighten further.
With respect to the aggregates, he would go somewhat further than
Mr. Holland had and would specify a short-run range of tolerance
for M 1 of 1 to 5 per cent.

Although he agreed with the Chairman's

comments concerning M1, financial reporters and market interpreters
were so focused on that aggregate that the Committee could not influ
ence them by saying that it would give somewhat more emphasis to
RPD's and less to M1.

With respect to the language of the opera

tional paragraph of the directive, he would not incorporate a
reference to RPD's; the broader reference to monetary aggregates

-66-

8/21/73

encompassed M 3 , about which the Committee was concerned.

Like

Mr. Daane, he would restore the reference to international develop
ments.

Moreover, he would restore the reference to domestic

financial market developments because the economy might be closer
to a turning point than could be foreseen.
The Committee agreed that the operational paragraph of the
directive should contain references to international developments
and domestic financial market developments.
Continuing, Mr. Mayo said he had mixed feelings about an
increase in the marginal reserve requirement on large-denomination
CD's, although he would prefer that to a further rise in the funds
rate.

An increase in the reserve requirement would have adverse

effects on the desirability of membership in the System.

Moreover,

it was not consistent with his basic policy position of allowing
market adjustments to occur without tightening further.

The markets

were still in the process of adjusting to the tightening actions
that had been taken, and he would expect--barring a drastic change
in psychology--that the prime rate would go to 10 per cent by the
time of the September meeting of the Committee; a discount rate of
8 per cent would not be out of line.

Like Mr. Hayes, he did not

believe an increase in the discount rate was needed in the next
week or two, but he regarded it as an inevitable part of the adjust
ment taking place.

That view was held by bankers and by participants

-67-

8/21/73

in financial markets abroad.

While the dollar had strengthened, it

was still subject to sinking spells and was not yet back to what he
would regard as its true value.
Mr. Balles observed that in terms of trying to steer a
proper course between Scylla and Charybdis it was important that
Committee members' views on the outlook be clear.

His own expecta

tion was that there would be no more than a temporary slowdown in
growth later this year and into early 1974 rather than a fullblown
recession.

Given that expectation, he was particularly concerned

about the growth of inflationary expectations, which were widely
evident.

For example, in a lead article in the Wall Street Journal

for the day before, entitled "Many Economists Think Government Gives
Up On Fighting Inflation," it was said that "The Federal Government
obviously doesn't want to see the economy suffer either a recession
or more inflation.

If there is a choice, however, federal officials

lean heavily toward more inflation.

That, at any rate, is the

assessment of many private economists as they watch developments in
Washington."

Inflationary expectations were growing, and their

effect on business and consumer behavior had not yet been fully
assessed.

In the months ahead, one could expect to hear the sort

of references--familiar in business circles a few years ago--to
looking across the valley of a brief downturn in economic activity.
In his view, a growing belief in persistent inflationary pressures

-68-

8/21/73

in the years ahead would strengthen business spending for fixed
capital and have other similar effects.

Given those attitudes about

inflation and those expectations concerning Government policies,
the System needed to be cautious about giving any intentional or
accidental signals to the market that monetary restraint was being
relaxed.
Mr. Balles commented that not very much progress had been
made in slowing growth in the aggregates; although

it had slowed

for M1, it remained in excess of targets for the other aggregates.
Apparently the latter would continue to grow at rapid rates in the
third and fourth quarters, and the slowdown in M1 growth was likely
to be transitory.

In the circumstances, he favored alternative B,

but he would point out that it was not so restrictive as it might
appear to be.

Growth rates based on quarterly averages rather than

terminal months gave a different and more meaningful impression of
prospective developments in the second half of the year.

Thus, the

expected rate of growth in M1 from June to December was 3.75 per
cent, but the rate from the second quarter to the fourth quarter was
5.5 per cent, which was close to the longer-run target of 5.25
per cent.

Noting that the blue book contained a very helpful

appendix showing growth rates for M1 based on quarterly averages,
he expressed the hope that in the future the staff would include
similar calculations for the other aggregates.

-69-

8/21/73

Mr. Balles commented that it seemed to him that the lack of
success in bringing the aggregates under control stemmed from setting

a range for the funds rate that was too narrow, and therefore,
differing with Mr. Holland, he would retain the 2 percentage point

range for the rate. Because of the danger of giving a false signal
to the market, however, he would be very cautious about approaching
the lower limit of the range.

Concerning what was sometimes referred

to as the great experiment of placing greater reliance on the price
mechanism and less on nonprice measures to ration credit, he supported
Mr. Holland's view.

That had been a useful step, and he would not

like to see the System back away from it.
Mr. Morris said he agreed with the view that it would be
premature to make monetary policy on the assumption that a recession
would occur in 1974.

However, the rate of growth had slowed--as

had been forecast on the basis of a decline in housing starts and
a slowing of the expansion in consumption expenditures--and it would
be imprudent to take any steps toward a more restrictive policy.
Believing that the current degree of restraint should be maintained,
he favored alternative B, although like some others, he would con
tinue the upper limit for the Federal funds rate at 11 per cent.
Hopefully, pursuit of the alternative B targets for the aggregates
would be accompanied by some downward drift in the funds rate, as
suggested in the blue book, but should the aggregates grow faster

-70-

8/21/73

than projected, he would support an increase in the upper limit to
11-1/2 per cent.

With respect to the marginal reserve requirement

on large-denomination CD's, he would favor an increase.

Although

it appeared that the high level of interest rates was not inhibiting
demands for funds, the high marginal cost of funds was inhibiting
bankers in seeking out loans, and a further increase in the marginal
cost would be desirable.

He would not raise the requirement on

Euro-dollar borrowings.
Mr. Morris observed that he agreed with Mr. Holland's view
that the Committee should pay more attention to M 3 in the months
ahead.

Because of the structure of policy in the current period,

monetary restraint tended to affect the thrift institutions promptly,
whereas in 1969 restraint tended to affect commercial banks first.
Mr. Kimbrel remarked that inflationary expectations remained
a serious problem; shortages of labor and materials were interfering
with various kinds of projects in the Atlanta District; and develop
ments in foreign exchange markets continued to be a source of concern.
Nevertheless, there was a danger of excessive monetary restraint,
particularly as it might be reflected in high interest rates.

He

had come to the meeting prepared to back away cautiously from the
degree of restraint that had been achieved, if for no other reason
than that so many restrictive measures had been taken since April.
In the period ahead, he would focus somewhat less on M1 and more on

-71-

8/21/73

RPD's and the Federal funds rate, with specifications in line

with those of alternative B.

Hopefully, the funds rate would not

need to rise above 11 per cent and might actually ease from the
current level.

Concerning the marginal reserve requirement for the

large-denomination CD's, he would favor an increase.
Mr. MacLaury said he was somewhat less sure than a month
or two earlier that the economy was moving quickly into a period
of no real growth, although, like Mr. Partee, he saw a recession
developing at some stage.

However, even the rates of growth in

real GNP projected in the green book were undesirably slow, and
the present degree of monetary restraint--as reflected in the interest
rates over which the System had some direct control--bordered on
being excessive.

That was especially so in light of recent revisions

in rates of M1 growth projected for the July-August period.

Accord

ingly, he would not have concurred in the inter-meeting increase
in the upper limit of the range for the funds rate and was glad
that, for whatever reason, the additional 1/2 percentage point of
the range had not been used.

As had been said many times, monetary

policy could not do the whole job, and it was appropriate to repeat
that at present because of the behavior of basic commodity prices;
a strongly restrictive monetary policy could not have as much impact
on the general level of prices as Committee members might wish.

At

the same time, he would not want to give a signal of overt easing.

-72-

8/21/73

For those reasons, Mr. MacLaury continued, he favored
alternative A.

However, he would widen the 2-month ranges for the

aggregates by reducing the lower limits.

He would not mind slow

growth in M1 and, like Mr. Mayo, could accept a range of 1 to 5 per
cent.

Because of his view that the System should not be seen to

be easing, he would set the lower limit for the funds rate at 9-1/2
per cent.

For the upper limit, a return to 10-1/2 per cent could

be justified on the grounds that the additional 1/2 point leeway
that had been approved since the last meeting had not been used.
He

Thus, the range would be narrowed to 9-1/2 to 10-1/2 per cent.
would not increase the marginal reserve requirement on large

denomination CD's because it would be interpreted as another overt
move toward restraint, but like Mr. Holland, he would prefer an increase
in the reserve requirement to a further rise in the funds rate.
Mr. MacLaury remarked, with respect to interpretation of the
aggregates, that he did not agree that M2 and bank credit had become
more important.

On the contrary, they might be misleading because

of the process of re-intermediation that was occurring as a result
of the increases in interest rates on time deposits.

In his view,

the rate of growth in M2 reflected shifts from time deposits at the
thrift institutions to time deposits at commercial banks rather than
shifts out of demand deposits, so that the observed slowing in M1
growth was real.

On the basis of the levels to which short-term

-73-

8/21/73

interest rates had risen, he would have expected the slowing in
M1 and did not discount it. Closer attention than heretofore to
the rate of growth of M 3 was desirable, but he would not lessen
the emphasis on M1.
Mr. Brimmer observed that the key policy issue was whether
or not to provide an environment in which inflationary pressures
would be dampened somewhat even though that would be accompanied
by higher levels of unused resources than would otherwise prevail.
Noting Mr. Balles' remark that many people believed that the Govern
ment had given up the fight against inflation, he suggested that
policy-makers faced with the choice between more or less inflation
and more or less unemployment were inclined to accept a little more
inflation.

As Mr. Partee had suggested, moreover, demands and

economic activity were likely to be stronger in late 1973 and early
1974 than indicated in the green book. Within the context of over
all stabilization policy, therefore, the System ought to hold the
present degree of restraint--leaning, if necessary, in the direction
of a little more restraint.

In one sense, the current level of

interest rates was not particularly high, and the role of interest
rates in the present environment was very different from that in
1969-70.

He favored an increase in the marginal reserve requirement

on large-denomination CD's in order to shift the focus of policy a
little, with the hope that it would have some sectoral impact.

-74-

8/21/73

Mr. Brimmer said he would put more emphasis on dampening

growth in RPD's and would pay less attention to M1 . The range for
the Federal funds rate would have to be wide enough to lessen the
risk of continued overshoots in RPD growth, and he favored the range
of 9-1/2 to 11-1/2 per cent specified in alternative B. He also
preferred the aggregate targets of alternative B. He would not favor
Mr. Hayes' language for the operational paragraph because the change
from the language the Committee had been using would suggest that
it was innovating with respect to policy as well.
Mr. Brimmer remarked that Committee members should be
cautious about the weight they attached to M2 and

M3

because of the

removal of Regulation Q ceilings on consumer-type time deposits
having maturities of 4 years or more and because of other regulatory
changes.

With respect to M3, he would follow its behavior along

with that of other variables, but it would not be appropriate to
attempt to use general credit and monetary policy to attempt to
affect the behavior of deposits at the savings and loan associations.
To do that would require specialized instruments.
Mr. Winn commented that any change in System policy was
likely to have a considerable impact on psychology, which would be
undesirable.

In view of the uncertainties about the course of

economic activity in the period ahead, a steady policy was appro
priate, and he favored alternative B. Considering that some observers

-75-

8/21/73

watched RPD's as an indicator of System policy, it was desirable
to limit its rate of growth.
Mr. Winn observed--with reference to the reserve requirement
on large-denomination CD's--that in the latest month banks in the
Cleveland District had not increased the outstanding amount of CD's
but had turned to other sources of funds.

They had borrowed more

in the Euro-dollar and Federal funds markets and had used sale
repurchase agreements on their securities to a greater extent than
normally.
Mr. Sheehan noted that the staff's projections suggested
that the rate of growth in real GNP would diminish for the next
five quarters

through the third quarter of 1974.

Considering that

monetary policy operated with a lag, he would associate himself with
other members of the Committee who had said that policy was restric
tive enough, and he would maintain the current degree of restraint.
He was glad the Desk had not used the additional leeway of 1/2 per
centage point in the upper end of the funds rate range approved dur
ing the inter-meeting period, and like Mr. MacLaury, he would set the
upper limit at 10-1/2 per cent for the period until the next meeting.
Mr. Black observed that the first order of business was to
demonstrate to the market that the System had achieved and would
maintain control over the aggregates.

While sharing the feeling that

the significance of M1 among the aggregates had changed, he agreed

-76-

8/21/73

with Mr. Mayo that the market was not aware of the change.

For the

next couple of months, therefore, it would be desirable to publish
rates of growth for M1 of around 2 or 3 per cent; that would have
constructive effects on domestic financial markets and the foreign

exchanges and also on business psychology in general.

He would

retain the Committee's longer-run targets for the aggregatesadding M3 to the list, as Mr. Holland had suggested.

He favored

alternative B as the best way to achieve those targets.

However,

the lower limit for the August-September range for RPD's should be
reduced from that indicated in alternative B in order to allow for
the possibility that time and savings deposits at banks would grow
less rapidly than projected, possibly tending to bring about a
decline in the funds rate.

For the period until the next meeting,

he would not object if the System concentrated on maintaining the
funds rate at about the level of recent weeks.

He would not increase

the reserve requirement on the large-denomination CD's.
Mr. Clay said inflationary pressures were strong and there
was little evidence to suggest a significant slowing in real growth
in the period ahead.

Policy should be formulated with care in order

to avoid either aggravating inflationary pressures or bringing about
a serious slowing in growth.

The longer-run targets adopted at the

preceding meeting were about right.

In the August-September period,

however, it appeared that growth in M1 would be low while growth in

-77-

8/21/73

M2 and RPD's would be high relative to the longer-run targets.

A

range of 9-1/2 to 11-1/2 per cent for the Federal funds rate appeared
appropriate.

Altogether, he favored alternative B.

Because he would

avoid any additional overt move of restraint at present, he would
not raise the reserve requirement on CD's.
Chairman Burns observed that the Committee had had a full
discussion.

The conclusion that emerged--and he believed it was

the correct one--was that over the next few weeks the System should
seek to maintain about the existing degree of monetary restraint and
should avoid any relaxing or liberalizing moves.

The Chairman then sug

gested that the members indicate informally whether they favored the
language that Mr. Hayes

had proposed for the operational paragraph

of the directive.
In the subsequent poll, three members expressed a preference
for that language.

Chairman Burns then proposed for consideration an operational
paragraph that would place slightly greater emphasis on RPD's.
would read as follows:

It

"To implement this policy, while taking

account of international and domestic financial market developments

and the forthcoming Treasury financing, the Committee seeks to limit
RPD growth and achieve money market conditions consistent with slower
growth in monetary aggregates over the months immediately ahead than

has occurred on average thus far this year."
After discussion of the appropriate placement of the refer
ence to RPD growth, an informal poll indicated that a majority of the

-78-

8/21/73

members favored such an operational paragraph, but that a larger
majority preferred the language of alternative B as amended to
incorporate references to international and domestic financial
market developments.
The Chairman then suggested that the Committee retain the
longer-run target for M1 agreed upon at the last meeting--namely, an
annual rate of growth of 3-3/4 per cent over the third and fourth
quarters combined--and that it accept the associated longer-run
targets for M2 and the credit proxy indicated under alternative B in
the blue book.

He suggested an informal poll to determine whether

Committee members wished to include M3 among the longer-run targets.
The poll indicated that a majority of the members did not
favor including M3 among the targets.

It was agreed, however, that

information on M3 should be included in the next blue book in the
section dealing with prospective developments.
Chairman Burns suggested short-run operating ranges--that is,
annual rates of growth for the August-September period--of 11 to 15
per cent for RPD's and 1 to 4 per cent for M1.

The upper ends of the

ranges were those of alternative B; the lower ends had been reduced
by 2 percentage points for RPD's and one point for M1. The range of
tolerance in the daily-average funds rate for statement weeks in the
period until the next meeting would be 10 to 11 per cent, which was
narrower than the alternative B range of 9-1/2 to 11-1/2 per cent.
The staff would supply an operating range for M2 that would be con
sistent with the other specifications.

-79-

8/21/73

Mr. Francis remarked that he liked all of the suggested
specifications except the range for the Federal funds rate, which

was too narrow.

He did not understand the reason for narrowing

the range, especially since in recent inter-meeting periods the

upper limit had been increased whenever the rate pressed against it.
In response, Chairman Burns said a moderately narrow range
for the funds rate seemed to be consistent with the preferences of
Committee members at present, although they might wish to change
the range before the next meeting. A narrow range was necessary
to maintain about the existing posture of monetary restraint, as it
would be interpreted in the market.

A decline in the funds rate to

9-1/2 per cent would be interpreted by the market as a major shift
in policy, and it was clear that Committee members believed such a
reaction would be undesirable.

He noted also that he had suggested

reducing the lower limit for the 2-month range for RPD's from that
shown under alternative B in order to lower the central value of the

range.

In his judgment the Desk should try to avoid a rate of growth

in RPD's in the upper half of the range.
Mr. Daane observed that the suggested range of 11 to 15
per cent for RPD's, when compared with the range of 11-1/2 to 13-1/2
per cent adopted at the preceding meeting, did not appear consistent
with the emphasis that the Chairman and other Committee members had
given to slowing the rate of growth in reserves.

-80-

8/21/73

The Chairman suggested that members indicate informally

whether reducing the RPD range to 11 to 13 per cent would be
acceptable.
In the subsequent poll, a majority of the members indicated

that the range of 11 to 13 per cent for RPD's was acceptable.
The Chairman then proposed that the Committee vote on a
directive consisting of the staff's draft of the general paragraphs

and alternative B of the operational paragraph amended to include
the references to international and domestic financial market develop
ments--on the understanding that it would be interpreted in accordance
with the following specifications.

The longer-run targets--that is,

the annual rates of growth over the third and fourth quarters combinedwould be taken as 3-3/4 per cent for M1, 6-1/2 per cent for M2, and
9-3/4 per cent for the credit proxy. The short-run operating rangesthat is, annual rates of growth for the August-September periodwould be taken as 11 to 13 per cent for RPD's, 1 to 4 per cent for
M1, and 6-3/4 to 9-3/4 per cent for M2. The range of tolerance in
the daily-average Federal funds rate for statement weeks in the
period until the next meeting would be 10 to 11 per cent.
With Mr. Francis dissenting,
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
was authorized and directed, until
otherwise directed by the Committee,
to execute transactions for the
System Account in accordance with
the following domestic policy directive:

-81-

8/21/73

The information reviewed at this meeting suggests that
growth in real output of goods and services, which slowed
in the second quarter from the exceptionally rapid pace of
the two preceding quarters, will be moderate in the third
quarter. Increases in nonfarm employment also have slowed
in recent months, but the unemployment rate has declined.
The rate of rise in wage rates has remained relatively
moderate. The exceptionally rapid advance in prices was
interrupted in July by the temporary freeze imposed in
mid-June. However, farm and food prices adjusted sharply
upward after mid-July, when the freeze was lifted on most
such products. The U.S. merchandise trade balance improved
in June, and the balance on goods and services was in sur
plus in the second quarter for the first time in nearly
two years. Since the end of July the dollar has strengthened
markedly in foreign exchange markets, and the price of gold
has dropped sharply.
Both the narrowly and more broadly defined money stock,
which had increased rapidly in May and June, grew more
slowly in July. Inflows of consumer-type time and savings
deposits strengthened again at banks in late July and early
August, while net outflows were experienced at nonbank
thrift institutions. Expansion in bank credit has continued
at a substantial pace. Since mid-July short-term market

interest rates have advanced considerably further on bal
ance. Long-term rates also rose substantially for much
of that period, but most recently they have declined in the
course of a sharp market rally. On August 13 increases
were announced in Federal Reserve discount rates from 7

to 7-1/2 per cent.
In light of the foregoing developments, it is the
policy of the Federal Open Market Committee to foster
financial conditions conducive to abatement of inflationary
pressures, a sustainable rate of advance in economic acti

vity, and progress toward equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.
To implement this policy, while taking account of
international and domestic financial market developments
and the forthcoming Treasury financing, the Committee
seeks to achieve bank reserve and money market conditions
consistent with slower growth in monetary aggregates over
the months immediately ahead than has occurred on average
thus far this year.

8/21/73

-82
Mr. Francis indicated that he favored the targets for the

aggregates being adopted by the Committee.

He had dissented,

however, because he could not accept the narrow range of tolerance
for the Federal funds rate included among the specifications.
Secretary's note: The specifications agreed
upon by the Committee, in the form distri
buted following the meeting, are appended to
this memorandum as Attachment B.
It was agreed that the next meeting of the Committee would
be held on September 18, 1973, at 9:30 a.m.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

ATTACHMENT A
August 20, 1973
Drafts of Domestic Policy Directive for Consideration by the
Federal Open Market Committee at its Meeting on August 21. 1973
GENERAL PARAGRAPHS
The information reviewed at this meeting suggests that
growth in real output of goods and services, which slowed in the
second quarter from the exceptionally rapid pace of the two pre
ceding quarters, will be moderate in the third quarter. Increases
in nonfarm employment also have slowed in recent months, but the
unemployment rate has declined. The rate of rise in wage rates has
remained relatively moderate. The exceptionally rapid advance in
prices was interrupted in July by the temporary freeze imposed in
mid-June. However, farm and food prices adjusted sharply upward
after mid-July, when the freeze was lifted on most such products.
The U.S. merchandise trade balance improved in June, and the
balance on goods and services was in surplus in the second quarter
for the first time in nearly two years. Since the end of July
the dollar has strengthened markedly in foreign exchange markets,
and the price of gold has dropped sharply.
Both the narrowly and more broadly defined money stock,
which had increased rapidly in May and June, grew more slowly in
July. Inflows of consumer-type time and savings deposits strength
ened again at banks in late July and early August, while net outflows
were experienced at nonbank thrift institutions. Expansion in bank
credit has continued at a substantial pace. Since mid-July short
term market interest rates have advanced considerably further on
balance. Long-term rates also rose substantially for much of that
period, but most recently they have declined in the course of a
sharp market rally. On August 13 increases were announced in
Federal Reserve discount rates from 7 to 7-1/2 per cent.
In light of the foregoing developments, it is the policy of
the Federal Open Market Committee to foster financial conditions
conducive to abatement of inflationary pressures, a sustainable
rate of advance in economic activity, and progress toward equili
brium in the country's balance of payments.

OPERATIONAL PARAGRAPHS

Alternative A
To implement this policy, while taking account of the
forthcoming Treasury financing, the Committee seeks to achieve
bank reserve and money market conditions consistent with somewhat
slower growth in monetary aggregates over the months immediately
ahead than has occurred on average thus far this year.
Alternative B

To implement this policy, while taking account of the
forthcoming
reserve and
in monetary
occurred on

Treasury financing, the Committee seeks to achieve bank
money market conditions consistent with slower growth
aggregates over the months immediately ahead than has
average thus far this year.

Alternative C
To implement this policy, while taking account of domestic
financial market developments and the forthcoming Treasury financing,
the Committee seeks to achieve bank reserve and money market condi
tions consistent with significantly slower growth in monetary
aggregates over the months immediately ahead than has occurred on
average thus far this year.

ATTACHMENT B

August 21, 1973
Points for FOMC guidance to Manager
in implementation of directive

A.

Specifications
(As agreed, 8/21/73

Longer-run targets (SAAR):
(third and fourth quarters combined)

3-3/4%

6-1/2%
Proxy
B.

9-3/4%

Short-run operating constraints:
1.

2.

Range of tolerance for RPD growth
rate (Aug.-Sept. average):
Ranges of tolerance for monetary
aggregates (Aug.-Sept. average):

11 to 13%

1 to 4%
6-3/4 to 9

3.

4.
5.

C,

Range of tolerance for Federal funds
rate (daily average in statement
weeks between meetings):

10 to 11%

Federal funds rate to be moved in an
orderly way within range of toleration
Other considerations:
account to be taken of international and
domestic financial market developments and of forthcoming Treasury
financing.

If it appears that the Committee's various operating constraints are
proving to be significantly inconsistent in the period between meeting
the Manager is promptly to notify the Chairman, who will then promptly
decide whether the situation calls for special Committee action to
give supplementary instructions.