View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in
the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
in Washington, D.C.,
PRESENT:

on Tuesday, August 13, 1968, at 9:30 a.m.

Martin, Chairman
Brimmer
Daane
Galusha
Hickman
Kimbrel
Maisel
Mitchell
Robertson
Sherrill
Bopp, Alternate
Treiber, Alternate for Mr. Hayes
Messrs. Clay, Coldwell, and Scanlon, Alternate
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Heflin, Francis, and Swan, Presidents
of the Federal Reserve Banks of Richmond,

St. Louis, and San Francisco, respectively
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Sherman, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Kenyon, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Broida, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Molony, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Brill, Economist
Messrs. Hersey, Link, Mann, Partee, Solomon,
and Taylor, Associate Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market
Account
Mr. Cardon, Assistant to the Board of
Governors
Mr. Farrell, Director, Division of Federal
Reserve Bank Operations, Board of
Governors 1/

1/

Entered the meeting at the point indicated.

8/13/68
Mr. Wernick, Associate Adviser, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Messrs. Keir and Weiner, Assistant Advisers,
Division of Research and Statistics,
Board of Governors
Mr. Bernard, Special Assistant, Office of
the Secretary, Board of Governors
Miss Eaton, Open Market Secretariat Assistant,
Office of the Secretary, Board of
Governors
Mr. Latham, First Vice President, Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston
Messrs. Eisenmenger, MacLaury, Baughman,
Jones, Tow, and Craven, Vice Presidents
of the Federal Reserve Banks of Boston,
New York, Chicago, St. Louis, Kansas
City, and San Francisco, respectively
Messrs. Meek and Snellings, Assistant Vice
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of New York and Richmond, respectively
Mr. Shotwell, Senior Economist, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Mr. Stahl, Research Officer and Economist,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Mr. Duprey, Economist, Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis
Mr. Fraser, Financial Economist, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas
By unanimous vote, the minutes
of actions taken at the meeting of
the Federal Open Market Committee
held on July 16, 1968, were approved.
The memorandum of discussion
for the meeting of the Federal Open
Market Committee held on July 16,
1968, was accepted.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of the
System Open Market Account on foreign exchange market conditions

-3

8/13/68

and on Open Market Account and Treasury operations in foreign
currencies for the period July 16 through August 7, 1968, and a
supplemental report covering the period August 8 through 12, 1968.
Copies of these reports have been placed in the files of the
Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. MacLaury
said that the Treasury gold stock would again be unchanged this
week at $10.367 billion.

It had now been two and one-half months

since the Treasury had had to announce any decline--thanks mainly,
of course, to the sales of gold by France to the United States.
Sales to the U.S. so far had amounted to nearly $300 million, or
slightly less than half of France's total sales of about $650
million.

Purchases by other countries of gold from the U.S. had

continued, with about $75 million pending at the moment.

However,

since the Stabilization Fund still had nearly $280 million on hand,
a need for a reduction in the Treasury gold stock in the near

future was not apparent.
Mr. MacLaury remarked that he could not recall a period in
the recent past in which the gold and exchange markets had been as

free from tension as the month since the previous meeting of the
Committee.

That was not to say that a good deal had not been going

on, mainly in the exchange markets; but the activity had been more
or less neutral, or, as in the case of sterling until today, even
bullish in its impact on market psychology.

-4

8/13/68

In the London gold market, Mr. MacLaury continued, the
price had held in a very narrow range around $39 since the last
Committee meeting, with the exception of a brief period around the
middle of July.

At that time a number of rumors, particularly

concerning agreement among central bankers not to buy South
African production until market prices moved close to the official
$35 price, unnerved the speculators and caused the price to drop
as low as $37.75.

Subsequent verbal exchanges--in what the market

considered to be a war of nerves between the U.S. authorities and
South Africa on the question of market gold sales--had had very
little effect, on balance, on either trading or price.

In general,

although it was clear to the market that the final chapter of that
dialogue had not yet been written, the net result for the time
being at least was a feeling of greater stability for the two-price
gold system than would have seemed possible a few months ago.
Mr. MacLaury observed that July was a very active month
for sterling.

As the Committee would recall, at the beginning of

the month the Bank of England had had to borrow $500 million under
its swap line with the Federal Reserve, after having cleared up
that line with the proceeds of an International Monetary Fund draw
ing and U.S. purchases of guaranteed sterling only a few weeks
earlier.

A combination of factors, including the announcements of

actual or potential credit lines for the Bank of France and for

-5

8/13/68

sterling balances, and particularly the improved U.K. trade
figures for June announced at mid-month, brought relief from the
extreme pessimism which had pervaded the markets during the early
part of July.

That improved atmosphere gathered a momentum of its

own and produced market purchases of sterling during the latter
half of July that enabled the Bank of England to pick up more than
$500 million, more than offsetting the losses of early July.

As a

result, despite net repayments of $50 million of short-term central
bank assistance, another $50 million in scheduled repayments, and
a sizable amount of forward maturities, the Bank of England had
been able to announce a reserve gain in July of just over $50 mil
lion.

Although until today the sterling exchange rate had held

near the peak of $2.3950 reached at the end of July, actual demand
for sterling since the beginning of August had tapered off, and
with it, acquisitions of dollars by the Bank of England.

On

balance during the period, however, the Bank of England had been
able to reduce its indebtedness under the Federal Reserve swap
line by $200 million,
moment.

leaving $300 million outstanding at the

Clearly one could not expect sterling to continue as

strong as it

was in late July.

Much would now depend upon the

reaction to the trade figures for July that had been announced
today.

The figures were not good; imports increased substantially

after declining in June, and although exports also rose somewhat

-6

8/13/68
the trade gap widened.

Under the initial impact of that announce

ment the sterling rate dropped 15 points, from $2.3940 to $2.3925,
but at the moment there was no particular pressure on sterling
In any case, the Bank of England had sizable commitments to meet
this month before it could show any reserve gains.

These included

not only the usual forward maturities, but the first instalmentamounting to about $85 million--on Britain's 1965 drawing from the
IMF, and some scheduled European Payments Union debt repayments.
At the moment, Mr. MacLaury said, the most worrisome factor
in the exchange markets was the persistent loss of dollars by the
Bank of France.

As the Committee knew, the Bank of France had now

borrowed a total of $250 million under its swap line with the
Federal Reserve.

In addition, it had borrowed $170 million under

its lines with continental European central banks.

Since the crisis

had broken out in mid-May, French reserves had declined by more
than $2.5 billion; and the pace of losses in the last three weeks
had remained above $100 million per week.

French trade figures

for July, announced yesterday, showed a surplus in contrast to the
deficit for the preceding month, and the franc was off the floor
today.

On balance, the market remained highly uncertain about

prospects for the franc over the coming year.

In his opinion,

developments with respect to the French franc posed the greatest

-7

8/13/68

potential threat to the stability of the international monetary
system in coming months.
With respect to the Swiss franc, Mr. MacLaury commented,
the demand pressures that had built up prior to the end of July
were largely attributable to a tight internal money market.
result, nevertheless,

The

was that the Swiss National Bank ended up

with $150 million which it asked the System to cover by swap draw
ings totaling $145 million.

Thus,

the period in which the System

had been completely free of indebtedness under the swap network
was all too brief.
On the other hand, Mr. MacLaury observed, the continued
existence of an extremely liquid banking system in Germany had
facilitated continued capital outflows from that country and, in
fact, had depressed the mark to its lowest level since the 1961
revaluation.

Under those circumstances, the Account Management

had been acquiring mark balances for both System and Treasury
account, and last week a $50 million equivalent mark-denominated
Treasury bond had been paid off in advance of maturity.
Mr. MacLaury then said he would report briefly on a few
other matters.

The first related to the $200 million of guaranteed

sterling that the System had warehoused for the Stabilization Fund
in mid-June,

at the time of the repayment by the British of their

drawings on the swap line with the System.

It had subsequently

-8

8/13/68

become clear that the Stabilization Fund had sufficient resources
to meet its exchange commitments for the time being, and it had
therefore agreed to reacquire the warehoused sterling.

Secondly,

while he had no specific information on the progress of the British
negotiations with sterling area countries with respect to the pro
posed sterling balance arrangements, he had the impression that
Bank of England officials thought there were grounds for some
moderate degree of optimism. Also, the Bank for International
Settlements had called a meeting of central bank technicians for
August 20 to review the arrangements; it had been agreed earlier
that such a meeting would be held only if the British were making
some progress in their current talks.
His final observation, Mr. MacLaury said, related to the
System's $225 million swap arrangement with the National Bank of
Belgium. As the Committee knew, that arrangement was unique in
the network in that, at the wish of the Belgian authorities, a $50
million portion had always been fully drawn.

He could report that

in September the $50 million portion would be paid off and the full
$225 million line put on the same basis as all of the other
arrangements in the network.
By unanimous vote, the System
open market transactions in foreign
currencies during the period July 16
through August 12, 1968, were approved,
ratified, and confirmed.

8/13/68
Mr. MacLaury noted that a number of drawings by other
central banks on the Federal Reserve would soon be approaching the
end of their first three-month terms.

They were drawings of $100

million by the Bank of France, maturing September 5, 1968; of $25
million by the National Bank of Denmark, maturing September 6; and
of $24.9 million and $29.8 million by the Netherlands Bank, matur
ing September 6 and 19, respectively.

He recommended renewal of

each of those drawings, if requested by the central bank concerned.
Renewal of the drawings by the
Bank of France, the National Bank
of Denmark, and the Netherlands
Bank was noted without objection.
Mr. MacLaury then noted that $18 million of System forward
commitments in Swiss francs, originally undertaken in December 1967
and March 1968,
1968.

would mature in

the period August 19 to August 26,

It had been possible to repay the $14 million of Swiss franc

forwards that had matured in July, and Swiss National Bank officials
thought the chances were good that the forwards maturing this
month could also be repaid.

In the event that their repayment was

not feasible, however, he would recommend renewal.
Renewal of the System's forward
commitments in Swiss francs was
noted without objection.
Chairman Martin noted that Messrs. Brimmer and Daane
recently had attended meetings of the Economic Policy Committee

8/13/68

-10

and of Working Party 3, respectively, of the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development.

He invited them to comment.

Mr. Brimmer said that at the EPC meeting, which was held
in late July, attitudes toward the U.S. economic situation had been
as favorable as at any such meeting he had attended in the last
few years.

There was a general willingness to accept the prospect

that the U.S. economy would cool off this year, although the
Germans, and to some extent the Dutch, seemed to doubt that the
slowdown would begin immediately.

Some of the delegates expected

the planned cuts in Federal spending to be offset in one way or
another.

The group hoped that the U.S. monetary authorities would

act cautiously and not move too far too soon in reducing monetary
restraint.

At the same time, they agreed in general that other

countries would have to modify their economic policies in response
to the expected slowing of the U.S. economy.

However, some

countries would have administrative difficulties in doing so;
problems were posed for the Germans, for example, by the calendar
for their Government budget.
The main focus of the discussion, Mr. Brimmer continued,
was on France.

The hope was expressed that France would be able

to adjust to the higher costs inherent in the wage settlements
following the May-June disturbances by expanding output rather
than by passing on the higher costs in the form of higher prices.

-11

8/13/68

The group was critical of the trade restraints France had imposed
recently.

Somewhat surprisingly, France's partners in the Common

Market were as critical of those restraints as other countries were.
Mr. Daane remarked that at the WP-3 meeting, held shortly
after the EPC meeting, there was a lively discussion of the world
adjustment process over the next two or three years on the assump
tion that the payments balance of the United States would move to
equilibrium and that of the United Kingdom to surplus.

The question

arose as to whether early activation of the Special Drawing Rights
scheme would not be required to permit the adjustment process to
work out under the circumstances assumed.

The French representatives

remained aloof for the most part, expressing the view that the
discussion was academic since the assumptions were unrealistic.
They thought there would be no adjustment problem unless the United
States over-shot the mark in moving toward equilibrium, and they
were highly skeptical of the ability of the U.S. to get close to
balance in the period in question.
The matter was left for further consideration at the next
meeting of WP-3, scheduled for a date just preceding the Bank and
Fund meetings, Mr. Daane said.

The main significance of the dis

cussion was that it might have signaled the beginning of a drift
toward sentiment for early activation of SDR's.

In that connection,

it now appeared that by year-end the number of countries that would

-12-

8/13/68

have ratified the amendment to the Fund's Articles of Agreement
would be very close to the number required.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System
Open Market Account covering domestic open market operations for
the period July 16 through August 7, 1968, and a supplemental
report covering August 8 through 12,

1968.

Copies of both reports

have been placed in the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Holmes
commented as follows:
The period since the Committee last met has
demonstrated once again the pervasive effects that a
shift in market expectations can have on interest rates
Interest rates in all
and money and credit flows.
maturity areas moved sharply lower as market participants
became increasingly convinced that the fiscal restraint
package would succeed in cooling off the economy, thereby
reducing demand pressures in financial markets, and that,
as a consequence, monetary restraint would be relaxed
over the coming months. In this atmosphere the market
paid close attention to the cut in the repurchase agree
ment rate to 5-1/2 per cent on July 17 and to market
letter and press comment on the likely decline in
economic growth and on an early shift towards a somewhat
easier monetary policy. Most market participants appear
to have operated on the assumption that a cut to 5 per
cent in the discount rate would be forthcoming shortly
after the Treasury financing was completed. This
assumption has come to be increasingly questioned in the
past few days, and interest rates have retraced a portion
of their earlier declines.
In this atmosphere the Treasury's offerings of a
$5.1 billion 6-year note issue--priced to yield 5.70 per
cent--was very well received, with allotments on large
subscriptions amounting to 18 per cent. In addition to

8/13/68

-13-

refunding $3.6 billion August 15 maturities held by the
public, the Treasury was able--with an overallotment--to
raise nearly $1.9 billion in new money. This should be
sufficient to meet Treasury cash needs until late
October. Over the rest of the calendar year the Treasury
needs about $5-1/2 billion, and it is likely that the
bulk of that need will be met through the auction of tax
anticipation bills--which implies minimal even keel
considerations. Despite the size of the Treasury
offering--the largest of its kind in over 20 years--prices
of outstanding Treasury coupon issues rose sharply on
balance, reducing yields on intermediate-term Treasury
notes and bonds by 1/4 of a percentage point and yields
on longer-term issues by 1/8 of a percentage point. Given
the attractive pricing of the new issue, a fair amount
of speculative interest was attracted, but it does not
appear to have been excessive. In secondary market
trading the new issue quickly moved to a premium which
ranged at one point to as high as 3/8 of a point. In
the past few days, as expectations began to shift, the
premium fell back to about 1/8 of a point at the close
of business yesterday.
In both the corporate and municipal narkets, prices
also rose sharply, lowering yields by 1/4 of a percentage
point or more over the period. Continuing growth of bank
interest was an important factor in the municipal market,
and despite lower yield levels there is as yet little
indication that corporations are rushing to the market
as they did in early 1967.
Short-term interest rates, spurred by the absence
of an anchor issue in the August financing, showed even
more dramatic declines. The 3-month Treasury bill
declined by over 1/2 of a percentage point to as low as
4.86 per cent, although it bounced back to about the 5.00
per cent level over the past week. CD rates were lowered
by as much as 3/8 of a percentage point, with only the
shortest dated maturities still being issued at Q ceiling
rates. Rates on bankers' acceptances and on commercial
paper were also reduced.
Along with the decline in interest rates, bank credit
expanded much more rapidly than had been anticipated as
securities dealers turned to the banks to finance their
swollen inventories, as bank investment portfolios
increased, and as bank CD's became more competitive with
In July the credit proxy rose
other market instruments.

8/13/68

-14-

at a 9 per cent annual rate, compared with the 1 to 4
per cent range projected at the last meeting; the
inclusion of Euro-dollars would bring the increase to 11
per cent. For August a 16 to 18 per cent growth rate is
currently projected, mainly reflecting the impact of the
Treasury's financing operations. Thus the growth in the
proxy for July-August combined is 5 to 6 percentage
points above the rate anticipated at the last meeting.
While, as the blue book 1/ suggests, this may well be a
one-shot expansion, based on the desire of dealers and
banks to catch the turn of the tide in interest rates,
it is still a disturbingly high rate of increase.
As the pattern of bank credit expansion became
increasingly apparent, open market operations became less
accommodative. With interest rates declining more rapidly
than had been expected and with strong investor interest
in the Treasury financing, firmer conditions were allowed
to develop in the money market as called for in the
proviso clause of the directive. While a large volume
of reserves had to be supplied on balance over the
period, they were supplied somewhat reluctantly and only
after some pressure had been felt in the Federal funds
market. Thus, the Federal funds rate, net borrowed
reserves, and member bank borrowings were all a shade
higher than had been considered desirable at the time of
the last meeting--desirable, that is, in the absence of
the bulge in bank credit that actually developed. The
degree of tautness that was permitted to develop in the
money market was not enough to choke off the bank credit
expansion. To have attempted to do so--in the face of
expectations--would have required a very tight money
market indeed and would have been completely inconsist
ent with even keel considerations.
The main consequence of the relatively taut day-to
day money market conditions that were permitted to
develop has been to open a wide gap between dealer and
other investor financing costs and the sharply lower
level of interest rates on market instruments. Dealers
obviously cannot for long finance Treasury bills yielding
around 5 per cent with borrowing costs at 6-3/8 per cent.
Thus, unless market expectations about a change in the
discount rate are fulfilled in the next few weeks,

1/ The Report, "Money Market and Reserve Relationships,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

-15-

8/13/68

interest rates are likely to back up. There can be little
doubt that the weight of expectations pushed interest
rates too low too fast.
Some correction may be needed,
and in fact the bill
rate has moved up considerably from
the low point reached a week or so ago.
In yesterday's
Treasury bill auction, for example, average rates of
5.08 and 5.27 per cent were established for 3- and 6
month Treasury bills, 18 and 17 basis points above last
week's auction, although still 40 and 28 basis points
below the auction just preceding the last
meeting of the
Committee.
There is a risk, however, that the market may--as
it usually does--push a rate reaction too far. Given
the size of dealer and other investor inventories, the
market is vulnerable to any basic change in expectations
that some easing of monetary policy is likely to occur
in the near future.
It thus appears that the period
ahead could see a head-on conflict between the Committee's
desires with respect to interest rates and its desires
with respect to bank credit expansion. More than ever
it would appear important for the Committee to establish
I
priorities as between these two sets of variables.
should also note that while the staff's draft directives 1 /
make no mention of even keel, I would assume that the
Committee would want the status of the Treasury's
financing to exert some marginal influence on open market
operations for the next week or so.
Mr. Mitchell asked Mr. Holmes if the dealers were becoming
restive in

view of the speculative positions

they had built

up.

He also inquired whether in the Manager's judgment the size of
their inventories should be a matter of concern for the Committee
and if there was any information available about the size of bank
speculative positions.
Mr.

Holmes replied that in

had become increasingly restive

1/

the past few days the dealers

about the level of their inventories,

Appended to this memorandum as Attachment A.

-16

8/13/68

which they had built up to more than $5-1/2 billion.

If the

dealers attempted to unload their inventories, they would encounter
considerable difficulties under prevailing market circumstances and
might trigger a substantial market reaction.

Such a reaction

would tend to start with short-term rates and might well extend to
longer-term rates.

The dealers would also incur losses in

the

process, although--given the substantial profits they had made in
recent months--they appeared to be in a good position to absorb
such losses.
Mr. Holmes added that he did not have any reliable
information about the size of bank speculative positions.

Banks

recently had been increasing their holdings of both U.S. Government
and State and local government securities.

In the case of

Governments, such acquisitions were partly related to recent
Treasury financing activity.
In response to another question by Mr. Mitchell, Mr. Holmes
expressed the view that implementation of a "no change" directive
might induce speculative holders to attempt to reduce their
inventories.
Mr. Daane asked what the Manager's judgment would be
concerning the impact of a reduction in the discount rate under
current market circumstances.

In particular, he (Mr. Daane)

wondered if such a reduction would tend to generate market

-17

8/13/68

expectations which would carry interest rates down much further
than anyone would like, of if it would tend to stabilize markets
by encouraging dealers not to rush to liquidate their inventories.
Mr. Holmes replied that it was always difficult to judge
the effect on expectations of any System action.

A week or so ago

he would have thought a reduction in the discount rate would have
increased market expectations of still easier credit conditions,
but now that expectations had chilled and rates had turned up, a
discount rate cut could tend to stabilize rates or perhaps reduce
them somewhat from current levels.

Even if rates stabilized,

dealers might still be inclined to reduce their inventories.
Mr. Daane asked whether the Manager saw any risk that the
System would have to supply more reserves to the market in order
to validate a reduction in the discount rate.
Mr. Holmes said he thought the contrary might well be true.
There was a technical problem at the moment relating to the
discrepancy between market rates and dealer borrowing costs, which
in turn bore a close relationship to the Federal funds rate.

A

reduction in the discount rate should result in a lower Federal
funds rate and in lower borrowing costs.

If the Committee wanted

to resist a rise in market rates, a reduction in the discount rate
might help to accomplish that objective with a smaller provision
of reserves than would be required if

reliance were placed only on

-18

8/13/68
open market operations.

However, one could not be sure about such

judgments.
Mr. Hickman inquired whether the Manager thought that the
size of a discount rate reduction would make a difference with
respect to the amount of reserves that might need to be supplied.
For example, it was possible that a 1/4 point cut in the discount
rate would minimize expectations of a further cut--with the results
Mr. Holmes had just outlined--and that a 1/2 per cent reduction
would generate expectations of still easier credit conditions,
thereby leading to a further build up in speculative positions and
a greater increase in reserves and bank credit.
Mr. Holmes said that it was difficult to predict the
market's reaction to a particular cut in the discount rate.

Whether

or not a reduction was regarded as the first in a series would
depend not only on its size but also on press commentaries and
attendant market circumstances.
Mr. Brimmer said he was interested in the Manager's
observation in his report that the System might have to choose
between a rate objective and a reserve objective.

However, the

Manager had also implied that use of the discount rate instrument
might help the System to achieve its reserve objectives more
comfortably by inducing speculative holders to reduce their
positions, thereby helping to moderate the growth in bank credit.

-19

8/13/68
Mr.

Holmes noted that while a cut in the discount rate

could create the technical conditions that would facilitate an
orderly liquidation of positions, it was possible that dealers
might choose instead to build up their inventories further if

they

viewed the action as the first in a series.
Mr. Brimmer asked Mr. Holmes if he was assuming any
particular date for a reduction in the discount rate in his remarks
about the possible impact of such a reduction.
whether,

in

He also asked

the absence of a discount rate cut, Mr. Holmes thought

the present level of interest rates could be held for the next two
or three weeks without having to supply a substantially larger
amount of reserves than otherwise.
In response to the first question Mr. Holmes said he had
no particular date in mind for a discount rate cut.

On the second

question, he could not speak with certainty, but he felt that there
was a risk that upward rate pressures would be substantial enough
to require a large provision of reserves.
Mr. Brimmer said he would be interested in hearing the
views of other Committee members concerning the appropriate time
to reduce the discount rate.

He had formed the impression that

the Treasury financing would not pose a serious obstacle to a rate
reduction toward the end of this week.

His own preference at the

moment would be to change the rate earlier rather than later and
by 1/4 point rather than 1/2 point.

A 1/2 point reduction might

-20

8/13/68

be helpful, but a 1/4 point cut would seem preferable in

terms of

both reserve objectives and interest rate objectives.
Mr. Hickman expressed the view that a discount rate change
in the current week might be somewhat premature and would provide
the speculators who had

bought the new note in the Treasury financ

ing with an undeserved windfall.

He did not think the Directors

of the Cleveland Reserve Bank would be willing to act in the current
week, although they might be prepared to establish a 5-1/4 per cent
discount rate in the following week.
In response to other questions, Mr. Holmes said that if
the Desk were instructed to maintain current money market conditions
without resisting possible rises in interest rates, dealers would
probably make strong efforts to reduce their inventories in the
face of continued high financing costs.

It was likely that buyers

would tend to back away, however, and the result could be a slower
run-down of dealer inventories than in a more receptive market
situation.

It was also likely that banks would attempt to reduce

their speculative holdings of securities and, in fact, some selling
by banks was reported yesterday.

Earlier, the market had been

anticipating an early 1/2 point reduction in the discount rate,
but in recent days market participants had become convinced that
it was no accident that the Federal funds rate had remained above
6 per cent.

-21-

8/13/68

By unanimous vote, the open
market transactions in Government
securities, agency obligations, and
bankers' acceptances during the
period July 16 through August 12,
1968, were approved, ratified, and
confirmed.
The Chairman then called for the staff economic and
financial reports, supplementing the written reports that had been
distributed prior to the meeting, copies of which have been placed
in the files of the Committee.
Mr. Brill made the following statement on economic conditions:
1/
will undoubtedly
Faithful readers of the green book
note that the staff has clung to the rather pessimistic
views on the outlook expressed a month earlier. We are
still
expecting a significant slowdown in over-all activity
that will bring real growth practically to a halt this
fall.
A legitimate question can be raised as to whether
the economic information that has become available since
the last meeting of the Committee supports or denies
this outlook. Unfortunately, there is not enough
information on which to base an adequate assessment, and
what is available constitutes a rather mixed bag. On
the one hand, the advance retail sales data for July are
definitely much stronger than would be consistent with
the staff outlook. Apparently, consumers went on a buying
binge in July, not just for autos but also for the long
neglected nondurable goods. We had allowed, in our
projections, for some initial adjustment in savings rates
to higher taxes, an adjustment in which consumers
maintained buying plans by reducing the proportion of
income saved. But our projection for the quarter did
not allow for anything like the surge in spending that
the sales figures for July suggest.
I can't explain it, any more than I have been able
to explain the quixotic behavior of consumers over the
It will be recalled that
past two and a half years.

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

8/13/68

-22-

1966 was marked by wide gyrations in consumer spending,
with consumption expenditures rising at a 9 per cent
annual rate in the first quarter, dropping to a 3 per
cent growth rate in the second quarter, rising 7 per
cent in the third quarter, and then falling back to 4
per cent in the traumatic fourth quarter.
Growth in
consumption was more stable, although slower, throughout
1967, but 1968 seemed to start off with a resumption of
the see-saw pattern of 1966. An extraordinary surge in
spending in the first quarter was followed by a sharp
drop-off in the second.
Does the resurgence of sales in July mark a return
to a full quarter of upswing? I hesitate to make a
prediction for so volatile a series, but I do think that
the odds are against it, at least to the extent that
current flows of income influence spending decisions.
We are likely to be in for a period of sharply reduced
rates of gain in disposable income. Here the July
evidence does supply some support. The employment
statistics for July reflect some further modest easing
in labor market pressures.
This shows up most clearly
in the teenage group, where unemployment rates for both
June and July were high and where in July large with
drawals from the labor force were symptomatic of
diminishing job opportunities. Weakening in labor demand
is also reflected in the very moderate employment growth
in manufacturing in July, after allowing for the delay
in model change-over in the auto industry, and for the
last push in steel production before the settlement.
The growth in jobs is beginning to lag significantly
behind the growth in the labor force, and even with
further withdrawals from the labor market and with
possible reductions in the workweek, the unemployment
rate should creep up over the months ahead.
Steel inventory liquidation for the next several
months will be a major factor exerting a drag on
employment, output, and incomes. In some previous post
settlement periods--most noticeable in 1965--developments
in steel were swamped by other expansive forces in the
economy. For example, the sharp acceleration in defense
orders during the summer and fall of 1965 and the
continued rise in business capital outlays far outweighed
the contraction in steel output. That doesn't seem to
be in prospect this year, however, barring a turn for
the worse in peace negotiations or an outbreak of

8/13/68

-23-

hostilities elsewhere. Indeed, our best guess at the
moment is for a leveling-off in Federal spending in the
third and fourth quarters, now that the initial impact
of the pay raise is behind us.
It seems more plausible, then, to expect that the
steel cut-back already in process will be reflected
fully in the aggregate figures on output, employment,
inventories, and income over the balance of the year.
In the absence of exogenous boosts, such as the increases
in social security benefits, minimum wages, and Federal
pay earlier in the year, and with higher taxes being
withheld from pay checks, the current flow of after-tax
incomes should be operating as an increasing restraint
on consumers in the months ahead. These are the factors
underlying our projection of only a moderate growth in
consumption expenditures this quarter and next. Whether
consumers behave as logically as the staff forecasts
remains to be seen.
Turning to another element of the staff's projec
tions--prices--the July data appear to be consistent
with the earlier staff outlook for some moderating in
the pace of inflation.
Industrial commodity prices
advanced only slightly, and the diffusion of price
increases was much smaller than earlier in the year.
But the steel price increase--even after the partial
roll-back effected by the Administration--could alone
speed up the industrial price rise and threatens price
stability over a wide range of industrial and consumer
goods. Most steel users will be liquidating, rather
than adding, to inventories for several months. But
higher steel prices will undoubtedly be used as one
basis for increases in the prices of many products.
Whether the increases are large, and whether they become
pervasive and stick, depends largely on the pace of
activity in the economy as a whole. We're still betting
that the forces tending to contract aggregate demand
will be strong enough to counteract the continuing
upward pressures on prices, as they did between the
summer of 1966 and the spring of 1967.
In another area of activity--housing--our projection
of sluggish activity over coming quarters appears to have
received some additional indirect confirmation in July.
Figures for the full month show a disappointing experience
for thrift institution inflows relative to underlying needs
for funds. The apparent success of mutual savings banks
and savings and loan associations in attracting and

-24-

8/13/68

retaining funds over the dividend- and interest-credit
ing period faded as the month progressed. This lack
luster performance of savings flows, coupled with the
reports obtained by Reserve Bank and Home Loan Bank
staffs in the recent survey of mortgage lenders'
experience and attitudes, do not suggest a rapid rebound
in housing activity over the balance of this year.
Indeed, unless a resurgence in savings inflows dispels
lender uncertainties or substantial changes in the yields
on competitive long-term investments make mortgages much
more attractive, we may see only a sluggish recovery in
housing starts even in early 1969.
This about exhausts the fragmentary information
available on recent economic developments. I haven't
dwelled on the production index--the index was up another
half point in July--since production developments
paralleled closely those in employment.
While this scattering of evidence isn't conclusive,
the apparent conflict of trends is not unusual in an
economy shifting gears. On balance, the changes that
occurred in over-all financial conditions in early
August seem to have been appropriate to the emerging
nonfinancial situation. Much of the recent easing in
financial conditions appeared to rest, however, on a
shift in market expectations both as to the economic
outlook and as to the course of monetary policy.
Persisting tautness in financial markets threatens to
reverse these expectations, and to return credit market
conditions to a degree of tightness inconsistent with
the degree of fiscal restraint that is now a fact,
rather than a hope. It would be unfortunate if such a
reversal occurred at a time when the economy is in
transition to a significantly slower pace of real growth
and diminishing pressures on resources.
In response to a question by Mr. Mitchell, Mr. Brill said
his presentation was consistent with the adoption of alternative B
of the draft directives.
Mr. Keir made the following statement regarding financial
developments:

8/13/68

-25-

Since the bank credit proviso has been a constraint
on the Account Manager during a good part of the period
since the last Committee meeting, it seems appropriate
at this point to ask what the nature of the unexpected
upsurge in bank credit has been, and whether the strength
of this upsurge casts any doubt on the staff outlook for
slower economic growth just reiterated by Mr. Brill.
In
light of our recent experience you may also be wondering
how confident the staff now is about its current credit
proxy projection. As reported in the blue book, even
with no change in policy stance we are now estimating a
drop in the proxy from a growth rate of 16 to 18 per
cent in August to a rate of only 5 to 7 per cent in
September.
The reason we underestimated growth in the July and
August proxies is clear. We simply failed to anticipate
the marked changes in market expectations and interest
rates that have occurred since the last meeting. A
principal factor contributing to these changes was, of
course, the conclusion reached in the market that the
discount rate would soon be cut. No allowance was made
for this possibility in our projection, nor did we
anticipate that the Treasury would offer only a long
option in the August financing, thereby creating a
scarcity of short-dated paper. When Treasury bill rates
in fact dropped well below the levels we had assumed,
sales of bank CD's ballooned by $2 billion or roughly
double our projected increase.
In this changed environment, banks moved aggressively
to increase their liquidity and investment positions.
At the same time, with dealers also expanding security
inventories, demands for security loans at banks rose
dramatically. Together, these two types of uses
accounted for the lion's share of bank credit expansion
in July. Business loans rose less than expected, despite
the tax-induced enlargement of corporate income tax
payments, and consumer and real estate loans accounted
for only a small part of the total increase.
There is nothing unique in this response to changed
expectations. A similar pattern emerged in late 1966
and early 1967, when interest rates also turned down
sharply after a period of substantial monetary restraint
and high interest rates. In that earlier period, the
credit proxy also rose sharply above initial projections.
But once banks had rebuilt CD's to a desired share of

8/13/68

-26-

deposit accounts, added to liquidity, and enlarged other
portfolio investments, and once dealers had profited
from the initial interest rate turn, the pace of bank
credit growth slowed down again. It seems likely that
in the present circumstances too, the unexpected credit
bulge is essentially a one-shot phenomenon, supported in
this case by the very heavy level of Federal cash borrow
ing which provided a ready source of securities to
accommodate dealer and bank objectives.
In short, the recent upsurge in bank credit does
not necessarily contradict the staff economic forecast.
On the contrary, it seems to have occurred precisely
because the expectations of bankers and other participants
in financial markets coalesced into a consensus similar
to the staff view.
Looking to August, any effort to induce a significant
reduction in the 16 to 18 per cent growth rate now
projected for the credit proxy would probably require
rather drastic action since so much of this change
reflects events that have already transpired. For
example, about two-thirds of the estimated growth
represents an increase in average Government deposits
resulting chiefly from already completed Federal cash
financing.
As for September, the odds are quite strong that
growth in the credit proxy will slow down as projected.
Major city banks already show signs of bidding less
aggressively for CD's. Federal cash borrowing will not
add to credit demands again until late October. With
dealers most recently becoming more cautious about their
extended inventory positions, security loans should soon
decline. Finally, if the staff economic forecast is
correct, business borrowing at banks should slow.
For Committee members who put major stress on the
money supply rather than the credit proxy, the outlook
also is for slower growth. After expanding at nearly
a 13 per cent rate on average in July, the money supply
is projected to show no growth on average in August and
to decline over the course of the month. In September,
with Government deposits expected to be lower on average,
growth of the money supply is likely to resume, but at
a fairly moderate rate.
Turning now to questions of policy implementation,
choice of an appropriate operating directive is
complicated at the present time because short-term

8/13/68

-27-

rates were reduced over the past month to levels that
reflected widespread expectations of a near-term easing
in policy. In the preparation of the blue book and the
draft policy directives, the staff recognized that any
Committee decision today which failed to fulfill market
expectations of near-term ease would in time be likely
to encourage a rise in Treasury bill rates to levels
more consistent with recently prevailing day-to-day
money rates and marginal reserve variables. Two
different approaches were advanced for dealing with this
problem.
Alternative A of the directive drafts was suggested
as a means of maintaining something approximating the
status quo in money and short-term credit markets. As
explained in the blue book, this objective was assumed
to be consistent with some back-up in Treasury bill
rates from levels then prevailing. But provision was
also made to allow the Account Manager to ease up on
day-to-day money rates and marginal reserve measures if
bill rates should show signs of moving up too rapidly.
It was recognized that with dealers so heavily positioned
in securities other than bills, any brisk snap-back in
bill yields could spread more widely outside the bill
area. In this regard the experience of late winter
1967, when a moderate shift in expectations led to a
sizable back-up in yields throughout securities marketseven though policy was seeking to ease--may provide at
least a partial analogy.
Alternative B was suggested as a means of guarding
against the possible repercussions of any further upward
movement in short-term rates. To achieve this objective,
it was recognized that the Account Manager would have to
ease both day-to-day money rates and marginal reserve
measures as soon as the even keel period on Treasury
financing was over. Also, it was recognized that a
higher range of permissible growth in the credit proxy
would probably be necessary than under alternative A.
As Mr. Holmes has already indicated, even before
today's meeting market participants began to doubt their
earlier expectations as to the timing of credit ease.
As a result, the snap-back in bill rates has now become
more a reality than a prospect. With yesterday's new
3-month bill auctioned at just under 5.10 per cent, the
prevailing yield on this maturity is already fairly
close to the point suggested by the staff as the one at
which some modification of money market and reserve
variables ought to begin to occur even under alternative

8/13/68

-28

A. If alternative B were to become operative, some
short-term rate roll-back would be required simply to
get back to the 5 per cent level suggested as the upper
end of the range allowable for 3-month bills.
In short, the key question now is how much modifica
tion of day-to-day money and reserve measures may be
needed under alternative A to keep rates from rising too
fast, and how much additional modification would be
needed to achieve the lower rate objectives of alterna
tive B. The blue book has specified suggested ranges
for these relationships, but given the present sensitivity
of market expectations, it is difficult to be absolutely
sure that these specifications would be correct.
Moreover, with money market banks recently operating
consistently in a deep basic deficit position, it might
require rather sizable Desk operations to reach even the
lower end of the ranges specified under alternative A.
Clearly, the most direct way to forestall upward
pressures on yields and to restore a more consistent
relationship between day-to-day money rates and bill
rates would be to cut the discount rate.
Mr. Mitchell said the staff evidently thought that the
recent decline in the bill rate could prove highly temporary, and
it recommended that increases be resisted.

It was his understanding,

however, that the bill rate had fallen well below the range the
Committee had anticipated at its previous meeting.
Mr. Holmes agreed that the magnitude of the bill rate
decline experienced had not been anticipated at the previous meeting.
He had thought at that time that the directive adopted might be
consistent with a range of 5-1/4 to 5-1/2 per cent for the bill
rate, and the lowest figure suggested in the course of the Committee's
discussion was 5.10 per cent, mentioned by Mr. Maisel.
Mr. Keir noted that while a bill rate as low as 4.89 per
cent had not been expected, the directive issued had instructed the

-29

8/13/68

Manager to accommodate the tendency toward somewhat less firm money
market conditions that had developed since the June 18 meeting.
Mr. Maisel remarked that the recent pattern of events,

in

which market expectations had outrun policy, seemed to him to have
been a direct consequence of the System's decision not to reduce
the discount rate in

That pattern should not

the recent period.

have been surprising; there was every reason to expect it at the
time of the previous meeting,

when most members had spoken against
In his judgment it would

a near-term cut in the discount rate.

have been better for the System to have aided in a more rapid
adjustment of market rates to the changed perspective for Treasury
borrowing by reducing the discount rate,

instead of fostering a

speculative build-up in dealer positions based on expectations of
such an action.
Mr.

Swan observed that it

was not at all clear to him that

a discount rate cut would have served to avoid a speculative build-up
in dealer positions.
Mr.

Daane said that the staff obviously was in

favor of

alternative B, calling for somewhat less firm money market
conditions,

for the directive.

However,

givings about such a policy course.

It

he would have some mis
seemed to him that unless

the discount rate were to be reduced immediately a very large
volume of reserves would have to be supplied to achieve the money
market conditions associated with alternative B.

8/13/68

-30
Mr. Holmes agreed, remarking that massive reserve

injections were likely to be required to move the Federal funds
rate down to the 5-1/2 to 5-3/4 per cent range specified under
alternative B.
Mr. Galusha asked whether the staff thought any modification
of the specifications for alternative A was required in light of
the further increase in bill rates yesterday.
Mr. Brill replied affirmatively.

He noted that on Friday,

when the blue book was being prepared, market uncertainty was
already evident but was not yet fully reflected in interest rates.
The bill rate had closed at just below 5 per cent that day, and in
formulating the specifications

for alternative A the staff had

suggested that the Federal funds rate should be permitted to drift
down into the 5-3/4 to 6 per cent range if
approach or exceed 5.10 per cent.

the bill rate were to

But the contingency for which

that course had been suggested had already eventuated; this morning
the new three-month bill was expected to trade at around 5.10 per
cent.

Accordingly, alternative A might now be interpreted to call

for beginning immediately to move the funds rate down.

How far

the funds rate would have to be reduced to minimize further increases
in bill rates would depend on the strength of the recent reversal
of expectations, and any effort in that direction would be a probing
action.

-31

8/13/68

Mr. Hickman said he would prefer to permit the bill rate
to rise to 5.20 or 5.25 per cent before beginning to move the
Federal funds rate down.

Such a course, in his judgment, would be

consistent with the Committee's expectation at the previous meeting
that the bill rate would not fall below 5-1/4 per cent.
Mr. Brill remarked that while the staff had suggested the
trigger point for lowering the funds rate be set at a 5.10 per cent
bill rate, it had not meant to rule out the possibility that as
the funds rate came down bill rates would continue upward, perhaps
to the neighborhood of 5.20 per cent.
At Mr. Daane's request, Mr. Keir reviewed the specifications
for net borrowed reserves, member bank borrowings, and Federal
funds rates given in the blue book in connection with the alterna
tive policy courses.

With respect to net borrowed reserves, he

noted that under alternative A the range given was $200 to $400
million if bill rates remained close to then-recent levels, and
$100 to $300 million if bill rates rose to or above the 5.10 per
cent area.

Under alternative B the range was $0 to $200 million.

Chairman Martin remarked that the differences in

the

specifications for the two alternatives did not strike him as
particularly great.
Mr. Hickman noted that under alternative B bank credit was
projected to rise at an annual rate of 7 to 9 per cent in September,

-32-

8/13/68

following growth at a 16 to 18 per cent rate in August.

In his

view such rates of expansion were highly inflationary and larger
than acceptable.
Mr. Sherrill commented that, as Mr. Keir had indicated in
his statement, the high growth rate projected for August could be
explained largely in terms of special circumstances and therefore
did not necessarily have the significance that might ordinarily be
attributed to it.
Mr. Hersey then made the following statement on the balance
of payments and related matters:
For the past three months--beginning last May, the
month the French troubles began--a remarkable improvement
seems to have occurred, at least on the surface, in the
U.S. balance of payments. I am not speaking of the
second-quarter liquidity balance that will be publicly
announced in a day or two, which was heavily weighted in
a favorable direction by special transactions with Canada
and Germany. I have in mind adjusted results that were
beginning to show up in weekly and monthly settlement
data for May and June and have been confirmed by the
weekly indicators for July. Three months' data are
perhaps enough to wash out the very short-run fluctua
tions that often bedevil our judgments.
For these three
months taken together, with rough allowance for
seasonality, the adjusted deficit has been negligible.
In April it had been extremely large. For the first
four months of the year the deficit on the liquidity
basis before special official transactions had been at
an annual rate of over $5 billion and for the year 1967
over $4 billion. The improvement of which I am speaking
is therefore very sizable.
Nevertheless, the improvement is not of a kind to
lessen the Committee's concern about the balance of
payments problem. Part of what I want to do this
morning is to repeat and underline some points Mr. Reynolds

8/13/68
made here four weeks ago in discussing the second
quarter results, which taken as a whole, showed no such
improvement. With our balance of payments, unhappily,
it's "plus ca change, plus c'est la meme chose."
One of Mr. Reynolds' main points, as you may
remember, was that favorable changes in capital flows
this year have offset a disastrous deterioration in our
international trade position. That is still just as true
as it was four weeks ago, We now have one more month's
trade results, for June, with one more substantial rise
in U.S. imports. For two months running, imports
exceeded exports. Even if July saw a change for the
better--which we do not yet know to have been the casethe three months' foreign trade balance must have been
far inferior to the $4 billion rate of trade surplus we
had in the first three quarters of 1967. With something
like a $4 billion worsening in trade and something like
a $4 billion improvement in the adjusted liquidity
balance, it is evident that since a year ago something
like an $8 billion annual rate improvement in other
transactions has occurred. A major part of this
improvement must have been in the capital account.
Mr. Reynolds' second main point was that some of
the favorable developments in capital flows during the
first half of this year are likely to lose force or be
reversed as the year goes on. This is certainly just as
true now as it was then, and perhaps more so. It applies
particularly to flows of U.S. capital influenced by the
Federal Reserve foreign credit restraint program or by
the Commerce Department controls on direct investment,
as well as to the mushrooming Euro-bond borrowings by
U.S. corporations. It is quite impossible to visualize
what could have caused the marked improvement in the
over-all position that occurred after April without
assigning high probability to favorable changes in the
It is even more likely
flows of U.S. corporate funds.
now than it seemed four weeks ago that the Commerce
Department program, like the Federal Reserve program, is
well along toward achievement of the goals for 1968.
Under both programs flows are likely to be less favor
able in the remainder of the year.
The third main point that has to be stressed again
is one that everyone concerned about the balance of
payments has emphasized over and over. This is simply
that no solution of the balance of payments problem is

8/13/68

-34-

viable without a reasonably large surplus in the trade
and services accounts of the U.S. balance of payments.
One would like to be more precise about this.
Obviously the size of the needed current account surplus
will depend on how much Governmental economic aid the
United States will be providing for the less developed
countries.
It will also depend, crucially, on how large
or small a net outflow of private capital gets established
in the long run. The flows we have been experiencing in
the past three months, whether or not they persist over
the next three or six months, are not representative of
what we can expect under stable conditions in the future.
This is not only a matter of the outflows subject to
regulatory programs, which presumably will be larger
when the programs come to an end.
In recent months there has undoubtedly been an
extremely large inflow of foreign capital in various
forms on a scale that will not be maintained indefinitely.
Any estimate of its size must be guess work, starting
with the difference between known over-all results and
known transactions in trade and in flows of U.S. capital.
I would guess that the foreign private capital inflow
in the past three months, including the purchases of
Euro-bonds, but not including liquid funds coming to our
banking system through the Euro-dollar market or
directly, has been at an annual rate around $6 billion.
The corresponding figure for the year 1966 was $1-1/4
and for the first
quarter
for 1967 $2 billion,
billion,
of 1968 over $4 billion.
Some of the most recent inflow
may never get identified and so would show up as a
in the "errors and omissions" account.
favorable shift
When one thinks about the possible causes of such
an inflow, one realizes how unstable it can prove. The
United States has been getting very large foreign
purchases of U.S. corporate stocks over the past twelve
months for a variety of reasons: a hedge against future
foreign inflations, greater liquidity than European stock
markets can promise, an alternative to gold hoarding, a
response to the promotional efforts of the organizers
of mutual funds, and so on. In addition, this year there
have been large purchases of the convertible debentures
issued in Europe by U.S. companies, facilitated
by
easier-than-average monetary policy in Germany. On top
of all
this have come the French troubles in the past
three months, which no doubt have helped to prolong the
wave of stock buying and no doubt have stimulated other

-35-

8/13/68

flows into U.S. assets and repayments of liabilities to

U.S. residents.
The conclusion to which one comes is that the recent
improvement in the capital accounts of the U.S. balance
of payments is unstable, and has not removed the
necessity of getting an improvement in the current
account. The need for checking the rise in U.S. costs
and prices is as pressing as ever, because inflation is
a slow process and because its effects in improving our
trading position may be long delayed.
The Committee must, of course, be looking ahead on
the domestic front, and asking itself whether immediate
additional stimulation of domestic demand by the route
of bank liquidity and credit availability is needed to
achieve our stated goals for output and employment. I
would urge the Committee to bear in mind that a 3 per
cent rise in exports plus a 3 per cent fall in imports
would stimulate the domestic economy by $2 billion
annual rate, about the same as a 6 per cent rise in
residential construction. Excessive credit stimulation,
by prolonging and intensifying price inflation, could
frustrate the chance we now have that foreign trade gains
may bring progress toward external equilibrium and in
the process help generate domestic output and income.
Chairman Martin then called for the go-around of comments
and views on economic conditions and monetary policy, beginning
with Mr. Treiber, who made the following statement:
The economy expanded rapidly in the first half of
1968, and there is little evidence that the country is
on the verge of a general decline. We have long
stressed the need for a slowing down in the rate of
expansion. Now we can expect a needed slowdown in the
remainder of 1968 as fiscal restraint takes effect and as
strike-hedge inventories are worked down.
A moderate rise in housing starts is likely in the
coming months. The underlying demand for housing, the
removal of fears of a credit crunch, the relaxation of
usury ceilings, and the decline that has already taken
place in many interest rates would probably stimulate
more residential construction whether or not there were
a further easing of monetary policy.

8/13/68

-36-

There is no evidence of "overkill."
On balance,
prospects are good for a pick-up in the rate of economic
growth early in 1969 after the needed period of readjust
ment. The tax surcharge legislation is scheduled to
expire in mid-1969; if, as time progresses, there are
strong expectations that the surtax will be allowed to
expire, the economy could be buoyed further.
The rise in consumer prices has continued unabated.
There continue to be strong upward pressures on prices.
Labor costs per unit of output rose sharply in the second
quarter. The wage settlement in the steel industry was
one more in a series of inflationary settlements. Although
we can expect some dampening of the pressures, a reduc
tion in the rate of advance in prices is likely to be
quite gradual.
Recent balance of payments developments present a
mixed picture. The tentative figures for July indicate
the possibility of a surplus on the underlying liquidity
basis in a month that customarily is unfavorable. But
the heretofore favorable balance on the official reserves
basis is likely to worsen.
Impressive gains in the capital and services account
have been offset in large degree by a deterioration in
our trade balance. Inflation may have undermined our
international competitive position more than expected.
The longer-run correction of our over-all international
balance, free of direct controls, will require that a
sizable trade surplus be restored. The further erosion
of the purchasing power of the dollar that is inevitable
in the coming months will make even harder the task of
restoring a good trade surplus.
In recent weeks market expectations regarding the
credit outlook and the level of interest rates have
changed greatly. Interest rates, especially in the
short-term area, have declined sharply amid widespread
discussion of the likelihood of an easing of monetary
policy in the near future. Government securities dealers
have added aggressively to their inventories.
As general market rates have declined, there has
been a significant improvement in the competitive position
of deposits in banks and thrift institutions and of
mortgages. The banks experienced a massive CD inflow in
July, and have lowered their rates. While corporate
demands on the capital markets have moderated somewhat,

8/13/68

-37-

the demands of municipal borrowers have remained large.
These developments, along with the Treasury financing
operations, brought a large increase in bank credit in
July, and another substantial gain is in prospect for
August. Indeed, the growth rate has been disturbingly
large, although special factors may account for most of
it. In my opinion, a continuation of this rapid growth
rate should be firmly resisted.
The successful sale by the Treasury of $5-1/2 billion
of 6-year notes to the public for delivery August 15 will
produce $1.9 billion cash for the Treasury, and will
provide it with a breathing spell of a couple of months
before it must go again to the market.
As for policy, it seems to us that the current and
prospective economic situation at home and the balance
of payments developments and prospects do not call for
a further easing of credit or of interest rates at this
time.
There are, however, some problems flowing from the
recent rapid decline in interest rates, especially short
term rates. It has been costly for the dealers to carry
securities but the dealers have been willing to bear the
cost because they have expected further credit ease soon
and a further rise in security prices. If these
expectations are not fulfilled, there will be pressure
to liquidate, with a resultant rise in rates, especially
short-term rates.
The rate on three-month Treasury bills (on a
discount basis) is now almost 1/2 of a percentage point
below the Federal Reserve discount rate, whereas two
months ago it was about 1/4 of a percentage point above
the discount rate. There is little doubt that the
Treasury bill rate--partly because of the nature of the
current Treasury financing--moved down too fast and too
far. An increase in the rate was to be expected, and
has occurred in the last few days. But a sharp further
increase, say to or beyond 5-1/4 per cent, should be
resisted.
It seems to us that the proper prescription for
open market policy is to maintain about the present
degree of firmness in the money market, with the under
standing that an undue rise in the rate on three-month
Treasury bills would be resisted. Such a prescription,
we think, would involve a Federal funds rate of perhaps
1/2 to 5/8 of a percentage point above the discount rate;

-38-

8/13/68

member bank borrowing in the $500 - $600 million range;
and net borrowed reserves in the $200 - $350 million
range. A departure from these targets would be
appropriate either to resist too great a rise in
Treasury bill rates or to resist too sharp a decline
stimulated perhaps by market expectations of a discount
rate reduction or other acts of ease. Indeed it seems
to us that, even if the discount rate were reduced in
the near future, the System should resist a marked
decline in Treasury bill rates from their present levels.
We have pondered the possibility of a reduction in
the discount rate in the near future. There is a risk
that a reduction would not be viewed by the market as
simply a technical adjustment to the lower levels of
short-term interest rates, It might well be interpreted
as a signal of more ease to come.
I recognize that, with no change in the discount
rate, the amount of reserves created to keep Treasury
bill rates from rising too much could be excessive. In
such a case, a modest reduction in the discount rate
without relaxation of open market restraint would per
haps foster the necessary technical adjustment. The most
desirable course is not crystal clear for it is hard to
judge people's expectations. For several weeks there
have been strong expectations of much more ease. These
expectations seem to be diminishing, but it is too soon
to conclude that there has been a significant change.
On balance it seems to me that it would be premature to
conclude now that there should be a reduction in the
discount rate.
As for the directive, I would prefer alternative A.
Mr. Latham reported that the New England economy continued
strong although there was evidence of a slowing down in the forward
movement.

While it was difficult to arrive at a true assessment

of July data due to the substantial seasonal adjustment necessary
for vacation shutdowns and the impact of strikes, it was clear
that consumer spending accelerated in July.

Net savings flows

-39

8/13/68

improved, building construction remained at a high level, and ample
funds were available at commercial banks.
Of particular interest, Mr. Latham continued, was the
evidence that consumers in New England had increased their spending
pace in recent weeks.

Weekly department store sales in the four

weeks ending July 27 were 8 per cent ahead of the same period last
year.

That was larger than the percentage gain for the year through

July 27, which was 6 per cent.

After declining for three straight

months the department store index moved up 6.8 per cent from June
to July.
During July, Mr. Latham observed, net savings flow--deposits
less withdrawals--improved appreciably at Boston mutual savings
banks, and such banks elsewhere in the District continued to
experience a comfortable net inflow.

Mortgage rates continued

their upward trend but increases were fewer than in recent months.
Rates paid on savings deposits were increased in a few cases.
Policy loans of life insurance companies continued to rise
in the second quarter, Mr. Latham added, with no apparent abatement
in that trend in July.

Despite that demand, mortgage and invest

ment commitments continued at good levels.

At commercial banks

there were substantial increases in CD outstandings at reduced
rates.

8/13/68

-40
Mr. Latham felt that developments during the next four to

six weeks would give a better reading on the impact of fiscal
action and on how significant monetary actions should be.
Mr. Coldwell reported that the most recent information
concerning economic developments in the Eleventh District still
gave little hint of a downturn.

In fact, although some of the

prime indicators might not be growing as rapidly as in prior
months, there still was evidence of a regional economy operating
at vitually full production, employment, and utilization of
resources.

The production index for Texas dipped fractionally in

June but virtually all of the decline centered upon a reduction in
the output of crude petroleum.

Even construction contract awards

issued in the five Southwest States touched by the District
advanced 3 per cent over the prior month and returned almost to
the peak for the year reached in March, with strength primarily
centered in nonbuilding construction.

Department store sales

levels in the Eleventh District for the month of July were 15 per
cent above a year earlier, and the cumulative sales for the year
to date were 13 per cent over a year ago.
Along with those evidences of continued strength, Mr. Coldwell
said, the tempo of agricultural activities in the District generally
increased with harvesting now moving rapidly ahead as dry weather
set in.

Some rain damage had occurred in cotton areas, but the

8/13/68

-41

crop was forecast at a level 22 per cent higher than in 1967.
Range and livestock conditions were excellent.
There was, however, an uneasiness associated with that
high level of production, employment, and spending, Mr. Coldwell
observed.

The impact of the new surtax and the curtailment of

expenditures expected under the spending restraint program in a
regional area heavily dependent upon Government contracts, as well
as the uncertainties bred by the normal airing of the nation's
problems in a political year, had given a tone to the District's
outlook which--although not quantifiable--might be somewhat less
optimistic than one might expect.
Financial conditions in the District mirrored some of the
changes at the national level with heavy inflows of time and savings
deposits, Mr. Coldwell continued.
continued strength in loan demand.

However, the District showed
With investments, demand

deposits, and time deposits advancing, the resources and liquidity
of the banking industry appeared substantially improved.

Negotiable

time certificates of deposits at the weekly reporting banks
reached a new record level, although the advances were concentrated
in a few banks.

Borrowings from the Federal Reserve Bank had

increased recently while net purchases of Federal funds had
declined.

Bankers' opinions concerning their institutions' positions

seemed to indicate a slightly easier tone but some element of surprise

8/13/68

-42

at the strength of the loan demand.

Statistically, the financial

conditions seemed reflective of the easier money market conditions
and rates, and that had transmitted a feeling of somewhat greater
ease to some of the District's larger banks; but with very high
loan-deposit ratios and continued demands for credit, the bankers'
feeling of uneasiness continued to persist, and their demands upon
the Federal funds market and over-all borrowings through bills
payable, recourse sales of loans, and other such devices were
indicative of some tightness.
Nationally, it seemed to Mr. Coldwell that the economy
reflected imbalances from the recent inflationary excesses, wage
cost price pressures, and downward influences of the recent fiscal
action, steel decumulation, and auto model change-over.

While some

of those forces were transitory, their conjunction at the moment
could be deceiving in a policy sense.

Thus, although the short-run

economy might be somewhat slow, the longer-range picture could be
quite different.

The consumer had not yet shown a marked shift

in consumption patterns, and unless he did curtail spending the
economy might be strong enough to weather the near-term downward
pressures with only a modest lessening of the growth rate, especially
if construction activity was stimulated.
Mr. Coldwell commented that financial demands were slowing
in the corporate area but were still substantial from municipalities

8/13/68

-43

and consumers.

If mortgage demands were regenerated and seasonal

demands developed fully, the loan picture might be fairly strong.
Credit supplies were improving; with the CD market strong and with
recent excessive growth in the money supply, there was a more than
adequate credit base for the near term.

The very high rate of bank

credit expansion pointed toward the distinct dangers in providing
too much new credit before imbalances had been corrected.
As to policy, Mr. Coldwell said he would favor being
basically accommodative to the market, without more than seasonal
credit provision.

He would permit short-term rates to back up but

in an orderly fashion, with the three-month bill rate not over
5-1/4 per cent.

A discount rate cut might be considered at a

later time, preferably in September.

For the present, he would

hold to ranges of $200 - $350 million for net borrowed reserves, 5
to 5-1/4 per cent for the bill rate, and 5-7/8 to 6 per cent for
the Federal funds rate.

He would hope that growth in the credit

proxy could be reduced to an annual rate of 7 to 9 per cent and
that increases in the money supply could be held to minimal levels.
Mr. Coldwell then proposed certain changes in the staff's
draft of the directive.

In the opening sentence, reading "The

information reviewed at this meeting suggests that some elements
of economic activity continued to expand vigorously in early
summer," he would replace the word "suggests" with "indicates."

8/13/68

-44

The next sentence might then be recast to begin "Other data suggest
that expansion in over-all economic activity may slow considerably
in coming months ...."

In the statement reading "....growth in the

money supply has continued large as U.S. Government deposits have
been drawn down further on average," he would delete the reference
to Government deposits, since rapid money supply growth had been
associated with declining Government deposits in three successive
directives.
For the second paragraph, Mr. Coldwell continued, he would
prefer alternative A.

However, he would suggest revised language

calling for operations "with a view to attaining more balanced money
market conditions at about the level prevailing at the time of
this meeting."
Mr. Swan reported that in California the unemployment rate
rose slightly in July; a small increase in employment was outpaced
by growth of the labor force.

Because the composition of demand

for steel in the West differed from that in the rest of the country,
western steel production had been affected less by the recent
hedging against a strike; output had not risen as sharply as
elsewhere before the strike deadline, and had declined less since
the settlement.
In recent weeks, Mr. Swan continued, Twelfth District banks
had been heavy net buyers of interbank Federal funds, had borrowed

-45

8/13/68

substantially under repurchase agreements, and had made a large
volume of funds available to securities dealers.
no dearth of CD money in the District.

There had been

There had been very little

borrowing from the Reserve Bank in July and early August; such
borrowing had declined both in absolute dollar terms and relative
to the rest of the country.

Otherwise, District banking develop

ments had been similar to those in the nation as a whole.
With respect to policy, Mr. Swan said, despite the green
book's forebodings about the economic outlook for the second half,
and in light of the strength evident in July, he was disturbed by
the excessive current and prospective rates of increase in bank
credit.

Consequently, he would be quite hesitant about moving

toward further ease or about reacting to further rate movements.
On the latter point, he would not favor action to offset increases
in bill rates until the three-month rate rose to the neighborhood
of 5.20 or 5.25 per cent.

It was important to recognize that, as

Mr. Holmes had indicated, the average rate for three-month bills
in yesterday's auction was still 40 basis points below that set
four weeks earlier.

Also, he would approach the question of a

discount rate reduction cautiously.

At the moment he was inclined

to wait until September before taking such action.
Mr. Swan said he would favor alternative A for the directive.
In view of the high rate of bank credit expansion projected for

8/13/68

-46

August and September, a one-way proviso clause was appropriate.
However, he would strengthen the clause shown in the draft by
deleting the word "significantly" from the statement that opera
tions should be modified "if bank credit appears to be significantly
exceeding current projections."

Indeed, the clause might be

strengthened even further by saying that operations should be
modified "if bank credit appears to be approaching the upper limit
of the range projected."

Mr. Galusha reported that in the Ninth District the crop
price situation was turning out somewhat worse than had been
expected earlier and there was nothing to indicate a turnabout.
Virtually each day's market report presented new seasonal lows for
almost every class of grain in both the cash and futures markets.
Wheat prices, for example, had declined almost 15 cents since
June and were currently about 45 cents a bushel below year-ago
levels.
path.

Corn and soybean prices had followed the same downward
That weakening had brought current prices to support levels.

He expected them to hold at such levels during the remainder of
the year, although further harvest-season declines might occur as
farmers marketed grain from the fields.

All signs indicated, how

ever, that there would be little grain marketed this fall; the
bulk of the crop would probably be placed under loan or in
storage.

farm

-47

8/13/68

As a result of those developments, Mr. Galusha observed,
cash receipts from crop marketings in the remainder of the year
would likely run below those of last year and, because there was
little prospect for an improved livestock picture, there would be
a year-to-year reduction in total District cash income.

Net

income, because of the inexorable upcreep in costs, should
register a rather pronounced drop.

The addition of the surtax,

of course, made the prospective cut in income all the more
severe.
While all of the responses had not been received to the
Minneapolis Reserve Bank's quarterly survey of District manufac
turers, Mr. Galusha remarked, preliminary indications were that
sales forecasts for the fourth quarter had been revised downward.
District employment should grow at a slower pace as those
revisions affected production plans.
Turning to the national scene, Mr. Galusha said the decline
in market rates that had taken place since the last meeting of the
Committee did not disturb him at all.

Indeed, it seemed to him

that the lower level of rates now prevailing placed the Committee,
at least for the time being, in about the right position.

A

continuation of current levels should help to reduce the uncertainty
that now existed over future deposit inflows and to encourage
depositary institutions to move ahead with their commitments, thus

-48

8/13/68

improving prospects of a step-up in housing construction during
winter months.

Furthermore, he had been assured by a leading

mortgage banker in the District that a number of multi-unit
builders were now holding back in their search for commitments
because of an anticipation of lower mortgage rates.

Holding short

rates, in particular bill rates, at current levels should foster
a quicker reaction in mortgage rates and move the point in time
closer when those builders who were hesitating stepped forward to
complete their plans.
Mr. Galusha suggested the System's efforts should be directed
at stabilizing the market as best it could.

Unless it moved fairly

resolutely, there was a real risk that the very recent reversal of
the earlier market trend would continue.

A discount rate reduction

immediately after the settlement date in the current Treasury
financing would provide a needed signal and would reduce the
amount of open market intervention necessary to achieve the range
of bill rates specified in the blue book in connection with
alternative A.

He was not urging a move toward pronounced

increased ease, such as was implied by alternative B, which he
interpreted as differing more in a qualitative than a quantitative
sense from A.

It seemed to him a prompt change of 1/2 per cent

in the discount rate would check the tendency of short rates to

-49

8/13/68

move up and would probably put them closer to the middle of the
proposed target ranges.
He realized that this was flying in the face of numbers for
retail trade,
said.

the money supply, and the credit proxy, Mr.

Galusha

As to the former, Federal expenditure reductions and the

surtax would take their toll; and he did not think the two pay
periods that had intervened since the surtax became effective had
been enough to change consumer thinking.

As to the money supply

and bank credit, the staff explanation was quite credible.
As he had implied, Mr. Galusha continued, he favored
alternative A for the directive.

He would accept ranges for money

market variables that combined the two sets of ranges given in the
blue book in connection with that alternative.1/

Specifically,

he

favored ranges of 4.90 to 5.10 per cent for the bill rate, 5-3/4
to 6-1/8 per cent for the Federal funds rate, $400 to $650 million
for member bank borrowings, and $100 to $400 million for net bor
rowed reserves.

1/ The blue book passage referred to read as follows: "If
bill rates were to remain relatively close to recent levels--say,
fluctuating between 4.90 and 5.10 per cent--the Federal funds rate
could be maintained in the 6--6-1/8 per cent range of recent weeks.
These conditions would likely be associated with average borrowings
of $500 to $650 million, and average net borrowed reserves of $200
to $400 million. If, however, bill rates were to approach or
exceed the top of this range, and particularly if they were rising
rapidly, the Federal funds rate could be permitted to drift down,
perhaps into the 5-3/4 to 6 per cent range. Such easing in the
cost of reserve funds would likely be associated with marginal
reserve measures about $100 million lower."

8/13/68

-50
Mr. Treiber asked whether Mr. Galusha would change his

target for the Federal funds rate if the discount rate were changed,
and Mr. Galusha replied affirmatively.

He added that he considered

the timing of the discount rate action to be of critical importance;
he thought a change at this juncture would have the maximum effect
in stemming the reversal of earlier expectations that seemed to
be proceeding rapidly, without requiring substantial intervention
by the Desk.
Mr. Scanlon commented that although real growth in the
economy probably was slackening in the third quarter, evidence
available in the Seventh District suggested no dampening in the
general price uptrend and little if any improvement in the supply
of labor relative to demand.

A number of observers in the District

were concerned that excessively expansionary monetary policy was
likely to offset the impact of the new fiscal restraint package.
Partly because of that, he found little support at this time for
the view of Administration spokesmen that the package might prove
too restrictive.
Mr. Scanlon noted that the expected sharp decline in steel
output had occurred in the first week of August.
production had passed its high in

Actually, ingot

his region in April and had

declined 10 per cent by the second half of July.

Rolling mills

continued to operate at a high rate and shipments, at about 10.5

-51

8/13/68

million tons in July, were much higher than in any earlier month.
Manufacturers' holdings of finished steel might have reached 15
million tons by August 1, but that was less than the 17 million
tons total

for August 1965--when there was a similar strike-hedge

buildup--and consumption was much higher now.

Delivery schedules

for steel had been well maintained through the inventory buildup.
In general, there was less "water" in steel order books and
customer inventories were less excessive now than in 1965 and some
earlier periods.
anticipated.

Nevertheless, a rapid inventory liquidation was

He was told that most of the decline in labor needs

in the steel industry was expected to be accommodated by use of
deferred vacation time and the dropping of temporary help, but
some layoffs of experienced personnel might also occur.
The strong trend in auto sales starting in May had raised
industry forecasts of sales for all of 1968 to 9.3 million units,
including more than 900,000 imports, Mr. Scanlon said.

Sales of

both domestic and foreign cars were at a record pace in May, June,
and July.

Forecasts indicated a 21 per cent year-to-year rise for

auto sales in August and a total of 1.9 million for the third
quarter--13 per cent above last year and a new high for the period.
Factory shipments of television, hi-fi sets, and most appliances
had been excellent, with some of the District's

producers

reporting

8/13/68

-52

record volume in recent months.

The picture for capital goods

varied greatly from industry to industry.
Although attitudes of lenders and builders varied, Mr. Scanlon
said, the gloom noted earlier concerning construction prospects
for the remainder of the year appeared to be lifting.

Permits

granted for residential projects in the Chicago area had been very
large, especially for apartment buildings.

Throughout the Seventh

District a seller's market prevailed for real estate.
rates were very low.

Vacancy

Costs and prices continued to rise sharply.

Because of demand for residential, commercial, and public construc
tion, he was told labor probably would be fully utilized throughout
1968 and into 1969 as well.

Crop prospects in the District were

excellent and as a result, prices of the District's most important
farm commodities, both crops and livestock, were expected to be
under downward pressure.
Mr. Scanlon observed that District banking figures showed
evidence of moderate credit demands from the private sector, on
balance, and very ample ability of the banks to meet it.

Business

borrowing appeared to have been lighter last month than had been
expected.

Consumer loans, on the other hand, showed the strongest

gains in many months.

Meanwhile, opportunities to add to invest

ment portfolios at the high current yields and the profit potential

8/13/68

-53

associated with expected further declines in interest rates had
been reflected in substantial acquisitions of securities and real
estate loans, which appeared to have absorbed most of the funds
obtained in the CD market last month.

Despite the fairly deep

reserve deficit positions indicated for large Chicago banks, they
were not under any pressure to meet loan demands.

Rather, their

increased reliance on borrowed funds, in addition to funds acquired
in the CD market, reflected a huge expansion in investments.
The very rapid expansion in total reserves and bank credit
in recent weeks and projected for at least the remainder of this
month troubled Mr. Scanlon for two reasons.

First, those rates

were considerably faster than projected at the Committee's last
meeting, even though money market rates (other than on Federal
funds) had declined substantially and rebounded slightly in the
intervening period.

Second, those rates were greater than would

appear to be consistent with the trends of prices and production
he believed to be desirable.

As he had noted the last time the

Committee met, it appeared that the path to stable economic growth
would entail a period of little or no growth in real terms in
order to ease the excessive demand for labor and the excessively
large wage settlements and to achieve a slower rate of price
increases.

The current rates of reserve and credit expansion had

not been consistent with economic stability at full employment in

-54

8/13/68

the past and were unlikely to be in the months ahead.

He was

additionally concerned since he expected the tone of economic
activity to be pitched somewhat higher than might be inferred from
the staff's projections, keeping in mind that revisions of staff
projections had been rather consistently on the upside.
Mr. Scanlon preferred a slower--although not slow--rate of
expansion in total reserves, on the order of 4 per cent annually,
and he would expect that to be associated with a growth rate in
bank credit of about 8 per cent.

While not greatly different from

the rates experienced in the first half of the year, in conjunc
tion with the change in fiscal policy those rates of expansion in
reserves and bank credit should accommodate the necessary slowing
in economic expansion during the remainder of the year and begin
to mitigate price pressures, without interfering with the emergence
of some pick-up in activity beginning early in 1969 as additional
labor resources became available.
The problem was how to attain the desired rates of growth
in those measures, Mr. Scanlon said.

Projected linkages between

money market measures and aggregate monetary measures had been
exceptionally poor in recent weeks and not very good in earlier
periods.

The current rapid rate of growth of bank credit had

occurred despite a Federal funds rate and a free reserve level
estimated at the Committee's last meeting to be consistent with

8/13/68

-55

significantly slower rates of expansion.

He again urged that the

Manager be instructed to attain some specified target of total
reserves or bank credit.

If the 4 per cent reserve and 8 per cent

credit targets were to be associated with some rise in interest
rates, he would interpret that to indicate that the demand for
credit was stronger than expected and he would not offset it.

He

would, of course, offset abrupt rate changes in either direction
in the interest of providing continuity in financial markets.
Mr. Scanlon did not favor reducing the discount rate
immediately.

He preferred alternative A for the second paragraph

of the directive although, like Mr. Swan, he would delete the word
"significantly" from the proviso clause.
Mr. Clay expressed the view that the domestic economy was
performing quite well so far as current activity was concerned.
slower rate of future growth was expected, but there was room for
differences of judgment as to the degree of adjustment ahead.
Over all, the cost-price situation continued to be a problem.
While the foreign exchange position of the dollar had improved,
the basic situation in foreign trade and the balance of payments
remained a matter of concern.
Under the circumstances, it had appeared best to move
cautiously in adjusting monetary policy subsequent to the enact
ment of the surtax, Mr. Clay said.

That still appeared to be the

A

8/13/68

-56

appropriate view.

It was important to avoid undue restraint on

economic activity with marked adverse consequences upon employment
and output, but it

also had to be recognized that the cost-price

inflation needed to be slowed down and brought into balance over
time.

The cost-price problem could not be corrected without some

adverse effect upon growth in employment and output.

An attempt

to do otherwise could be expected to bring an acceleration in the
cost-price inflation.
Developments of recent weeks once again raised the issue
as to how open market operations should be conducted during periods
of Treasury financing, Mr.

Clay continued.

As it

was,

the System

seemed to lose control of bank reserve and credit expansion during
such periods and the results sometimes deviated sharply from what
was intended.

Recognition of statistical seasonal adjustment

problems did not preclude the judgment that credit policy appeared
to have been much more expansive in recent weeks than the Committee
had intended.

Changed market expectations and increased inflows

of CD funds were factors in the credit expansion.

Presumably the

bank credit proviso clause could not be implemented effectively in
view of the behavior of several money market indicators,
Federal funds rates and dealer loan rates.

including

At the same time,

security yields generally, and Treasury bill yields particularly,
had moved downward sharply.

-57

8/13/68

Mr. Clay noted that it was expected that the rate of
growth in bank reserves and bank credit would slow down markedly
as Treasury financing operations ceased to be a dominant factor in
the money markets and in the conduct of monetary policy.

Staff

estimates indicated a bank credit growth rate of 5 to 7 per cent
for September, assuming a continuation of the "present stance of
policy."

That rate of bank credit growth would appear to be

acceptable, although a growth rate at the lower end of the range
would be preferable.

That approach might be associated with a 90

day Treasury bill rate of 5.00 to 5.25 per cent, net borrowed
reserves of $200 - $400 million, and member bank borrowings of
$500 - $600 million.

A near-term reduction in the Federal Reserve discount rate
would seem to be premature, Mr. Clay observed.

In a highly

speculative securities market such as had developed recently, some
market adjustment was to be expected and should not surprise profes
sional market people.

Accepting the responsibility to avoid any

such market adjustment would severely handicap the administration
of monetary policy.

Toleration of a moderate upward adjustment in

securities yields probably would be consistent with a more
appropriate rate of growth in bank reserves and bank credit.
Moreover, Federal funds and dealer loan rates probably would ease

-58

8/13/68

under those circumstances, as some short-term speculative positions
were liquidated.
Alternative A of the draft economic policy directive
appeared to Mr. Clay to be satisfactory.
Mr. Heflin reported that business activity in the Fifth
District over the last four weeks had shown some signs of decelera
tion.

While business indicators had registered no significant

declines, they were growing at a reduced rate and the Richmond
Reserve Bank's business conditions survey indicated a definite
shift in business sentiment.

Some tapering off was apparent in

the rate of growth of employment and retail sales, and cutbacks in
residential building were reported to be under way in some parts
of the District.
Mr. Heflin remarked that his views on policy today were
determined more by the economic outlook than by evidence in hand
on actual economic developments.

He thought there was good reason

to expect a significantly slower rate of growth in the national
economy over the next several months.

The steel negotiations had

ended without a strike, but the cutback in steel production
already under way would exert a dampening influence for several
months to come.

Add to that the impact of the recent fiscal

measures and weakness in private construction and it seemed
reasonably clear that a lessening of pressures on the economy was

8/13/68

-59

in prospect.

The System had been trying to achieve some dampening

effect, of course, but it

must also face up to the question of

whether the prospective curtailment in demand was greater than was
necessary.

It seemed to him that given the combination of

deflationary forces now in prospect, the current posture of credit
policy involved a definite risk of too much restraint.

For that

reason, he believed that some reasonably early move toward a less
restrictive policy was in order.
The Committee's actions since the last meeting had permitted,
if not encouraged, a continuation of the welcome downdrift of
interest rates in process since the end of May, Mr. Heflin said.
He was concerned, however, about the changes in the pattern of
rates that had accompanied that downward rate movement.

Treasury

bill rates had fallen somewhat more sharply than expected, largely
because of the nature of the Treasury's refunding operations.

But

dealer loan and Federal funds rates had remained at higher levels
than appeared desirable.

That, combined with large dealer bill

positions, could produce a back-up in bill rates and retard the
orderly progression of the entire spectrum of rates to lower
levels.

In brief, it seemed to him that confirmation of the

recent rate declines required some adjustments within the rate
pattern, and particularly a reduction in Federal funds rates and

-60

8/13/68
in the costs of dealer financing.

A cut in the prime rate might

also be desirable.
Mr. Heflin believed that an early reduction in the discount
rate might be a necessary step in achieving such rate adjustments.
In his view, the question currently was primarily one of timing.
While he would not argue for immediate rate action, it seemed to
him that in the absence of a rate change, the Desk should seek to
attain somewhat easier market conditions.

If there was to be a

change in the discount rate he would favor alternative A, as
modified by Mr. Coldwell, for the directive.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that while the staff's GNP projections
might have a higher probability of being realized than others
which could be offered, he did not think that probability was very
high.

As Mr. Brill had indicated, it was not easy to predict what

consumers might do.

He would prefer to hedge against the staff's

projections by following the policy course implied by alternative
A of the directive drafts.
Mr. Mitchell observed that he was not overly concerned
about the bill rate, even though its recent substantial gyrations
were explainable only in part by technical factors related to the
Treasury financing.

He thought it would be unwise to give much

attention to bill rates in formulating policy today, subject to
one qualification--he would become somewhat concerned if rates

-61

8/13/68

rose to a level at which banks would not have leeway to sell
intermediate- and longer-term CD's.
Like others, Mr. Mitchell remarked, he was disturbed by
the speculative buildup in the positions of banks and Government
securities dealers.

In his judgment, however, for the Committee

to validate the expectations that led to that buildup would be
going well beyond its intentions at the last meeting when it agreed
to accommodate tendencies toward less firmness.

He thought the

tendencies that had been meant were those associated with the
market forces of supply and demand, not expectations regarding
Federal Reserve policy.
Mr. Mitchell said that Mr. Keir's explanation of the recent
and projected performance of the bank credit proxy satisfied him,
although he doubted that it would satisfy some of the System's
critics.

As to Mr. Coldwell's suggestion that the reduction in

Government deposits should not again be mentioned in the directive
as an explanation of the recent rapid growth in the money supply,
he (Mr. Mitchell) saw no reason for omitting the explanation so
long as it was valid.

By the same token, however, he would want

to have the directive mention rises in Government deposits when
they were the cause of declines in the money supply.

He con

curred in Mr. Swan's suggestion that the word "significantly"
should be deleted from the proviso clause.

8/13/68

-62
In concluding, Mr. Mitchell remarked that he would have

been prepared to accept a 1/4 point reduction in the discount rate
if

it

had appeared likely that the market would conclude that that

was as far as the System planned to go for the time being.

From

the Manager's comments, however, he (Mr. Mitchell) gathered that
it

would take quite a bit of explaining to convince the market of

that.

Accordingly, he would not favor a discount rate cut now.
Mr. Daane said he found the question of appropriate System

policy to be a particularly difficult one today.

In general, he

favored continuing on the course of gradually letting up on the
brake of monetary restraint, while retaining flexibility.

He was

concerned more with the rate at which reserves were supplied than
with the particular fluctuations in

bill rates, and did not favor

alternative B for the directive since its adoption evidently would
lead to massive injections of reserves.

It was possible that a

course combining alternative A for the directive with a discount
rate reduction would involve the smallest injection of reserves;
if

so, a discount rate cut would be in order.

had wisely observed,

But, as the Manager

one could not be sure of the market's reac

tion to a discount rate cut.

In his judgment the discount rate

would have to be reduced by 1/2 rather than 1/4 point, since the
market was not likely to view a 1/4 point cut as a one-time
technical adjustment.

More likely, there would be expectations of

another cut soon and renewed speculative activity.

8/13/68

-63
In sum, Mr. Daane said, he favored alternative A for the

directive.

While a discount rate cut might be needed to avoid the

need for large reserve injections,

he would hope that consideration

of such action could be postponed for a few weeks.
In reply to a question by Mr. Galusha, Mr. Holmes said that
since the market was now less certain than a short time ago of the
course of System policy, there probably was less risk now that a
small discount rate change be interpreted as signaling substantial
further ease to come.

That judgment was supported by developments

in the market this morning,
was continuing.

which suggested that the recent reaction

As he had indicated, however, one could not be

sure of the effect on the market of a discount rate cut.
Mr. Maisel remarked that he did not consider the choice
today between alternatives A and B for the directive to be partic
ularly important because he thought that policy for the bulk of
the period between now and the Committee meeting tentatively
scheduled for September 10 should be set in a telephone conference
meeting following an immediate lowering of the discount rate.
The problem, Mr. Maisel continued, was clearly one of
attempting to evaluate the effect on total credit expansion of a
failure to act.

It

seemed to him that a failure to lower the

discount rate at this time would constitute a change in policy.
The System would be trying to retrace time and the market actions

8/13/68

-64

of the past six weeks.

That would be a positive action--shown as

a failure to act--which the market and the country would correctly
interpret as a sign that the Federal Reserve System was assuming
that the current fiscal policy would not be likely to bring about
an increase in unemployment and a fall in the rate of real growth.
It would be assumed that the Federal Reserve believed that suffi
cient fiscal restraint would not be forthcoming, and as a result
was determined to hold interest rates up--at record levels compared
to previous years--rather than allowing the fall in demand for
credit to carry rates down.

Furthermore, it would be assumed that

because of that belief, the System was not changing the discount
rate in order to force the whole complex of rates back up to
higher levels.
Mr. Maisel felt that a discount rate reduction now would
not be a change in policy to lead rates down; rather it would be
the theoretically neutral expression of adjusting the discount
rate to coincide with market rates, which had correctly fallen as
participants read the implications of the Committee's policy cut
in the repurchase rate plus previous statements regarding the
correct mixture of monetary and fiscal policy.

A failure to

adjust the discount rate would, on the other hand, be a strong
policy statement in favor of greater monetary constraint.
While it was clearly a matter of judgment, Mr. Maisel said,
he thought those who felt that delay and small movements were

8/13/68

-65

safe and conservative were incorrect since they allowed the market
to force moves of an undesirable size.

The failure to control

events by actions, as had just been seen, was likely to lead to
more rapid and abrupt movements than desired.

He thought a 5 per

cent discount rate now, with a slower provision of reserves than
had been the case, was preferable to the System's present stance.
As he indicated at the previous meeting, Mr. Maisel
continued, the Committee's goal for this quarter and the next should
be basically that of a neutral monetary and credit policy, defined
as growth in total deposits at an 8 to 9 per cent annual rate.

In

actuality, that was about the rate that was indicated for the
current quarter.

It probably would have been better if the initial

expansion--particularly in bank credit--had been slower.

He

believed that the System was, however, paying the penalty for
delaying last time and allowing the market to take over with a
speculative binge based on expectations.

As he pointed out in his

statement at the last meeting, the System could have cut down the
rate of expansion in reserves and the buildup of speculative
positions in bills and notes based on expectations by changing the
discount rate after the previous meeting.
Mr. Maisel observed that what had not been done was past;
the market had moved ahead of the System.

Now the System should

simply adjust the discount rate to the existing market situation.

-66

8/13/68

With respect to the directive to be issued today, alternative A
would probably cause an undesirable reaction; he would favor
alternative B in case there was any delay in the discount rate
change and the telephone meeting of the Committee.

Clearly, how

ever, the situation with respect to both alternatives was confused
because of the changes that had occurred in the market since the
blue book was written.

The Manager would have to rely on his

interpretations of the statements made by members today.

His

(Mr. Maisel's) view was that the bill rate should be kept around
5 per cent.

He would expect that the Federal funds rate would

have to be decreased and large amounts of reserves furnished to
keep the rate near 5 per cent unless the discount rate was lowered.
Mr. Brimmer said he thought it would be appropriate at
this juncture for the Open Market Committee to stand aside and
permit the Reserve Banks and the Board to make the next policy
move by reducing the discount rate.

Earlier he had indicated that

he favored a reduction of 1/4 point, but in light of the
subsequent discussion he was now inclined to a 1/2 point cut.

In

his judgment the action should be taken no later than the middle
or end of next week, and preferably earlier.

He concurred in the

view that a discount rate cut was likely to reduce the volume of
reserves that would have to be supplied.

There was no doubt in

his mind that in the absence of such action the bill rate would
remain under upward pressure.

-67-

8/13/68

Mr. Brimmer remarked that the Committee had taken a "rate"
action at its previous meeting when there had been a consensus for
reducing the RP rate from 5-5/8 to 5-1/2 per cent at the first
possible moment.

RP's were in fact made at 5-1/2 per cent the

next day, and the market had correctly read that as a policy
action.

While the Committee had not anticipated that the Treasury

would not include a short-term anchor issue in its financing, the
market had interpreted that decision as a quasi-monetary action.
Mr. Brimmer said he had no particular comments to make
with respect to language for the directive.

In general, he thought

open market operations should be directed at backing up the dis
count rate reduction, which might call for money market conditions
somewhere between those specified for alternatives A and B.

He

agreed with Mr. Heflin that it was appropriate to formulate policy
in light of projected economic developments rather than by
considering only the situation at the moment.
Mr. Sherrill said he thought the System had to take account
of the effects of its policy actions not only on such variables as
money and bank credit but also on market expectations.

Recently,

interest rates had declined sharply as a result of heavy specula
tion on an imminent easing of monetary policy,

and then had

reversed course as doubts about System intentions began to grow.
At present, he thought the worst expectation the System could

8/13/68

-68

engender would be one of a rapid, deep decline in interest rates.
But the next worst expectation was the opposite--that the current
exceptionally high structure of rates would continue indefinitely.
Ideally, the System's actions should indicate a long-run policy
intent of lowering the rate structure in an orderly manner over a
reasonable period.
To do that would not be easy under current circumstances,
Mr. Sherrill remarked, but he would suggest a possible two-stage
strategy.

In the first stage, which would be launched immediately,

the Federal funds rate would be allowed to drop below 6 per cent
in the hope that that would stop the bill rate from rising and
would lead to an orderly liquidation of speculative positions.

If

those hopes were not realized it would be clear that a move to the
second stage--a reduction in the discount rate--was necessary.
Mr. Hickman remarked that as expected, the economy seemed
to have moved into a period of virtually no growth in real GNP.
Signs of cooling were accumulating, particularly in the heavy
industries.

Inventories of autos and steel were being liquidated,

and steel output was being reduced drastically.

Consequently,

industrial production would show little growth during the second
half of 1968, and the margin of unused plant capacity would widen
further.

Despite the current no-growth phase of economic

activity, cost-price pressures and inflationary psychology were

-69

8/13/68
prevalent and pervasive.

Until inflationary forces and sentiment

had moderated substantially, he saw no reason for the Committee to
change its policy position.
Having said that, Mr. Hickman continued, he had to confess
that he felt somewhat less certain than usual about what the
stance of monetary policy actually was.

As he interpreted the

directive adopted at the last meeting, it called for open market
operations that would accommodate the somewhat less firm conditions
then existing in the money market, provided that the bank credit
proxy did not deviate significantly from current projections.
Including adjustments for Euro-dollar flows, the projections
indicated growth at an annual rate of 6 to 10 per cent, on average,
for July and August.

For several weeks now, the July-August

estimates of the credit proxy had been indicating a rate of
expansion far in excess of a 6 to 10 per cent range--in fact, 13
or 14 per cent, according to the latest estimates.

Open market

operations should therefore have become less accommodative up to
the announcement of the Treasury financing, and no more accommoda
tive thereafter; at least that was the way he interpreted the
proviso clause.
As a participant in the morning conference call during the
past four weeks, Mr. Hickman said, he had been deeply troubled by
those inconsistencies.

The Committee's reluctance to bring open

8/13/68

-70

market operations fully to bear on bank credit stemmed largely, he
thought, from the fact that the Committee was concerned with a
broad constellation of variables rather than a single one--and
those variables frequently did not behave as expected under the
complex conditions of the market place, given institutional changes
and shifting expectations.

If the proviso clause had been invoked

when it should have been, considerably different patterns would
have developed for a number of key money market variables.

For

example, the Federal funds rate would probably have moved even
higher--in fact it was well above the staff projection most of the
time; the bill rate would not have been so low as it was--early in
the period it fell well below the staff projection; net borrowed
reserves would have been much deeper; and so on.
That suggested to Mr. Hickman that the proviso clause had
not been allowed to perform its intended function.

If the proviso

clause was retained in the policy directive, the Committee should
be prepared to accept wider swings in either direction in the
major money market variables.

If it was not prepared to accept

wider swings, then the proviso clause should be eliminated.

He

personally would vote to retain the proviso clause, and would
tolerate wider swings in money market variables than the Committee
had been willing to accept thus far.

-71

8/13/68

In that vein, Mr. Hickman said, he favored alternative Aor a modified version under which the bill rate would be allowed
to drift above present levels.

That would be consistent with no

change in policy and a reduced rate of bank credit expansion in
September, as projected in the blue book.

He would underscore the

word "provided" in the second paragraph of the directive, and
would delete the word "significantly" from the following clause.
As to the discount rate, he would move slowly and at this time
would prefer a reduction of 1/4 rather than 1/2 point.
Mr. Bopp commented it was still too early to predict with
any confidence the vigor of the economy by year-end.

However,

preliminary second-quarter data did confirm earlier forecasts of a
slowing down in the rate of increase in economic activity, and
further moderation was likely.

Thus, with the steel settlement in

hand, a key component in the inventory buildup had shifted from a
plus to a minus factor in the economic outlook.

Residential

construction probably would .showa smaller volume of outlays in
the third quarter, owing to a drop in starts.

The bite of the

surtax on consumer expenditures was yet to be felt.
In the Third District, Mr. Bopp continued, the Reserve
Bank's Business Outlook Survey indicated that a majority of manufac
turers expected business to continue at present rates for the
next several months, but they were becoming less optimistic about

-72

8/13/68
the year-end.

Prospects were for continued price increases, both

paid and received, although those opinions were not. quote so pre
valent as a month earlier.

Philadelphia commercial banks said

that loan demand had picked up modestly, as they had expected.
Mr. Bopp concluded that both nationally and locally the
signs of softness were still relatively few and that the evolving
moderation in the pace of the economy should not be interpreted as
weakness.

Near-term moderation should be welcomed in view of

persisting cost-price pressures.

Further out, the bite of the

fiscal package might be considerably less than expected.

Thus,

two-thirds of the proposed expenditures reduction for fiscal year
1969 had already been offset by additional appropriations in the
categories exempt from expenditure constraints.

The surtax not

withstanding, consumers were in a position to accommodate the
higher tax liabilities without cuts in spending levels.
The big problem, of course, was to project economic
conditions by year-end when policy decisions made now would be
taking hold, Mr. Bopp said.

But money market developments since

the last meeting gave the Committee additional time to wait and
see.

The July growth in the credit proxy and the money supply had

been well above the upper limit projected a month ago.
had fallen substantially more than expected.

Bill rates

For August a further

-73

8/13/68

substantial increase in the credit proxy was projected and, although
the expectation was for little

or no growth in

the money stock,

the annual rate of growth for the past several months would still
average over 6 per cent.

By most of the usual financial and

monetary indicators, considerable easing had already taken place.
As had been predicted by the Board staff, Mr. Bopp noted,
signs of weakening had been few in July.

Should more of those

signs begin to show up in August, four weeks from now would be
time enough to consider a positive move toward ease.

Granting the

dangers of a delayed recognition of, and reaction to, a significant
slowdown in the economy, he still believed those risks were out
weighed by the risk of further inflation with all its implications
for domestic and international stability.
Therefore, Mr. Bopp recommended alternative A as the
appropriate directive for the period until the next meeting of the
Committee.

He would delete the word "significantly" from the

second paragraph.
Mr. Kimbrel remarked that so far as the Sixth District was
concerned he found little in the economic indicators to suggest
that the widely predicted economic slowdown had yet started.
Employment, retail sales, and personal income continued to advance.
The outlook for crop production and livestock prices seemed favor
able.

District construction had been surprisingly strong.

Basic

-74

8/13/68

conditions in most housing markets had been and remained favorable
for further expansion even though at the present time there might
be a tendency to hold off a bit on making further commitments at
current money costs.
Those generalizations, of course, were based upon past
statistics, and statistics were always stale, Mr. Kimbrel said.
If he had not heard the discussion at the meeting of the Atlanta
Reserve Bank Board last Friday, he possibly could be convinced
that when statistics became available on the economic situation of
the present moment, they would reveal a change in the trends.

But

neither in the economic reports from the Branch Directors on the
current situations in their respective States nor from the general
discussion had he detected any suggestions that the Sixth District
was entering into a phase of declining activity.

He did hear a

great deal about price increases, both past and anticipated.
It

seemed to Mr. Kimbrel that any further monetary policy

easing could be justified at the present time only on the basis of
a possible slowdown to come and not on what was happening now.
The dangers of awaiting very definite evidence of a slowdown before
turning to an easier policy had been pointed out not only at meet
ings of the Committee but also in the press.

But if

there was a

danger of doing too little, too late, there was also a danger of
doing too much,
done so.

too soon.

He hoped that the System had not already

-75

8/13/68
Mr.

Kimbrel recalled that the Manager had rightly pointed

out at the last meeting of the Committee that firm predictions
could not be made about the relationship between the money market
variables and bank credit for the period just past.
difficult period in which to conduct operations.

It had been a

Nevertheless, as

others had suggested today, reserves and bank credit had expanded
more than the Committee had thought desirable and interest rates
had fallen more than it had anticipated.

He would hope, therefore,

that the Committee could agree at least to hold the line.
Mr. Kimbrel preferred alternative A of the directive drafts
but agreed that the word "significantly" should be deleted in the
second paragraph.

He shared Mr. Daane's feeling that the System

would have some difficulty in conveying the full significance of
a 1/4 point reduction in the discount rate.

At the same time, he

thought an early reduction of a larger size would be premature.
Mr. Francis remarked that total demand for goods and
services had continued to rise excessively and prices were advanc
ing at a 4 per cent annual rate.

Nevertheless, many analysts

seemed to be preoccupied with fear of a coming recession.

In his

judgment, the view that the recently adopted fiscal package would,
by itself, adequately restrict total demand and cure the inflationary
problems was overly optimistic.

Monetary actions had continued to

be excessively stimulative, negating the desirable anti-inflationary
impact of the fiscal package.

-76-

8/13/68

The nation's money stock had risen at a 7 per cent annual
rate since the first of the year, more than double the trend rate,
Mr. Francis observed.

References to the very rapid growth of

money in the second quarter usually noted that a reduction of
Treasury deposits in that period contributed to the high growth
rate of money.

Those references implied a subsequent increase of

Treasury deposits and a lower growth rate of money.
It was true, Mr. Francis said, that the movements of
Treasury deposits were a factor in the rapid monetary growth in
the second quarter and in the slower growth in July and early
August.

He would submit for the record a table showing the

determinants of the money supply in the second quarter and in the
first six months of the year.1/

Growth in the first quarter was

restrained as the Treasury built up its balances more than was
usual for that period.

Money then rapidly increased in the second

quarter as Treasury balances were drawn down.

If the excessive

growth of money from March through June was attributed to the
decline in Treasury balances, the substantially slower growth at
present might similarly be attributed to a rise in Treasury
balances.

Over the whole period since December, money had grown

at an excessive 7 per cent annual rate, and he considered that to
be the trend or effective rate up to the present time.

1/ The table referred to is appended to this memorandum as
Attachment B.

-77-

8/13/68

The greater concern about a possible recession than about
present and prospective inflation seemed unwarranted to Mr. Francis.
Projections of little real growth by the first quarter of 1969
appeared unduly low as judged by economic models which placed
significant weight on monetary variables.

But a lack of economic

growth might be desirable for a brief period as a necessary
accompaniment of reducing the intense inflationary pressures and
to set the stage for the tax reduction next July.

Unless total

demand during the coming year was sufficiently limited, there was
no hope of restricting the onward rush of prices.
Mr. Francis remarked that the Committee might receive some
guidance in formulating an appropriate monetary policy at a time
when fiscal policy was being changed significantly by reviewing an
earlier period when fiscal policy was approximately the same as

was now foreseen for fiscal 1969.

According to the Reserve Bank's

estimates, the high-employment budget was expected to shift from
about a $14 billion deficit in the first half of 1968 to about a
$10 billion surplus in the first half of 1969.

In the period from

1961 to mid-1965, the Federal Government also ran high-employment
surpluses averaging roughly $10 billion.

Despite that fiscal

stance, the early sixties were a period of generally rising total
demand and real production, declining unemployment, and relatively
mild price increases.

During that 1961 to 1965 period the money

-78

8/13/68

stock rose at a 3 per cent annual rate, and he felt that a rate of
increase of about 3 per cent was the best policy that the Committee
could adopt for the near future.
Mr. Francis said he did not question that interest rates
should be lower during the next year than they would have been if
the fiscal action of late June had not materalized.

But that did

not mean that the Committee should undertake to push them down any
further or any quicker than the supply and demand forces determined.
With respect to the U.S. international payments situation,
Mr. Francis felt it would be a mistake to undertake to push U.S.
interest rates down relative to those in other countries.

While

one must regret the inflation and the Federal deficits which had
contributed so much to the high U.S. interest rates, the rates had
become more consonant with those of other countries.

That benefit

should not be abandoned lightly.
Along that line, Mr. Francis thought it would be a mistake
to reduce discount rates at this time.

With the Federal funds

rate still at 6 per cent, a 5-1/2 per cent discount rate was none
too high.

With member bank borrowings from Reserve Banks amounting

to from $500 to $700 million, he saw no reason to invite an increase.
The discount rate should not be reduced with the idea that that
would be a signal affecting anticipations and forcing interest
rates down.

If the supply and demand forces called for lower

8/13/68

-79-

interest rates, they would come down anyway and that would be a
good time to reduce the discount rate.

If the forthcoming demand

and supply forces did not call for lower interest rates, then any
thing the Committee did to push them down would not avoid their
coming back up and would simply have contributed to inflationary
forces.
Mr. Robertson made the following statement:
It seems to me that a fair degree of ease--at least
relative ease--has developed in financial markets. This
is one of the expected consequences of the tax increase.
The position of banks has improved, in the sense that
they have more funds for lending and investing.
It
would appear that mutual savings banks and savings and
loan associations, too, are in a somewhat better posi
tion to expand mortgage commitments. And certainly the
Treasury has had little difficulty in marketing recent
issues.
As financial conditions have eased, so too have
prospects for economic activity become weaker. Thus,
the ease in financial markets not only averts what could
have been undue strains on various financial institutions
but also provides a basis for encouraging credit
demands--such as in the housing area--to keep economic
activity from slowing excessively. The principal
questipn at this meeting is whether we need even more
financial ease at this time.
My answer to that is that we should do our best to
hold what we have, while being sure to keep market
psychology from reversing itself, hopefully without
adding more and more to the growth of the money supply
and, if necessary, by using a reduction in the discount
rate. However, I would prefer not to move at this time
toward substantial further ease because it seems to me
that, while our staff is fearful of a sharp weakening
in economic activity, we do not yet have sufficient
evidence to establish that as the certain course of
events. Clearly there will be a slowdown, and some
slowdown is desirable.
But whether the slowdown will
tip us into a contraction of activity, or be in the
nature of a pause before we move into a period of more

-80-

8/13/68

I take
sustainable growth, requires further evidence.
the recent comparatively good performance of retail sales
to be on the hopeful side. Furthermore, the steel price
increases, even trimmed as they have been, suggest that
with us.
inflationary pressures are still
The July-August expansion in bank credit bothers me
as it does others. It was more than we anticipated.
It
would bother me more if I were not fairly sure that it
represented, in good part, an expectational or psychological
response of banks and Government securities dealers to
the changed financial atmosphere, rather than any basic
strength in credit demands.
In any event, I am glad that
it now appears that a more moderate bank credit expan
sion is in prospect for the period immediately ahead.
As to the directives before us, I would prefer one
that would be interpreted to mean that we should continue
to keep following down the gradual easing in over-all
money market conditions, without any overt action designed
to ease them further and faster, but with adequate
measures to ward off a reversal of the trend. Whether
this means "A" or "B" of the alternative drafts is imma
We should recognize, of course, that the
to me.
terial
various elements of money market conditions may, and
sometimes should, show shifting relationships; it is the
over-all picture that we should keep in mind.
The bank credit proviso should be included and be
two-way. Now that banks have recovered to their previous
level of outstanding CD's they may be less eager to
obtain such funds at a rapid rate.
If bank credit were
to expand less rapidly than projected, this might indicate
that basic credit demands were weakening further and
would signal to me that the Manager ought to let market
conditions ease further--and vice versa, if bank credit
were rising well above projections. However, I would be
much more hesitant to tighten market conditions than to
ease them, particularly if a larger than expected credit
expansion appears to represent mainly security invest
ments by banks as a counterpart to a return flow of time
and savings deposits.
Mr.

Robertson added that he would favor changes in

the

opening sentences of the first paragraph of the directive along the
lines of those proposed by Mr.

Coldwell.

He thought that with such

-81

8/13/68

changes the directive would more clearly reflect the sense of the
Committee regarding the economic outlook, rather than the staff's
forebodings.
Chairman Martin said he had been encouraged by the
Committee's discussion today.

Although the members were divided

in their views, the discussion had been thoughtful and highly
useful.

The problem of formulating appropriate monetary policy at

this juncture seemed to him to be an extremely difficult one.

In

his judgment the difficulties were largely traceable to the long
delay in introducing fiscal restraint and to the fact that monetary
policy had moved toward restraint too slowly.

He now thought that

the discount rate should have been raised to the current 5-1/2 per
cent level considerably earlier than it had been.
The Chairman remarked that July evidently was a good month
for business and he was not as pessimistic as the staff was about
the economic outlook for the rest of the year.

Nevertheless, he

thought that a correction at some point would have been inevitable
even if fiscal restraint had not been introduced.

While the cor

rection might be fairly sharp he would hope it would not be
extended.

As he had indicated at the previous meeting, the

objective should be disinflation without recession, but the line
between the two was admittedly fine.

-82

8/13/68

In general, Chairman Martin continued, he thought a move
ment toward a lower level of interest rates was desirable.

He was

as concerned as other members were about the high current rates of
growth of bank credit and other manifestations of crosscurrents.
But the System was faced with a technical market problem at the
moment; as a result of expectations of greater monetary ease, short
term interest rates had been forced down to a point at which the
discount rate was out of line.

The problem had been compounded by

the Treasury's decision not to include a short-term anchor issue
in its current refunding.

To a certain extent System officials,

including himself, might have contributed to the expectations that
had developed.

In the process of working hard for fiscal restraint,

both System and Administration officials might at times have over
stated the implications of fiscal restraint for interest rates.
If he were acting on his own, the Chairman said, he would
want to reduce the discount rate promptly to 5 per cent without
large injections of reserves.

He did not think Mr. Sherrill's

suggestion for a two-stage approach was feasible, given the state
of expectations.

Obviously, it was a matter of judgment as to

whether a 1/2 point cut in the discount rate would stabilize the
situation or whether it would create new expectations of another
1/2 point cut soon, but he personally would expect such an action
to have a stabilizing effect.

As to timing, unless the discount

-83

8/13/68

rate were reduced promptly there would be good arguments for
delaying action for a month or six weeks.

He did not think it

would be feasible to wait that long, however, in light of various
considerations, including the state of market psychology.
The Chairman concluded by saying that no one could be cer
tain of the most practical means for dealing with problems of
market psychology.

Perhaps it would be best for the Committee to

discuss the matter further at this point.

From the go-around it

appeared that a majority favored alternative A for the directive.
Mr. Galusha said it seemed to him--assuming that the upward
rate pressures of the last few days persisted--that it would be
necessary to begin injecting reserves in fairly significant volume
to get interest rates back down.

Accordingly, operations under

alternative A might be much like those that would be pursued under
alternative B.
Mr. Holmes remarked that, as he understood it, under
alternative B the Desk would be instructed to ease money market
conditions promptly in order to prevent a further rise in bill
rates, without waiting for evidence that the rise was occurring.
Under alternative A, however, there would be no move toward ease
unless bill rates moved up further--perhaps to the neighborhood of
5.20 per cent.

In that event, the Federal funds rate would be

brought closer to 6 per cent and, if the bill rate pressures

8/13/68

-84

continued, below that level.

It was possible that the money market

conditions that would then develop would be similar to those called
for under alternative B, but they would come about only if it
proved necessary to resist bill rate increases.

Such operations

would no doubt suggest to the market that the System did not want
rates to rise very much.

If bill rates subsequently came under

downward pressure, under alternative A the Committee presumably
would expect the Desk to let day-to-day money market rates move
back up again.
Mr. Galusha said he gathered that if alternative B were
adopted it would be expected that the bill rate would be pushed
below 5.10 per cent.

Assuming upward rate pressures continued,

that evidently would require overt action on a scale large enough
to create a climate of a substantial move toward ease, for which
there seemed to be little if any sentiment today.
Mr. Mitchell, referring to the Chairman's comments about
the discount rate, said that the market's expectations of a 1/2
point cut seemed to him to have an aura of unreality; such a move
by the System would be too much in too little time.

If the Com

mittee was going to focus on the bill rate and if the Chairman's
views on the need for a prompt discount rate reduction were
correct, he (Mr. Mitchell) would favor a cut of only 1/4 point.

-85-

8/13/68

Chairman Martin remarked that it was a matter of judgment
whether a 1/4 point reduction would not simply lead the market to
anticipate another similar step soon.
Mr. Mitchell agreed.

However, he said, with a 1/4 point

cut in the discount rate some market participants would undoubtedly
be under pressure to reduce positions they had built up in the
expectation of making profits on the basis of a 1/2 point cut.
Mr. Daane remarked that, as he had indicated earlier, he
would like to minimize reserve injections to the extent possible.
If a modest reduction in the level of net borrowed reserves would
keep the bill rate about where it was at present, he would prefer
that course to action on the discount rate.

Like Mr. Robertson,

he would be willing to lower the discount rate if necessary; but
he was not completely convinced that it was necessary at this
juncture.
Chairman Martin said that Mr. Daane's comment went to the
heart of the problem.

He also would prefer not to change the

discount rate, but he did not believe such a course was feasible.
As he had indicated, it was a matter of judgment.
Mr. Brimmer said he shared the Chairman's judgment and,
unlike Mr. Mitchell, he did not think a 1/4 point cut would
suffice.

For one thing, the market probably would not conclude

that that was as far as the System was prepared to go for the time

-86

8/13/68
being.

For another, it was clear that a lower structure of interest

rates would be required over the next year in view of the economic
outlook and that the discount rate would have to be reduced further
at some point.

He would favor a 1/2 point reduction now not only

on economic grounds but also to remove the System to the extent
possible from the arena of the public debate on economic policy
that probably lay ahead.

Accordingly, he hoped that the Committee

would agree today that open market operations

should assume a sup

porting role in the expectation that the Reserve Banks and the
Board would act to reduce the discount rate by 1/2 point.
Mr. Coldwell said he suspected that if the bill rate had
remained within the expected range in recent weeks rather than
declining sharply there would have been little sentiment today for
a 5 per cent discount rate.

He thought a 1/2 point reduction

would represent overreaction by the System to unexpected develop
ments that already were in process of correction.
Mr. Galusha remarked that while much of the discussion
today had focused on the bill rate, that rate was significant
mainly because it was viewed in the market as symptomatic of
Federal Reserve policy.

The basic problem for the System was that

posed by the large overhang of positions; and he believed that in
dealing with the problem the method that was likely to prove least
expensive in terms of reserve provision was a 1/2 point cut in the
discount rate.

-87-

8/13/68

Mr. Brill said he was concerned about the procedural
problem of interpreting the proviso clause when the assumptions
underlying the blue book projections of bank credit did not encom
pass policy actions subsequently decided upon.

Such a problem had

arisen in the recent interval in connection with the reduction in
the RP rate to 5-1/2 per cent, an action that had contributed
importantly to the market expectations that had depressed bill
rates and boosted bank credit growth.

Although it was by no means

certain that the staff would have correctly anticipated the effects
of that action on bank credit, the fact was that no allowance for
it had been made in the blue book.

He was concerned that the prob

lem of the appropriate interpretation of the proviso clause would
arise now if the discount rate were reduced by 1/4 or 1/2 point,
since no discount rate action had been assumed in making the latest
projections.

The problem would be more acute if the acceptable

range of variation around the projections was narrowed by deleting
the word "significantly" from the proviso clause.
Chairman Martin said that Mr. Brill had made a valid point.
The Chairman then noted that during the past week he had been
giving thought to the question Mr. Coldwell had raised today.

Were

it not for the circumstances that had arisen as a result of the
long delay in getting the needed fiscal and monetary restraint, he
would agree completely with Mr. Coldwell that for the System to

8/13/68

-88

cut the discount rate by 1/2 point now would be to overreact to an
unanticipated decline in interest rates.

But under the circumstances

actually prevailing, he thought the Desk would have great difficulty
in coping with the effects of shifting expectations unless the
discount rate were reduced.

A discount rate cut would not neces

sarily resolve the problem.

But he hoped it would reduce the

volume of reserves that would have to be injected and help stabilize
conditions in a period when interest rates were adapting to the
evolving economic situation.
Mr. Swan noted that the settlement date for the August
refunding was Thursday of this week.

While one could not be sure

how long the distribution process would take, even keel considera
tions would seem to militate against a discount rate change before
next week.
Chairman Martin remarked that the refunding was, of course,
a relevant matter.

In general, however, he thought the System

should not consider itself bound to maintain an even keel for any
specific number of days after the payment date in a financing.
Moreover, even keel considerations had a somewhat different
character when the policy change under consideration involved less
rather than more restraint.
Mr. Sherrill said his position was much closer to that of
the Chairman than his earlier remarks might have suggested.

Only

-89

8/13/68

if short-term rates started to move sharply downward again would
he be opposed to a discount rate reduction.
Mr. Bopp asked whether a reduction in the large inventories
of dealers would necessarily tend to lower the rate of bank credit
growth.
Mr. Maisel commented that liquidation of dealer positions
should tend to reduce outstanding bank credit to the extent the
securities were sold to non-bank investors who financed them by
means other than borrowing from banks.

The approach he favored

was to reduce the discount rate while supplying reserves at a pace
calculated to keep day-to-day money market rates relatively high,
in order to maintain pressure on dealers to reduce their inven
tories.

If the discount rate were not reduced, the dealers were

likely to conclude that they had been misled about the System's
policy intentions, and they might attempt to dump their inventories
on the market.

In the first case the liquidation would proceed in

an orderly fashion; in the second case it would not.
Mr. Mitchell expressed the view that a 1/2 point reduction
in the discount rate would lead dealers to expect lower financing
costs and encourage them to hold on to their inventories.
Mr. Holmes said that discount rate action would bring
about some fall in dealer financing costs but that dealers would
still have an incentive to sell if pressure was kept on day-to-day
rates.

-90

8/13/68

Mr. Daane remarked that while he thought the discount rate
should be reduced if necessary, he saw some real risks in moving
too quickly.

He asked whether the Manager thought it was clear

that the discount rate would have to be reduced before the
September 10 meeting of the Committee if a massive injection of
reserves was to be avoided.
Mr. Holmes said that it was likely to be quite difficult
through open market operations to lower day-to-day rates enough
to keep dealers from wanting to dump their inventories and to
maintain their willingness to engage in two-way trading.

He would

not want to say it was an impossible task; but clearly from a
technical point of view somewhat lower dealer lending and Federal
funds rates would make the task of open market operations much
easier in the month ahead.

The objective presumably was to get

dealer inventories down but in an orderly fashion.

In the event

of a change in the discount rate, the Desk could resist any overly
rapid decline in interest rates if expectations of still further
discount rate reductions developed.
In reply to questions by Mr. Mitchell, Mr. Holmes said
that dealer positions had nearly doubled in the past month.
Dealers had made very good progress through last Friday in distrib
uting the new 6-year notes, but he suspected that that process had
slowed down yesterday.

Dealers were more than willing to reduce

-91

8/13/68

their inventories; the problem was that buyers were holding back.
He agreed with Mr. Mitchell that lower day-to-day rates would
reduce the incentive for dealers to draw down their positions, but
thought that many nevertheless would probably be willing to take
presently available profits.

If day-to-day rates remained high,

the effect of dealer efforts to unload would be to push rates up
rapidly.
Mr. Brimmer commented that in his conversations with market
participants over the last few weeks he had not detected a general
expectation that the System planned to dismantle monetary restraint
rapidly.

The expectation, rather, was that the move toward ease

would be gradual.

He asked whether the Manager had the same impres

sion.
Mr. Holmes replied that he had heard various views.

Some

observers expected the System to ease quickly; others were convinced
that some measure of restraint would be retained.
Mr. Robertson remarked that the recent run-up in speculative
positions suggested that the former view was widespread.
Mr. Swan commented that the materials recently released in
connection with the System's study of the discount mechanism had
emphasized the desirability of smaller and more frequent changes
in the discount rate.

Against that background, a 1/2 point cut in

-92

8/13/68

the discount rate now would be particularly likely to be interpreted
as a major step toward ease rather than a moderate move.
Mr. Daane remarked that the magnitude of the reaction to
the 1/8 point reduction in the RP rate suggested that a 1/2 point
cut in the discount rate was hardly likely to be dismissed as a
technical move.
Mr. Brimmer said he did not think the Committee had intended
the cut in the RP rate to be interpreted as a purely technical
move.
action.

Rather, it was expected to be viewed as a "mini-policy"
In his judgment a 1/2 point reduction in the discount rate

could be considered as a moderate move in the existing environment.
Chairman Martin noted that no Reserve Bank had acted thus
far to change the discount rate.

He suggested that the Committee

move on to the matter of the directive, on the understanding that
the Board would stand ready to review any discount rate actions
Reserve Banks might take.

He then asked whether the Secretary had

directive language to propose in light of the comments made today
on the staff's drafts.
Mr. Holland remarked that, as recommended by Mr. Coldwell,
the word "suggests" in the opening sentence of the first paragraph
might be replaced by "indicates."

With respect to the second

sentence, the problem at which Mr. Coldwell's proposed revision
was directed--that the outlook described reflected staff projections

8/13/68

-93

about the likelihood of which Committee members had varying viewsmight be dealt with most simply by modifying the language to read,
"Expansion in over-all activity, however, is projected to slow
considerably in coming months . . . ."

As to the second paragraph,

the consensus appeared to be for alternative A with the word
"significantly" deleted from the proviso clause.

The specifications

associated with the second paragraph presumably would be those
given for alternative A in the blue book, including those provid
ing for somewhat lower day-to-day rates and net borrowed reserves
if bill rates remained under upward pressure.

It was also his

presumption that the Committee would want to reconsider the
directive if changes were made in Reserve Bank discount rates.
Mr. Hickman noted that the directive would call for firming
if the credit proxy appeared to be exceeding the rate projected
in the blue book.
Mr. Maisel remarked that he did not think such a directive
would serve for the full period until the September 10 meeting of
the Committee,

particularly if

the proviso clause.

firming action was required under

It was his hope that discount rate action

would be taken within a few days, and that the Committee would
revise the directive promptly thereafter.
Mr. Robertson said he thought it would be a mistake to
delete the word "significantly" from the proviso clause.

Such a

8/13/68

-94-

qualification customarily had been included to permit small devia
tions from the projections before implementing the proviso, and he
thought it would be appropriate to permit such deviations now.
After several members had expressed similar views,

it was

agreed that the word "significantly" should be retained.
By unanimous vote, the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York was
authorized and directed, until other
wise directed by the Committee, to
execute transactions in the System
Account in accordance with the following
current economic policy directive:
The information reviewed at this meeting indicates
that some elements of economic activity continued to
Expansion in over
expand vigorously in early summer.
all activity, however, is projected to slow considerably
in coming months as a result of the new fiscal restraint
measures and a marked reduction in inventory accumulation.
Industrial prices have been increasing less rapidly in
recent months, but consumer prices have continued to rise
substantially. Wage pressures remain strong, and the
recent wage settlement in the steel industry was followed
by announcements of steel price increases. Both short
and long-term interest rates have declined considerably,
in large part as a result of expectations of easier
credit conditions.
Bank time and savings deposits,
particularly large-denomination CD's, have expanded
sharply in early summer; growth in the money supply has
continued large as U.S. Government deposits have been
drawn down further on average; and growth in total bank
credit has been unusually rapid. Although the U.S.
balance of payments has recently shown a marked improvement,
the foreign trade balance and underlying payments position
continue to be matters of serious concern. In this
situation, it is the policy of the Federal Open Market
Committee to foster financial conditions conducive to
sustainable economic growth, continued resistance to
inflationary pressures, and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's balance of payments.

8/13/68

-95

To implement this policy, System open market opera
tions until the next meeting of the Committee shall be
conducted with a view to maintaining, on balance, about
the prevailing conditions in money and short-term credit
markets; provided, however, that operations shall be
modified if bank credit appears to be significantly
exceeding current projections.
Chairman Martin then noted that memoranda from the Account
Manager and from the Secretariat, both entitled "System lending of
U.S. Government securities," had been distributed to the Committee
on August 6 and 7, respectively.1/

He asked Mr. Holmes to comment.

Mr. Holmes observed that on July 11, 1967, in a paper
captioned "Policy Issues #4,"

the Steering Committee of the

Treasury-Federal Reserve Study of the Government Securities Market
had recommended adoption of a proposal for System lending of
portions of its holdings of U.S. Government securities to dealers
and to nondealer banks participating in the clearing arrangement
operated by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

That proposal

had been scheduled for discussion at the Committee meeting of
September 12, 1967, but had been held over to provide more
opportunity for study by Committee Counsel.

On July 10, 1968,

there had been distributed a memorandum from the Committee's
Counsel entitled "Legality of plan for lending of Government
securities by Federal Reserve Banks," in which Mr. Hackley expressed

1/ Copies of these documents and those subsequently referred
to by Mr. Holmes have been placed in the Committee's files.

-96

8/13/68

the opinion that "it is doubtful whether the Reserve Banks have
authority under the law to lend Government securities in the manner
proposed."

Attached to Mr. Hackley's memorandum was a memorandum

prepared by Mr. Sloane, Assistant General Counsel at the New York
Reserve Bank, which concluded that Federal Reserve Banks "are
authorized to lend securities in aid of open market operations."
Thus, Mr. Holmes continued, the Committee had before it
two opinions.

He obviously was not qualified to comment on the

legal questions, and would hope that Mr. Hackley would do so.

He

could report that after a further review last month, the Steering
Committee had unanimously concluded that the legal questions were
not sufficiently serious to make undesirable Committee considera
tion of the proposal on its merits.

The Steering Committee had

also reaffirmed its earlier position that the proposal would offer
advantages to the market and hence to the System and the Treasury.
Mr. Holmes went on to say that the two purposes for which
it was contemplated that System securities would be lent were to
enable dealers to avoid delivery failures and to facilitate the
securities clearing arrangement of the New York Federal Reserve
Bank.

It was expected that most of the lending activity would

arise in connection with the first purpose and that there would be
only a negligible amount in connection with the clearing arrangement.

8/13/68

-97
His memorandum of August 6 concluded with two recommenda

tions, Mr. Holmes observed.

The first was that the Committee

amend the continuing authority directive to authorize lending of
securities from the System Open Market Account under terms and
conditions to be established from time to time by the Committee.
The Secretariat's memorandum of August 7 proposed a specific
amendment to the directive for consideration by the Committee if
it approved that recommendation.

His second recommendation was

that the Committee establish the terms and conditions outlined in
his memorandum as those under which the System would lend Govern
ment securities, on the understanding that any substantial changes
that might be indicated by discussions with dealers would be submitted
for the consideration of the Committee.

The dollar limits included

among the recommended terms and conditions were clearly experimental,
and he might want to propose changes in them at a later time.
Mr. Holmes noted that there were three attachments to his
August 6 memorandum:

a draft of a letter for Mr. Hayes'

to the Presidents of the other Federal Reserve Banks,

signature

requesting

that they authorize the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to lend
securities from the System Open Market Account in accordance with
the directions of the Open Market Committee; and two proposed forms
of contracts--for lending securities overnight and for lending

8/13/68

-98

securities for more than one day.

He would propose one change in

the draft of the letter from Mr. Hayes, to delete the words "equal
or" from the sentence reading "Loans of Government securities would
be secured by Government securities of equal or greater market
value."

In response to the Chairman's request for comment, Mr. Hackley
said it was quite obvious that the legal questions were debatable.
Basically, he had concluded that it was doubtful whether the Reserve
Banks had incidental powers to lend Government securities in the
manner proposed because it did not seem at all clear to him that
that activity was reasonably necessary for carrying out their
express powers.

He had great difficulty with the argument that

the Reserve Banks had legal authority to engage in any activity
not prohibited by law that would aid in the discharge of their
statutory responsibilities.

On the basis of that argument, it

would not have been necessary for the Board to recommend legisla
tion specifically authorizing the Reserve Banks to invest foreign
currency balances in foreign Government securities, but the Board
had so recommended.
Mr. Hackley added that he had reviewed the several documents
to which Mr. Holmes had referred and concluded that if the Committee
approved the proposal those documents would be adequate from the
legal point of view.

It might be well, however, to make clear that

8/13/68

-99

the securities to be lent would not be those required to be held
as collateral against Federal Reserve notes.
Mr. Holmes agreed that that point should be clarified.
Chairman Martin commented that the matter under discussion
was an important one.

While the Steering Committee had recommended

favorable action, a decision could be postponed until a later
meeting if the Committee members thought that would be desirable.
Mr. Mitchell noted that the proposal had been pending for
over a year.

He would be prepared to vote favorably on it today.

Mr. Brimmer remarked that the Steering Committee's favor
able recommendation would carry great weight in his thinking.
Mr. Bopp said he thought there were real hazards in proceed
ing on the assumption that the proposed activity was authorized
under the System's incidental powers.

He would prefer to seek

specific enabling legislation.
Mr. Hickman said he would like to have the matter held
over so that he could have an opportunity to discuss the legal
questions with the general counsel of his Bank.
Mr. Heflin remarked that he concurred in Mr. Hackley's
views on the question.
It was then agreed that the Manager's recommendations
regarding System lending of Government securities should be considered
further at a later meeting of the Committee.

8/13/68

-100
It was agreed the next meeting of the Committee would be

held on September 10, 1968, at 9:30 a.m.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

ATTACHMENT A
August 12, 1968
Drafts of Current Economic Policy Directive for Consideration by the
Federal Open Market Committee at its Meeting on August 13, 1968

FIRST PARAGRAPH
The information reviewed at this meeting suggests that
some elements of economic activity continued to expand vigorously
in early summer. Expansion in over-all activity, however, is
likely to slow considerably in coming months as a result of the
new fiscal restraint measures and a marked reduction in inventory
accumulation. Industrial prices have been increasing less rapidly
in recent months, but consumer prices have continued to rise
substantially. Wage pressures remain strong, and the recent wage
settlement in the steel industry was followed by announcements of
steel price increases. Both short- and long-term interest rates
have declined considerably, in large part as a result of expecta
tions of easier credit conditions. Bank time and savings deposits,
particularly large-denomination CD's, have expanded sharply in
early summer; growth in the money supply has continued large as
U.S. Government deposits have been drawn down further on average;
and growth in total bank credit has been unusually rapid.
Although the U.S. balance of payments has recently shown a marked
improvement, the foreign trade balance and underlying payments
position continue to be matters of serious concern. In this
situation, it is the policy of the Federal Open Market Committee
to foster financial conditions conducive to sustainable economic
growth, continued resistance to inflationary pressures, and
attainment of reasonable equilibrium in the country's balance of
payments.

SECOND PARAGRAPH
Alternative A
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a
view to maintaining, on balance, about the prevailing conditions
in money and short-term credit markets; provided, however, that
operations shall be modified if bank credit appears to be
significantly exceeding current projections.

-2
Alternative B
To implement this policy, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with a
view to attaining somewhat less firm conditions in the money market;
provided, however, that operations shall be modified if bank credit
appears to be significantly exceeding current projections.

CONTRIBUTION OF "PROXIMATE" DETERMINANTS TO
RATES OF CHANGE IN THE MONEY SUPPLY
Monthly Averages of Daily Figures - Seasonally Adjusted

Dec. 1967
June 1968

ATTACHMENT B

Annual Rate of Change in Money Stock '_
Dec. 1967
Mar. 1968
Mar. 1968
June :968

1. Banking System

Borrowing from Reserve Banks

3.4

Excess Reserves
Bank Structure I

0.5
1.1

Other Banking 2 /
Total Banking

-

0.5
4.5

8.5

-

2.1

1.7
2,4

-

0.7
0.2

0.2
9.4

-

0. 6
1.0

-

2. Public
Currency Held
Time Deposits at Member Banks
Total Public

-

3. Government
Demand Deposits at Member Banks
4. Other Reserve Factors-5.

Total of 1, 2,

3, and 4

Total Federal Reserve
7. Rate

of Change in Money Stock

-

9.1
0.8
9.9

2.0

-

1. 7

-

6.0

-

9.8

6. Federal Reserve
Federal Reserve Portfolio
Reserve Requirement Changes

9.9
0.4
10.3

-

5.3

-

5.6

9.7

-

1.9

11.9

-

8.2

27.2

22.0
-

10.8
0.1
10.9

10.5

16.8
0. 0

16.7

16.7

16.8

6.9

4. 8

8.6

1/ Shifts in deposits among classes of member banks.
Z/ Net of member bank demand balances "due to" and "due from" banks, and nonmember bank demand deposit
component of money.
determining total member bank reserves other than Federal Reserve Holdings of U.S. Government
Factors
3/
securities, member bank borrowing from Reserve Banks, and currency held by the public.
June data are preliminary.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
August 9, 1968