View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

August 11–12, 2009

1 of 165

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on 

August 11–12, 2009 

A joint meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee and Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System was held in the offices of the Board of Governors in Washington, D.C.,
on Tuesday, August 11, 2009, at 2:00 p.m., and continued on Wednesday August 12, 2009, at
9:00 a.m. Those present were the following:
Mr. Bernanke, Chairman 

Mr. Dudley, Vice Chairman 

Ms. Duke 

Mr. Evans 

Mr. Kohn 

Mr. Lacker 

Mr. Lockhart 

Mr. Tarullo

Mr. Warsh 

Ms. Yellen

Mr. Bullard, Ms. Cumming, Mr. Hoenig, Ms. Pianalto, and Mr. Rosengren, Alternate
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Fisher, Plosser, and Stern, Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks of Dallas,
Philadelphia, and Minneapolis, respectively
Mr. Madigan, Secretary and Economist 

Ms. Danker, Deputy Secretary 

Mr. Luecke, Assistant Secretary

Mr. Skidmore, Assistant Secretary

Ms. Smith, Assistant Secretary

Mr. Alvarez, General Counsel 

Mr. Baxter,¹ Deputy General Counsel 

Mr. Sheets, Economist 

Mr. Stockton, Economist 

Messrs. Altig, Clouse, Connors, Slifman, Sullivan, and Wilcox, Associate Economists
Mr. Sack, Manager, System Open Market Account
Ms. Johnson, Secretary of the Board, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors
Ms. George, Acting Director, Division of Banking Supervision and Regulation, Board of
Governors
Mr. Frierson,¹ Deputy Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors
_______________
¹ Attended Tuesday’s session only.

August 11–12, 2009

2 of 165

Mr. Struckmeyer, Deputy Staff Director, Office of the Staff Director for Management,
Board of Governors
Mr. English, Deputy Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Ms. Robertson, Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors
Ms. Liang, Messrs. Reifschneider, and Wascher, Senior Associate Directors, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Mr. Meyer, Senior Adviser, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Messrs. Leahy and Nelson,¹ Associate Directors, Divisions of International Finance and
Monetary Affairs, respectively, Board of Governors
Mr. Carpenter, Deputy Associate Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Mr. Small, Project Manager, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Ms. Wei, Economist, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Ms. Beattie,¹ Assistant to the Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors
Ms. Low, Open Market Secretariat Specialist, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Mr. Lyon, First Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Mr. Sniderman, Executive Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Mr. McAndrews,¹ Ms. McLaughlin, Messrs. Rudebusch, Sellon, Tootell, and Waller,
Senior Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of New York, New York, San Francisco,
Kansas City, Boston, and St. Louis, respectively
Messrs. Burke, Dotsey, Koenig, and Pesenti, Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of
New York, Philadelphia, Dallas, and New York, respectively
Mr. Weber, Senior Research Officer, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Mr. Hetzel, Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

_______________
¹ Attended Tuesday’s session only.

August 11–12, 2009

3 of 165

Transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee Meeting on 

August 11-12, 2009 

August 11—Afternoon Session

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good afternoon, everybody. Today is the last meeting for
our colleague Gary Stern. Gary first attended the FOMC meeting as a staffer in 1982 and then
was appointed President in March 1985. To provide some cultural context, in 1982 the top
grossing movie was “An Officer and a Gentleman,” followed closely by “Tootsie.” [Laughter.]
The leading hit song was “Physical” by Olivia Newton-John. [Laughter.] We are in a different
world, I think. Gary, you have attended 218 regular FOMC meetings, so you are the most senior
member of this Committee by a small margin of six years. That is a remarkable record, and you
have provided a great deal of collegiality, insight, and wisdom over that period, and we want to
thank you for that. But we will thank you in more substantial way at the September meeting. So
thank you. [Applause]
As has been our custom, this is a joint Board–FOMC meeting. So I need a motion to
close the meeting.
MR. KOHN. So moved.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. We’ll begin with staff presentations—first,
with open market operations by Brian Sack, followed by Q&A, and then some additional
presentations. Brian.
MR. SACK.1 Thank you. I should start with a warning that I’m going to talk for
a pretty long time. I apologize in advance. Prices of risky assets have continued to
recover at an impressive pace, boosted by a more optimistic assessment of economic
prospects and by favorable news on corporate earnings. The advance in equity prices,
shown in the top left panel of the first exhibit, was particularly sharp, with broad
indexes up 12 percent to 15 percent since the last FOMC meeting. Equity prices were
supported by sizable second-quarter earnings surprises that spanned a range of
sectors. As shown in the top right, over three-quarters of S&P 500 companies posted
1

The materials used by Mr. Sack are appended to this transcript (appendix 1).

August 11–12, 2009

4 of 165

positive earnings surprises in the quarter—about the highest percentage observed over
the past fifteen years. At the same time, investors continued to become more
optimistic about economic prospects. The responses to our dealer survey indicated
that market participants raised their forecasts for second-half growth and saw fewer
downside risks to those forecasts.
Given the news on earnings and the economy, investors’ perceptions of risk
declined further, as indicated by the drop in the implied volatility of equity prices, the
middle left panel. Corresponding with that shift, investors showed a greater
willingness to hold risky assets. Retail investors, for example, have been reallocating
large amounts of capital out of the safest asset classes, such as money market mutual
funds, as shown in the middle right panel. That capital appears to be making its way
into a range of riskier asset classes, including equity and fixed-income funds both
here and abroad.
Given this shift in risk appetite, corporate bond spreads continued to narrow
sharply, as shown in the bottom left panel, with the spread on the investment-grade
index declining about 75 basis points and that on the high-yield index declining
nearly 250 basis points since the last meeting. Other risky asset classes, such as
emerging-market debt and stocks, have also benefited.
The panel to the right suggests that the dollar has also been strongly influenced by
shifts in investor risk appetite. In particular, there has been a tight relationship
between the dollar and risky asset prices, here captured by an emerging-market equity
index, with the dollar appreciating last fall as investors attempted to move into safe
assets and depreciating more recently as risk appetite returned. On net, the dollar has
fallen 1 percent to 2 percent on a broad, trade-weighted basis over the intermeeting
period.
The increased optimism about the economic outlook has coincided with favorable
developments in the financial sector. Share prices of large financial institutions rose
substantially, as shown in the top left panel of exhibit 2, in response to robust
earnings reports. Those earnings were fueled by strong profits in trading and
investment banking activity. The durability of those sources of revenue is
questionable, but that did not seem to trouble investors.
Earnings results for smaller and regional financial institutions were not as strong.
Those institutions benefited little from the robust trading gains that helped large
firms. Moreover, some regional banks posted greater-than-expected loan loss
provisions for consumer loans, and many of them have considerable exposure to
commercial real estate and construction loans. Despite those hurdles, regional banks
managed to meet their earnings expectations on average, and their share prices
performed as well as those of larger firms over the intermeeting period.
The difficulties at CIT that surfaced in mid-July highlighted the fact that financial
institutions can still run into difficulties. Nevertheless, financial markets continued to

August 11–12, 2009

5 of 165

function well throughout that episode. Moreover, investors’ perceptions of
counterparty risk in the financial sector improved notably over the intermeeting
period. CDS spreads for major financial institutions moved lower, by 50 to 200 basis
points in most cases, as shown in the top right. Moreover, the spread of LIBOR over
the OIS rate, the middle left, continued to shrink, with the three-month spread falling
below 30 basis points. At those maturities shown, spreads have reached levels that
many thought would constitute the post-crisis normal. Longer-term spreads,
however, still remain elevated.
One hurdle that the financial sector faces going forward is the expiration of the
FDIC’s temporary liquidity guarantee program (or TLGP) on October 31. The TLGP
has allowed financial institutions to issue debt at a much lower cost than they would
have otherwise paid, as indicated in the middle right panel. Financial firms currently
have $330 billion of outstanding debt under the program, with maturities out to three
years. As that debt matures and has to be rolled over into new securities, these firms
will likely face higher financing costs. However, given that the maturity of that debt
is spread out and that firms have been making efforts to reduce their reliance on the
program, market participants do not currently anticipate any problems around its
termination.
This argument raises a broader point to be considered. While money markets and
financial markets more broadly have healed to a great degree, the improvement has
been conditioned on a number of government support programs—many of which are
scheduled to expire over the next six months. Over the period between now and
February 1, in chronological order, the markets will need to digest the end of the
Treasury’s money market guarantee program, the FDIC’s TLGP, the Fed’s largescale asset-purchase (LSAP) program in Treasuries, the Fed’s MMIFF, the Treasury’s
purchases of agency MBS, the Fed’s LSAP programs in agency debt and MBS, the
Treasury’s credit facility for the GSEs (or GSECF), the Fed’s CPFF, AMLF, PDCF,
and TSLF, and potentially the Treasury’s TARP authority. The good news is that we
will all benefit from some much-needed acronym relief; [laughter] the bad news is
that there are many risks involved. The expiration of any one of these programs
individually seems manageable, but it is more challenging to judge the effects of
removing them all together. That is one reason that we want to continue to monitor
markets closely with this in mind.
As shown in the bottom panels, securitized credit markets also improved over the
intermeeting period. Here the story very directly involves the effects from
government programs aimed at supporting those markets. The consumer ABS market
has made considerable strides in the right direction. ABS spreads narrowed further,
as shown to the left, and new issuance continued at a decent clip. These
developments have been driven importantly by the ongoing support from the TALF
facility. The July and August TALF subscriptions for ABS involved about
$21 billion of TALF-eligible issuance, of which about $12 billion was financed
through the facility. Improvements in the CMBS market have generally been slower,
but the market has reacted favorably to recent news about the inclusion of CMBS in

August 11–12, 2009

6 of 165

the TALF program and in the Treasury’s PPIP program. As shown to the right,
CMBS spreads have narrowed significantly since the last FOMC meeting. However,
spreads are still very wide by historical standards, and there has been no new
issuance. With commercial real estate prices falling, delinquencies rising, and
considerable amounts of CMBS coming due through 2012, this sector is likely to face
considerable pressure for some time.
As shown in the next exhibit, the positive sentiment reflected in recent asset-price
movements put upward pressure on Treasury yields. However, the changes were
fairly modest, with coupon yields moving up 5 to 15 basis points, on net, over the
intermeeting period. The market’s expectations for monetary policy steepened a
touch, as reflected in the rates on federal funds and Eurodollar futures contracts,
shown to the right.
Our dealer survey helps to shed some more light on these policy expectations.
The middle panels show the distribution of outcomes for the federal funds rate that
are perceived by the respondents for horizons of 12 months ahead (to the left) and
18 months ahead (to the right). As can be seen, the modal forecast is for the federal
funds rate to remain unchanged at the 0 to 25 basis point range, even at that longer
horizon. However, one feature of being at the zero bound is that the risks tend to be
skewed in only one direction. The distributions show that respondents see some
probability of higher rates, with that probability building as the horizon extends
through 2010. This skewed risk profile has presumably pulled the futures rates up
relative to what is perceived to be the most likely outcome. Overall, investors
apparently expect that the recovery will be anemic enough to allow the Fed to keep
policy rates low well into 2010—a view that has been supported by FOMC
communications.
Even though it is seen as still being a way off, market participants also focused on
whether the Fed will face any difficulties exiting from its accommodative policy
stance. Investors reportedly took some comfort from Chairman Bernanke’s op-ed
piece in the Wall Street Journal and his monetary policy testimony on July 21. This
subject was also addressed by several other FOMC members over the intermeeting
period, with market participants taking note of the consistency of the message. The
discussion of exit is presumably aimed, in part, at keeping longer-term inflation
expectations anchored. As shown in the bottom left panel, measures of the five-year
five-year-forward breakeven inflation rate rose over the intermeeting period and are
near the upper end of the range seen over the past several years. Our interpretation of
the level of the breakeven rate is the same as it was at the last meeting—that it has
moved up to levels that, while not alarming, show more balance in the perceived risks
around the inflation outlook. As shown to the right, our dealer survey indicates that
the perceived likelihood of CPI inflation from five to ten years ahead is the highest in
the buckets from 1.5 percent to 2.5 percent—levels that are consistent with the long­
term inflation projections of most FOMC members.

August 11–12, 2009

7 of 165

The next exhibit focuses on the Fed’s large-scale asset-purchase programs. As
shown in the top left panel, purchases in those programs have continued at a fairly
robust monthly pace, though for each asset type the pace has slowed a touch. For
Treasuries, the slowing was intended to put the Desk on a trajectory to complete the
$300 billion of purchases in September. For agency securities and MBS, the slowing
was driven by market conditions and concerns that a faster pace of purchases would
risk some market disruption.
In the Treasury market, there are no signs that our purchase program is having
detrimental effects on market functioning. As shown in the top right panel, the
amount of dispersion in Treasury yields around our smoothed yield curve has
diminished sharply from the very elevated levels that were seen late last year. This
improvement suggests that market participants have been increasingly willing and
able to engage in arbitrage, limiting the difference in yields across securities with
similar characteristics. The improvement was also likely driven by the Fed’s
participation in the market, as the Desk has often purchased less-liquid securities that
were trading at yields well above the smoothed yield curve. As shown in the middle
left, trading volume in the Treasury market stabilized and began to pick up in recent
months. Moreover, bid–asked spreads ticked down for both repo and outright
transactions in recent months. Given these improvements in market functioning and
the fact that our purchases are not disproportionately large in that market, we
anticipate that there will be no significant disruption by the approaching winding
down of the Fed’s purchases of Treasury securities. As shown to the right, our
Treasury purchases, while certainly sizable, are not overwhelming the market. The
scheduled total purchases for the program will constitute about 8 percent of the
outstanding stock of Treasuries and 39 percent of the expected net issuance.
As you know, the story is quite different for the purchases of agency debt and
MBS. For MBS, scheduled Fed purchases will take up 28 percent of the outstanding
stock of securities and more than three times the amount of net issuance. Our
purchases represent even larger shares for the agency debt market. Given these sizes,
the impact of the Desk’s purchases has been considerable in the agency and MBS
markets. As shown in the bottom left panel, those purchases have contributed to a
dramatic decline in the option-adjusted spread of MBS to Treasury securities. That
spread has reached negative territory—an anomaly by historical standards. The
compression of the MBS spread and the associated pressures on the functioning of the
MBS market make the exit from this program trickier than is the case for the Treasury
program. Some options for winding down the purchase programs will be discussed at
the end of my briefing.
In terms of economic effects, the MBS spread compression has strongly
contributed to the FOMC’s objective of providing stimulus to the economy. As
shown in the figure, the narrowing of the MBS spread has passed through to some
degree to the conforming-mortgage spread, which has declined to around 175 basis
points—near its historical norm. That, in turn, has kept primary mortgage rates lower
and supported housing activity. It may be difficult or problematic for the Desk to

August 11–12, 2009

8 of 165

collapse MBS spreads any further. Thus, it is worth considering why conformingmortgage spreads have only retraced to their historical norm and not further. There
are two factors in play. First, the prepayment option that is afforded to households in
their mortgages is very costly today. That is, the option adjustment in computing the
option-adjusted spread for MBS is unusually large, mostly because long-term interest
rate volatility has been very elevated. Second, but less important, the primary–
secondary mortgage spread still remains somewhat elevated. This likely reflects the
reduction in the number of originators and the tighter credit conditions for
warehousing those loans until securitization. Even with these impediments, the
compression of the conforming-mortgage spread has far outpaced that for other
mortgage products, such as adjustable-rate mortgages. As can be seen in the chart to
the right, while the ARM spread has come off its peak, the improvement in this
spread has been much more limited than is the case for fixed-rate mortgages. This
difference likely reflects the fact that, while the fixed-rate mortgage market has
benefited appreciably from the Federal Reserve’s MBS purchase program, the
adjustable-rate mortgage market has not. I will return to this issue and potential
changes to the Desk’s outright purchases of MBS at the end of my briefing.
The ongoing purchase of assets has, by itself, continued to add to the size of the
Fed’s balance sheet. As shown by the blue area in the top left panel of the last
exhibit, outright securities holdings associated with those programs expanded to
about $880 billion—about halfway toward the specified limit of $1.75 trillion. In
contrast to this ongoing expansion, the Fed’s liquidity programs continue to shrink, as
shown by the orange area in the chart. This pattern largely reflects the substantial
improvement in money markets that was discussed above, which has made these
programs increasingly unattractive to users. Overall, summing across these
programs, the total size of the liquidity facilities has declined more than $1 trillion
from its peak earlier this year. This decline has just about offset the expansion of
asset holdings in recent quarters, keeping the overall size of the balance sheet near the
$2 trillion mark. Nevertheless, as shown in the table, we expect the balance sheet to
begin to grow again going forward, as the steady rise in asset holdings and the
ongoing expansion of the TALF will begin to outpace the declines in liquidity
programs. We currently project that, absent any policy changes, the balance sheet
will reach a peak of just over $2.6 trillion by early 2010, after which it will begin to
decline gradually.
That concludes my summary of recent developments in financial markets and
Desk operations. I will now turn to two specific issues regarding Desk operations
going forward. The first issue is whether to include mortgage-backed securities
backed by ARMs in the large-scale asset-purchase program. A memo was circulated
to you describing the arguments for and against a shift in this direction and
recommending a specific structure for those purchases if the FOMC were to decide to
move forward. I will briefly review the main points from the memo.
The case for including ARMs rests primarily on the fact that they are currently an
expensive form of mortgage finance for households relative to fixed-rate mortgages.

August 11–12, 2009

9 of 165

As shown earlier, the Fed’s MBS purchases seem to have depressed the rates on
fixed-rate mortgages, whereas the rates on ARMs have instead remained high in
comparison. Given that they are relatively expensive, the use of ARMs has come to a
near stand-still. Including ARMs in the asset-purchase program might be seen as
beneficial for several reasons. First, given that their spreads remain wide, purchasing
ARMs-related securities might achieve a considerable improvement in their pricing
and hence might provide more economic stimulus than using those same funds to
purchase fixed-rate mortgages. Second, it would eliminate the distortion that the Fed
has created in households’ decisions between what mortgage product best suits their
needs. Third, it would help the Desk to achieve the $1.25 trillion of MBS purchases
while, at the margin, taking some pressure off the fixed-rate MBS purchases. And
fourth, because ARMs have lower duration than fixed-rate mortgages, it would
reduce some of the interest-rate and income risk in the SOMA portfolio.
However, there are also some counterarguments to consider. First, any
reallocation to ARMs, because it would come out of the total allocation of MBS
purchases, could reduce the effect of the fixed-rate MBS purchases. Second, it could
involve certain political and reputational risks. In particular, ARMs carry some
stigma given their association with the recent housing and financial crisis, and Fed
purchases may be seen as an endorsement of this product. Third, encouraging
households to move into ARMs may subsequently present an awkward situation
when the FOMC begins to raise short-term interest rates. Fourth, the ARM market is
less liquid and less transparent than the fixed-rate MBS market, which raises some
complications in the trading process and requires even more extensive reliance on
external investment managers. And fifth, given the size of the ARM market, the
magnitude of potential purchases is limited.
If the FOMC decides to move in this direction, the Desk recommends a program
that would include 3/1, 5/1, 7/1, and 10/1 hybrid ARMs backed by Fannie Mae,
Freddie Mac, and Ginnie Mae. The majority of purchases would be expected to take
place at the 5/1 sector, which has the largest amount of outstanding securities.
Purchases would include both newly issued and existing ARMs and would exclude
interest-only ARMs. The program would start with a targeted amount of $25 billion
in purchases, to be conducted over the remainder of the asset-purchase program,
although the pace and eventual size of the program would be adjusted in response to
market conditions. This allocation would come out of the $1.25 trillion total amount
of MBS purchases. These are the broad principles that the Desk proposes for guiding
ARMs purchases. Actual implementation will also require the Desk to make a
number of decisions about specific operational issues, as summarized in the memo.
The second issue for the FOMC to consider is the possibility of tapering the
Desk’s asset purchases as the end dates for the asset-purchase programs approach.
The desirability of doing so depends on how one views the effects of those programs.
The primary effect of those programs on market interest rates likely occurs through
altering the stock of securities available to investors. In a framework that considers
only such “stock effects,” there would be no response to the end of the LSAP

August 11–12, 2009

10 of 165

programs as long as it was fully anticipated in the markets. However, it is also 

possible that various market frictions allow the flow of purchases to have meaningful 

effects on market interest rates. In this case, the cessation of purchases could create a 

discrete market adjustment—the so-called “cliff effect.” This latter concern may be 

particularly relevant when the Fed’s purchases are very large relative to the amounts 

of outstanding supply and net issuance in a market, as is the case for the agency debt 

and MBS programs. If there is at least some possibility of flow effects, it may be 

desirable for the Fed to gradually reduce the pace of asset purchases rather than to 

terminate them abruptly. The tapering could take place over a period of several 

months around the end of the programs. This approach would allow any flow-related 

effects on the markets to be spread out, helping to facilitate a smooth market 

adjustment to a post-LSAP regime. Moreover, as long as the FOMC’s commitment 

to the overall stock of purchases is unchanged, this strategy should have no 

detrimental effects under the stock-based perspective on markets. 

In order to taper purchases and still reach the full amount of the programs, the
Committee would have to extend the end dates of the programs. The only other
alternative would be to increase the pace of purchases today in order to reduce it later,
but this approach could disrupt market functioning over the near term. The Desk
recommends a short extension of the Treasury program to the end of October, to
allow purchases to be tapered off over a period of two months or so. For agency debt
and MBS purchases, the Desk believes that a slightly longer tapering period is
appropriate. The Desk would recommend extending those programs to the end of the
first quarter, with the intention of beginning to taper off purchases in a meaningful
way in December. For each program, the Desk would decide on a more precise
schedule for reducing purchases while still hitting the total amount of purchases
decided by the FOMC. The Desk recommends reaching the full allocation of
purchases for Treasuries and MBS in order to validate the market’s expectations that
have had beneficial effects on financial conditions. It is less important, in our view,
to reach the full allocation for agency securities.
At this juncture, the FOMC has to decide only on its strategy for the Treasury 

program, given that its expiration date is approaching. The agency and MBS 

programs are not scheduled to expire until year-end. However, market participants 

are beginning to discuss the exit from these other programs as well, and they are 

likely to draw some inference about how these programs will be wound down from

the approach taken with Treasuries. These considerations will be raised again in the 

discussion of policy options and statements by Brian Madigan tomorrow. 

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, Brian. Questions for Brian? President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. I am looking at exhibit 4, figure 24, on mortgage spreads. I just want
to understand your interpretation of this chart. I see toward the end here that conforming spreads
come down dramatically and the ARMs come down dramatically, but you said that you thought

August 11–12, 2009

11 of 165

the purchase program did not have an effect on the ARMs. That means just that the level is
high?
MR. SACK. Right.
MR. BULLARD. What about the sharp downturn that followed the other line?
MR. SACK. So that’s right. I was focusing on the level. The level of the conforming
spread is not far from historical norms, but the level of the ARM spread is still extremely
elevated compared with historical norms, although it has improved. I would interpret the
improvement as being driven not by Fed purchase programs but just by the broader recovery in
markets. You point out that it is not that different a magnitude from the improvement in
conforming-mortgage spreads, but I think that probably has to do with the fact that it was starting
from such a wider, more disrupted level.
MR. BULLARD. I expect ARMs to be unpopular in the stage of the business cycle when
interest rates are low and people are talking about, well, when are you going to tighten, as
opposed to being in the stage of the business cycle when rates are higher and might come down
at some point.
MR. SACK. Well, I think that would presume that households have a more efficient
outlook on monetary policy than the bond market more broadly. Obviously, the yield curve in
Treasuries or in mortgages should reflect the expected path of short-term interest rates, so I
would think that normally the market would be priced in a way to make households relatively
indifferent, in terms of the risk, between ARMs and fixed-rate mortgages. The point is that
different households may have different preferences based on their different situations. So if the
purchase programs have had a very large effect on one product and absolutely no effect on the

August 11–12, 2009

12 of 165

other, it is creating a distortion that does not allow households to choose efficiently between the
two.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. I have a question and then a point to make. The question is with regard to
the size of the population of ARMs that are available. You mentioned in your paper that we
would eliminate interest-only ARMs. Is it roughly $200 billion that are eligible here in terms of
the total population? Is that correct?
MR. SACK. Of interest only?
MR. FISHER. No, of not interest-only ARMs. We would not pursue interest-only
ARMs.
MR. SACK. Sorry. Yes, that is correct. There is about $400 billion of ARMs in total.
About $200 billion is interest only. In the memo, we presented the arguments for and against
interest-only ARMs. In the end, we made a recommendation, but I certainly think we viewed
that as an open issue for the Committee to discuss.
MR. FISHER. The point is actually based on the question because, if you look at the
Greenbook, Part 2, page III-12, there is a chart of delinquencies on prime mortgages, and the
delinquency rate on variable-rate mortgages is four times that of fixed. So here is the question:
Do we want to be seen expanding our balance sheet and our asset purchases for poorly
performing mortgages such as these or encourage households to take out this kind of mortgage
now that they have a 12 percent past-due rate, or is there a chicken-and-egg issue here? I’m
curious as to what your opinion is because that is one of the cons you did not mention—that is,

August 11–12, 2009

13 of 165

that ARMs have a much higher delinquency rate. Do we want to be perceived as assisting that
weak market, or will our assistance lead to an improved market? What’s your opinion?
MR. SACK. I guess I wasn’t thinking of the ARMs purchases as really affecting the risk
profile of the outstanding securities. Obviously, those delinquency rates are very high. They are
very high for a lot of reasons, not necessarily that those products are ARMs but rather that those
ARMs are sold with very lax underwriting standards. So I think a benefit of purchasing ARMs is
not to bring back the kind of mortgage conditions that we saw previously but just to make these a
viable product if used with responsible underwriting going forward.
In terms of whether to hold assets that have those delinquencies, we are talking about
buying only GSE-sponsored securities. So part of the answer is that we are getting credit
protection from that and basically we are buying securities where any credit risks and issues like
that are already priced in. So I do not really see it as a portfolio issue that the delinquencies are
going up but more as a reputational issue about whether the Fed wants to be involved in products
that are still very visibly associated with the housing bubble and the problems that ensued.
MR. FISHER. Just so I understand—again, out of, say, a population of $200 billion,
what percentage of that is GSE and what is non-GSE? Do we know?
MR. SACK. The $200 billion is GSE-sponsored. In total, there’s $400 billion of GSEsponsored ARMs. I believe that outside the GSEs, there is about $1trillion of ARMs
outstanding.
MR. FISHER. We’re talking only about GSE-sponsored ARMs.
MR. SACK. Correct.
MR. FISHER. At least half are not interest only.
MR. SACK. Correct.

August 11–12, 2009

14 of 165

MR. FISHER. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. One approach to addressing some of these issues would be
to take only 5/1s or longer initial periods. Then, you stay away from the 2/28s and 3/27s, and
you don’t have the issue that you have an incentive not to raise rates because that will not have
any effect on a five-year fixed rate. President Stern.
MR. STERN. There is a two-hander over there.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Oh, sorry. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Just in terms of the credit quality, if you look at the 5-, the 7-, and
the 10-year, the credit scores for those are appreciably better than they are for the 30-year and the
15-year products actually. So following up on the Chairman’s comment, I think that, if you
focused on the 5, 7, and 10 rather than the 1 and 3, you have a very different risk profile, and it
actually does tend to match up with the duration that many people plan on staying in their
house—5, 7, or 10 years—rather than 30 years, which also has that advantage. So it would
recommend potentially thinking about starting with the 5, 7, and 10 rather than focusing on the
3and the 1, which have a different historical experience with default rates.
MR. FISHER. Thank you. I think that is a very important point. Thank you for
addressing it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Yes. If we were to buy agency ARMs at the magnitude you are
considering, what are your expectations for effects on rates and on volumes in that market?
MR. SACK. We’re starting with the $25 billion proposal. It is going to be useful to
compare that magnitude with the purchase program in fixed-rate MBS proportionally to that
market. With $25 billion, we are essentially buying a smaller portion of the outstanding stock.

August 11–12, 2009

15 of 165

We would be buying about 15 percent of the eligible outstanding stock compared with 25 to 30
percent for the fixed-rate program. But we would be buying a much larger share of the gross
issuance—about double what we have seen for gross issuance so far this year—whereas on the
fixed-rate side, we are buying something like 75 to 100 percent of gross issuance. We have
calibrated it that way to be somewhat comparable, but I think that the question about what
market effects might ensue has to do with that gross issuance. The possibility is that, once the
ARM purchases begin, if the pricing improves, then of course you’ll see more ARM issuance,
and that will give you some scope to raise the size of the program if that is seen as a good
approach.
In terms of what effect we might have on rates, I would not be surprised to see an effect
in the 50 to 100 basis point range. The memo had some measures of the relative pricing of
ARMs versus fixed-rate mortgages, and the deviations were 50 to 150 basis points of difference.
You can actually see in figure 24 that there’s a considerable difference in the size of the spreads.
So given that this market is disrupted and given that it is relatively small, it wouldn’t be
surprising to have a very meaningful effect on the pricing. With fixed-rate mortgages, we started
from a very high spread in a market that was functioning poorly but not that poorly. Here we’re
talking about a market that’s not functioning well at all, so I think we could really have a
substantial effect by participating in the market.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have a broad question that was stimulated by
Brian’s discussion of the improvement in market functioning. I wonder, Brian, if you could just
offer more of a summary opinion on how much better things are in financial markets. How far
are we toward sustainable improvement? You talked about the end of the government programs.

August 11–12, 2009

16 of 165

The Greenbook, as near as I can tell, still has the special financial factor add-ons to that, and I’m
just ultimately going to wonder where we are with that. It’s a little awkward because the
Governors have the responsibility for assessing 13(3) conditions, and yet things feel markedly
different from March 2008 or September 2008. Here we are in August 2009. We have moved
from general market dysfunction to something now that is better, and there is actually some
market differentiation, where some markets are doing substantially better than others. They’re
discriminating—whether or not it is appropriate is the question. So any additional color you
could offer on that would be helpful to me.
MR. SACK. In some of the bigger liquid markets—Treasuries, MBS—we’ve obviously
seen considerable improvement from late last year and early this year, and I think enough
improvement to where we are now perhaps just on a slower ongoing trajectory for improvement.
We are not back to where things were before the crisis. Bid–asked spreads are still a bit wider
than they were. One thing that’s very different is that trade sizes seem to be a lot smaller. So
even at the quoted bid–asked spreads, market depth is much more limited. But it’s certainly not
bad. It may take some time to get back to that. We may never actually get back to that. So I
think you would have to say that those markets in general are functioning quite well. The
corporate bond market as well. We have had a lot of corporate bond issuance, a lot of
improvement in pricing. So that looks quite decent. The markets that are still very disrupted, as
I mentioned in the briefing, are the securitized credit markets. There market activity is very
dependent on the TALF. There was basically nothing going on in CMBS until the TALF and the
PPIP came along, and what we have seen since the TALF and the PPIP is some pickup in
trading—actually some encouraging signs—but no new issuance still. So I think that those
markets will take quite some time to come back.

August 11–12, 2009

17 of 165

MR. MADIGAN. Two other points may be worth making. One is that, of course, credit
intermediation through the banking sector seemingly remains still quite impaired, judging by
actual credit flows and by responses to things like the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey.
Also, as Brian mentioned in his briefing, there’s still a tremendous range of support that’s being
provided to financial markets and institutions. It is difficult to know exactly how to factor that
in, but surely that is still providing support.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I would like to go back to the point about the 3/1s, 5/1s, and 7/1s and
whatever—how that affects the credit scores, a point that President Fisher raised. If we were to
go in and concentrate our purchases in some subset of these ARMs, hence driving their rates
down, then we expect the market response to that would be that maybe those credit scores
wouldn’t stay the same, that there would be a response where mortgage brokers and others would
help direct people into those products for which we are trying to drive down the yields and make
them more attractive. I think there is going to be an endogenous response to that, and we have to
be careful that we don’t put ourselves in a position by which we are creating even more
distortions than we already are by picking products in individual securities and trying to affect
their individual prices and not others. I think that is a very dangerous position for us to be in,
and we end up perhaps aggravating problems and actually preventing markets from doing the
healing that they need to do rather than just helping them along.
My point is that there will be a demand response to this price change and that we cannot
necessarily assume that we won’t be, in effect, driving people to particular products and away
from others, and I think that’s something we have to be very, very careful of. So I just think we
should be very dubious about our strategy here in terms of making this work. Also it runs a risk

August 11–12, 2009

18 of 165

politically—not economically, but politically—and I think this is probably what President Fisher
was suggesting. Actually the staff memo raised this issue. Politically it looks as though we’re
going into something that everybody has been condemning as part of our problem, and I think
we should be very, very careful about that.
So I’m just wondering, Eric, do you really think there wouldn’t be a demand response to
our driving? If Brian is right and we can drive down the yields on the 5/1s and 7/1s by 100 basis
points, do you think that there wouldn’t be a demand response to that and, therefore, that credit
scores might, in fact, decline as opposed to being high?
MR. ROSENGREN. My observation on credit scores was based on the historical data
that includes the last recession. As you can see from the charts, in the last recession, the rates
were substantially lower than they are now.
MR. PLOSSER. It wasn’t much of a recession though.
MR. ROSENGREN. Well, it was a different recession. I’m just saying that the
observation on credit scores was based on a period in which actually we weren’t intervening and
that was a recession. I think it is an open question as to who would take advantage of the
program, but right now it looks as if the spreads are outsized relative to what they have been
historically. So you might argue that some people who would prefer a five-year or a seven-year
product now don’t have a product that’s functioning in the way that it has historically.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Just to amplify President Rosengren’s remarks, we were
already distorting the market by just buying fixed-rate mortgages. So you could argue that, if
you were to purchase fives, sevens, and tens, actually you’d be reducing the amount of distortion
because you’d be bringing those rates back into better alignment with where they have been

August 11–12, 2009

19 of 165

historically. So I’m not convinced that the distortion argument goes against the ARM purchases.
I think you could argue just as strongly that it gives a case for the ARM purchases.
MR. PLOSSER. So you create one distortion, and you fix it by creating other distortions
to offset it?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Right now you are pushing people into fixed-rate
mortgages because those yields are so much lower than the ARM yields because you’re
intervening in the one market and not the other.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. We are in the Q&A session for Brian. [Laughter]
We will have a chance to discuss these issues further, of course. President Lacker, did you want
to ask a question?
MR. LACKER. Brian Sack, I’m looking at chart 1 on page 7 of 8 of the memo that you
distributed, which shows agency ARM issuance monthly beginning in 1994 and up through the
present, and it looks as though in late 1998, early 1999, that there was a really strong dip.
Quantities got down exceptionally low, and then the same thing happened in 2001. My memory
is that those were occasions in which interest rates fell, and if I look at chart 1, it doesn’t seem
that surprising that ARM volumes are low. Now, in chart 3, you show us the results of some of
the regressions. The way it is described in the text, you say that you address this ARM–fixed
spread on the slope of the yield curve?
MR. SACK. Right.
MR. LACKER. But did you include the level of the yield curve? This goes back to
President Bullard’s remark that it certainly seems as if you could look at the data and be forgiven
for thinking that, when the overall yield curve is low, there is an effect depressing ARM rates
because people think it’s going to be mean reverting rather than just a random walk.

August 11–12, 2009

20 of 165

MR. SACK. To my knowledge, we did not try the level of yields, and of course, chart 3
shows the outcome of just one model. But I think the argument that ARMs look expensive to
households seems pretty compelling. I mean, you do not need a regression to tell you that; you
can pretty much see it in chart 24. Even if activity tends to fall off when rates are low, we have
to at least entertain the idea that the apparent expense of ARMs—the wide spread that we see
today—is contributing to that falloff. So it’s possible that the purchase program would bring the
ARM spread in and make it more comparable with the fixed-rate spread but still households
would choose fixed-rate mortgages because those rates are very low. I think that’s possible, and
that’s fine. I think one would argue, well, let’s bring that spread down and then let households
make that choice. So in no way are we suggesting that you target some proportion of ARM
issuance or push on this until you get ARM issuance back up. We are just saying that, you could
argue, Let’s bring down what looks to be a very wide yield spread, and let households make that
choice.
MR. LACKER. If I could follow up, Mr. Chairman—you used the word “disrupted”
about the agency ARM market. I am assuming that this yield spread and the quantities are part
of the evidence that you would use to bolster that case. So here is the question: It could be the
case that you have qualitative observations bolstering the characterization as “disrupted”—things
like market makers who have left the market, wider bid–asked spreads, and the like. But if it is
just quantities and these spreads, I guess I find this less than compelling to qualify for the word
“disrupted,” the way I usually think of that. More broadly, we did intervene in the fixed-rate
securitization market. We would have predicted that the intervention would increase the flow of
credit to that sector and reduce the flow of credit to other sectors. It is exactly what we would
have expected. So there is going to be an endless supply of other sectors that, because of our

August 11–12, 2009

21 of 165

intervention, now are seeing less credit than they otherwise would. So are we on a treadmill here
that we will do this and then we will find that interest-only ARMs really deserve some help, and
we will do that? What are the criteria here for drawing a boundary between where we are
intervening and where we are not? I am not sure I see it in the way you have laid out the pros
and cons—it makes it seem as if we just assemble a pro and con list and see what wins each
time.
MR. SACK. That last question is certainly a tougher one than we aim to answer in the
memo. How far to go is a question for policymakers. However, let me say something about the
liquidity issue and whether the ARMs market is disrupted. In general, you know, the ARM
market is less liquid than the fixed-rate mortgage market. The fixed-rate mortgage market trades
on a TBA basis. That means that a bunch of securities can be delivered into a contract, and that
adds a lot of liquidity to that market. It is traded over an electronic trading platform, Tradeweb.
The ARM market is different. It trades much more on a specified pool basis. There is no TBA.
It is not on Tradeweb. It is literally a deal-driven market in which, to execute an order, you need
to pick up a phone and talk to some dealers.
MR. LACKER. It was this way before the crisis.
MR. SACK. This is the way it was before and the way it is now. So just in general the
ARM market is less liquid than the fixed-rate mortgage market. Today I think that difference is
greater than normal, and you can see that in terms of bid–asked spreads. The bid–asked spreads
for ARMs, for comparable-sized trades, are four to eight times what they are for fixed-rate
mortgages. I think that difference has gotten greater, and one reason for that is that you have a
market in which there is just no new issuance, so there is no flow that is creating liquidity in

August 11–12, 2009

22 of 165

trading. So it is really a market that—I don’t want to say it is completely dried up in terms of
trading, but it has suffered in terms of liquidity.
MR. LACKER. Well, I think the bid–asked spread in any market would go up if the
volume went down. I wonder what happened in ’98, ’99, and 2001 to the bid–asked spread. Do
you have a benchmark against which to compare those bid–asked spreads and view them as too
high, or is it just a byproduct of the low issuance?
MR. SACK. We don’t have a nice time series of bid–asked spreads. In part because
there is no electronic platform, we don’t have a nice data source to give us a long historical
perspective.
MR. LACKER. You don’t know if it is high relative to what it would be if it were
efficiently undisrupted?
MR. SACK. No. I am saying that, given the lack of liquidity by these measures, given
the lack of issuance, and given the cheap pricing, I think the evidence in general supports the
idea that, if the Fed were to purchase those securities and encourage new issuance, you would
see a pickup in liquidity, and you would see these liquidity measures improve.
MR. LACKER. Mr. Chairman, I have another question about the asset purchase
programs, but I understand the discussion here has been about this, so I defer my question until
later.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. President Yellen, a two-hander?
MS. YELLEN. I just wanted to comment on President Lacker’s question and Brian’s
response and say that our staff also undertook independent analysis of this issue and estimated an
econometric model trying to assess how distorted the ARM and fixed-rate mortgage spreads are
relative to their benchmarks. That included more than the slope of the yield curve. It was a

August 11–12, 2009

23 of 165

principal-component analysis that implicitly included levels and other things. And it supports
the conclusion that Brian drew based on the exercise that he undertook. In fact, our staff
concluded that the fixed-rate mortgage rate relative to its benchmark is now reasonably normal
and the ARM rate is on the order of 150 basis points higher than you would expect, given the
entire constellation of rates.
Another thing that they did was to estimate an econometric model using individual data
from the McDash data set to try to get a sense of how the existing differentials are affecting
choice between conventional and adjustable-rate mortgages, and they found that the essentially
no-issuance, no take-up on adjustable-rate mortgages is precisely what you would expect based
on the current constellation of rates.
Finally, they tried to estimate what the likely responsiveness would be if we were able to
push the differential down about 150 basis points or other magnitudes to more-normal levels by
entering this market. They tried to look at those borrowers who were currently in the mortgage
market because historically you have had subprime borrowers with very low FICO scores who
aren’t in the mortgage market now. So they controlled for a lot of borrower characteristics and
tried to compute what the response would be of borrowers who were in the market as of early
2009, and they found a very high interest-elasticity. In fact, they computed that, if we could
drive that rate down 150 basis points, you should see the share of ARMs versus fixed-rate
mortgages rise to about 35 percent. I offer that just as a clarifying comment.
MR. LACKER. Mr. Chairman?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes.
MR. LACKER. If I can just follow up: First, let me say that that sounds like admirable
research, and I enjoy benefiting from it, President Yellen. This brings to mind another aspect of

August 11–12, 2009

24 of 165

the adjustable/fixed-rate margin. My understanding of the empirics of mortgage losses over the
last couple of years is that they have revealed that a substantial selection effect goes on in the
choice between adjustable and fixed-rate mortgages. And what we know of models with adverse
selection suggests that the relative frequency of good types and bad types in the canonical model
is going to influence equilibrium pricing in those models. So you would expect that, if there is
more in the general population of the riskier types, you might get higher risk premiums on the
ARMs because they are selected by the riskier types of agents, and this could be a factor
explaining the high spreads on adjustable-rate mortgages now. Whether it would be picked up in
an atheoretical principal component analysis or not, I don’t know. I just mention that as
something that has arisen out of the data recently. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Let the record show that President Lacker’s reference to
ARMs dealers had to do with mortgages and not with other things. [Laughter] A short
intervention, President Plosser?
MR. PLOSSER. Yes, a short one. Brian, the way you have described the ARM market
and how it is not functioning the way we think—or at least some estimates suggest that it
might—I wonder if New York and the staff have on their agenda what the next market is. If I
listen to what you say, we ought to be in the jumbo market. And I am wondering, with the very
high spreads in the jumbo market, can we expect to see a proposal from the staff that we are
going to buy jumbos now in order to get their spreads down?
MR. SACK. No. [Laughter]
MS. MCLAUGHLIN. We are not allowed to.
MR. PLOSSER. The argument is the same, though, isn’t it?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. You can’t buy jumbos. They are not GSE guaranteed.

August 11–12, 2009

25 of 165

MR. SACK. Yes, they have to be GSE guaranteed.
MR. PLOSSER. We could think of a way, couldn’t we?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. No, no, no, no. [Laughter]
MR. SACK. There is another point, which is that the expansion of the conformingmortgage limit has actually brought what would have been a lot of jumbo new issuance into the
conforming-mortgage market. Moreover, most fixed-rate MBS pools can have up to 10 percent
of jumbo conforming mortgages in them. So the asset-purchase programs already in place are
already helping to support some high-balance mortgages.
MR. PLOSSER. Okay.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. In a sense this is going to carry the discussion where it has already been,
but if I remember right, we had some discussion of this at the last FOMC meeting and went
against going forward with it at the time. And given my sense of things, although things remain
fragile in the housing market and elsewhere, things have improved. They are better than they
were. It is not that I mind having it brought back, but I am wondering, Brian, what has happened
between the last FOMC and this FOMC that makes this worth bringing back for discussion? The
market is not perfect yet. We still have this distortion in the ARMs, but there is some
improvement showing. I think that the markets will straighten out with time, especially if the
economy is on a healing path. Is there enough need for this to accelerate the recovery or settle
out the markets to bring this back and reconsider it at this meeting?
MR. SACK. Just to be clear, we are not bringing up this issue because of something that
has happened, a worsening of conditions, over the intermeeting period. I think we left the last
meeting thinking that this was an open issue and that we wanted to present the Committee with

August 11–12, 2009

26 of 165

the full range of arguments on both sides and let the Committee decide it. You know, we are
well into the program. We are at a point where people are beginning to discuss the exit. Maybe
there is an issue about whether it is the right time to be making changes like this, but we just
wanted to present the case. In terms of timing, given the size of the program we are talking
about, there is no issue. It would be very easy to get this program done in the size we have
talked about, in the time left.
MR. HOENIG. Thank you very much, Brian.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Just to be clear, we will survey everybody’s views either in
the go-round or, if you don’t express a view in the go-round, we will check with you after the
meeting. So everyone’s thoughts will be heard.
MR. HOENIG. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Other questions for Brian? President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Yes. This has to do with our asset purchase program. I want to refer to
chart 25, “Balance Sheet Assets by Category,” on the last page of your presentation. It looks as
if, when we buy our large-scale assets, short-term liquidity facility usage goes down. That
suggests that maybe banks have a certain amount of reserves they want to hold, and when we
buy stuff, they have to borrow less to have the reserves they want to hold. In fact, reserves went
down in the last intermeeting period, and we keep missing the forecast of reserve balances and
short-term liquidity facility usage on the low side as we ramp up these purchases. My
understanding is that you go around facility by facility and construct these forecasts, and then
reserves sort of pop out as the residual. Now we are going to keep purchasing assets, and my
understanding is that the forecast says that we are going to take reserve balances from
$700 billion to $1.4 trillion.

August 11–12, 2009

27 of 165

There is an interesting memo by Charles Sims and Kevin McDonald on the
MarketSource website that forecasts balances for the large banks and for various bank categories
like community banks. My sense is that there is a sort of judgmental forecast as to how the
shares of total reserve balances are going to change, but it has Bank of America—this is the
largest holder—going from $140 billion to something over $250 billion. I checked this morning.
They are planning to reduce their reserve balances over the next several months, and the reason
is that the cost of carry is too high. I mean, it is valuable to them in terms of the liquidity it gives
them; but at 25 basis points, it is below their cost of funds, and they are planning to shift funds
into cash equivalents, like Treasuries and agencies, that are higher yielding and have a lower cost
to carry. So my question is, What effects do you expect, if this hypothesis is true, of our
expanding large-scale asset purchases enough that short-term liquidity facility usage is driven to
zero and yet reserve balances keep going up? What yields are going to change to get banks to
hold this? How does that square with the Greenbook’s forecast that yields increase rather than
decrease over the period? And how much stimulus does that provide, in some broad sense? I
realize that is a tall order, but I am just raising the question of whether there is a discrete change
in the sense of the stimulus we provide as we cross that threshold.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. This is how quantitative easing works. You induce banks
to substitute away from reserves, but they have to hold the reserves in the end.
MR. LACKER. Right.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. So the yields change, assuming that we would be more
accommodative. And that is exactly what we are trying to do.

August 11–12, 2009

28 of 165

MR. LACKER. Well, I argued in January that is the effect of what we were having to do,
so I am aware of that. But we didn’t sign up to do an infinite amount of it. We want to do the
right amount.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Right.
MR. LACKER. And as economic conditions change—and I argued this in January as
well—we need to adapt, just the way we adapt our funds rate when the funds rate is operative.
We ought to be thinking about how much stimulus we are supplying. So the question arises, Do
we know what kind of stimulus we are going to be supplying? Apparently, the banking system
isn’t planning on doubling their holding of reserves any time soon.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, these asset-purchase plans are not set in stone. We
began them in March at a time of very weak conditions. We have reviewed them at each
meeting. And if we decide there is too much stimulus in the economy, given our projections,
then we can reduce them. So they are a choice variable at each meeting. But you have just
described exactly the way the quantitative easing part of this is supposed to work.
MR. LACKER. Yes, I know. But is this consistent? I mean, this suggests that, when we
cross this threshold, there will be a discrete downward effect on these longer yields. We may
want that; we may not.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I don’t see any reason why it would be discontinuous. I
think it is continuous.
MR. LACKER. Well, because there is a discontinuity in the use of our short-term
liquidity facilities at zero.
MR. CARPENTER. Just one minor clarification, though, President Lacker. Some of the
facilities, if we take two of them in particular—well, just take the CPFF as a single example. At

August 11–12, 2009

29 of 165

its peak, the CPFF was very, very large—well over $200 billion. And it wasn’t necessarily just
banks borrowing that. As that usage came down, that was not in the first instance a bank
deciding that they have access to funds in one case and so they are going to give it up in another
case. So it is not obvious that it is quite as tight a link of reduced use of liquidity facilities,
simply because of the increase in the provision of balances from that asset purchase.
MR. LACKER. No, I understand that the CPFF is in this orange part here. And to some
extent that is different from the PCF and the TAF, where it is driven by their demand for funds, I
think.
MR. SACK. Yes. I would just add, as Chairman Bernanke said, that the example you
gave of Bank of America is basically describing the portfolio balance effect, which underlies the
stock effect that I talked about. Basically, the system as a whole has to be forced to hold these
liquid assets instead of longer-term assets. To make participants happy to do that, the yields on
the longer-term assets have to be lower. The way we have thought about it is that this is all
priced in already. If you believe a stock effect, where the effects are based on the expectation of
what the stocks are going to be, completing the asset purchase programs that are already
announced is going to force this portfolio reallocation. But markets tend to bring it forward, so
you don’t get the flow effect as it happens. You get it priced up front. This flow versus stock
issue is something that we are conscious of, and maybe you are raising the fact that the flow
issue also depends on the level of reserves, and so we are still going to get some effect there. But
we tend to think of most of the effect as coming through the expected stock, even though we
allow some possibility of flow effects and make recommendations for policymakers to hedge
themselves in case there are these flow effects.

August 11–12, 2009

30 of 165

MR. LACKER. Strange as this may sound, I am sort of willing to entertain the notion
that the yield curve doesn’t build in this sort of effect yet.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. You have raised a good point, President Lacker, about the
substitutability between these two forms of stimulus, and I think we ought to continue to think
about that. If there are no objections, I would like to go on to the next portion. We have some
staff presentations on reserve management, which bears exactly on some of these issues, and
then a presentation on the TALF. So let me turn first to Chris Burke. We will hear four
presentations, and then we will have Q&A for all four. Chris.
MR. BURKE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The FOMC has discussed using
reverse repo operations in scale as part of its strategy for eventually draining reserves
and raising short-term interest rates from their current low levels. This briefing will
provide an update on operational readiness, describe some of the key aspects of the
program and their implications, and briefly discuss the importance of counterparties,
including a discussion of the special case of conducting reverse repos with the GSEs.
An important operational aspect of large-scale reverse repos is the form of
settlement. There are three different types of settlement—delivery versus payment,
held in custody, and triparty. The Federal Reserve has used all three, but for largescale reverse repos, triparty settlement is the only feasible choice. In triparty repo,
both the borrower and the lender have cash and collateral accounts at the same
triparty repo agent, either JPMorgan Chase or Bank of New York Mellon. There are
several reasons why triparty settlement is required. Most important, it provides
access to the wide range of institutional cash investors who use triparty repo. In
addition, triparty agents provide collateral management services for term repo and
other services that current FRBNY systems are not set up to provide.
A Federal Reserve reverse repo in the triparty structure, however, is not sufficient
to drain reserves, as at the end of the day the funds that the Fed borrowed are in the
Federal Reserve account of the clearing bank. To drain reserves, therefore, the
clearing banks must take the additional step of sending the funds to the Fed at the end
of the day, and because of the nature of triparty, the Fed must return the funds to the
clearing banks each morning. These additional steps create operational and legal
complexities for the program. As such, the staff believes that the Desk should
establish a complete operational and legal system for conducting reverse repos using
Treasury and direct agency debt first, before designing the ability to conduct reverse
repos using agency MBS collateral, which involves further complexities.

August 11–12, 2009

31 of 165

An initial reverse repo program with the capacity of as much as $100 billion,
using primary dealers as counterparties and Treasury and direct agency debt as
collateral, is expected to be available in early September. This has required the
establishment of new tools to manage the operational aspects of the program, new
legal documentation with both the clearing banks and the dealers, and negotiations
with the clearing banks on the fees involved. Because the main services that triparty
repo agents perform involve the management and pricing of collateral, the triparty
fees are paid by the collateral providers. Even though the Federal Reserve has been
using the triparty system for repo transactions for years without paying fees, the use
of triparty repo to drain reserves will require the Fed to pay fees to the clearing banks.
Initial discussions with the clearing banks suggest that annual triparty fees for a
reverse repo portfolio of $500 billion are likely to be in the range of $10 million to
$15 million. Current discussions with the clearing banks are focused on eliminating
the differences in proposed fees from the two clearing banks and reducing the final
fees. Negotiations could take up to another month to complete and document.
The legal and fee groundwork laid for reverse repos using Treasury and agency
debt should also cover the use of agency mortgage-backed securities. However, new
operational processes will need to be designed and implemented for agency MBS,
primarily because of our use of investment managers and custodial accounts for
managing our agency MBS holdings. We anticipate that the extension to agency
MBS collateral should be completed in the fourth quarter.
The most important issue regarding the potential scope of the reverse repo
program is the set of counterparties. Our current open market operations are
conducted with only the 18 primary dealers. However, primary dealers tend to be net
borrowers, not net lenders, in the repo market, meaning that as a group they are a
poor fit as reverse repo counterparties. Further, dealers have limited capacity to act as
intermediaries between the Fed and other cash investors, as doing so would gross up
their balance sheets. Based on discussions with about half the primary dealer
community, total dealer capacity for reverse repos is expected to be only about
$100 billion and perhaps only half of that on month-ends. Dealers simply do not have
the balance sheet capacity to handle the size of program being contemplated. Thus a
program of any size will require an expansion of the counterparty list. The
identification and establishment of an expanded set of counterparties, which is what
would enable the expansion of the program beyond its initial $100 billion size, should
be complete by year-end.
One area of exploration related to expanded counterparties is a reverse repo
program focused on the GSEs, in particular Freddie Mac, Fannie Mae, and the
12 Federal Home Loan Banks. Nearly all have expressed a willingness to consider
engaging in reverse repos with the Fed, and current estimates suggest that a program
targeted at these GSEs would be between $50 billion and $75 billion in size. The
potential costs and benefits of a program of this nature, however, require more study,
as the magnitude of the effect on the federal funds rate is not yet fully clear. A
$75 billion program would not substantially reduce the overall level of reserve

August 11–12, 2009

32 of 165

balances from their current and expected elevated levels. And while it may be the
case that removing these particular participants in the federal funds market would
help increase federal funds rates in general, that conclusion is not obvious. Staff
members at the New York Fed and the Board are working to better understand the
potential rate effects of such a program. In addition, removing the GSEs from the
brokered federal funds market would significantly shrink that market and make it
more idiosyncratic and perhaps a less relevant indicator of broader funding
conditions.
These are issues that will have to be addressed when the FOMC considers the
scope of the reverse repo program and the way it fits into a broader strategy for
tightening financial conditions. My purpose today was simply to indicate some of the
operational conclusions that we have reached to date and define some of the issues
that policymakers will have to take into consideration going forward. Thank you.
Seth Carpenter will now update you on the term deposit facility.
MR. CARPENTER. Thank you, Chris. A term deposit facility could be another
part of the tool kit for implementing a decision to raise short-term interest rates.
Because a deposit facility would be created under the authority for paying interest on
reserves, access would be limited to depository institutions and not, for example, the
GSEs. This distinction is a clear difference from Chris’s description of reverse repos.
Funds deposited in a term deposit facility would not be available to clear payments,
satisfy reserve or clearing balance requirements, or be treated as balances for
purposes of calculating overdraft fees. In essence, by shifting balances out of DIs’
master accounts, a deposit facility would lower excess reserves.
The quantity of excess reserves that could be absorbed by a deposit facility is
unclear, though logically it should increase as the interest rate paid on term deposits
rises. The staff is evaluating two potential approaches for setting the rate paid on
term deposits. The Federal Reserve could auction a fixed quantity of term deposits,
with the rate established in the auction. Alternatively, the Federal Reserve could post
the interest rates that it will pay on term deposits, and DIs would decide what
quantities they wish to deposit at those rates. In either case, the rate paid would be
constrained by the statutory requirement that rates not exceed prevailing market rates.
The staff currently envisions that a deposit facility would be a somewhat blunt tool
and be used to drain a block of reserve balances rather than as an instrument for day­
to-day reserves management. The auction-rate approach would likely give the
Federal Reserve greater control over the quantity of term deposits than would a
posted-rate facility. Such control might be desirable if other tools, such as reverse
repos or asset sales, were to drain such a large quantity of reserves that precision over
the level of reserves would become important again. That said, under either
approach, settlement would likely occur with a lag of at least one day, partly to
enhance the predictability of the quantity of reserves.
In practice, the Federal Reserve would announce the details of each operation, and
an administrator would enter those details into an automated application that has been

August 11–12, 2009

33 of 165

largely developed. Using a web-based interface for the new application, depository
institutions would submit tenders electronically and get notification of awards. For
auction-rate facilities, in particular, the application also provides the capability of
noncompetitive bids, which might appeal to some of the smaller depository
institutions.
The background work to put a deposit facility into operation is well under way.
The Federal Reserve could announce a deposit facility as early as November and
implement the facility before the end of the year. IAS, the Integrated Accounting
System, has been modified to accept settlement entries from the new term deposit
application. During the next several months, System staff members will complete
and test the deposit facility application. Implementing a deposit facility would also
require a number of additional steps beyond those already completed, including
preparing any necessary Federal Register notices, drafting legal agreements,
educating DIs about the new facility, obtaining signed versions of the legal
agreements from DIs that may wish to use the facility, and issuing the electronic
certificates that DIs would need to access the deposit facility application through the
web-based interface. Completing these steps would take several months and entail a
significant, coordinated effort by System staff members across a number of business
lines. Jamie McAndrews will now discuss reserve collateral accounts.
MR. MCANDREWS. Thank you, Seth. I will update the Committee on the
possibility of creating reserve collateral accounts as a means to achieve better control
of the federal funds rate using interest on reserves. As you know, the effective
federal funds rate has generally been lower than the interest rate paid on excess
reserves since October 2008, and the size of this divergence has fluctuated over time.
Competition among banks might be expected to narrow that divergence because
buying funds and placing them on deposit at their Federal Reserve Bank is both
relatively inexpensive and completely risk free. One explanation for the divergence
is that imperfections in the fed funds market short-circuit the competitive process by
which the fed funds rate would be bid up. Some banks are paying, for example, 15
basis points to borrow and then earn 25 basis points at the Fed, but other banks are
not bidding up the rate to 16 basis points or higher. Reserve collateral accounts are
intended to facilitate competition that would bid up the rate and generate a tighter link
between the interest rate paid on excess reserves and the market rate. Creating this
tighter link now would help dispel doubts about the Fed’s ability to use interest on
excess reserves to raise the fed funds rate when the time comes.
Why isn’t competition bidding up rates more efficiently? One possible reason is
that counterparty credit risk impedes rate-based competition. Fed funds trades are
uncollateralized loans. Consequently, a firm must carefully select its counterparties
and limit the amount lent to each of them. These restrictions limit competition for
funds. If a firm could be freed from concern about its counterparty’s credit quality, it
could search among a wider set of firms for higher bids and for larger trade sizes.
Reserve collateral accounts, or RCAs, would create the possibility of collateralized
fed funds trades, which would allow many more banks to bid for funds in the market.

August 11–12, 2009

34 of 165

How do RCAs facilitate collateralized fed funds trades? To begin, note that an
analysis of data from Fedwire suggests that, in July 2009, approximately half of the
daily average of $125 billion of fed funds trades consisted of GSEs lending to banks,
with the other half consisting of bank-to-bank trades. So suppose that two firms, a
GSE and a bank, agree to use RCAs to conduct collateralized fed funds trades. The
bank would request that its Federal Reserve Bank create an RCA, separate from the
bank’s master account. The account would have a unique feature: The bank could
not wire funds out of its own RCA. The funds in the account would, however, earn
interest on reserves for the bank paid at the rate on excess reserves. Under the terms
of their collateralized fed funds trade, the GSE would wire funds into the bank’s
RCA, and the next day, the GSE would pull the funds out of the bank’s RCA back
into its own account, using the operational capabilities of the Fed’s National
Settlement Service. So the account can be thought of as a locked box into which
funds are placed and to which the GSE is given the key. The funds are put into the
box by the GSE at night, they earn interest for the bank, and the GSE retrieves the
funds the next day. Separately, the GSE and the bank agree on what interest rate the
GSE would earn from the deal.
This arrangement would be governed by agreements among the Federal Reserve
Bank, the GSE, and the bank, in which the Fed would acknowledge that the GSE has
a lien on the funds in the RCA. That acknowledgement would allow the GSE to
perfect a security interest in the account. As a result, if the bank with which it was
doing the deals failed, the GSE would still get back its principal, as the funds in the
account would be collateral for repayment. With the infrastructure of RCAs in place,
we could expect the GSEs and other firms, perhaps including banks, to establish
RCAs with banks if they can earn higher rates by doing so. Parties to RCA
agreements would be free to borrow or lend on an uncollateralized basis; this
possibility should help in aligning short-term rates through arbitrage activity.
Another possible impediment to competition for funds in the current environment
might come from banks’ balance sheet concerns. Some banks might fear that their
buffer of capital to assets above minimum levels is too low for them to bid
aggressively for funds. Establishing an RCA would be most attractive to those banks
with the least balance sheet concerns, because they would be willing to pay the
highest rates. In this way, RCAs would allow market prices to be determined by the
banks that are best positioned to purchase funds, which would further reduce the
divergence of market rates from the interest rate paid on excess reserves.
Our next step would be to approach a number of the GSEs and some banks to
gauge their views as to the feasibility of RCAs and their attractiveness. If a sufficient
appetite for these arrangements appears to exist, Federal Reserve staff would then
plan to establish a Systemwide steering group to form a precise timeline for all the
implementation steps and to determine if any remaining unforeseen impediments to
the creation of RCAs exist. I now turn to Bill Nelson, who will update the Committee
on issues in the TALF program.

August 11–12, 2009

35 of 165

MR. NELSON. Thank you, Jamie. I will briefly review the staff’s evaluation of
legacy RMBS as potential TALF collateral and then discuss a proposed extension of
the facility’s end date. Staff members from the Board and the Federal Reserve Banks
of Atlanta and New York have worked to understand the potential economic and
financial benefits and costs of accepting legacy RMBS as collateral for TALF loans.
The staff limited their investigation to about 16,000 bonds, with a face value of
$1.2 trillion, that are still performing, have relatively straightforward structures, and
were originally rated triple-A.
RMBS are a complex and heterogeneous group of assets. As a result, it’s
impossible to identify a set of bonds with the lowest credit risk from the larger
universe without conducting a bond-level analysis. In short, there is no equivalent of
the legacy super-senior CMBS bonds that are currently TALF eligible. The prices of
the pool of bonds under review have risen from their mid-March nadir, with gains
accelerating in recent weeks. The expected return to an investor buying a bond at
today’s prices is now typically half the return available a few months ago. Given the
recent increase in prices, adding legacy RMBS to the TALF, especially if confined to
the safest bonds and paired with large haircuts, might not increase bond prices
appreciably. Instead, the facility would act more as a backstop financing vehicle
should risk premiums widen dramatically in coming months. Moreover, because
most bonds are expected to take at least some write-downs in coming years, to
implement even a limited facility we would have to hire multiple vendors to carefully
analyze candidate bonds, determine conservative haircuts, and effectively
communicate loan terms to potential investors.
Turning to the TALF end date, currently the facility is scheduled to close on
December 31, 2009. The staff is proposing that the Board authorize TALF loans to
finance new-issue CMBS through June 30, 2010, and authorize all other TALF loans
through March 31. We are proposing an extension because at this point ABS and
CMBS markets appear to require the TALF to function and because issuers and
investors need assurance that the TALF will be available for several months into the
future. The ABS and CMBS markets remain impaired and appear likely to remain
impaired through the proposed new deadlines. There is little near-term prospect for a
significant revival of non-TALF investor interest in ABS in volume, and the
economic recovery remains tentative and potentially contingent on the continued
availability of credit for consumers and businesses. The new-issue CMBS market has
been shuttered for over a year, and the only deals on the horizon are relatively small
TALF-financed deals. Despite the impairment, the TALF is encouraging the flow of
credit to businesses and households. Staff analysis and a recent survey of issuers
indicate that the TALF has contributed to narrower spreads and has played a critical
role in facilitating new securitizations.
There are benefits to announcing an extension sooner rather than waiting till the
end date is closer. Potential issuers of new CMBS report needing six months, on
average, to arrange relatively large deals involving multiple borrowers.

August 11–12, 2009

36 of 165

Consequently, an issuer that begins the process of putting together a new-issue 

CMBS deal today risks not completing the deal by the end of 2009, after the current 

TALF deadline. Similarly, potential investors in the TALF indicate that it takes time 

to organize investment pools, and the looming deadline is damping interest. 

While extending the TALF may yield benefits, it may also have costs. In 

particular, allowing the program to close might speed the development of alternative 

methods for financing loans to businesses and households, albeit at the expense of 

near-term disruptions in securitization markets. A potential cost of extending the 

deadline for legacy CMBS is that it might reduce the urgency among investors to 

arrange TALF-financed deals. 

If the Board decides to extend the facility in the manner proposed, it could 

evaluate the need for a further extension later this year or early next year. At that 

time, the staff can propose potential adjustments to the program to make TALF 

financing less attractive, if appropriate. Conversely, if market conditions improve 

more quickly and significantly than expected and conditions are no longer unusual 

and exigent, the facility would be required to be closed at an earlier time. 

These issues were discussed by the Board at a meeting yesterday. No decisions 

were made, but Board members generally expressed support for suspending staff 

work on legacy RMBS and extending the TALF deadline to the proposed dates. If 

these are the Board’s conclusions after the discussion today, a press release reporting 

the new end dates and indicating that further expansion of the TALF appears unlikely 

at this time could be released later this week. That concludes our prepared remarks. 

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Just to summarize briefly—first, on
our exit strategy, we have a belt-and-suspenders approach, a two-pronged approach. One part is
the interest rate on reserves, and the other is management of reserve balances. What we heard
today was, I think, considerable progress on a variety of mechanisms that would allow us to
manage reserve balances to help us exit from our accommodative policies going forward. On the
TALF, to reiterate what Bill said, the sense of the Board—and we are interested in FOMC
input—was that we would suspend any further expansion to other asset classes. We looked at
CLOs, RMBS, and CDOs. Is that the right list?
MR. NELSON. CLOs, new issue RMBS, and now legacy RMBS.

August 11–12, 2009

37 of 165

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes. So just for clarity, we would announce later this week
that we are suspending consideration of additional asset classes—not saying so, or perhaps even
saying so—but obviously, if conditions change radically, we could revisit that. But for now we
will suspend that. In the same press release we would announce the extension of the TALF to
March 31 and for new CMBS only to June, because that particular category requires a much
longer lead time to put together deals. So that is what is on the table as far as the Board’s
discussion is concerned. Now, let me turn first to Q&A for the staff, and then we will have an
opportunity for further discussion as well. Are there any questions for the staff? Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I was just curious where the staff came out in rank
ordering of these different proposals and whether they were viewed as complements or
substitutes? Should we on embark all three, or should we go forward with one faster than the
other? They were three separate briefings, but I didn’t get a sense of how to think of them in
total.
MR. MADIGAN. I think at this stage we view all of them as potentially productive to
work on further. They are at somewhat different stages of development, but I think that they all
have significant plausibility as methods of dealing with reserve issues. I think we wouldn’t
recommend at this stage deciding definitely to use one in favor of another one.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My question is a little like Bill’s question, but
it is aimed, Jamie, at the RCAs. Very clever. I have a number of questions, but I wonder, if we
do those other things, whether the RCAs, which strike me as a more radical kind of thing to do,
are necessary or even helpful. In talking about the reverse RPs, we said there was concern that
doing reverse RPs with Fannie and Freddie might detract from the workings of the fed funds–

August 11–12, 2009

38 of 165

brokered funds market. Why wouldn’t the RCAs have the same negative effect? And if we were
doing reverse RPs with Fannie and Freddie, which seems like a more natural extension of what
we are doing now, wouldn’t the RCAs be redundant with that? What would they do? Then, sort
of more broadly, wouldn’t doing this splinter the fed funds market to some extent, detract from
liquidity in the market by breaking it into two pieces—a collateralized piece and a
noncollateralized piece? And then, why aren’t RPs a substitute for RCAs? What do we need
those for when we have RPs already for securitized borrowing and lending and presumably
putting upward pressure on the funds rate?
MR. MCANDREWS. Great list of questions. With regard to the workings of the fed
funds market, I think that, as I mentioned, there is about $125 billion traded per day in the fed
funds market. About half of that is bank to bank, and I don’t think we know how disruptive that
would be if there were reverse RPs or whether that would continue. I have looked at the
distribution of banks’ balances after you remove the fed funds trades they do per day, and there
are still many banks that operate with negative balances per day and, therefore, have to enter the
fed funds market. This is obviously a choice that they are making today. Even with an expanded
balance sheet of $1½ trillion, let’s say, the payments that cross our systems each day amount to
about $3 trillion to $4 trillion. So there will still be a need for banks to trade fed funds. I don’t
think that that market would necessarily either disappear or be severely adversely affected.
Would these be redundant if we used reverse RPs with the GSEs? I think largely they
would be redundant, if we use reverse RPs with the GSEs. However, these would be available to
banks as well as to other entities. So as Chris explained, if we just remove the balances from the
GSEs, there is still a question of where the funds rate would settle. I believe that the RCAs, by
virtue of their applicability to any participant in the market, would set a harder floor on the fed

August 11–12, 2009

39 of 165

funds market. I think the question is whether we think RPs are more operationally complex,
more hands-on intervening in the market, versus the RCAs, which might be thought of as
allowing the market participants to trade among themselves and find the rate.
Then, the question is, Would the market bifurcate into two pieces? That is a clear
possibility. We would have the collateralized market, which would be the floor rate essentially,
and the uncollateralized market, which would continue as it is today. So it would add a new part
to the market. Whether or not that would be seen to be desirable I don’t know. If I may say, as
the Chairman was saying that we have a belt-and-suspenders approach, the RCAs are an idea to
tighten the belt. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. On a couple of the ideas that are being
discussed with respect to excess reserve balances, the GSEs—either in Chris’s context as
potential additional counterparties or in your context, Jamie—could be useful here. What if the
status of the GSEs changed during the period in which we need to conduct these operations? I
think in all likelihood the GSEs will be in the same muddled mess they are in now, and the
Congress and the Administration will leave them as they are in effective conservatorship forever.
But what happens if in fact that is wrong and the GSEs end up finding themselves either more or
less wards of the state with a different mission and capital structure? Does the prospect of the
change in that potentially limit our options—again, depending on when this period of draining
excess reserves comes into being?
MR. MCANDREWS. You are looking at me, but I will turn to Chris as well. I think
that, with regard to the balances of the GSEs, what is important is that all of these payments on

August 11–12, 2009

40 of 165

mortgages funnel into the GSEs. So my first answer to your question is that I don’t think that
part would change for the GSEs regardless of their overall regulatory environment.
MR. BURKE. I guess a piece of it is going to have to do with their liquidity position. In
talking to them, I think they are feeling that they are being forced to hold more liquidity than
they would have chosen to hold on their own. So as their future status changes, if they are
required to hold more liquidity, then they might be selling more into these markets, and then
these solutions would become more important. Or if their liquidity requirements were to
decrease, then they become a bit less of an issue.
MR. CARPENTER. I think one extra point, because you did note accurately the role that
the GSEs played in a lot of the discussion, we are still working out precisely whether it is the
aggregate quantity of reserves all by itself that matters or if there is an extra effect of the GSEs
selling into the market. Chris noted the quantity of fed funds sales that the GSEs did, and so did
Jamie. Relative to the $750 billion of excess right now, it doesn’t seem as though it is that huge
a portion. So there is definitely an argument to be made that we might be focusing too much
attention on them utterly and completely idiosyncratically when it is a larger issue in terms of
just the sheer quantity. I think all of these issues that Chris and Jamie brought up have to be seen
through that filter as well.
MR. BURKE. Our main tool for measuring the fed funds rate is the “fed funds
effective,” which is looking at just that subset of fed funds transactions that are brokered. And in
that market, the GSEs dominate. They are 80-plus percent of those transactions. So when you
start talking about doing something to those transactions, that is the backdrop to my statement
that, if you remove those, you leave a small and potentially idiosyncratic market from which you
are then calculating an effective fed funds rate. So, to Seth’s point, a $75 billion program

August 11–12, 2009

41 of 165

targeted at them is not much with a backdrop of $700 billion or $1.4 trillion in excess, but it may
be that their role and where they are trading and the visibility of their trades imply another
transmission mechanism affecting just them. That is one of the things that we are trying to
puzzle out.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Given these idiosyncrasies in the federal funds market, even
though we might be operating in the overnight market, we may have to consider alternative ways
of expressing our policy target. That should be something we should keep on the table.
President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My question is for Chris, and my
question is this: Potentially we are going to be doing reverse repos both in large magnitudes and
for extended periods of time. Do you have any concern with having only two clearing banks that
are central to that role? And are there ways that we can either increase the competition or spread
out the number of entities that can help with that infrastructure?
MR. BURKE. We have been working with our payment systems folks in New York,
who have been working on identifying the issues with the triparty platform and working on
alternatives to the triparty platform, which is, as you noted, based on those two institutions. As
we know with Bear and Lehman and the outcomes there, there are clearly issues with that
system. So, yes, we are somewhat concerned. And I think, with the PDCF sunset date coming
and the role that it is playing in backstopping triparty, clearly some issues are there. A number
of ideas have floated around. Some are less difficult to implement than others, but we are going
to follow along with that work and, I hope, piggyback on that.
We have started to think a bit about alternatives. The scale of our program is such that it
is going to carry a lot of weight whatever we do, so we are being quite cautious. But depending

August 11–12, 2009

42 of 165

on who our counterparties end up being, it is entirely possible that we could create our own sort
of mini triparty with another clearing bank, say a State Street or something along those lines.
There are an awful lot of issues with that. For that piece of the program, we would end up with a
single clearing bank that was working on it. So it is absolutely an issue, it is a concern, and we
are concerned about it, but we will continue to follow the progress of other groups.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. If I can just interject very briefly.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chair.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. The triparty repo is probably going to be changed very
substantially, and so I think that the clearing bank issue will be resolved in the context of that
adjustment. It won’t be the separate issue in terms of how we are doing the reserve management.
Triparty repo has to be altered, irrespective of the excess reserves issue.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have a question about both the TALF
piece and the tools. First of all, I very much support the Board’s views to suspend work on
RMBS and expanding the range of assets we include in that. It probably comes as no surprise to
most people. I think that is the right thing to do. The Board’s staff actually gave a pretty good,
compelling case from my perspective of why that is a risky and maybe not a wise thing to do.
With regard to the CMBS extension, I have two questions. One is that, no matter when
we choose to end it, if the view is that there are always six months of planning that go into it,
when are we going to decide to actually stop it? Part of that has to do with the question of what
we mean by “unusual and exigent” circumstances and when that will come into play. So we
won’t get four months from June 30 and we won’t say, well, we need another six months to keep
it going. I think we need to clarify a little for ourselves what the criteria are that we’re going to

August 11–12, 2009

43 of 165

use to choose to say “no more” and when we’re going to stop it. It also raises the question for
me, given the long planning time, about some of the rationale for these programs and the 13(3)
lending, in particular. It is unusual and exigent circumstances, but it has been things that had to
be done immediately. Given the long planning periods for CMBS and other types of lending—
the Congress certainly was willing to do “cash for clunkers” and supply a lot of money to
subsidize the automobile companies and the automobile industry— and given the unusual nature
of the challenges in the commercial real estate market, oughtn’t this be a program for the
Treasury rather than a short-term liquidity program for the commercial real estate market? That
is just an open question. How do we determine when the right time is going to be, and when is
the six-month lead period going to be enough on the TALF?
On the tools, in listening to the discussion, I was struck that for the reverse repos the
volumes, at least relative to the size of our balance sheet, are pretty small. And I, like everybody
else, hope that interest on reserves works, that it is enough, and that we do not have to do a lot of
this extra stuff. But we need plans A′ and B to make sure that we can deliver on the policies that
we want. So given the volumes that we would have to do, if the task really came to shrinking the
balance sheet in order to be able to do this, are these tools enough to keep the interest rates where
we want?
I guess that raises the question for me, which is sort of the last stop, about actually selling
assets. We did have a discussion—I think it was at the last meeting—in which we talked about
income implications of selling assets and interest rates. It seems to me, when we talk about
reviewing these tools and mechanisms for hitting our targets in managing reserves, that
understanding both the consequences and the mechanisms by which we would actually sell
assets if the time came to do so need to be in our hip pocket. I guess my request is that, in the

August 11–12, 2009

44 of 165

process of reviewing these reserve management tools, we include the selling-assets piece as a
way of better understanding what the consequences might be if the world came to that’s what we
had to do. That’s all.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Buying and selling we know how to do. [Laughter]
MR. PLOSSER. Buying and selling we know how to do.
MR. BURKE. Should I comment on the scale question?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes.
MR. BURKE. There are clearly scale issues. The entire size of the triparty repo market
for collateral eligible for open market operations is not much more than $1 trillion. So clearly, if
we get into a market and start trying to double its size, there are going to be issues. We are
starting work now on how these tools might fit together. One assumption may be that reverse
repos would be one of a set of tools that we would use to achieve our objective. As you note, it
doesn’t seem likely that we’d be able to find a market to successfully reverse out $1.4 trillion in
assets.
MR. PLOSSER. On a continuing basis.
MR. BURKE. On a continuing basis. Notwithstanding that, we will have over $2 trillion
on our own balance sheet. But an interesting side effect of our doing this amount of repo is that
we know the repo and the fed funds rates are very interconnected and that pressures in one flow
over into the other. So the transmission mechanism may actually be that, as we do these reverse
repos and we drive up GC rates, that the increase in GC rates flows through and starts affecting
other rates. So it may be with this tool that you do not necessarily need to drain all of the excess
out of the system before you start affecting short-term rates in general. That is another aspect of
this that we will be working on.

August 11–12, 2009

45 of 165

MR. PLOSSER. Thank you.
MR. NELSON. With respect to the TALF, the criterion that we applied in thinking about
the problem was that it should be appropriate for emergency lending to take place throughout the
future period that the staff recommends that the facility stay open. So in particular for CMBS,
we thought that there was a reasonably high likelihood that the situation would remain unusual
and exigent through June 30, 2010. In addition, we required that it would be helpful to be open.
Also, even if these criteria were met, if you could wait to announce, then it would be desirable to
delay because your perspective on whether it is going to be unusual and exigent in the future will
become more accurate as time passes. But as I explained, there is a benefit to announcing now
so that people can begin at this time to arrange these deals. That said, as I noted, if the situation
is not unusual and exigent at any point between now and then, it would still be necessary to close
the facility down at that time regardless of the deadline.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. A quick question. Brian, in your charts it says
that the TALF is projected to go to $155 billion by the end of next year. Does that include this
extension? That’s a projection with whatever we are expecting would come from this?
MR. SACK. Yes. When we did the balance sheet projections, we assumed the
extensions that Bill talked about.
MR. EVANS. Okay. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Just to clarify your statement in terms of the
Board’s decision suspending consideration of additional asset classes, I want to follow up on a

August 11–12, 2009

46 of 165

point you just made, Bill. We are talking only in terms of high-grade CMBS, is that correct?
We are not going to extend that category to lower-grade CMBS?
MR. NELSON. That is right. There is no expectation that there will be a change in the
types of CMBS that we would lend against.
MR. FISHER. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thanks. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. About scale, I was wondering, the thought that occurs to me is that
surely it is sort of endogenous. It is a matter of price. If we pay them enough, they will increase
their capacity. I mean, is that reasonable intuition?
MR. BURKE. I think it is a reasonable intuition. The discussions with the dealers
suggest that there is a limit to the size of their balance sheet “regardless of price.” That will be
something to test, I suspect. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. A vertical supply curve.
MR. LACKER. And just a question for Jamie McAndrews. Chris Burke said that
80 percent of the funds market is GSEs to banks?
MR. MCANDREWS. Brokered.
MR. LACKER. Brokered, right. That suggests that typically GSEs lend to a lot of
banks. How many typical counterparties does a GSE have in the fed funds lending market?
How small are the numbers? How limited is competition?
MR. MCANDREWS. I don’t have the figures in front of me. It is in the dozens, and
they lend very similar amounts. We have looked at some of the activity. It is very regular
activity. They don’t seem to lend to that many for a period of time. They apparently have lines
of credit with several, but they choose to lend fairly repeatedly to individual participants.

August 11–12, 2009

47 of 165

MR. LACKER. So you are essentially claiming there is an oligopsony consisting of
dozens of U.S. banks.
MR. MCANDREWS. I am saying that we are far from perfect competition. That is a
market with search frictions and dominated by counterparty credit risk. And it is likely that these
impede pure rate-based competition that we would see if we alleviated the need to engage in
counterparty credit risk—a screening. They could widen the net of potential counterparties to
hundreds and thousands if they were alleviated from counterparty credit risk if these
collateralized fed funds trades were available to them. The issue is, How can we get competition
so that in the interest rate on reserves that the Fed is paying to banks is a floor for society more
generally?
MR. CARPENTER. Just to reduce the incredulity a bit about the market power, one of
the main factors of the non-collateralized market is that risk mitigants include just line limits.
All of the market participants know that the GSEs have limits on their counterparties, and they
also know that on many days, if you were to add up the line limits across all their counterparties,
that would be less than the aggregate amount they are going to want to sell into the market. In
that sense, each individual counterparty has a line limit. They know that the GSEs are going to
use up their line limits, and that is where the market power comes in because the aggregate
amount that they would like to sell is greater than the sum of the individual line limits to
counterparties. And the “dozens” is closer to two dozen, not three, four, or five dozen.
MR. MCANDREWS. What Seth is explaining is very similar to the California energy
market, where only one among dozens of generators would have to go out of service in order for
maximum capacity to be used for all other generators.

August 11–12, 2009

48 of 165

MR. LACKER. I guess the deeper question I have about this is—again, it seems clever,
to echo Governor Kohn—that it seems like a lot of work for a few basis points. We have lived
for years tightly targeting the fed funds rate but tolerating the RP rate 10 or 15 basis points on
either side of the fed funds rate. And we have never had a solid conviction that it was one and
not the other that was relevant for the constellation of rates. Or even look at, I don’t know, onemonth T-bill rates, right? So tolerating 15 basis points seems in the grand scheme of things to be
something we are willing to do.
MR. MADIGAN. A question, President Lacker, is whether it would persist at just
15 basis points, 10 basis points, or so as the level of rates goes up. And we just don’t know that.
MR. LACKER. That is a serious question.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I have a question about the brokered fed funds market
versus the other. It seems as though we are a bit captured by the brokered fed funds market
because that is where we have the rate information. But couldn’t we actually get the rate
information on the bank-to-bank funds market if we really made an effort and because we
regulate these entities? [Laughter] And if that were the case, we might not want to have the
brokered funds market be the dominant element driving our decisions. It is just an observation
question.
MR. MCANDREWS. We gathered that information today with error, and I think we can
improve it if we work with the banks. It is with some delay, so the brokers are real time, which
is a benefit.

August 11–12, 2009

49 of 165

MR. BURKE. But in principle you could establish a collection scheme by which you get
directly from the banks at the close of business each day the average rate and volume of business
that they have done and then aggregate it and get a more complete picture of fed funds rates.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Then you don’t have to worry about the GSEs
contaminating your observations of the brokered funds market. You know, a lot of this is an
effort to take the GSEs and the fact that they are contaminating that market. There might be an
easier way to ignore that market and go to the broader market.
MR. BURKE. Until very recently, all of our evidence suggested that the brokered fed
funds market was just a good and representative subset of the overall market. Clearly, we are
under the impression that that has changed.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Yes, not so much anymore.
MR. BURKE. Right.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Once again, there is a lot of benefit to trying to figure out
what is the right target and what is the most meaningful target for policy. Are there more
questions or comments on this range of issues that anyone would like to bring up? We will of
course have two more go-rounds. If not, we have a vote to ratify domestic open market
operations.
MR. KOHN. So move.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Without objection. Okay. Why don’t we take a coffee
break? We have coffee available. Return at 4:15. Thank you.
[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Why don’t we recommence and turn to the
economic situation. Presentation is by Larry Slifman and Nathan Sheets. Larry.

August 11–12, 2009

50 of 165

MR. SLIFMAN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. If I may paraphrase Garrison
Keillor, it’s been a relatively quiet few weeks for macro forecasters. For the most
part, the high-frequency data on activity that we have received since the June FOMC
meeting have come in either in line with our expectations or a bit better, and the
numbers continue to remain consistent with the hypothesis that economic activity is
stabilizing. At the same time, as Brian has already described, financial conditions
have continued to improve.
Before I discuss some of the details of the forecast, let me briefly cover two other
matters: last Friday’s labor market report and the comprehensive revision to the
national income and product accounts. First, regarding the labor market, the BLS
reported that private nonfarm payroll employment fell 254,000 in July, and the
declines in May and June are now estimated to have been a little smaller than
previously thought. The net result is that the level of private employment in July was
about 85,000 higher than we were expecting when we published the Greenbook. In
addition, the unemployment rate ticked down to 9.4 percent—we had been expecting
a small increase. Although we would not be inclined to make any changes to our
GDP projection as a result of this more favorable labor market news, it does help
reinforce our view that a gradual turnaround in economic activity will begin in the
second half of the year.
As regards the NIPA revision, I would emphasize two elements. First, as you
know, real GDP was revised down considerably in 2008 and the first quarter of 2009.
This downward revision reduced some of the tension between our estimates of the
output gap and the unemployment rate gap but did not eliminate it. During the next
several weeks, we plan to reassess all of our supply-side estimates, but at this point
we don’t anticipate any major changes. The second important element of the NIPA
revision was a sequence of sizable downward revisions to real disposable personal
income beginning in early 2007. The cumulative effect of the revisions was to put
DPI on a significantly weaker trajectory through the middle of 2009, which was an
important ingredient in our thinking about the outlook for consumer spending.
One other data revision, which we learned with the release of the June figures for
personal income and outlays, was a downward revision to personal consumption
expenditures in the first half of 2009. Prior to the revision, it appeared that consumer
spending was edging higher during the first half of the year. However, the new data,
instead, now show consumption to have been drifting down over much of the period.
Nevertheless, we still expect a gradual turnaround in consumer spending in the
second half of the year—based in part on a further boost from fiscal stimulus as well
as less-pronounced employment declines and improving financial conditions.
Outside the consumer sector, the latest readings on housing starts and orders for
capital goods point to a lessening in the declines for residential construction and
equipment spending. Moreover, with final demand stabilizing and inventory
positions considerably improved from earlier in the year, we think that over the next
several months firms will slowly begin to move production back up toward the level

August 11–12, 2009

51 of 165

of sales. Indeed, a number of indicators of near-term movements in factory output—
such as weekly steel production, durable goods orders, and various business
surveys—suggest that such an adjustment may already be in process.
For next year, we continue to expect the growth rate of real GDP to pick up.
Importantly, continued financial healing, supported by accommodative monetary
policy, sets the stage for further improvements in household and business sentiment
and an acceleration in final demand. All told, real GDP is projected to rise about
3 percent over the four quarters of 2010, close to the projection in the June
Greenbook. Nevertheless, the rate of increase in GDP next year—while still faster
than the rise in potential—is relatively tepid for an economic recovery, only enough
to reduce the unemployment rate to 9½ percent.
Our forecast reflects a balancing of a number of forces. A negative factor was the
lower trajectory for disposable income that I previously mentioned; given the typical
lags between income and spending, this acts as a drag on consumption in coming
quarters. On the plus side of the ledger, as Brian noted earlier, equity prices are up
appreciably since the last Greenbook, whereas corporate bond yields and spreads are
down. In addition, as Nathan will discuss, the foreign exchange value of the dollar is
down, and the forecast for foreign growth is stronger.
As for the components of real GDP next year, the basic stories haven’t changed in
any important ways. In the household sector, we expect consumer spending to
strengthen and the saving rate to drift down a bit as prospects for jobs and incomes
brighten, negative wealth effects wane, and the availability of consumer credit
improves. Meanwhile, housing demand and construction, which appear to have
reached their bottoms this summer, are expected to strengthen as income picks up and
low mortgage rates and lower real estate prices enhance affordability. In the business
sector, we think that the usual accelerator mechanism should spur outlays for
equipment and software, augmented by some easing of financial constraints and by
some extra demand as a result of replacement spending that had been deferred during
the recession. In contrast, business outlays for structures such as office and
commercial buildings are expected to continue to contract throughout 2010 in the
presence of extremely tight credit conditions and falling property values.
Turning to the outlook for inflation, the NIPA revision incorporated new
information on nonmarket prices, which now show a sharp deceleration in the first
half of the year. But we don’t take any signal from this; and when all is said and
done, it looks as though the underlying pace of core inflation has been running a little
higher than we had anticipated. In addition, survey-based measures of longer-run
inflation expectations have remained relatively stable. In contrast, the incoming data
on hourly compensation have decelerated sharply this year. The employment cost
index increased at an annual rate of only ¾ percent in the first half of 2009, whereas
the Labor Department reported this morning that the productivity and cost measure of
hourly compensation declined at a rate of about 1 percent. These low readings
suggest that economic slack already is weighing heavily on labor costs. We continue

August 11–12, 2009

52 of 165

to expect that the low level of resource utilization will hold down price inflation as
well over the projection period, with core PCE prices rising about 1½ percent this
year and 1 percent next year.
In the Greenbook, we highlighted several risks to our output and inflation
forecasts. On the downside for output, we noted the possibility that the improvement
in financial conditions observed since the spring could prove to be short-lived and the
financial system could suffer a relapse rather than recuperate. We also highlighted
the possibility that, in the wake of the financial and economic turmoil of the past two
years, households could raise by a significant amount their desired saving relative to
the baseline. According to the policy rule we use, either outcome would noticeably
delay the eventual liftoff of the funds rate from the zero lower bound. That said, we
also recognize the possibility that financial healing could occur more rapidly than we
anticipate. Such a development would lead to a more robust recovery of economic
activity and less unemployment. Under those circumstances, the federal funds rate
lifts off from zero a year earlier than in the baseline.
The funds rate also would be expected to lift off sooner under our assumed policy
rule if the inflation outlook were to take a decisive turn upward. This might occur,
for example, if the public’s concerns about the expansion of our balance sheet were to
manifest themselves in an appreciable increase in inflation expectations. We
examined this possibility in an alternative Greenbook scenario in which we assumed
that long-run inflation expectations rise about 1 percentage point over the next several
months. In that scenario, core PCE inflation climbs steadily over the projection
period, reaching 2½ percent by 2013. That development in turn brings forward the
liftoff in the federal funds rate by three quarters.
So, what does this all mean? Well, while it’s been a quiet few weeks for macro
forecasters, the risks to the economic outlook are still all above average. Nathan will
now continue our presentation.
MR. SHEETS. Since the June FOMC meeting, some encouraging signs have
emerged in the foreign economies. We now estimate that average growth abroad
edged positive last quarter, and we expect that it will rise to above 2½ percent in the
second half of this year and to 3¼ percent next year. Relative to our June forecast,
these projections are up 1 percentage point in the second half of the year and
¼ percentage point in 2010. Given the remarkable depth of the recent downturn, we
continue to characterize the projected recovery as sluggish but not quite as sluggish as
we previously envisioned. We also note that progress has been uneven across the
regions of the global economy. Asia has seen a blockbuster rebound, while in many
advanced economies and Latin America the declines in activity have continued,
although at a much reduced pace.
In emerging Asia, Chinese GDP soared at an estimated 18½ percent annual rate in
the second quarter, driven by fiscal stimulus measures and accelerated bank lending.
Strikingly, the increase in bank credit over the first six months of the year was equal

August 11–12, 2009

53 of 165

to 25 percent of China’s annual GDP. These hefty stimulus measures successfully
lifted domestic demand, with both investment and consumption moving up sharply.
Chinese imports have also risen significantly of late, creating positive spillovers for
other countries in the region. Boosted by Chinese demand but also by their own
stimulative macro policies, domestic demand in several emerging Asian economies
has revived of late, including in Korea, where second-quarter GDP moved up at a
10 percent pace. All told, we judge that emerging-Asia GDP expanded at a
12½ percent annual rate in the second quarter. Going forward, we expect economic
growth in the region to moderate to around 6 percent through the second half of this
year and in 2010. However, there are risks to this outlook. The apparent intention of
the Chinese authorities is to leave stimulative policies largely in place until external
demand recovers. The problem is that the available policy tools are mainly
administrative in nature and difficult to calibrate. If the present stimulus is removed
too abruptly, we could see a hard landing in the region. And if the stimulus is left in
place too long, the result could be an upsurge of bad loans, other financial
imbalances, or overheating economies. How this will all play out strikes us as very
much an open issue.
Demand from emerging Asia appears to have resuscitated the Japanese economy.
A rebound in exports and production fueled an estimated 4 percent rise in Japanese
GDP during the second quarter, following two double-digit quarterly declines. Going
forward, continued demand from emerging Asia and the gradual strengthening of
global activity more generally should allow the export-dependent Japanese economy
to grow at a rate of 2 to 3 percent through the forecast period.
For the advanced foreign economies other than Japan, the pace of decline in the
second quarter appears to have let up some, but GDP by our reckoning still fell at an
annual rate of nearly 3 percent. Here too, however, recent signs have been hopeful:
Exports have halted their downward slide; confidence and activity surveys have
rebounded; and equity prices have continued to move up. Given these developments,
along with ongoing policy stimulus, we see growth in these economies edging back
into positive territory in the second half of this year and to 2¼ percent in 2010. This
gradual recovery is likely to be constrained by persisting financial headwinds—
particularly related to the still-fragile condition of major financial institutions in many
of these countries—and by further deterioration in labor market conditions. The
possibility that these factors may be more adverse than we now expect represents a
notable downside risk to the outlook.
The spot price of WTI oil is currently around $70 per barrel, essentially
unchanged from the time of your last meeting. Although the stronger-than-expected
rebound in emerging Asia likely points to a firmer path of oil demand going forward,
oil inventory levels have increased further in recent weeks, and oil production in
Russia and several OPEC countries appears to be edging up.
Concerns about the extent and timing of recovery have remained the primary
focus of policymakers in the foreign economies. Since your last meeting, major

August 11–12, 2009

54 of 165

foreign central banks have largely extended their policy measures. The European
Central Bank in late June auctioned a mammoth €442 billion of one-year term
funding at its main refinancing rate, pushing overnight market interest rates down to
about 35 basis points. Additional one-year auctions are scheduled for September and
December, but the ECB has indicated that these auctions may be at an interest rate
above the main refinancing rate. In July, the Bank of Canada reiterated its
conditional commitment to keep its policy rate at 25 basis points until the end of the
second quarter of 2010. Finally, the Bank of England surprised markets last week
when it announced that it was expanding the size of its asset-purchase facility by
£50 billion. The BOE plans to acquire the additional securities over the next three
months, which suggests a slowing in the pace of its monthly purchases from about
£25 billion to £17 billion. We see major central banks leaving policy rates at their
current low levels through the end of next year. Given the gradual projected pace of
recovery in these countries and our expectation that headline CPI inflation will
remain muted, foreign central banks are likely to have ample room for maneuver in
unwinding policy stimulus.
The somewhat better global outlook and a resulting increase in investor risk
appetite have led to a further 1½ percent decline in the dollar, as Brian Sack has
indicated. Notably, the dollar is now near the center of its trading range over the past
18 months, down about 10 percent since its peak in early March but also up nearly
10 percent from the lows recorded during the first half of last year. Going forward,
we project that the dollar will remain on a modest downward trajectory, depreciating
at an annual rate of about 2 percent, reflecting ongoing financing pressures associated
with the current account deficit.
Consistent with news around the globe, we are also seeing signs that U.S. trade
may be bottoming out. Although real exports on average appear to have declined
further in the second quarter, recent monthly data are now pointing to a rebound. In
line with these signals, we expect exports to bounce back at a 7¼ percent pace in the
second half of the year and to expand 5¼ percent in 2010. Prompted by the weaker
dollar and the upward revision to foreign activity, we have marked up export growth
4 percentage points in the second half of this year and 1¼ percentage points next
year. Similarly, we see imports expanding at a pace of roughly 7 percent in the
second half (boosted in part by a recovery in automotive imports) and nearly
5 percent next year (supported by the recovery in U.S. demand). Taken together, net
exports are expected to subtract about 0.1 percentage point from U.S. GDP growth on
average over the forecast period, somewhat less negative than in our June forecast.
The following point bears emphasis, however. Both imports and exports fell
sharply during the recent recession. The level of real imports in the second quarter is
estimated to be 20 percent below the previous peak, and the level of real exports is
down 15 percent. While our forecast does incorporate some additional cyclical
rebound, over and above what our models would suggest, there is a risk that imports,
exports, or both could bounce back much more vigorously than we have written
down, with potentially sizable implications for the contribution from net exports to

August 11–12, 2009

55 of 165

U.S. GDP growth. That concludes our presentation, and we are happy to take your
questions.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Are there questions for our colleagues?
President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. A question for Nathan. You know, the
Chinese economy is increasingly a central focus as we evaluate the global economy. And you
referenced the bank lending in the last quarter, which appeared to be directed lending, top down,
telling them to lend. Some years ago there was continuing concern about the banking system in
China being insolvent. They seem to have muddled through that, but do we know anything
about the potential of a banking crisis in China that could have been exacerbated by this directed
lending?
MR. SHEETS. My sense is that there are some significant risks to the banking system
associated with this extraordinarily rapid rise in bank credit that we have seen over the last six
months. Now, a good chunk of that lending was associated with the fiscal stimulus program, and
so in some sense it is at least being implicitly guaranteed by the government. Another piece of it
seems to be related to lending to regional and provincial governments. So, again, there is
something of a public guarantee. But I think, even over and above what we can link even loosely
to the fiscal stimulus, there was a substantial quantity of lending that happened. I personally find
it difficult to believe that that much credit could be allocated as quickly as we saw in the first
half of the year and for it all to be perfectly efficiently allocated. So my instinct here is that at
some point we will see some bad loans emerge. I think that is a risk. I think there is also ample
room to question how effective and efficient the Chinese banks are. On the other hand, you have
the Chinese government, which has ample resources. So my sense is that, yes, at some point
down the road we are going to see some financial aftermath of what has happened over the last

August 11–12, 2009

56 of 165

six months. But my sense is also that the Chinese authorities have resources to be able to
recapitalize and address and resolve these problems in their banking sector without its
necessarily being a first-order issue for the Chinese economy or more broadly for the global
economy.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Yes, thank you. Larry, I was struck by the decline in the productivity and
cost measure of compensation in the first half. Is there something special going on there? Or
should we conclude that compensation is less sticky than we might have earlier thought? If so,
what are the implications, if any, for employment going forward?
MR. SLIFMAN. We don’t know for sure, but our speculation is that some of this had to
do with bonus payments—that there are just a lot fewer bonus payments being made now than
had been made in 2008, 2007, and so on. So we think that that might have been part of what is
going on; that is, taking the bonuses out lowers the level of compensation. But the broader point
is that we think that labor market slack is having an effect on wage determination; probably there
is less nominal wage stickiness in the economy than there was 20 or 30 years ago. And as I said,
with the unemployment rate up in the 9½ percent range, that is putting a lot of downward
pressure on wage determination.
MR. STERN. There certainly have been a lot of anecdotes about voluntary cuts in wages
and salaries to preserve employment.
MR. SLIFMAN. Absolutely. So while we have not built in further outright declines in
hourly compensation in the forecast, we do have very slow rates of increase in hourly
compensation in the forecast.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Bullard.

August 11–12, 2009

57 of 165

MR. BULLARD. Larry, a year ago or more, we talked some about regime-switching
models, where when we entered recession some of the relationships are different, coefficients are
different, and so on. Now it appears that we might be exiting the recession. Would we switch
back to some sort of more normal times model, or is this all by the bye here?
MR. SLIFMAN. In a mechanical sense, the way we have implemented this in the
forecast for much of 2008–09 is to take what our models would want to forecast and then put in
negative add factors to take account of the financial turmoil as well as a regime switching that
you would get in a normal recession. In 2010, we are not getting rid of them, but we are
diminishing the size of those negative add factors as we think the financial system recuperates
and as we move out of recession and into a recovery period. But that said, it is important to keep
in mind that this recovery is still quite tepid by historical standards. Typically, the economy goes
back to its previous peak level of real GDP in two to three quarters. In our projection, it takes
seven quarters for that to occur; so these things are still, in our view, weighing heavily on the
economy.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would like to ask a question of Nathan. At
our last meeting and in previous meetings in talking about China, the issue was whether or not
they might be able to convert their economy to be more domestic demand driven. Clearly, the
stimulus package, in addition to leaking into the securities markets and all of the corruption that
has ensued, has affected infrastructure, and that is where I think you see some of this boom
coming in the rest of Asia. For what it is worth, my Chinese contacts and the ones in Singapore
suggest that there still is a long-term dependency on U.S. and European demand, to the point that
they assert that this boom or boomlet might go on for another two years or so. But unless we

August 11–12, 2009

58 of 165

pick up demand and unless Europe picks up demand, it is unlikely to continue. I wonder if that
is an assessment that you might share.
MR. SHEETS. I think it is very much the intention of the Chinese authorities to continue
these policies until they see the pickup in external demand. Governor Tarullo used the analogy
at the last meeting of the Chinese being in a holding pattern, waiting for the global economy to
pick up, and I think that is exactly the right analogy. I guess what I am wondering and what I am
questioning is whether they can calibrate this stimulus, particularly the awesome monetary
stimulus, in such a way that they are able to build a bridge from where they are to the time when
global demand picks up and whether there might not be some significant imbalances that
manifest themselves between now and that point in time.
One way to articulate this concern very concretely is that I very much doubt that six
months ago the Chinese authorities came to the conclusion that in the second quarter of the year
they wanted to put in stimulus such that the economy would expand at an 18½ percent annual
rate. The fact that they got this outcome really emphasizes the blunt nature of the policy tools
they have. If they overshoot in the second quarter, I see that there is a risk they may further
overshoot on the upside or significantly undershoot on the downside.
So I just don’t fully see what the exit strategy is. Earlier this decade, people were very
concerned about a hard landing in China, and they were able to thread the needle. Maybe they
will be able to do that again. In fact, for what it is worth, that is what our forecast has written
down as a baseline against which to talk about these risks. So there is a chance that they will be
able to grow at 9 percent on average for the next six quarters or the next couple of years. But I
for one am very concerned. I see this rebound in China as really being the key driver of a lot of
what we have seen in the global economy, certainly in emerging Asia and Japan and even echoes

August 11–12, 2009

59 of 165

of it in certain places in Europe, such as Germany, where exports are picking up. So if the pace
of Chinese recovery steps down, we are looking at a much softer global outlook than we are with
a stronger China or a Chinese growth path similar to what we have in the forecast.
MR. FISHER. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I agree with the idea that they are looking to Europe and the
United States. But in the latest strategic and economic dialogue that we had with the Chinese—
Governor Warsh was there as well—I heard much more seriousness about a longer-term
transition to a more domestically driven economy. What time frame that has and how that bears
on the current situation is a different question, and I heard much more talk about that and a much
more detailed discussion of that.
MR. SHEETS. Consistent with that, to their credit, through this period of softness and
external demand, instead of trying to depreciate the exchange rate, they have depended on
domestic demand and fiscal stimulus, and they are trying to do it themselves. So I would say
that is a step in the right direction. But then the question is, How committed are they, and at
what pace are they willing to pursue the deeper structural reforms that are going to be necessary
to support private spending and private consumption in China, such as developing financial
markets and social safety nets and that sort of thing?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Other questions? Seeing none, we are ready for our
economic go-round. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The incoming data have been encouraging
though a bit bumpy. On balance, although the developments over the past several weeks left my
medium-term outlook essentially unchanged, they did give me more confidence. In my view,
this reduced uncertainty strengthens the case for a wait-and-see approach to policy. The reports

August 11–12, 2009

60 of 165

from my directors and business contacts support the improving tenor of recent data releases.
Business activity is plausibly stabilizing, albeit at very low levels; and in some sectors where the
contractions have been on a horrific scale, we have even seen a bit of a bounceback.
Most of these turnaround cases are in auto-related manufacturing. Arcelor-Mittal Steel is
following through on my earlier report of increasing its online capacity this summer. This
reflects both an auto-related rebound in production and the completion of an inventoryadjustment cycle at steel service centers. Accordingly, steel prices have moved up off very low
levels. And a large-scale manufacturer of relatively small auto parts said that his order flow has
picked up and that the new rate is consistent with the higher level of production currently
scheduled by the OEMs (original equipment manufacturers) for the third quarter. I spoke with
Ford about the effect of the cash-for-clunkers program. They had an interesting story about
which future sales were being stolen by the program. A substantial segment of the clunker tradeins have been well-maintained SUVs that are about ten years old and whose owners have good
FICO scores, above 650. This leads Ford to think that, without the program, these people would
have driven their clunkers for another couple of years. So perhaps we are stealing sales from
2010 or beyond, not just the fourth quarter. But GM suggested that the payback would be
sooner. Also, any uncertain extensions of this program could freeze potential buyers, and so they
seem to indicate that it was very important to have a certain date to this program to fix
everybody’s attention. Nevertheless, both Ford and GM suggested that there would be a small
upward adjustment to their current third-quarter plans and then further output increases in the
fourth, and apparently Chrysler news reports are similar to this.
Moving to broader economy-wide conditions, labor markets seem to be stabilizing.
Obviously, last month’s pause in the unemployment rate’s inevitable continued rise is a welcome

August 11–12, 2009

61 of 165

sign that moderating forces may be gaining some traction. But labor markets are still weak, and
the predominant view among my business contacts is that companies’ current plans are to
strongly resist rehiring many of their laid-off workers when demand eventually does pick up.
They would see anything more than minimal rehiring as undoing the difficult and productive
labor cost-cutting that they had done during the recession. Now, there are reasons to be skeptical
of this talk. They probably say it in every cycle, and they have been very aggressive in cutting
employment this time. Still, it does suggest that the unemployment rate could remain stubbornly
high well into the recovery stage of this cycle.
With regard to financial conditions, our market contacts say that the extreme tail risks
have dissipated and that this is reflected in more-normal spreads and lending relationships. The
Chicago Mercantile Exchange reported that market depth in euro, dollar, and Treasury futures
has returned to pre-Lehman levels. I did hear that the legacy CMBS TALF has contributed to a
dramatic improvement in liquidity in commercial real estate credit markets. Still, the
fundamentals underlying commercial real estate markets are poor. A number of my contacts
think that many properties are overvalued and that prices are headed for a further fall.
Summing up all of the developments, our near-term outlook for growth is a little more
optimistic than the Greenbook’s, but our projections for next year are about the same. As I noted
earlier, my uncertainty over the economic outlook is a bit less than it was at our last meeting.
I can’t say the same about my uncertainty over the inflation forecast, and this is perhaps
the most difficult and confusing period we can imagine. Clearly, resource gaps will be an
important factor restraining inflation over the immediate projection period and beyond. I hear
this rationale for disinflationary pressures from many of my business contacts, particularly with
regard to respective labor costs. But many of these very same contacts, and much of the more

August 11–12, 2009

62 of 165

general public, can easily visualize potential inflation pressures coming from the enormous
current growth in narrow money and huge future fiscal deficits. And measures of inflation
expectations have not moved down appreciably with the greater awareness of this coming
resource slack. So that is a little surprising to me. Our task as prudent central bankers is to
assure them that we will do what it takes to achieve our price stability goals. And yes,
everybody is doing that. But I think we are unlikely to see much relief from this educational
burden for some time to come. We are going to need to talk about this a lot more before we
actually change monetary policy appreciably, I would guess.
Despite the risks on both sides, I continue to have a middle ground inflation forecast. By
“middle ground” I mean that I see an uncomfortable balance between these disinflationary forces
from large resource slack and inflation expectations that give notable weight to the large growth
in our balance sheet and concerns that we may be reluctant to make a timely exit from our
programs. This leaves me with a forecast that calls for core PCE inflation to remain near its
current 1½ percent pace over the next couple of years. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, if I may, before I make my comment, I do want to thank
Gary for his service. I have a friend who turned 107 and who died the other day. When he
turned 100, [laughter]—he ran Kidder Peabody in 1931—being a great stock picker, he said it
would split two for one. Gary, even if you split two for one, you would still have the shortest
interventions of anybody at this table and probably the pithiest. You will be seriously missed.
I would like to start out by talking a little about what we see in the data, and then I would
like to provide a summary of what I gleaned from my corporate contacts. Then given the

August 11–12, 2009

63 of 165

taxonomy that Mr. Wessel has imposed on this table, I am going to conclude with a comment
about balls.
First, on the data in terms of our District, we are seeing significantly better signs about
stabilization. Our initial claims for unemployment insurance are declining. Our housing
industry, which wasn’t suffering as much as others, has experienced an uplift. Our single-family
permits were up 13 percent year over year in June; existing home sales were up 3½ percent. And
other than President Pianalto’s District, we had the best Case–Shiller performance, I think from a
slightly higher base, in the recent numbers that were reported. As the leading exporting state, we
are taking some succor in the data that are coming out. Our exporting activity is getting less bad,
but it is still not positive. And from our own calculation of leading indicators at the Dallas Fed,
we have seen three months of increase after nine months of decrease. So from the narrow
perspective of our District, we are encouraged to see some stabilization.
I think the national picture has been well covered by the presentations that were made,
with one exception. We don’t quite share your relative pessimism about the bounceback in
economic growth. We can expect, over the next few quarters perhaps, a little more aggressive
activity. It is really when we deemphasize the negatives and accentuate the positives, as I like to
say, and get a boost from inventory investment and government purchase. Nonetheless, both of
those will be assuredly temporary. It is what happens after that that we are concerned about. So
I would say from the standpoint of my District and from what we are seeing in the data
nationally, if you will forgive a bad joke, it is a slightly brighter shade of beige—not
tremendously exciting but nonetheless improved from what we saw before.
In terms of CEO contacts—and the Chairman has my list—just to comment, Brian, on
your presentation, particularly your slide number 2 with regard to corporate earnings. By my

August 11–12, 2009

64 of 165

calculations, so far 443 of the S&P 500 have reported. Of the 419 nonfinancials that reported,
revenues—I am not talking about earnings but revenues—are down 19.1 percent versus
4.6 percent for the 24 financials that have reported. This is the third double-digit quarterly
decline in sales, and the previous quarter was the second back to back that we have seen since
1965. It seems to me, if I were to summarize the one theme I am hearing from my CEO
contacts, that it would be that there is too much of everything relative to demand for the
foreseeable future. There are too many ships at sea. And speaking of the Chinese, as you know
they are becoming a building power. I talked about this many, many months, if not a couple of
years ago, at this table. They expect, according to some shippers I talked to, to deliver up to
40 percent of the existing global fleet in 2010, 2011, and 2012.
There are too many railroad cars. There are 507 miles, Mr. Chairman, of unused
mothballed railroad cars now in the United States, 5,280 feet in a mile, and each car is 90 feet
long. I will let you do the math. But the point is we are not going to build a railroad car in this
country for years. There are too many airplanes; there are too many homes; there are too many
hotels, too many office buildings, and too many retail stores and malls. There are
145,000 convenience stores in this country, and the operators of those companies all expect to
rationalize significantly.
There is too much oil. And to give you a number that comes from Rex Tillerson, the
CEO of Exxon, there are 120 million barrels of floating inventory. That is the highest he can
recall in his experience. There are 3 trillion square feet of natural gas on the ground. We have
not before, to anybody’s knowledge that I have been able to find out, had this high an inventory
count this early in the year. And the resource wells and these narrow wells—that is, like the
Barnett Shale—have to be counted as reserves as well.

August 11–12, 2009

65 of 165

There is too much corn. There is even too much polyester. [Laughter] As Governor
Tarullo points out—and he and I watch the same television shows; we were raised on “Saturday
Night Live”—there has always been too much polyester. But the Chinese are now bidding down
their prices 5 to 6 percent for the fashion year that starts at the end of this year.
So capacity is vast. Cap-ex will remain subdued. As to head count—and the point that
President Evans was making earlier about employment—many, many business people I talk with
report that they have cut to the bone. But they also report that, not surprisingly, their workforce
is much more productive than it was before, perhaps driven by fear of losing their jobs and
benefits. They realize that, at least for the immediate term, these business operators can drive
their businesses with fewer workers than they had assumed. So most remain in a defensive
crouch. Most are focused on cost containment. They are driving their margins, but they are
struggling to grow their top line.
I would just conclude with my earlier reference to balls: We seem to have to stay on the
balls of our feet because—I am sure you are relieved about that reference—[laughter] as I
believe you said earlier, Larry, the risks, like the children of Lake Wobegon, are all above
average here. We are eliminating the negative. We are accentuating the positive of inventory
replacement, a slight pickup here and there. But it is pretty clear to me, if you will again forgive
a terrible pun, that business operators in this country are suffering from post-traumatic slack
syndrome. They see it in the abundance of supply. They see it in labor. Their plans to step up
to the plate in terms of cap-ex and head count are, it appears to me, constantly being postponed,
and therein lies the difficult issue of how we are going to deal with unemployment. So that is my
report, Mr. Chairman. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, President Fisher. Governor Tarullo.

August 11–12, 2009

66 of 165

MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Having exhausted my limited stock of
witticisms about coming last in line before the Chairman, I asked Debbie to move me up.
[Laughter] But I also wanted to come a little earlier because, even in the five months since my
first FOMC meeting, a lot has changed. At that time, we were contemplating essentially two
scenarios, very bad and even worse. In no small part because of the various actions of the
Federal Reserve, the financial system and the economy have largely stabilized, albeit at
historically lower levels than we would certainly like to see.
It seems very likely now there will be positive, perhaps quite positive, growth in the
second half of this year. As for 2010, more upside risk has crept into many people’s forecasts.
So in thinking about our policies going forward, we may be at a point at which it is useful to
consider alternative outcomes in a roughly probabilistic fashion and to test how readily we can
craft the narrative that leads to each outcome. It would be a bit quixotic of me to undertake this
task for all seven of the Greenbook scenarios to which Larry alluded earlier, so let me distill the
manifold possibilities to just three. One, grind it out—a gradual, somewhat halting recovery that
leads to 2010 growth somewhere in the vicinity of trend but below what one might expect in a
rebound from a severe slump. Two, relapse—a significant stumble for the recovery next year,
with GDP growth again dropping significantly below trend. And, three, rejuvenation—a much
more robust recovery, with GDP growth significantly exceeding trend, not quite a V-shape
perhaps but a reasonably steep slope on the way up.
So just to put my cards on the table, I would assign roughly even odds to the first possible
outcome, the grind-out scenario. Not coincidentally, I regard the Greenbook extended baseline
to be consistent with this outcome. Although I am somewhat less optimistic about next year than
the staff is, I note that their forecast for the second half of this year is pretty conservative. So if

August 11–12, 2009

67 of 165

one averages out their forecast over six quarters, it yields something akin to the first outcome.
Of the remaining two, I see a somewhat greater chance of relapse than of rejuvenation, though I
should say that I now regard the odds of the two alternative outcomes as considerably less
skewed than I thought as recently as the June meeting. So clearly I find the story of measured
recovery the easiest to tell, in part because the very factors that augur well for the remainder of
2009 may not have sufficient staying power to maintain a healthy pace of recovery through all of
next year.
The salutary effects of the fiscal stimulus package will start tapering off in the first part of
next year. The undoubted need for firms to replenish their inventories will lead to sustained
production increases only if consumption increases can themselves be generated and maintained.
The case for a steady increase in personal consumption expenditures is certainly plausible, but it
is hardly compelling. According to the reported employment cost index, private wages and
salaries have been decelerating. With large and still growing slack in labor markets, there is
good reason to believe that personal income will continue to suffer from rising unemployment
and suppressed wage gains. Moreover, there remains, as Larry mentioned, the important
question of what saving rate we will see once incomes do begin to rise again. The Greenbook
makes a reasonable case based on past experience for a 4 percent rate, but the present crisis may
contain the seeds of a behavioral shift among some classes of consumers that could move the rate
up a percentage point or more.
It appears that even the new normalcy in credit availability, both retail and wholesale,
may be some way off. The progress in the corporate bond markets, and to a lesser degree shortterm funding markets and plain vanilla securitization markets, has not extended to credit markets
more generally. In particular, the rate of decline in bank lending has been accelerating during the

August 11–12, 2009

68 of 165

spring and summer. There will doubtless be multiple revisions to the July figures, but the
preliminary estimate of a whopping 18 percent decline spread across all forms of lending is a
sobering reminder of the difficulties ahead. While a considerable part of this drop is surely
attributable to the decline in demand and cautiousness in underwriting that are typical of
recessions, it seems likely that there are also structural factors in both bank lending and credit
markets, such as capital impairment and business model challenges, that will weigh on credit
markets for some time.
I can certainly tell the other two stories—though with less conviction and, in the interest
of time, more briefly. A relapse could occur if privately generated demand cannot adequately fill
in behind the waning effect of fiscal stimulus, given such factors as the expected persistently
high levels of unemployment; the potential for more-rapid efforts to repair personal, corporate,
and financial balance sheets; and the severe retrenchment of sub-federal government spending
that is coming in the next two budget cycles. If commercial real estate markets turn out to be
even moderately worse than currently expected—bad enough—loan losses at many regional and
community banks could become truly debilitating.
Rejuvenation might come if both confidence and wealth are significantly boosted by a
continuation of the equity market rally and a more rapid recovery of housing markets. The latter
of course would also prompt a greater rebound in construction. Along with the effects of pent-up
consumer demand for durables and other items, these developments could provide not just a
substitute for fiscal stimulus but a boost beyond the temporary effects of cash-for-clunkers,
infrastructure investment, and the various income transfer features of the February legislative
package. Global economic recovery, particularly in Asia, may proceed more quickly with an
attendant boost to U.S. export growth. While I can sketch out this more optimistic path, each of

August 11–12, 2009

69 of 165

its elements seems quite a bit less likely than those supporting the more sluggish outcome and
modestly less likely than the catalyst for relapse.
I will be interested to hear if some of you can tell this last tale more convincingly. For
the present, though, what I think is most important in my little exercise is that the chances of next
year being somewhere between tepid and bad appear to me somewhere north of 75 percent in the
absence of further monetary or fiscal policy measures. Where exactly along that spectrum the
actual outcome falls will probably not become much clearer for some time. If this is a
reasonable way of looking at things, our best-advised posture for at least a few more, and maybe
more than a few more, meetings may be the somewhat unsatisfactory and awkward one of
neither lifting another implement out of our toolbox nor closing the box up and declaring the job
finished. Mom was right at least sometimes: Patience really can be a virtue. [Laughter] Thank
you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The data since the last meeting have
been broadly consistent with what we expected in our June forecast. We have received
confirmation that the economy has improved significantly from the sharp declines in the first
quarter. Economic growth in the second half of 2009 is likely to be positive, albeit too slow to
prevent further job losses. Our forecast still expects a weak recovery as the balance sheets of
consumers, businesses, and banks slowly improve. The improvement is, of course, contingent on
no significant adverse shocks appearing over the next year. It also assumes that households and
businesses will increase spending, as the stimulus provided by the variety of fiscal and monetary
programs subsides—a component of the forecast that remains quite tentative at this point.

August 11–12, 2009

70 of 165

That the rate of decline in payroll employment in July was much slower than earlier in
the year is welcome news. However, the unemployment rate is quite high and is likely to remain
quite elevated for several more years. With many workers on reduced hours and much of the
labor force still concerned about their job prospects, workers are accepting much lower growth in
wages and benefits. Models run by economists in my research department that estimate inflation
as a markup over labor costs, as well as many specifications of traditional Phillips curves used to
forecast inflation, imply outcomes closer to the disinflation scenario in the Greenbook. Thus,
there is a significant downside risk to the baseline forecast to inflation.
Significant impediments to the recovery, of which I will highlight just two, also remain.
Until recently, most complaints by businesses in New England regarding credit availability were
from customers of large, out-of-region banks that needed TARP capital. However, there are
increasing complaints that small and medium-sized banks are now behaving as if they are capital
constrained, despite New England’s smaller exposure to the real estate and auto-related problems
that plague many other parts of the country. The problem appears particularly acute for
commercial real estate. Part 2 of the Greenbook characterizes commercial real estate as dismal.
Most of my contacts are using much more colorful language. Problems with commercial real
estate look likely to get worse, and many banks’ loan loss reserves already lag with the growth in
nonperforming loans.
Tight credit conditions are likely to make it difficult for businesses and households to
finance spending critical for the recovery. A second potential concern is the unintended
consequences of some of the remedies to recent problems. One example is money market
mutual funds, which have experienced declines in assets as investors have increased their risk
appetite, as Brian highlighted. At the same time, the SEC is considering measures that would

August 11–12, 2009

71 of 165

reduce the risk of mutual funds, including potentially prohibiting purchases of asset-backed
commercial paper and A2/P2 commercial paper and reducing the weighted average maturity of
holdings. While reducing the risk of mutual funds is desirable, if poorly implemented it could
disrupt asset markets where mutual funds have been key players. Although I am cautiously
optimistic that the recovery is beginning, the situation remains quite fragile. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Third District’s economy seems to be
bouncing along the bottom. Signs of stabilization abound, but evidence of robust activity is
lacking in any specific sector. Let me hit just a couple of highlights.
There has been some improvement in the residential real estate market, and a large
national homebuilder told me that the pickup might in fact be understated in the data. He
indicated that very few offers are now being canceled, and he is actually becoming less willing to
negotiate on price and in some markets even beginning to raise prices on homes. This seems to
support the national data, which seem to show some firming in house prices nationwide. Further,
he indicated that his firm is beginning to purchase raw land for development. On the other hand,
non–real estate investment is still declining. Office vacancy rates continue to increase, and
nonresidential construction contracts are few and far between outside of government, education,
and health care. A number of leaders in small and medium-sized business have told me that they
are willing and able to expand in the near term. But the Congress’s debates about health care,
taxes, deficits, and spending give them great pause, and they are indeed inclined to wait until
some resolution has occurred in the Congress. This, in fact, could delay recovery rather than
enhance it.

August 11–12, 2009

72 of 165

Labor markets continue to deteriorate in our District, although the pace of decline has
lessened. One encouraging bit of anecdotal evidence comes from the CEO of a very large
temporary employment agency, who told me that both requests and placements have risen
substantially in the last couple of months. This seems broadly in line with what seems to be a
somewhat less dour employment picture at the national level.
Bankers in our District are reporting deteriorating loan quality, and they are watching
their commercial real estate portfolios very carefully. However, a very large national credit card
issuer told me last week that new credit card delinquencies—that is, those showing up in 30-day
delinquencies—have fallen for 8 consecutive weeks. Although there remain many delinquent
accounts that are working their way through the system, this is indeed an encouraging piece of
news and may suggest that the financial situation of the consumer may be starting to stabilize.
Our Business Outlook Survey was a tad weaker in July than June—and the August
numbers are not in yet—but it was not significantly so. However, the general level of activity
and new orders and shipments have all improved substantially since earlier in the year and are
well above what were previously characterized as recessionary levels. Manufacturers in our
District are not signaling that they plan to increase future hiring or capital expenditures as yet,
but they do expect activity to pick up over the next six months. Indeed, our index for economic
activity six months ahead remains at a very high level, consistent with early phases of recovery,
given historical statistics. So the Third District’s economy and outlook is largely in line with the
national economy. We are seeing signs that both investment and manufacturing may be
stabilizing and, I hope, improving.
I believe that we will see a bit more strength in residential investment than is indicated in
the Greenbook projection, and I think inventory investment may become a source of short-term

August 11–12, 2009

73 of 165

strength as firms rebuild inventory from what seem to be very low levels. Countering that
strength is weakness in nonresidential construction and consumption. Some of the weakness in
consumption may wane, though, with the rise in asset prices and abating declines in house prices.
And the credit card data I referred to earlier may be an early precursor of that improvement. All
in all, I believe that the second half of this year looks a little better to me than it did at our last
meeting and perhaps a little better than indicated in the Greenbook; and I expect to see
approximately trend growth in 2010. That said, I am cognizant of the economy’s fragility.
On the inflation front, my view of the underlying inflation pressures, unlike that of some
of my colleagues, is less rosy than that of the staff, although let me stress that my near-term
outlook for inflation is benign. But the divergence of the way I think about the inflation process
and the underlying methodology for forecasting inflation in FRB/US leads me to see stronger
inflationary pressures over the next few years than does the Greenbook. It is interesting that
inflation expectations seem well anchored for now, and that’s good. At the same time, both
survey and financial market measures of inflation expectations are not particularly well aligned
with the current Greenbook inflation forecast.
Indeed, one-year-ahead consumer survey measures of inflation expectations have been
unusually volatile over the past year, but they have been rising since the beginning of this year
and are now at about 3 percent, which is where they were in 2007. This is more than twice the
inflation forecast in the current Greenbook. Longer-term survey measures have moved very
little, and they, too, remain in the 3 percent range. Longer-term inflation compensation based on
TIPS, the staff’s over-five-year-forward rates, has actually increased this year. Now, I agree that
we need to be very careful in taking signals from the TIPS measures at this point. I think
expectations of increased liquidity in TIPS markets and other things can certainly affect that

August 11–12, 2009

74 of 165

market. But I don’t think we should completely ignore them. Thus, the public and the staff
seem somewhat at odds over the likely path of inflation over the next several years, and at this
point I am a little closer to the public’s view than to the Greenbook’s. I think this disparity is
reflected in the market’s expected funds rate path, which anticipates a funds rate of almost
3 percent by the end of 2011, compared with the Greenbook baseline scenario, where the rate
remains at zero.
Now, given my outlook for inflation, my views on appropriate policy conflict with the
underlying policy assumptions in the Greenbook as well. Maintaining a funds rate so close to
zero for another two years would, I believe, reignite significant inflation. Moreover, given the
lags between policy actions and the surfacing of inflation, we will have to act well before
inflation pressures become evident. Otherwise, we will be too late, risking both inflation and our
credibility.
I have several reasons for this less optimistic view on inflation. As I have discussed at
previous meetings, I put a good deal less weight on output gaps as predictors of inflation. As I
continue to analyze this concept in more detail—and I really appreciate Michael Kiley’s
excellent presentation at the last meeting—I remain convinced that the usefulness of output gaps
for policy depends very much on the nature of the shocks affecting the economy. In the standard
New Keynesian model with the traditional time-series measures of potential output—whether
trend or smoothed output measures—the output gap and inflation are negatively correlated with
markup in technology shocks. But a monetary policy shock or a demand shock generates
positive correlations between output gaps and inflation. Thus, in order for measures of output
gaps to give an accurate read on inflation, you need to condition on the underlying disturbances.

August 11–12, 2009

75 of 165

This explains in part why the empirical relationship between output gaps and inflation are found
to be consistently fairly unstable.
Without a clear explanation of or a buy-in as to what types of shock the forecasters
believe are hitting the economy, I grow increasingly reluctant to rely on inflation forecasts based
on output gaps. Indeed, the Board staff has estimated sizable output gaps in Canada and Europe
over the past year, and yet we have seen very little decline in core inflation rates in these
countries. I am happy that we are not seeing deflation, but I do think this should give us pause
and we should be very skeptical of the reliability of output gaps for forecasting inflation. As
always, I continue to study this issue and will continue to do so because I think the issue will
loom large for us in assessing the point in time at which we must reverse course. Thank you
very much, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My outlook for the economy has not
changed materially since the last meeting. I think we’re in the beginning stages of what is likely
to be an exceptionally slow recovery. In the period since the last FOMC, we engaged our
contacts in the Sixth District and elsewhere around the country on the questions of slack in the
economy, inflationary pressures, the inventory situation, and the state of the real estate sector,
particularly commercial real estate.
In residential real estate, we are seeing more stability in sales and prices in our District,
even in the Florida markets. The exception to this improved picture is the market for
condominiums in large urban areas, which remains burdened by oversupply and very slow sales,
due in part to very limited credit availability. The commercial real estate sector is still
deteriorating and poses a threat to recovery in its potential drag on the credit system. Our

August 11–12, 2009

76 of 165

District contacts reported rising vacancy rates across every significant market and property type,
resulting in widespread rent concessions. Financial contacts opined that so far delinquency,
default, and valuation problems have been managed through restructuring but pointed out that
much of the refinancing calendar is ahead.
The Southeast has a sizable leisure and hospitality industry, which is suffering from a
slow tourist season. Even with pervasive rate concessions, hospitality and resort vacancy rates
are high. We asked a number of contacts about inventory levels and the direction of inventories.
We got the sense that inventory reduction has a bit further to go before firms align their
inventories-to-sales prospects. Business contacts at all points along the spectrum from materials
manufacturing to retail claim that they are still cutting inventories. Furthermore, based on these
conversations, I doubt that inventories will be replenished to pre-recession levels as the economy
improves. This projection of businesses running on leaner inventories on an extended basis
contributes to my view that the recovery will be exceptionally weak.
In the latest round of calls made in preparation for this meeting, we probed contacts about
their perceptions on available production capacity and willingness to rehire in a recovery. We
heard that a large share of what is counted as excess production capacity should not be
considered standing ready to be brought back into service. Contacts expressed unwillingness to
bring previously idled capacity, including permanent hires, back on line without much stronger
buyer commitments and better margins. This suggests much less disinflation potential in a slowgrowth scenario than would otherwise be the case.
In this cycle, our financial market contacts exhibited much more confidence and
described an unwinding of the flight to quality based on the view that a catastrophic scenario has
been avoided. These contacts reported that they believe markets in general have confidence and,

August 11–12, 2009

77 of 165

more particularly, that the Fed has the tools to engineer an exit strategy as recovery proceeds. A
widely held concern, however, is the timing of exit and the risk of a premature exit. In
preparation for the meeting, we had a long conference call with several representatives of the
American Securitization Forum in an attempt to gauge the rebound of the securitization sector
and its ability to support consumer activity. We talked about the TALF earlier today, and they
said that the TALF had been successful in bringing back the triple-A segment, but they cited a
number of factors that pointed to a protracted period of less securitization. This adds to my view
that consumer spending broadly will be constrained over at least the medium term. I think it’s
plausible that a major shift in household spending appetite is under way. But even if no
structural change in consumer behavior is building, consumer credit markets seem to be weighed
down by a still-compromised securitization process and constraints on credit card terms and
issuance.
My view of the outlook is less optimistic than the Greenbook’s baseline scenario. There
are elements of the Greenbook’s “higher saving rate” and “labor market damage” scenarios in
my current thinking about recovery. I see an economy burdened by voluntarily restrained and
credit-constrained consumer spending, a still-challenged financial industry that will be slow to
expand credit, weak re-employment prospects, and what we believe is lower growth potential
during a period of necessary structural adjustments. In light of this expected sluggish pace of
recovery, I see the risks to economic growth as still weighted to the downside.
My view of inflation risks is roughly balanced. I do not get a sense that inflationary
pressures are on the rise, and I don’t see any indication that businesses and households are acting
on inflation concerns in any way that would suggest that inflation expectations are currently on
the rise. That said, in almost every venue I am hearing strong concerns that inflationary

August 11–12, 2009

78 of 165

pressures will develop in the intermediate term as the economy recovers. And to anticipate the
policy discussion just a bit, I don’t think these concerns warrant an immediate policy response,
but they do tell me that our messaging is dealing with challenging crosscurrents and is
particularly crucial at this time. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Winston Churchill once remarked that
nothing in life is so exhilarating as to be shot at without result. [Laughter] Well, exhilaration
may be an exaggeration, but I am at least hugely relieved that our financial system appears to
have survived a near-death experience. And I am optimistic that you will not be the Chairman
who presided over the second Great Depression. [Laughter] Most, though not all, of the recent
economic data suggest that the economy is bottoming out and the worst is over. Although the
labor market is still struggling, auto sales have rebounded in part because of government rebates,
and the bleeding has subsided in the housing market. My directors and advisory council
members take the view that the economy looks to have survived a very sharp drop. It is now
starting to brush itself off and climb out of the deep hole that it’s in.
I expect that the current quarter will mark the end of the recession. Looking ahead,
however, I foresee a slow recovery over the next several years with stubbornly high
unemployment and very low price inflation, not the sharp rebound that typically follows deep
recessions. In particular, I don’t think that we can look to consumer spending as a strong engine
of recovery. In addition to factors such as continuing job losses, heightened job insecurity, tight
credit conditions, and the need to rebuild lost wealth and deleverage household balance sheets,
all of which are weighing on consumption, I have been struck by the recent very weak labor
income growth, driven in part by stagnating nominal wages. Wages have posted some of the

August 11–12, 2009

79 of 165

smallest gains ever recorded. Furthermore, my contacts report widespread reductions in pension
contributions, medical coverage, and other benefits.
It seems equally unlikely that investment spending will propel a robust recovery with an
overhang of excess capacity serving as a headwind. President Fisher provided some lovely
examples of that. This excess capacity, or gap effect, is evident in the housing market, where a
sizable inventory of unsold homes is holding down new residential investment. It is also likely
to stifle capital spending in manufacturing, where utilization stands at its lowest level of the past
60 years. Even after adjusting for factories that will never reopen, this huge overhang of
industrial capacity sets a high hurdle rate for new business equipment outlays.
I share the Greenbook’s pessimism about nonresidential construction. My contacts
uniformly expect commercial real estate conditions to deteriorate further, with rising foreclosures
as loans come due that cannot be supported by falling rents and lower appraisals. Moreover, the
shortage of credit to this sector may cause property prices to decline quite dramatically.
State and local budgets are another factor likely to depress growth in overall final
demand. California is the poster child in this regard, but most states face entrenched, structural,
fiscal problems. Despite all the press coverage, these problems actually have been tempered
recently by the federal fiscal stimulus and by drawdowns from states’ rainy day funds. Going
forward, the pain may worsen with further revenue shortfalls and spending cutbacks acting as a
drag on the whole economy.
Although I do not anticipate a strong recovery, I now see the risks around my modal
forecast for a gradual recovery to be more balanced than before. My greatest worry on the
downside relates to commercial real estate and the potential for deteriorating conditions to cause
many community and midsized banks to fail. But with the improvement that we have seen in

August 11–12, 2009

80 of 165

broader financial conditions, there is now some appreciable upside risk as well. Even if we are
lucky enough to get sustained, robust GDP growth of, say, 4 to 5 percent for the next two years,
we are still likely to fall short of our full employment goal, given the size of the output gap and
the pace at which potential output appears to be growing. Like President Evans’s contacts, my
directors report they are intensely focused on cost-cutting measures, and recent readings on
productivity and earnings suggest that these efforts are paying off. With such healthy
productivity growth, we’re likely to see yet another jobless recovery.
Turning to inflation, I have two separate concerns. On the one hand, I am worried about
the increasing degree of public alarm regarding the longer-term inflation outlook, and at the
same time I am worried that the intense downward wage pressure reported by my contacts could
result in disinflation over the next few years that is more severe than in the Greenbook forecast.
Both of these separate concerns are apparent among forecasters participating in the survey of
professional forecasters. Over the past six to nine months, the lowest quartile of forecasters has
become increasingly concerned with disinflation over the next five years. In contrast, the top
quartile of forecasters has become increasingly concerned with rising inflation five to ten years
out. These shifts in the distribution of forecasts suggest a very different skew to the inflation
risks we face over the next five years versus the longer horizon.
The fear of higher long-term inflation reflects to a large degree a loss of confidence that
the Federal Reserve will be able to attain price stability in the face of unsustainable federal
budget deficits. This fear is real, growing, and disruptive. To assuage this concern, it is
important for us to emphasize and defend our independence, to express confidence in our ability
to tighten monetary conditions when the right time comes, and to stress our determination to
maintain price stability.

August 11–12, 2009

81 of 165

These inflation fears notwithstanding, the main threat to the attainment of our price
stability goal over the next several years stems from the disinflationary forces that have been
unleashed by the enormous slack in the economy. The 1980s provides a useful historical
comparison along several dimensions. Remember that during the 1980s fears about burgeoning
federal deficits in an unsustainable fiscal situation were widespread, as they are today.
Moreover, the Federal Reserve was under significant political pressure, and there were concerns
about its independence. Even so, with unemployment hitting 10.8 percent in 1982 and
plummeting oil prices, core PCE inflation fell about 6 percentage points during the first half of
the 1980s.
Inflation expectations appear to be more firmly anchored now than in the 1980s, and I
expect that to help avoid a calamitous disinflation. But I am mindful there is a lot we don’t know
about how these expectations affect actual inflation and how to measure the expectations that are
relevant for price setting. It is sobering to recall that, from 1981 to 1986, professional forecasters
consistently overestimated year-ahead inflation, but these expectations did not stop inflation
from falling quite rapidly. So while I would not quibble with the Greenbook projection of only
1 percentage point or so of disinflation, I think we should remain attentive to downside risks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me start with some comments about the
District economy, where the anecdotes have been distinctly a mixed bag recently. On the
positive side, clearly, there has been some acceleration in hiring in parts of the service sector.
Auto sales are improving at least for the time being. Volumes in the housing market in terms of
sales of both new and existing homes have picked up, and there are certainly anecdotes of the
positive effects from the fiscal stimulus program regarding some infrastructure projects and so

August 11–12, 2009

82 of 165

forth. On the negative side, things related to transportation, whether it is trucking or volumes
from the ports and so on and so forth, are weak. Residential and commercial construction
remains weak, and tourism activity and most other measures of discretionary consumer spending
are pretty soft as well.
As far as the national economy is concerned, I do think that the contraction in activity has
ended and expansion has resumed. If we think about the circumstances today relative to four or
five months ago, the bulk of the surprises both here and abroad have been on the positive side in
terms of economic performance, and I would include in that the corporate earnings reports that
we have been getting. Now, there may be some noise in all of this, of course, but I think it has
been going on long enough and looks broad enough that there is a real signal here. Also,
financial conditions have distinctly improved in both equity and credit markets and certainly
more broadly than I would have earlier expected. So that is all to the good. And I do think that
the latest information on compensation, where it appears that it is less sticky than we might have
earlier expected, may augur well for employment at least going forward. All of those are on the
positive side. My trajectory for real economic growth for the balance of this year and next year
is for a bit more rapid growth—and it has been for some time—than in the Greenbook. I would
not make any changes to it at this point, but if I were going to, I would probably mark it up a
little further given the way things have developed.
Let me just make a comment or two about the dual mandate at this point. As everybody
is well aware, we have had a very significant shock or a series of financial shocks, and in the
wake of that, it seems to me that we ought not expect to achieve the dual mandate very quickly.
Now, as far as inflation is concerned, if you take the Greenbook forecast seriously—and I do—
and you look at core inflation, we are not very far off from it, at least not unless you are really

August 11–12, 2009

83 of 165

wedded to 2 percent as the precise target. But as far as employment is concerned, we are a good
deal further away, and of course, if you look at the experience of the economy coming out of the
recessions of ’90, ’91, and 2001, even though I would argue that a fair amount of stimulus was
applied during and following those recessions, it took quite some time for employment to pick up
in a sustained way and for the unemployment rate to begin to decline in a sustained way. What I
conclude from that, and what I think we ought to be prepared for this time around as well, is that
recessions are partly about, maybe largely about, resource reallocation, and it simply takes time
for that to occur. There is only so much that traditional stimulative policies can do to hasten
those kinds of adjustments, and if that is a reasonably accurate assessment of the situation, it is
simply going to take time for us to resume the achievement of the dual mandate. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Eighth District economy remains
weak. The latest reading on Eighth District unemployment, 9.3 percent, is about the same as the
national average, but this does mask a considerable variation within the District. Arkansas, for
instance, has an unemployment rate of 7.1 percent, whereas Kentucky and Tennessee are at
11 percent. This variation has actually increased the spread between those numbers, which has
about doubled in the last year.
Like others here, the reports from my contacts are mixed. There are reports of continuing
job cuts from contacts in the automotive, transportation, electrical equipment, and aerospace
industries—Boeing has a big presence in St. Louis. But firms in steel, fabricated metal,
furniture, and plastic products reported plans to actually hire additional workers. I would
interpret mixed signals like this as typical of a business-cycle trough, and I am hopeful that this

August 11–12, 2009

84 of 165

is what we are experiencing. I think the story from the Eighth District is very consistent with the
narrative for the national economy.
On the national outlook, I am encouraged by signs of improvement, especially that the
financial market turmoil continues to abate by many measures, but I think we still have some
way to go on that dimension. And while the financial sector continues to repair, we are still
vulnerable to further shocks, and so we have to remain vigilant. My sense is that we have
established the credibility of government guarantees in many areas since late last year, and that
the credibility of government guarantees has largely controlled what Governor Warsh and many
others have called the Panic of 2008. I think we may be at the end of that phase right about now.
Control of the panic is not the same as actually having a healthy and efficient financial
intermediation sector. The next phase will be to emphasize efficiency and health in the financial
intermediation industry. My sense is that getting that right will have important consequences for
U.S. economic growth in the medium term. In particular, the Japanese have been widely
criticized for not finding the right policies during this phase, contributing to their lost decade
outcome.
I thought that during the intermeeting period our discussion and communication of exit
strategy, mainly by Chairman Bernanke but also by many others around the table, was very
useful. Markets seemed to back off the idea that the Fed does not have a plan. I think we did
establish that the Fed certainly has tools and a plan for exit, and I think some medium-term
inflation fears receded during the intermeeting period because of that communication. More—
maybe much more—may have to be done in this area, though, because the message is quite a
complicated one, as I found myself trying to explain to people. We have complicated
interactions among our set of liquidity programs, the asset-purchase program, and what to do

August 11–12, 2009

85 of 165

about interest rates going forward in the longer or medium term. One lesson from this
intermeeting experience is that markets are still pretty focused on interest rates at the end of the
day, really overly focused on interest rates, given this Committee’s apparent plans and given the
fact that we have stressed that we intend to keep rates low for an extended period. I would like
to knock markets further off the focus on rates because our plans do not contemplate moving
back to ordinary interest rate targeting any time soon. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me start with the District. Like the
national economy, we are showing some signs of stabilization. In our manufacturing surveys
and with contacts, we have seen modest increases in production and new orders for the past
couple of months, driven in part by rising export demand. In housing, sales and home prices
have stabilized, and the inventory of unsold homes is the lowest in some time. With the collapse
of the energy market, we did see some really sharp declines in drilling and production activities,
and the declines account for much of the fall in our structure investments during the first two
quarters of this year. With the stabilization of that market, that area has also stabilized in our
region as oil production or drilling has begun to stabilize and increase slightly.
The labor markets, as everyone else has said, tend to lag, and they remain weak. In the
nonresidential real estate markets, the volume of commercial construction activity continues to
fall relatively sharply, and the financial difficulties in the industry continue to worsen.
Delinquency rates on construction loans are rising. CMBS quality is deteriorating, and there is
little refinancing available for maturing loans, and that is the case even when the properties are
leased. There is just a very significant reluctance to finance right now. Appraisers are also being
quite conservative. If they take a leased property and they look at their 2006 appraisal values,

August 11–12, 2009

86 of 165

they will discount them 20 percent, the assumption being that the higher cap rates have to be
worth less and harder to finance. For those that are not leased or not occupied, the discounts run
from 30 to 60 percent, with the greatest number in the condominium markets. However, they are
working through that. The banks are being conservative right now, and I will come back to that
in just a second.
In terms of the national outlook, I agree with others who have said that the economy is
showing mixed data, and that is usually an indication that we are likely at the bottom of the
recession. I expect very modest growth in the second half of this year and then a picking-up of
momentum as we get into 2010, as fiscal stimulus engages even more than it has at this point.
Monetary policy remains easy. Inventory rebuilding begins to occur, and consumer and business
attitudes hopefully improve, and I think the consumer attitude will. It has been there in the past,
and I think it will be once again.
Obviously, the risk to the outlook is in the financial system, which remains weak. Setting
aside the largest institutions, we know that there is some retrenching in regional and community
banks, especially in the commercial real estate area. What we find—and I think it is
interesting—is that the banks with stress in their commercial real estate portfolio usually have
stress in the rest of their portfolio as well—C&I loans and so forth. But in this instance, I think
that going forward their effects will not be as negative as we sometimes fear, for a couple of
reasons. They are in a defensive mode right now. They are conserving capital. Those that can
survive will survive; and as the economy improves, they will be able, and will be interested in
beginning, to lend again. For those that will not survive, another fiscal net is there, and that is
called the FDIC because many of those regional and community banks will go under purchase
and assumption when they fail. What that does is take the bad assets out, set them aside, and

August 11–12, 2009

87 of 165

recapitalize the bank, which is then actually in a better position to reengage as a financial
institution than it otherwise would be. So they are either going to strengthen themselves and
come out of this, or they are going to be taken over, which will recapitalize them. I think that
will be a mitigating factor on the drag that these banks will otherwise have.
So it is a climb out. It is not an easy climb out, but on the outlook side, I think that it is a
pretty positive outlook going forward so long as the economy is basically turning around and
improving. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. We made a great deal of progress on our agenda,
and I understand that there is a 6:00 p.m. reception for the Conference of Presidents. So if
everyone is agreeable, why don’t we adjourn and begin tomorrow at 9:00 a.m. Thank you very
much.
[Meeting recessed]

August 11–12, 2009

88 of 165

August 12, 2009—Morning Session
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good morning, everybody. Overnight, Brian Madigan
polled the members about the issue of adding ARMs to the MBS program, and we did not find a
consensus in either direction. We are pretty evenly divided. So what I propose that we do is to
hold this in abeyance until such future date as we decide to make significant changes in the MBS
program one way or the other. At that point, if we were to expand it, for example, we might
want to reconsider. But if we are winding it down, there would not be much point. So we won’t
take any further action on this until such time as we reconsider the MBS program. Let’s
continue with our economic go-round. President Pianalto, you are first up.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My contacts are growing more confident
that the sharp decline in economic activity is in the process of ending. Auto producers are
benefiting from the very popular cash-for-clunkers program. The success of this program is now
showing up not just in sales but also in plants restarting or increasing production. Similarly,
housing markets in my District appear to be stabilizing, with starts actually heading up. This, of
course, is welcome news to the producers of building materials, who have been waiting a long
time to see any signs of a recovery in housing.
Still, it would be hard to characterize the mood of business executives in my District as
good. “Resignation” is a better summary. The declines in their activity levels have been so large
that the uptick in growth that they are now experiencing is easily being met either by inventories
or by only incremental increases in production. Most of my business contacts anticipate that
their surplus capacity will continue for months or even years to come. They agree with President
Fisher’s view that there is too much of everything relative to demand.

August 11–12, 2009

89 of 165

The auto industry remains a clear example. A number of assembly plants in my District
are not going to survive the restructuring that has already been announced. When I consider only
the plants in my District that are going to continue to produce after the restructuring is
completed, I find that those auto assembly plants produced 2.3 million cars and light trucks in
2007. Toyota and Honda plants account for over half of the total. Now, to give you an example
of how low production has been for the past few months, in June these same plants collectively
produced less than 36 percent of their 2007 output. Honda and Toyota were operating at well
less than two-thirds of their 2007 levels, while the Big Three were at roughly 10 percent of their
2007 levels. The cash-for-clunkers program has been viewed as a national success, boosting July
auto sales by 16 percent above June sales. Nevertheless, while this was a sizable percentage
increase at the national level, this represents just a month’s worth of 2007 production capacity
for the surviving plants in my District. This is hardly a dent in the excess capacity available in
this entire industry.
The problem is not limited to autos. Primary metal producers, as an example, are
operating at less than 50 percent of their capacity. One community banker in my District who
noted improving economic conditions cautioned that every plant in her region is operating on
some form of reduced workweek. In fact, the dominant reaction of business people in my
District to date has not been to close plants permanently but rather to hunker down and manage
output levels to match current demand by cutting back on labor or other variable inputs.
Workforces have largely accepted a variety of pay and hour cutbacks to make these lower levels
of output possible. This downward pressure on wages is showing up strongly both in the
employment cost index and, as we saw, in yesterday’s unit labor cost numbers. While this
pattern might sound as if it is limited just to the Midwest, international producers report similar

August 11–12, 2009

90 of 165

experiences in their locations worldwide. From the producer standpoint, it is just hard to see an
impending acceleration of prices, although the growing stability in output does seem to have
been enough to limit further discounting.
To gain further insight on the output gap, I met with a group of academic advisers who
worked on different models that try various approaches of evaluating the output gap over the
business cycle. They all essentially agreed with my business contacts’ opinions that it is likely to
take a long time before this output gap is absorbed. Combining their perspective with the
information that I gathered from my business contacts, I ended up leaving my output projection
largely consistent with my forecast at the last meeting, which has been broadly consistent with
the Greenbook’s viewpoint on output. I expect output to grow slowly in the second half of this
year, followed by a return to more-solid growth rates next year.
Although I expect inflation to dip in the coming months, my outlook for core inflation
calls for a gradual climb back toward 2 percent in the next two or three years. My inflation
outlook runs a little higher than the Greenbook baseline, largely because of differences in our
views of where inflation expectations will settle out. And although the large output gap in my
outlook does serve as a disinflationary pressure, the research on this issue leads me to be
cautious about how much effect this output gap is going to exert on my inflation projection.
So the risks to my outlook remain to the downside for output because the improvements
that I have seen, notably in housing and auto sales, have relied on stimulus programs that may be
quickly depleted and a still uncertain recovery in consumer spending. My talks with both
researchers and business people leave me with a lot of uncertainty about the inflation trend, and I
see those risks remaining symmetric. So while the news has been encouraging, I think watchful
waiting seems like the right course for monetary policy to me. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.

August 11–12, 2009

91 of 165

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Manufacturing in the Fifth District appears
to be running ahead of the nation, and I guess fairly confidently I can say running ahead of the
Fourth District’s. Our survey index moved up again last month and has been in positive territory
for three months in a row. And the new orders component registered a particularly strong
increase. Our service sector continues to contract, however, although somewhat less broadly
than before. What improvement has taken place has been most notable in nonretail businesses.
Apart from the cash-for-clunkers frenzy at auto dealers, retail firms in our District still report
very slow shopper traffic and depressed big ticket sales.
Our directors and other contacts continue to describe conditions as gloomy—a view that
seems to be associated with the low level of current activity rather than its rate of change. I
suspect they are less impressed than economists by trends in first differences. Some of our
contacts wonder how long current conditions will last, and one director reported that people are
hanging on like Sergeant Snorkel, a character in the “Beetle Bailey” comic strip who is
sometimes seen dangling from a small tree growing out of the side of a cliff. [Laughter] On the
other hand, we have also heard reports of activity picking up here and there around the District.
Both our surveys and our other contacts indicate little or no price pressures at this point. A
couple of our bankers report strong deposit growth. One cited state and local government
shifting funds out of money market mutual funds in order to obtain unlimited federal insurance.
Some of our large banks—and I have seen these reports from elsewhere in the country—have
seen a small decline in early-stage credit card delinquencies, thirty days or less, which they
believe may be the beginning of a peak in consumer credit losses.

August 11–12, 2009

92 of 165

But one of our banks has done some really interesting research. This is a large, formerly
monoline credit card bank with a fairly good reputation for quantitative research. Their staff
looked at the 2001 and 2008 stimulus programs. And there, because the disbursement was
staggered by the last two digits of your Social Security number, they were able to trace the effect
through their customer base. They estimate an effect between 20 and 50 basis points on their
second-quarter early-stage delinquencies from the stimulus payments this year. This is enough
to undo the decline from the first to the second quarter in the early-stage delinquency results that
they saw. Now, that said, if you look at their monthly data, even with the adjustment they still
show a peak in May rather than in March as in the unadjusted data. So there is still a glimmer of
hope, but it is a fainter glimmer than one would take just from the raw numbers. I thought that
was pretty interesting.
Since our last meeting, the national data have come in pretty much as expected or, in
some cases, not quite as dismal as expected. As a result, our projections haven’t changed
appreciably. It seems pretty clear now that the downturn has ended, and positive economic
growth is set to resume. But as I said, I get the sense that economists are taking more comfort in
this than anyone else. And it seems as though many people are coping with the depressed level
of current activity and uncertainty about the timing and strength of the recovery. I think that, in
turn, is going to depend critically on the path of household spending. The 2 percent decline in
real consumption from the end of ’07 through the beginning of this year has been fairly
extraordinary. But the fact that consumption has been fairly flat this year I take as encouraging,
considering the decline in compensation and the tightening in credit terms over that period. This
suggests that consumer spending is likely to expand if labor market conditions stabilize and the
recent gains in household net worth are sustained. That expansion is likely to be at a cautious

August 11–12, 2009

93 of 165

pace, however. Labor market conditions may stop deteriorating, but they are unlikely to improve
dramatically anytime soon, I think. And any recovery in consumer creditworthiness is likely to
depend on improvements in consumer income prospects.
For other components of demand, the outlook is more mixed, as some of you have said.
The prospects in nonresidential construction are bleak, given the ongoing rise in vacancy rates.
But the inventory swing in GDP is going to give us a second-half boost, and the drag from
residential investment appears to be lessening as housing starts begin to affect the flow of
residential construction spending.
Inflation has been sort of choppy lately but reasonably well contained. Core PCE over
the last six months averaged 1.8 percent or a few tenths lower if you back out those tobacco tax
hikes. One widespread view is that some sort of output gap is going to hold down inflation.
There has been a little commentary on this so far around this table. This situation bears some
resemblance to the beginning of the last recovery in late 2003, when the Greenbook forecast had
inflation falling to 1 percent because of the remaining slack in the economy at that time. Of
course, we had that scare in early 2003, when core inflation seemed to fall below 1 percent for a
time. But by the time of the December meeting, inflation was running around 2 percent in the
data we had at that meeting. Moreover, TIPS inflation compensation had risen pretty sharply in
the second half of 2003, so inflation expectations and our expectations about the output gap were
giving conflicting signals about how inflation was going to evolve. As it turned out, what we got
was a small inflation scare in 2004, not disinflation. Overall inflation turned out to be 3 percent
in ’04. Core inflation was 2¼ percent. And it suggests that, at least in that episode, expectations
trumped the gap.

August 11–12, 2009

94 of 165

Reflecting on that episode reinforces my skepticism—others have commented on this—
about the usefulness of conventional output gaps for forecasting inflation, particularly at the
beginning of a recovery. Now you might argue that the amount of slack in the economy was far
less then and it is far larger now. The unemployment rate then was only about 6 percent. And
that may be true, but then the question that arises is, Why hasn’t inflation fallen by more now if
the output gap is so much larger? And a recent San Francisco Fed publication by a couple of its
economists made this point pretty firmly.
President Plosser and I discussed output gaps with Mr. Kiley at the June meeting. That
conversation may have seemed a bit confusing. It was when I read the transcript. [Laughter]
But I think the point to take away from it is that in DSGE models, like the Board’s EDO model,
and all of the broad class of New Keynesian models that are coherent accounts of how the gap
interacts with inflation, the relevant potential or natural output is something that varies a lot with
supply and demand shocks. This is the point that President Plosser made yesterday. Now, you
can always step outside one of those models and calculate some smoothed output trend from the
data, and you can call that potential, but that number has no significance for the behavior of
inflation within the model. I think these models provide a way of understanding how it would be
possible for monetary policy to generate an increase in inflation even if output is fairly low
relative to some smoothed trend calculated from outside the model. These issues have important
implications for our strategy and our recovery, and that suggests to me that it could be very
dangerous to rely on a sense that output and labor markets are not tight enough to trigger an
increase in inflation. That completes my remarks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.

August 11–12, 2009

95 of 165

VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Like I think most people
around the table, I am pretty confident that real GDP growth will be positive this quarter. Much
of the economic news has been better since the last meeting, with a wide range of indicators
suggesting that the recession is either over or will be over very soon. For the remainder of the
year, the economy should be boosted by three factors that a lot of people have cited around the
table—recovery in housing and a significant rise in motor vehicle sales, the effect of the fiscal
stimulus program in supporting domestic demand, and a sharp swing in the pace of inventory
investment. In fact, if the inventory swing were concentrated in a particular quarter, we could
actually see fairly rapid growth for a brief period.
But I expect that, as in the 2001–03 period, the recovery will be slower than usual, at
least over the next year or two. In particular, I expect that consumption is likely to grow only
modestly. First, growth of real disposable income will probably be weak by historical standards.
As I noted at the last meeting, there are a number of special factors that boosted real disposable
income in the first half of the year, helping to offset a sharp drop in hours worked and very
sluggish hourly wage gains. These special factors will be absent during the second half of the
year. Second, households are still adjusting to the sharp drop in net worth caused by what will
likely be a persistent decline in home prices and last year’s fall in equity prices. This suggests to
me that the desired saving rate will not decline sharply as the recession comes to an end. As a
consequence, consumer spending is unlikely to rise much faster than income. In other words,
weak income growth will act as an effective constraint on the pace of consumer spending. Third,
the financial system is still in the middle of a prolonged adjustment process. Banks and other
financial institutions are working their way through large credit losses, and the securitization

August 11–12, 2009

96 of 165

markets are recovering only very slowly. This means that credit availability will be constrained
for some time to come, and this will also serve to limit the pace of the recovery.
Despite the big buildup of slack in the economy, the core measures of inflation have been
somewhat sticky. I don’t think this will last. Thus, I think the risks on inflation are still likely to
be on the downside over the next year or two. There are two reasons why I think core inflation is
likely to decline going forward. First, the variables that respond to labor market slack, such as
the employment cost index, have already fallen quite sharply. This suggests that the output gap
is exerting downward pressure on labor costs, which is a key component of overall costs in many
industries. Second, during the first half of the year, core services inflation has been lower than
core goods inflation. I think this is meaningful because core services inflation exhibits much
more inertia than core goods inflation and because it is unusual for inflation for core services to
be running lower than core goods inflation in the first place. I don’t expect that we will see this
pattern persist for long, and I suspect that it is more likely that core goods inflation will moderate
than that core services inflation will pick up in the near term. So I would expect the overall core
inflation rate to come down. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As others have remarked, the incoming data
have confirmed that the forces that have been dragging down the economy are abating, and as a
consequence, activity is leveling out. Those forces included consumption, which fell very, very
rapidly in the second half of last year and is in the process of leveling out. Housing demand is
picking up a little. Most important, as others have pointed out, the inventories of goods are being
brought into better alignment with the lower level of sales. Declines in inventories should taper
off, and that will add to industrial production and damp declines in employment. In the

August 11–12, 2009

97 of 165

Greenbook, inventory investment subtracts 1½ percentage points from H1 growth and adds
1½ percentage points to H2 growth. So that is a big swing by itself. And, of course, better
economic data are feeding, and feeding off, the better environment in financial markets and the
resulting decline in risk perceptions and risk aversion.
Beyond the inventory cycle, the fundamental shape of the recovery will be determined by
final demand. The question I asked myself was, Is there any reason to be more optimistic about
that now in any fundamental way than the very gradual path most of us had written into our
forecasts a month ago? And I think there are some reasons for greater optimism. The rebound in
asset prices, including equity prices and wealth, has been faster than anticipated, and that will
feed consumption and lower the cost of business capital; global economic growth is picking up
more than expected; and with the weaker dollar, net exports will be less of a drag. I think we can
have more confidence in a multiplier–accelerator effect from the shift in inventories feeding back
on final demand.
But I think there are a lot of reasons for caution as well, and my fundamental outlook
hasn’t changed. Many of my reasons were already given by the Vice Chairman, Governor
Tarullo, and others, but let me list them here. In fact, final demand was weaker in the first half
of the year than we had anticipated, especially for consumption, which was held down by the
sharp drop in labor compensation. I think labor compensation is going to be depressed going
forward, given the high margin of slack in labor markets and the slow recovery of jobs. Some of
the current signs of stability in demand are being driven by policy-induced borrowing from
future consumption. I am thinking of the cash-for-clunkers program and the first-time
homebuyer tax credit. That is all just taking demand from 2010. The stabilization of
consumption spending occurred in the context of a major increment to income from the stimulus

August 11–12, 2009

98 of 165

program. So even with all of that extra income, consumption just stabilized. That doesn’t
repeat. Fiscal impetus dies out over the next few quarters, removing that source of support for
final demand. The saving rate is not likely to go down from here, as the Vice Chairman
remarked, and is more likely to rise than fall. The staff’s roughly 4-percent constant saving rate
is consistent with wealth-to-income ratios based on relationships over the past decade, and I
think that is the most likely outcome. But those saving patterns could, partly at least, have
reflected the not only rising comfort levels and increased appetite for risk associated with what
had been thought of as the Great Moderation but also the innovations in credit markets that
increased the availability of credit. I think the risk is that greater uncertainty about jobs and
reduced access to credit will spark greater saving out of current income.
Despite the improvement in financial markets, credit is definitely tighter for households.
They are facing substantial increases in borrowing rates and reductions in credit lines, especially
for credit cards, due to rising loss rates and in anticipation of the effective dates of new laws and
regulations. Respondents to the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey didn’t see this going away
anytime in the foreseeable future.
More generally, although financial conditions have improved, they are still quite tight in
a number of dimensions. Small businesses have been constrained by the tightening of credit card
and HELOC credit. These businesses, in addition, are likely to suffer disproportionately from
the failures and churning in banking markets that President Hoenig and others discussed. There
is a lot of asymmetric information in a small business loan. It is hard to transfer that business
from a failing bank to another bank. The National Federation of Independent Business’s survey
suggested that small businesses themselves see great difficulty in getting credit. It is much
tighter, much worse than even the early ’90s,when we had the 50-mile-an-hour headwinds. The

August 11–12, 2009

99 of 165

banks’ ability and willingness to take over more credit flow is constrained by their concerns
about losses in capital. Credit availability is likely to loosen up gradually for those credits that
aren’t easily channeled through securities markets.
And even after the recent gains, there are important asset prices that don’t really reflect
the policy easing. Bond yields, say for the triple-B corporation, which is approximately the
median corporation, are not far from where they were in August ’07 or September ’08, before the
Lehman collapse. Stock prices are down 30 percent from August ’07, despite the recent gains,
and 20 percent from just before Lehman fell. The broad index of the dollar is unchanged relative
to August ’07, and it is higher relative to September ’08. So I think in the context of a
substantial widening in the output gap, you would like to see a marked easing of financial
conditions. And although certainly in the short-term markets financial conditions have eased, I
think across a broad array of markets they really haven’t eased very much. So, on balance, I
think this is going to damp the recovery, and I see the very gradual pickup in final demand as the
best forecast, implying high and rising margins of underutilized resources. In that circumstance,
it is likely to be consistent with damped inflation for the foreseeable future.
I am a little surprised at how damped the decline in inflation and underlying inflation has
been, but I also recognize that the relationship between the gap and inflation is not tight. My
sense is—and Nathan commented on this, and it was in the Greenbook as well—that globally
inflation hasn’t come down that much. This has been true for inflation-targeting countries and
non-inflation-targeting countries. It has also been true, as near as I can tell, in countries that did
a lot of quantitative easing and in countries, like Canada, that didn’t do much quantitative easing.
I was looking at the Canadian nominal TIPS spread this morning. It looks exactly like ours,
despite the fact that they don’t have the worry about exit strategy that we have. So I think what

August 11–12, 2009

100 of 165

we have is very firmly anchored inflation expectations. We could see that long-term inflation
expectations remained anchored in ’07 and ’08, when headline inflation was high and rising, and
they have remained anchored in ’09, when headline inflation has fallen to the lowest level in
several generations. I think the underlying pressure here is for lower inflation with the weakness
in compensation and labor costs, and I interpret that weakness as indicative of the fact that there
is an output gap. However large it is, it is substantial enough to put downward pressure on labor
costs. And I think it will be very difficult to raise wages or prices by very much in such a
competitive environment. There won’t be any pricing power for a number of years under the
most likely scenario.
Although inflation has been sticky, by most measures—even measures of core inflation—
it has come down over the past year. I was looking at the Greenbook table of broad measures of
inflation, which look at 2007:Q2 to 2008:Q2 and 2008:Q2 to 2009:Q2. Every measure, except
one, in that table is off, and all of the core measures had declined over the past year. For
example, core CPI inflation went from 2¼ to 1¾ in the four quarters ending in 2009:Q2. I think
this does reflect weak demand and slack and is a situation in which expectations will remain
anchored or could even begin to recede a bit. The lesson is, when inflation expectations are well
anchored, the Phillips curve is flat. This suggests to me that we could have substantial output
growth and a narrowing of the output gap without added inflation pressures. In fact, in my view,
the next move in underlying inflation is more likely to be down than up. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I did some thinking overnight about the
assessment of financial markets that Brian Sack highlighted yesterday, and I realized that

August 11–12, 2009

101 of 165

markets haven’t seemed so good or seemed so self-satisfied since, I don’t know, the spring of
2007. [Laughter] So I thought we should all take some good caution from that.
Let me put an exclamation mark around some of the points that Brian made in describing
the remarkable move across equity and credit markets. First, on the equity market front, more
industries, more companies, and more subsectors have participated in this rally and the
expectation of recovery. The breadth of this move across assets and across geographies has been
far more durable than I would have expected when we last met. The credit market improvements
have been even more significant. We have seen the positive sentiment move down the capital
structure. The bank loan syndication market, which had all but disappeared, to where obituaries
had been written about it, is building remarkably over August. It wouldn’t surprise me at all if,
come the post–Labor Day rush to the capital markets, we see the bank loan market coming back
after the improvements we have seen in the last several months in high yields, convertibles, and
preferreds, again attesting to remarkable improvements in credit markets. Now, in some ways
these improvements have been made possible by an increase in the emergence of investable
assets. So re-risking is the new de-risking. Re-risking is the new fad in financial markets. Fund
flows, particularly toward riskier assets, are impressive, and I think we have to continue to watch
this trend and this development.
If I were to assess where we stand here in August against what our expectations of the
financial markets could have been over the last few quarters, I can’t help but think that we are
very much at the high end of what might have been reasonably achievable. How much credit is
owed to the Fed and how much credit is owed to the self-corrective nature of these markets or to
some good fortune is hard to judge.

August 11–12, 2009

102 of 165

Let me turn now to the trends in these financial markets and what they might suggest for
the real economy. Amid this rally, I think it is possible that this breadth of improved market
activity ends abruptly. We don’t want to suffer from a failure of imagination, and I think we
could envision a series of exogenous shocks that bring many of these improvements to end more
quickly. My own sense is that the prospects of those shocks are more likely outside the United
States, particularly outside the U.S. banking sector, but not impossible here. But given the rally
in these asset prices, they seem to be able to cover up for a lot of sins on balance sheets of banks
overseas. So I think the prospects that I worried about six weeks ago—of a surprise that causes
these markets to retreat—are lower but still not negligible.
Well, it would be nice if these trends were to continue unabated. But my sense would be
that straight-line, undifferentiated moves in financial markets tend not to end well. What we
might be enduring over the next few months might be some period of pause, some period of
patience and consolidation that could give this rally some longer legs. If the next six months
look like the last three or four, then it does strike me as possible that there is an upside, not only
in financial markets but in the real economy, along the lines of what Governor Tarullo
highlighted yesterday.
So fundamentally, one central question for us is whether financial market trends persist long
enough and strong enough so as to markedly drive sustainable gains in the real economy. That is,
will the wealth effects of improved balance sheets both to consumers and businesses offset the weak
outcomes that were highlighted in the Greenbook and by the discussion yesterday?
Let me turn now to the real side. I broadly share the Greenbook’s view of the real economy
over the next six quarters, though I suspect that we will see pretty significant volatility quarter over
quarter in GDP. But I think the Greenbook strikes it about right. You take some account of the

August 11–12, 2009

103 of 165

positive incoming financial market data but recognize that they cannot mask the weak incomes and
the slow trajectory for improvement in labor markets. Weak real disposable incomes coming from
weak labor markets and the problems that small businesses will no doubt confront in the next
18 months, as highlighted by Governor Kohn, suggest to me that we run the risk of more-persistent
weakness on the income side than the upside improvements in balance sheets and household net
worth.
So after these six quarters of somewhat bumpy but real improvement, what is next? I
suspect that the predominant risk in the medium term is for slower growth and weaker labor markets
than we have long grown accustomed to coming out of recoveries. The headwinds posed by
financial markets have probably turned into crosscurrents in figuring the direction of the real
economy, making our jobs around this table even more difficult than usual. Prudence probably
requires us to take less signal from the improved financial market conditions and to seek further
evidence not only of improved corporate profits but also of revenue growth. As I think President
Fisher said yesterday, the most telling tale for the future, at least of the equity markets and the real
economy, will be revenue growth. Outside of financials, is there top-line growth from the rest of the
Fortune 500? Does that suggest some top-line growth from small businesses that is telling us that
the economy is gaining some enduring strength not because of or supported by government
programs but because of the improvements on the real side of the economy?
In the course of the last 18 months, we have debated first the prospects of recession and now
the prospects of recovery. I think around this table we have struggled with trying to understand
what has gone on. During the recession, we first asked ourselves some 18 or 20 months ago what
was the breadth of the weak signs that we were seeing. Then we turned to a discussion of what was
the depth of the real recession that we were confronting. Then late in the cycle, even now, we are

August 11–12, 2009

104 of 165

talking about what was the length of this recession. And I suspect that these same words—breadth,
depth, and length—end up capturing our discussions in the next 18 months. What is the breadth of
the improvements—the breadth of the green shoots—that we try to envision as we think of an
economy coming out of recession? What is, in this case, the height—that is, what can this economy
aspire to? What can it drive? And as questions of double dips happen as some of the fiscal and
monetary stimulus and some of the extraordinary actions tend to abate, the question will be, What is
the length of this recovery? I think it will make our challenge over the period in front of us as
difficult as that over the past 20 months.
A couple of final items. First, on the international front, I was encouraged by Nathan’s
description of the improvements, particularly in the emerging markets. But I have to admit being
less persuaded that there will be a V-shaped recovery, particularly in places outside China. I am
less persuaded that there will be a V-shaped recovery or anything even like a U-shaped recovery in
Europe and among many of our trading partners absent a strong U.S. recovery. Europe is likely to
be materially weaker than the United States and emerge later from recession.
And a final note on inflation, after having heard a broad discussion around this table.
Inflation measures do appear quite satisfactory for now. The situation certainly bears watching. My
own sense is that, while expectations of inflation remain firmly anchored, the Fed has played in the
last several weeks an important role in describing our conviction that we have the tools to exit from
the extraordinary practices we put in place and that the Fed will be central to those expectations
over the next 20 months, putting further burden on folks around this table. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.

August 11–12, 2009

105 of 165

MS. DUKE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am going to echo and maybe expand upon some
of Governor Kohn’s comments about credit. First of all, the current situation: In the overall lending
environment, demand is extremely low, although bankers are very happy with the quality and the
spreads on the new credit that they are originating and they continue to shift resources to work
through problem credits. In C&I lending, credit quality is actually holding up better than they
expected, but line utilization is at very low rates, in some cases 30 percent, maybe 50 percent on the
high side, and again, new demand is weak. In consumer credit, they did cite early-stage
delinquencies as being improved, but nobody seemed particularly comfortable with calling that a
trend.
In residential real estate, the low-end product is beginning to move. Sellers are lowering
their price expectations, in some cases being forced by the banks that will no longer extend interest
carry to get through this, and the buyers seems to be less fearful of further price declines. Most of
the buyers are either first-time homebuyers or investors who now see that the rental cash flow on
these makes sense. The inventory is actually fairly tight in the 3-to-6-months’ supply for the low
end and in the 30-to-40-months’ supply for the higher, larger properties. Some of the inventory is
just plain bad product. It is bad construction; it is poor design, poor location, or too big. The new
construction is generally smaller with fewer extras but still with quality finishes because that is what
is being demanded at the moment.
On the commercial real estate side, they are working down construction loans—some
through payout, some through charge-off, some through sales, and much through mini perm
financing. There is very little demand for new CRE (commercial real estate loans)—a reminder that
commercial real estate loans are still just business loans and their performance is dependent upon
the industry and the local economic conditions. So the deterioration depends on the type of

August 11–12, 2009

106 of 165

property. Condos are awful. Hospitality properties are extremely weak. Retail is still suffering
from rent renegotiation and vacancy rates, with rural areas and small towns being hit particularly
hard by big box closures. Office and multifamily properties are weak but are still holding up
reasonably well.
When I look at credit availability, I am struck by the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey
results, particularly the part that shows reductions in the number of respondents that have tightened
terms while, when weighted by balances outstanding, more than 75 percent of the respondents
expect the standards for prime borrowers to remain tighter than normal for the foreseeable future
and the fraction for tighter terms for the foreseeable future for subprime is even higher. In addition
to having tighter terms for approval, banks are unlikely to engage in the aggressive acquisition
strategies that they had—from the credit card mailings, the teaser rates, and that sort of thing—
because of the inability to reprice post-acquisition. Those are unlikely to resume, and I did hear
reports of 40 percent to completely eliminating those types of promotions.
On mortgage and home equity, as the indirect channels have performed so poorly, again,
they are unlikely to resume indirect acquisition. The existing credit card and home equity line
availability is still being reduced. I heard a lot about the credit card regulations, and my sense is that
they are going to affect availability, pricing, and terms for maybe a couple of years but ultimately a
new equilibrium will be found and a new business model will take hold. Most actually expect C&I
lending to return with improving business performance as banks look for income. This is the place
to which they all seem to be looking for additional income, but this may not translate into improved
availability for small businesses. Charge-offs are running very high on small business credit, and
small businesses are, frankly, very thinly capitalized. Many of them are just giving up, no longer
willing to advance the funds to keep the businesses running. SBA eligibility is a very, very tiny

August 11–12, 2009

107 of 165

slice of this market. The majority of these loans are not even in C&I. Some are in CRE—if you
think about hotels, gas stations, and that sort of thing, where the property is the business. Some are
in consumer, in mortgages, in home equity, and in credit cards.
Then I have a hard time even envisioning what the future of mortgage finance is going to
look like. The originate-to-distribute model is still broken, and there is no new model in sight. The
future of the GSEs is murky. The FHA volume is growing amid rumors of credit problems and
potential fraud. The private label is closed and unlikely to return without changes to originator
compensation and examination, rating agencies, contracts with servicers, payment priorities, loss
distribution and trust agreements, and transparencies of the loans underlying the securitizations. So
it is difficult to determine how dependent even the GSE market is on the Fed purchases.
Finally, bankers are making loans regarding credit in light of a number of uncertainties in
addition to uncertainties about economic outcomes. The first one is capital requirements. Will all
banks be stress-tested? Is that the new norm? There is limited understanding of what the capitalassessment process is designed to do and what it might mean. Community banks insist that
12 percent is the new 10 percent in terms of risk-based capital, and many note statements regarding
higher capital requirements for systemically important institutions.
In terms of treatment on commercial real estate loans, while all of the anecdotes are
certainly not applicable to all banks and may not be applicable even to some banks, all banks
believe that they could be true. They discuss the revival of the performing nonperformer. I heard
reports of the entire construction portfolio being classified. If a property is not sold through two
sales cycles, although nobody seemed to know what that meant, it must be converted to a 10-year
amortization. Examiners are requiring new appraisals, and these are being affected by both reduced
cash flow and higher cap rates and also by the fact that either there are no comparables or there are

August 11–12, 2009

108 of 165

distress sales on the comparables. The CRE loans are creating large classifications due to the
reduced cash flows and lower appraisals, even if no loss is ultimately expected, followed by MOUs
and C&Ds if the classified loans are over 100 percent of capital, and then a requirement of dollar­
for-dollar capital for classified assets.
Accounting issues are also of concern because they actually affect the measurement of
capital. FASB is getting ready to propose fair value accounting for all loans. Securitizations,
participations, and loan sales are moving back on the balance sheet. We found in the stress test the
issues in understanding acquisition accounting and what that means for reserve measures, capital
measures, and loan book measures, and then loan loss reserve accounting, consumer protection
rules, the credit card rules, the proposed CFPA, the proposal for plain vanilla products, the loss of
preemption, and the prospect of a duty of care and fiduciary responsibility. All of these are
weighing on banks as they make their decisions.
Given all of these issues, I cannot take my eyes off the alternative scenarios in the
Greenbook for financial fragility or higher saving rates and their unwelcome outcomes. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, and thank you all. Let me try to summarize the
discussion I heard around the table, and then I’ll add a few comments. There was a substantial
consensus that the economy is stabilizing, albeit at a low level, and that the technical recession is
ending. Conditions are quite heterogeneous, but that in itself was viewed by some as characteristic
of a turning point. Participants agree that output is likely to grow over the remainder of this year,
and the downside economic and financial risks may be moderating somewhat. Most expect the
recovery to continue into 2010, but there were divergent views about the strength of that recovery.
Uncertainties include the strength of the consumer rebound, the extent to which credit conditions are

August 11–12, 2009

109 of 165

normalized, and the rate of growth of economic potential. Fiscal stimulus should help to support
growth, but state and local governments remain severely constrained. Slack in resource utilization
may cap inflation in the near term, but there is a risk of an increase in inflation expectations
associated with aggressive monetary and fiscal initiatives.
Now, turning to a bit of detail, consumer spending growth remains weak and discretionary
purchases are limited; nevertheless, most saw signs of stabilization in this sector. Households still
face considerable headwinds, including slow growth in labor income, uncertainty about jobs and job
security, declines in asset prices, excessive leverage, and tight credit. An important issue is whether
households’ propensity to save will be permanently altered by the recent experience. Real income
growth is likely to remain weak for the remainder of the year as stimulus payments decline and as
labor markets remain slack. Retail sales are weak, outside of autos where sales have responded to
the cash-for-clunkers program and perhaps greater stability in the industry. Households are facing
much tougher terms on credit cards, home equity lines, mortgages, and other forms of credit, but
stimulus payments may have helped reduce financial stress for some consumers.
Home sales, residential construction, and prices have shown signs of stability or even
improvement in some areas, especially at the low end. The more-serious concerns now seem to be
in the nonresidential sector, where deteriorating fundamentals, falling prices, and lack of refinancing
capacity are weighing down the sector. Commercial real estate defaults are a significant threat to
banks, especially small and medium-sized banks. Firms are seeing better-than-expected profits,
mostly from rigorous cost-cutting, but revenues remain weak. Inventories are under better control,
especially in the auto sector, although there is more to do. Firms are generally setting a high bar for
expansion either through capital investment or hiring as managers see a good deal of excess
capacity in the system. Uncertainty about government policy may also be slowing expansion plans.

August 11–12, 2009

110 of 165

However, some surveys show some optimism among manufacturers, particularly for the medium
term. Manufacturers are benefiting to an extent from a better-than-expected global economy and
export demand and perhaps a weaker dollar. In the service sector, tourism and retail, transportation,
and other sectors are weak, but some areas such as health care continue to grow. Small businesses
may suffer disproportionately from the credit environment.
In the labor market, employment data continue to be weak, but there is evidence that
payrolls are stabilizing or at least falling more slowly. Staffing is now quite lean, and productivity
has risen. Long-term unemployment and permanent separations remain high, suggesting possible
problems of skill loss and a need for labor reallocation that could slow recovery in aggregate output.
There was considerable discussion that reallocation is linked to the NAIRU. Wage and benefits
growth continues to decelerate, reflecting poor labor market conditions.
The cumulative improvement in financial markets since the spring is quite significant. The
stock market is up broadly. Private credit spreads continue to come in. Money markets are
performing better, and risk-taking has increased. Market participants see the risk of catastrophic
outcomes as much reduced. However, financial concerns remain. In particular, banks face
significant credit losses yet to come, and as I mentioned, small and medium banks are particularly
vulnerable to losses in commercial real estate. Bank lending has fallen dramatically. Loan officers
report tight terms. Deleveraging is still under way, and securitization markets for their part are not
yet taking up the slack.
Inflation has been moderate and generally stable recently. As measured by TIPS
breakevens, inflation expectations have risen, especially at the medium-term horizon, though they
still may be characterized as anchored. On the other hand, utilization gaps remain large, and wage
growth has slowed markedly. Overall the risks to inflation seem balanced, with output gaps

August 11–12, 2009

111 of 165

exercising a deflationary influence and public concerns about the Fed’s balance sheet, the federal
deficit, and monetary and fiscal exit strategies tending to raise inflation expectations.
Communication about the Fed’s ability and willingness to withdraw accommodation at the
appropriate time remains important. Any comments?
Let me add just a few words to that. Again, Governor Tarullo mentioned that coming last
has some difficulties. I agree, of course, with most of you that the intermeeting news has been quite
encouraging. On the real side, there had not really been much of a markup in the expected path of
growth, but we have seen now firm evidence of stabilization, and I think we can agree that the
downside risks to the real economy are moderating.
In the financial markets, we have been head-faked before. We need to be careful.
Nevertheless, improvements are substantial and do feel more durable. I think there may be some
evidence, in fact, that we are getting into a more beneficial feedback loop, the opposite of the
adverse feedback loop that we saw last fall as an improving economy raises stock prices, reduces
credit spreads, and improves confidence in the banking system, which in turn helps the economy.
I think we will be seeing some growth for the rest of the year. In fact, I would venture to
guess that there may be some upside risk to the Greenbook forecast for H2 growth. There are a
number of forces that I think have baked-in growth for the next couple of quarters. Let me just give
a short list. First, obviously, is inventory dynamics, notably in autos, which is being helped by the
cash-for-clunkers program, but in other sectors as well. Inventories don’t have to increase to
improve economic growth; they just have to fall more slowly. Second, we have seen a rise in new
orders in manufacturing and significant increases in global industrial production, which suggest
some strength in the manufacturing sector. Third, there is a good bit of evidence of bottoming-out
of residential construction, which will remove a significant drag. Fourth, fiscal support. Fifth, the

August 11–12, 2009

112 of 165

better-than-expected economic growth abroad, which both is directly supportive and suggests that
some of the forces at work may be reversing more quickly than expected. Then, sixth, we shouldn’t
forget about the normal cyclical patterns, which include a rebound in demand—pent-up demand, for
durable goods, for housing and other investment goods, and for other things that have been below
normal in the last year.
So, again, I think the next half year will be reasonably good with positive growth. Of
course, the $64 billion or trillion question is what happens in 2010 going forward. I guess, as we
have discussed around the table, the two key questions will be, first, once the inventory cycle has
worked through, is final demand growth going to be sufficient to sustain a near-term recovery; and,
second, as evidenced by some of the discussion of the NAIRU, what is really happening to
potential, and what constraints will that put on growth?
The consumption path is very difficult to forecast. We are projecting recovery, and we
should just keep in mind that so far we really haven’t seen really strong evidence even on
stabilization at this point. Consumption and disposable income were revised down quite a bit in the
NIPA revisions. Consumer confidence ticked down in the latest readings and is still very low in
absolute levels, and we have talked about all of the various constraints and drags on consumer
spending. And so there certainly is some risk still in that sector. The question, again, is, Will
consumption begin to strengthen next year? The Greenbook projects both real final demand and
real consumption growing at a rate of about 2.6 percent in 2010. The standard errors for this are
very wide, as I will discuss further, but I actually think this is a pretty reasonable guess. First of all,
we have to keep in mind always that what matters for growth is the rate of change and not the level.
So even if consumption is weak relative to some benchmarks, so long as there is improvement
coming from higher asset prices, some improvement in labor markets, greater confidence, and

August 11–12, 2009

113 of 165

improving financial conditions, that would support growth in consumption even if the level in some
sense is low. So that is important.
A deeper, almost philosophical question is, What is going to happen to saving rates? The
Greenbook has households sticking with the household saving rate of about 4 percent that we have
seen recently, and that is what the staff projects into the 2010 period. In this respect, the Greenbook
saving rate projection is lower than that of many outside forecasters. I think the reason that some
people think the saving rate is likely to go up comes from staring at a picture that shows the
household saving rate over the last 20 years, which shows a steady decline from 8 or 9 percent to
close to zero to where we are today, about 4 percent. I am actually, again, inclined to side with the
staff on this. I think that the household saving rate is a pretty flawed measure of consumer behavior
for a number of reasons. One reason has to do with the artificial distinction between household
saving and private saving—private saving including the saving of businesses. To the extent that
households can either see stock prices going up or know what the value of their small business is,
they ought to integrate very largely their saving behavior with the business sector. When I was in
graduate school, I learned about Denison’s law from 1958, which said that private saving is more
stable than its components, sort of a preliminary to Ricardian equivalence in a way, and there is
some good evidence for that. If you look at the private saving rate, it has been much more stable
than household saving. Another indicator that I think is useful, and we discussed in the Board
meeting on Monday, is the wealth-to-income ratio, which theory says would be a determinant of
saving behavior. What is important to understand is that wealth-to-income ratio behavior was
abnormal in the late ’90s and the early part of this decade, when you had first a surge in stock prices
and then a surge in house prices, and in neither case was consumption able in some sense to keep up
with those increases in wealth. The longer-term wealth-to-income ratio is about 4.75 rather than the

August 11–12, 2009

114 of 165

5.5 to 6.0 that we have seen recently, and it happens to be exactly where we are today. So there is
less of a sense that we need to have substantial wealth building when you look at those data than
when you look at the household saving rate. Finally, just in terms of looking at the data, despite all
the uncertainties and the drags on consumer spending, we really haven’t seen saving go above
4 percent thus far. The temporary increase in the second quarter was due largely to the transfer
payments.
So just to reiterate, I think the Greenbook forecast for saving and final demand in 2010 is
reasonable. That said, as I said initially, the standard errors around this are large. I think we can be
confident that, at some point, consumption will begin to grow again—we don’t have to worry about
secular stagnation—but the exact timing of the consumer recovery and the speed at which it occurs
will obviously make a big difference for medium-term cyclical dynamics. In particular, the
Greenbook simulation shows a case in which the saving rate rises sharply. That causes the
economy to be very weak in 2010 and then just to begin to grow again in 2011. Another possibility
is that the saving rate will rise but only very slowly, which would give us slower growth and a
longer, more-extended transition period. So this remains a very important question. Again, I think
the modal forecast of moderate growth next year is a good one, but there is an awful lot of
uncertainty about that.
On the side of economic potential, we had some very interesting discussion today about
output gaps, the NAIRU, and so on, and I think it is an interesting question as to what extent the
NAIRU may have risen or may be rising going forward. There are some arguments for a higher
NAIRU. The level of long-term unemployment now is exceptionally high, and as we have seen in
other countries, the loss of skills and loss of job attachment can lead to hysteresis-type effects,
which can raise unemployment going forward. As I had noted myself in the past and others noted

August 11–12, 2009

115 of 165

today, there is a significant amount of sectoral reallocation going on from certain sectors that were
overexpanded to other sectors. Indeed, as others have noted, a relatively high fraction of layoffs in
this episode have been permanent rather than temporary. In the medium term also, we had very low
rates of capital formation. We have tight credit and other factors that may inhibit job creation and
business creation. So those are some factors that may raise the NAIRU.
My own sense is that the NAIRU may be a bit higher, but I wouldn’t go nearly so far as the
6½ percent in the “labor market damage” scenario that the Greenbook looks at. There are a number
of reasons to think, in particular, that the reallocation argument should not be taken too far. First of
all, if you look at the cyclical variation across industries, it is, in fact, relatively normal for a deep
recession. The sectors that are suffering the most are sectors like construction, manufacturing,
durable goods, wholesale, and transportation. Those are the sectors that normally are badly hit
during a recession, and of course, I would have to say that most of these sectors are now well below
what their steady state was likely to be. Diffusion indexes and cross-sectional standard deviations
of growth in employment also don’t suggest that we are in an extraordinarily different situation
from other recessions.
With respect to the permanent layoffs, the real change seems to have happened around 1985.
In the ’70s and early ’80s, we saw a dominant factor. The marginal firing in recession in the ’70s
and early ’80s was more likely to be temporary than permanent. But since about 1990, in the last
three recessions, the temporary and permanent shares have been about as constant on the margin as
they are on average. That did not say it very well, but what I am trying to convey is that the role of
permanent layoffs is not particularly striking compared with the last two recessions. It is striking
compared with the ’60s, ’70s, and early ’80s. In fact, there is a good bit of evidence of labor

August 11–12, 2009

116 of 165

hoarding of different types. One example I would give is part-time work, which is a way of keeping
workers, who can be restored to full-time work when the economy recovers, connected to the firm.
Finally, a note on the NIPA revisions: Prior to the revisions we had the puzzle that
unemployment seemed too high given the decline in real output, which suggested that maybe there
was a more-strenuous-than-normal effort to get rid of workers and to reduce staffing. With the
NIPA revisions, Okun’s law is looking better; again, it looks as though we are fitting a more normal
cyclical pattern. So there is a lot of uncertainty here, and I find it fully plausible that the NAIRU
will be a bit higher than it has been in the past. But in looking at that issue, I don’t think we should
overstate the differences between this recession and at least the last two recessions.
By the way, there was an interesting interrelation between the two issues I talked about—the
consumer response and the NAIRU—which was, in fact, captured in the staff’s “labor market
damage” scenario. They assumed in their simulation that consumers understood that the NAIRU
was higher and that, therefore, employment, growth, and output will be lower in the future. That
feeds back on their consumption decisions in a permanent income sense, and as a result, the
simulation actually showed bigger effects on GDP than it did on inflation, contrary to your simple
intuition about what the NAIRU would do. I think that is an open question. If the NAIRU is larger
and we around this table are not sure, are consumers better able to assess that than we are? That
may turn out to be an interesting question as we see what connections there are between the
potential of the economy, on the one hand, and consumer behavior, on the other hand.
I don’t have much to add to what has been said about inflation. I think we have to wait and
see how the gap story works. I agree with President Plosser that in principle it depends a lot on the
source of the gap, although I do think that aggregate demand has been very important in this
particular episode. We did work very hard, all of us, during the intermeeting period to try to

August 11–12, 2009

117 of 165

communicate our exit strategy and our resolve to defend price stability. We should continue to do
that, and I hope that will be constructive going forward. So those are my comments. Brian, if you
will, we can just turn now to the policy alternative.
MR. MADIGAN.2 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll be referring to the package
labeled “Material for Briefing on Monetary Policy Alternatives,” which includes the
same set of statements that was distributed earlier this week. Although the economic
outlook has changed only gradually on balance, the economic and financial situation
has improved significantly since early spring. The economic downturn has abated
considerably, with activity apparently now in the process of leveling off; financial
markets display fewer strains and have become much more supportive of growth; and
downside risks to the economy seem to have diminished appreciably. Still, the
outlook continues to be weak, with the staff, many private forecasters, and Committee
participants projecting a subpar recovery and slow progress in reducing
unemployment. Meanwhile, inflation has been subdued, but not as low as might have
been expected given the substantial resource slack that has developed. Moreover,
concerns persist about the possible effects of unprecedented monetary and fiscal
stimulus on inflation. Depending on your assessment and weighting of the risks, you
might consider a substantial range of policy adjustments to be appropriate.
In addition to this broad economic backdrop, the calendar itself may be a factor in
the Committee’s consideration of its options today. The Treasury purchase program
is scheduled to come to an end in September, and the agency and MBS programs are
due to expire at year-end. Given these impending expirations, the Committee would
seem to have reached a key decision point at this meeting. In particular, an important
part of your deliberations today and presumably at your September meeting will be
whether to allow the existing programs to expire, to let them reach their existing
limits, or to extend and expand them. Against that background, the Bluebook
presented four policy alternatives: A, B, C, and a variant of alternative B, labeled B′.
In addition, on Monday we provided another version of alternative B, labeled
alternative B (revised), for your consideration.
The staff forecast and the analytical approaches summarized in the “Monetary
Policy Strategies” section of the Bluebook continue to suggest that a near-zero federal
funds rate will remain appropriate for some time. Consistent with that view, each of
the alternatives maintains the existing 0 to ¼ percent target range for the federal funds
rate. The alternatives differ primarily in their options for large-scale asset purchases
and in their guidance about the federal funds rate going forward.
Under alternative A, page 2, the Committee would expand its purchases of

Treasury securities to $450 billion. The Committee would also indicate its 

expectation that it will purchase the full $1.25 trillion of agency mortgage-backed 

securities while continuing to state that purchases of agency debt will total “up to” 

2

The materials used by Mr. Madigan are appended to this transcript (appendix 2).

August 11–12, 2009

118 of 165

$200 billion, thus implicitly allowing for a likely shortfall in this program. The time
frame for Treasury purchases would be extended by three months to year-end.
The Committee might be motivated to adopt alternative A if, like the staff, it
continues to expect a comparatively slow economic recovery, with high levels of
resource slack persisting for several years and inflation falling to rates below those
that Committee participants see as most consistent with the Federal Reserve’s dual
mandate. Based on our reading of market reactions to previous announcements of
changes to LSAP quantities, we estimate that the $150 billion expansion in Treasury
purchases would likely reduce longer-term interest rates by 10 to 20 basis points. In
turn, we estimate that a reduction in longer-term rates of this magnitude would lower
the unemployment rate two years ahead by 0.1 to 0.2 percentage point. However,
these estimates are subject to considerable error, in part because it is difficult to tell
whether worries among some market participants about monetization of the debt
could be exacerbated by the expansion in Treasury purchases.
If members are also concerned that market participants may be pricing in a much
earlier shift toward monetary policy tightening than currently seems likely and that
these expectations are resulting in financial conditions that are tighter than
appropriate, the Committee could consider sending a more explicit signal about its
expectations for the path of policy. In particular, as shown at the end of the third
paragraph of alternative A, the Committee could indicate that “economic conditions
are likely to warrant maintaining the 0 to ¼ percent target range for the federal funds
rate at least through mid-2010.” This statement would provide a more specific time
frame than indicated by the current “extended period” phrase, and it would also be
more explicit about the trajectory of rates than the current “exceptionally low levels
of the federal funds rate.”
If the Committee broadly concurs with the staff forecast but judges that the costs
of expanding LSAPs—such as potential difficulties in tightening policy down the
road or possible adverse effects on inflation expectations—would likely exceed the
benefits, it might opt for one of the versions of alternative B. Under the Bluebook
version of alternative B, page 3, the Committee would essentially maintain the current
limits of its large-scale asset purchases. However, the statement would indicate that
the Committee will gradually slow its purchases of Treasuries in order “to promote a
smooth transition in markets” and, to allow time for that transition, will extend the
period for completing these purchases through October.
Under alternative B, the Committee would not specify its plans today for exiting
from its MBS and agency debt programs. Although Desk and Board staff members
recommend tapering those purchases as they are brought to a close, the MBS and
agency debt programs are not scheduled to expire until year-end. Thus the
Committee might conclude that it is not yet necessary to spell out its exit strategy for
these programs and may see silence on this point as helping to preserve optionality
over coming weeks to increase these purchases if economic or financial conditions
unexpectedly deteriorate. However, the Committee would probably wish to decide

August 11–12, 2009

119 of 165

and announce no later than its September 22-23 meeting whether and how to wind
down its MBS and agency programs. If it were so inclined, the Committee could
announce at its September meeting that it was tapering the current program of MBS
and agency purchases into the first quarter of next year. Such an approach would be
consistent with the recommendations in the Desk’s memo.
The language of alternative B would suggest that the Committee was unlikely to
resume purchases of Treasury securities absent very unexpected developments.
Should the Committee instead wish to preserve significantly greater scope for
restarting Treasury purchases in coming months, it might choose instead to adopt the
language of alternative B′, page 4. Under this variant, the statement would note
explicitly that the Committee “is prepared to consider resuming its purchases of
Treasury securities in light of the evolving economic outlook and conditions in
financial markets.” Like B, alternative B′ would preserve flexibility with respect to
possible changes in the agency debt and MBS programs.
Alternative B (revised), on page 5, incorporates several changes from the draft of
B in the Bluebook. First, to avoid a possible implication that the inventory correction
is close to completion, the third sentence has been revised to indicate that businesses
“are making progress” in bringing inventory stocks into better alignment with sales,
rather than “have made progress.” Second, on further consideration it seemed
appropriate to characterize financial market conditions as having improved “further”
rather than just “somewhat further.” Finally, changes to the third paragraph would
preserve the option of resuming Treasury purchases but use language that is less
explicit than that in B′. In particular, the penultimate sentence would indicate that the
Committee will continue to evaluate the timing and overall amounts of its purchases
of securities generally, not just those of agency debt and MBS. Overall, alternative B
(revised) would maintain significant flexibility for the Committee to change its
purchase strategy in either direction.
Market participants generally appear to expect an announcement along the lines
of the various versions of Alternative B, and any market reaction seems likely to be
relatively modest. If anything, market rates might move up a little as investors would
be confronted with the reality that the Committee’s asset purchases were now being
wound down.
Under alternative C, page 6, the Committee would begin to lower the degree of
monetary policy stimulus, partly by reducing its large-scale asset purchases and partly
by revising its forward rate guidance. Members might be attracted to this alternative
if they were more optimistic than the staff about the likely strength of the recovery or
if they were otherwise concerned that inflationary pressures could be greater or build
more quickly than expected by the staff. The latter concerns could reflect a view that
the influence of slack on price pressures is likely to be smaller than the staff
anticipates, perhaps because you judge that financial turmoil is restraining the
economy’s potential by more than allowed for in the Greenbook projection.
Alternatively, you may worry that the high current degree of monetary

August 11–12, 2009

120 of 165

accommodation, if sustained much longer, could spur inflation through any of a 

variety of channels—for example, by leading to an unmooring of inflation 

expectations. Such concerns might have been amplified, for instance, by the recent

nearly ½ percentage point increase in five-year-forward inflation compensation. 

Under alternative C, the Committee would state that “in view of the improved
economic outlook,” it “now expects that its purchases of agency mortgage-backed
securities (MBS) and agency debt will cumulate to about $1 trillion and about
$150 billion, respectively, somewhat less than the previously announced maximum
amounts.” The Committee would also indicate that, with its purchases of Treasuries
well along toward completion, it anticipates buying the full amount of $300 billion.
As in the B alternatives, the Treasury purchases would be extended through October,
thus encompassing a tapering strategy, and the reduced purchases of agency debt and
MBS would permit those transactions to be tapered over the balance of the year. The
announcement would also note that the Committee now expected that it would
maintain the current 0 to ¼ percent range “at least through the end of this year” rather
than “for an extended period,” which would likely be seen as a weaker policy
commitment.
Overall, the combination of reduced asset purchases and a signal that policy
tightening might begin soon after the turn of the year would represent a considerable
surprise to investors and probably would cause quite a sizable market reaction. A
reduction in total asset purchases—apart perhaps from a small undershoot in the
agency debt program—is not expected by the market, and thus the announcement of
these reductions would likely prompt a noticeable backup in market interest rates—
perhaps 20 to 25 basis points on MBS rates and 10 to 15 basis points on Treasuries
from the supply effects alone. Those increases would be reinforced by the revision to
the Committee’s forward rate guidance, as that change would probably be seen as a
signal that the Committee now anticipates that it might begin tightening policy early
next year. Although market participants currently see some chance of such an
outcome, most appear to expect policy tightening to commence no sooner than mid­
2010 and probably later. The decision to combine the revised expectations for the
funds rate with the reduced size of asset purchases might be seen as reinforcing the
message that the Committee clearly wants to move away from its accommodative
policy stance, and hence this announcement would probably lead to a significant
increase in yields on instruments with terms of six months or more.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, Brian. Are there questions for Brian? Seeing
none, we can begin our go-round with President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support the policy described in
alternative B, much for the reasons laid out in the Bluebook and as Brian just explained in his

August 11–12, 2009

121 of 165

lead-in. The economic story in my view is unfolding close to my expectations, and negative
deviations from this outlook might justify an increment of stimulus as detailed in alternative A,
but I don’t see such deviations developing quite yet. At the same time, as noted in the earlier goround, I view the economy as remaining in a fragile condition, so I think the reduction in
stimulus laid out in alternative C is premature.
I support the language in alternative B (revised). I think it best serves us in remaining
flexible and keeping our options open. And I don’t favor the language “prepared to consider” in
alternative B′. In our deliberations, we translated this subtly suggestive language into Southern.
In Southern it would come out “fixin’ to ponder.” [Laughter] If you detect a little sarcasm in
that, that was my view of the “prepared to consider” language.
I do support the extension of TALF. I favor this. As I mentioned in my economic goround discussion, we had a long conversation with the American Securitization Forum, and the
take-away from that conversation convinced me that the securitization sector is extremely vital to
the financial system. Its recovery is important, and it continues to need help. I think it does raise
the question, in terms of exit, of whether we will have to extend the TALF further in order to
continue that support, particularly for CMBS, beyond June 1 of next year. So at this time, I think
it is sensible to extend the TALF. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Financial market conditions have indeed
improved, and there is increased evidence that the economy has bottomed out with all of the
mixed signals that turning points generally experience and, therefore, it is poised to grow
somewhat in the second half of the year. Based on these developments in the outlook, I see no
compelling reason to increase our purchases of long-term assets. Indeed, I would prefer that we

August 11–12, 2009

122 of 165

cut back the scale of our MBS purchases somewhat. Our current rate of purchase is outstripping
the issuance, and the Fed’s share of that market is significant. We are potentially crowding out
private investors and risk preventing the healing process from progressing and, in doing so,
perhaps permanently affecting the functioning of this important market.
Thus, I am going to favor beginning to taper our rate of purchases of MBS immediately.
Doing so would have two primary benefits. It would allow us to better gauge whether private
financial intermediation in MBS is improving and thus allow us to recalibrate our total asset
purchases based on those additional data. If the experience is good, we may not choose to reach
the maximum we indicated—that is, the $1.25 billion. If we have concerns, we can always
extend the purchases into next year. Given the increased stability in residential real estate
markets and the improvements in intermediation in some other MBS markets, my expectation is
that the MBS market will improve and that we will be able to pull back.
I welcomed yesterday’s discussion of the tools we will use to tighten policy when the
time comes. Improving the efficiency of interest on excess reserves is an important avenue. But
given the size of our balance sheet, as I indicated yesterday, I wouldn’t want to rely entirely on
just this. I think we need to discuss whether or not we are prepared to sell assets, even if it
means taking losses on our balance sheet, should the need arise. I for one would want to do so if
our price stability goals required it. Another element that would help our efforts in this regard to
maintain price stability is to continue to pursue our efforts to implement inflation targeting. I
appreciate the difficult political environment we are in, but I hope we don’t lose sight of that
initiative.
As I have stated in the past, I think the language in our statement should be modified with
a view toward our eventual exit from the zero bound. That means trying to find a way to

August 11–12, 2009

123 of 165

extricate ourselves from the current exceptionally low levels of the federal funds rate for
extended periods. At some point, we will have to move away from the “extended” language. I
believe we should be preparing ourselves and the markets for that eventuality. My preference
would be to say that the Committee will maintain the target range for the federal funds rate at
zero to ¼ percent and anticipates that economic conditions will likely warrant low levels of the
funds rate for a period of time. Just drop “extended.”
The options in alternatives A and C are, however, worse than the current language in my
view. At least the use of “extended period” can be interpreted as a state-contingent or a statedependent context. I think that replacing state-contingent language with time-dependent
language is misguided for a number of reasons, not the least of which is that we actually make
policy on a state-contingent basis. Tying ourselves to a time table, given the tremendous
uncertainty surrounding the future economic conditions, I believe is not wise. In general, I
would prefer alternative C, without the time-dependent language because it scales back our asset
purchases.
I would be comfortable, though, with alternative B or B (revised) if we indicate that we
will immediately begin to taper the pace of MBS purchases without necessarily committing to an
end amount or an end date. We have already said that we will go to $1.25 trillion, yet we may
not want to get there. We don’t have to decide that yet. But reducing the pace immediately
would give us some flexibility to allow the private markets to gradually reenter this market and
would let us reemphasize that policy decisions are in fact state-dependent. We might want to
stop the agency debt purchases altogether, given the size of that market. But the amount is not
very significant, so I don’t feel terribly strongly about that. Thus my preference would be to
replace the sentence regarding MBS with something very simple like “the Desk is authorized to

August 11–12, 2009

124 of 165

purchase up to $200 billion in household-related agency debt and up to $1.25 trillion of agency
MBS. The Desk is expected to gradually slow the pace of purchases of these securities as
markets improve.”
Finally, Mr. Chairman, I think we must be very careful in our interpretation of recent
declines in inflation. A tremendous run-up in oil prices in 2007–08 had both a significant effect
on headline inflation and, to some degree, a pass-through into core inflation. We are fortunate
that expectations remained well anchored during that period, and we were helped when oil prices
made a sudden, dramatic reversal and declined. I think this oil price decline accounts for much
of what we have seen this year in the decline in inflation, though expectations have been
remarkably stable throughout this period, which is a very good sign. Apparently, the markets are
looking through the large relative price changes, both in the run-up as well as the come-back­
again. So I think we must be careful not to attribute inflation to last year’s oil prices and then
attribute the reduction in inflation this year or the risk of persistent deflation to output gaps. That
is my view. Those are two sides of the same coin. We will learn more, I think, about underlying
inflation pressures, or lack thereof, in coming quarters as we have a more stable period of oil
prices, so that it is not jerking around both headline and core inflation. Thank you very much,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. I am thinking about what President Plosser just said. I haven’t changed
my hawkish feathers, but I don’t want to be anybody’s pigeon. I think we have to be cognizant
of what is actually happening in the microeconomic sector. Yesterday I spoke of post-traumatic
slack syndrome, and I want to expand slightly upon that to explain why I am in favor of
alternative B. On the run-up side, which was only a year ago, what business women and men did

August 11–12, 2009

125 of 165

was to tighten the cost of goods sold. They were ferociously driven by the fact that everything
under their control was accelerating in price. Now that they cannot grow their top lines, they are
continuing that process. I will give you an example. If you look at the spending pulse data that
is compiled by MasterCard—and this is not yet public to my knowledge, because it goes until the
end of July—and you look at the airline industry, the spending pulse data will tell you that
revenues for airlines were up 1.6 percent year over year in July. Airfares were down 14 percent.
What accounts for the difference? A 48 percent increase in transactions. They are nickel and
diming everybody on baggage, what you pay for food, et cetera, et cetera, and that is how they
have made up the shortfall. You can see this also roll over into the way small business suppliers
are being treated. In my conversations with the CEO of AT&T, he told me that he listens in to
their small business call center. Fifty percent of the current calls are women and men in small
businesses begging to have their phone bills reduced by at least half. Bad debts are rising, and
they have other pressures operating upon them.
My point is this: We are likely to have significant slack for some time. We are unlikely
to see cap-ex grow, as I mentioned earlier, for some time. And, yes, Mr. Chairman, we have to
be careful not to make assumptions that are somehow different from those in previous
recoveries. But I think that, on a microeconomic level, the shock that business women and men
have gone through does condition their response and is likely to lead to an additional lag in
cap-ex and give pause to hiring new workers for a longer period than we would like, particularly
in the globalized environment in which we live and which in previous recessions didn’t exist to
the extent we have today. So we know that in the short term, for several quarters at least, slack
does have an effect on price movements and inflation. Long term, we know from Milton
Friedman and others that sustained inflation is always a monetary phenomenon.

August 11–12, 2009

126 of 165

Therefore, I think it is important that we recognize reality. We are likely to have a
snapback here. It may be somewhat frisky in the short term, assisted by inventory corrections, as
you mentioned, and more-felicitous market conditions, such as have been described at the table.
The longer-term outlook is still somewhat tenuous, so we have to take account of that. We also
have to take account of the still-palpable concern that we may or may not be willing to pull the
trigger. Mind you, I come from a state where even the former Vice President of the United
States did not hesitate to pull the trigger.
I think all of us have made an effort—in addition to the tools laid out—to make it clear
that we are not going to be hesitant. Therefore, I think it is very important that we signal clearly
that we are not going to buy Treasuries beyond the number that we mentioned. I was against it
in the beginning. I am still against it. I am happy to see it die. I think it shows that we have
resolve. That, combined with the statement that, if I understood correctly, you will issue on
Thursday at the Board, that we will—and I am quoting you, Mr. Chairman—“suspend
consideration of additional asset classes” while we extend the timeline to March 31. To me that
is sufficient to indicate that, indeed, we have the resolve to do what we are going to do. At the
same time, it doesn’t cut off the salutary effects of what I think we are doing to offset the forces
that I just described.
So I would favor alternative B. I do not favor alternative B′ or B (revised). To me, those
are like St. Augustine’s prayer, “O Lord, help me to be pure, but not yet.” I think we should
proceed to show our resolve. Alternative B does it, and it also reflects the reality of the current
economic circumstances. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Is the coffee ready, do you think? [Laughter]
All right. It is 10:30. Why don’t we take a 20-minute break.

August 11–12, 2009

127 of 165

[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Why don’t we recommence. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The baseline forecast has inflation too
low and unemployment too high for the next several years. Such a forecast would almost surely
imply further easing, if we had not hit the zero bound. The asset-purchase program has probably
helped stabilize markets and lowered key interest rates compared with what they would have
been without the purchases. However, the amount of macroeconomic stimulus produced to date
by our large asset purchases has been smaller than I expected. In part, our implementation
continues to favor market functioning over the broader macroeconomic goals of pushing rates
down more aggressively to more rapidly achieve desired macroeconomic outcomes. Given
current implementation strategies, I prefer alternative B (revised), though I remain concerned
about the pace of a likely recovery and would favor more-aggressive measures if the economy
were to falter or the risk of significant disinflation were to increase. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, favor alternative B (revised). Despite
the series of positive surprises that President Stern pointed out yesterday, since March the center
of gravity of expectations around this table is for a slow recovery—maybe a little faster than the
Greenbook but not much—and damped inflation.
I think it is way too early to signal that we are thinking about withdrawing or cutting back
on stimulus, so that leaves one with two consequences. I would keep the “extended period”
language in there unchanged, and I would not curtail the large-scale asset-purchase programs. I
would complete our announced purchases, with the possible exception of the agency securities,
as that market is not liquid enough. I would taper off those mortgage-backed security purchases

August 11–12, 2009

128 of 165

over the fourth quarter and maybe into the first quarter to get up to the total, but I am okay with
waiting until next meeting to tell the public what we are going to do there. I think the public is
expecting something like alternative B (revised). They won’t miss it, and we can do that next
time. I am okay with winding up the Treasury purchase program. The economic situation is
improving. There are some costs in terms of concerns about the exit strategy and our ability to
keep inflation low. But I wouldn’t rule out anything for the future, including resuming the
purchases under certain circumstances.
I think we need to keep all our options open. As President Rosengren just said, the
central tendency itself isn’t a really satisfactory outcome relative to our legislative mandate.
There is huge uncertainty. And while there is upside risk, there is still a lot of downside risk as
well. And, there are nontrivial odds on whether we get a slow recovery, inflation begins to
abate, unemployment rises, and bank losses mount further, and we are back into a kind of
adverse feedback loop in the financial markets. I don’t think that is what is going to happen, but
I think there is some possibility. There are lots of things we need to think about if the economy
starts going down and if we start getting into a deflationary situation. In that case, if we were to
resume Treasury purchases while inflation was going down and while the economy was
weakening, there wouldn’t be adverse consequences for inflation expectations. So all of those
things lead me to want to keep all of the options open, and I think alternative B (revised) does a
good job of that. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I favor alternative B (revised). I think it has at
least two important virtues. One is that it maintains our flexibility, and the second is that it is
likely to do no harm. [Laughter] And I think these are both constructive.

August 11–12, 2009

129 of 165

I have given some serious thought to alternative C, but I really think it is premature to go
to something like that. In that connection, I have been asking myself if it is possible that the
economy will grow considerably more rapidly over the next six quarters than I currently expect
and than is indicated in the Greenbook. And I just don’t see the ingredients, the precursors, for
something like that over that time frame. So I think alternative C is premature at this point.
In light of the discussion, I have also been thinking some more about the inflation
situation and the inflation outlook. I have never been a particular enthusiast of the gap models,
mainly because my impression is that you have to work pretty hard empirically to get a
significant and stable relationship. I guess if you work hard enough you can, but I don’t think it
is overwhelming. The staff can correct me if I have mischaracterized that situation. On the other
hand, it takes a model to beat a model, and I don’t think we have another model in the short run.
So we are kind of left with that. But in the longer run, I do think it pays to look at the monetary
aggregates. In particular, if you look at M2, you see that—going back as far as 2003, anyway—
growth there has been pretty moderate for a sustained period of time, something between 5 and
6 percent on average. It was certainly rapid last year. It was certainly rapid in the first quarter of
this year, but it has tapered off again. I certainly don’t see in the aggregate data a case for a
sustained near-term burst of inflation—“near-term” meaning within the next six or eight
quarters. You might say, “Well, the monetary base gives you a different picture”; but if the base
were so reliable, we would have targeted it. I think we have learned that its relation to broader
aggregates and to things like inflation just isn’t very convincing even in the longer run. So I
don’t see a significant inflation threat in the near term. I do think, if you look at those M2
numbers, we may want to bring those down consistent with the price stability part of the dual

August 11–12, 2009

130 of 165

mandate eventually. But there doesn’t seem to be any urgency to it, and I think the deceleration
required isn’t likely to be terribly great. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think we need to be very careful going
forward and watch the banking system very carefully as we continue with our large-scale assetpurchase program, as we discussed yesterday. I don’t think of discussing cutting back on
additional purchases as withdrawing stimulus so much as reducing the size of the planned
increase in stimulus. Our understanding of just what will happen when we reach this
discontinuity, when our asset holdings drive short-term liquidity facility usage to zero, is
significant. And there is a chance that we may inadvertently at that time begin increasing our
stimulus quite powerfully and more than we expect and more than we intend, just at a time when
we are starting to consider withdrawing stimulus or reducing the amount of stimulus we provide
in light of a strengthening economy.
I see some merit in alternative C for this reason—to hedge our bets somewhat with the
economy turning and downside risk moderating. In addition, I think there are abundant
reasons—at least, I see abundant reasons—to be deeply uncomfortable with large-scale holdings
of agency mortgage-backed securities. There is a sense—and I think this was explicitly
acknowledged in the design of the program—that it is impeding a structural transition to
whatever is next by way of the configuration of our housing finance system. But it also involves
some very serious political entanglements that I have alluded to before and that give me pause
about our ability to flexibly shed that portfolio should we find the need to do so.
However, I am prepared at this meeting to support alternative B (revised) for now. Along
with President Stern, I think it is a little premature to scale back our announcement about what

August 11–12, 2009

131 of 165

we intend with mortgage-backed securities. But, again, we need to be very watchful of what is
going on in the banking system with reserve holdings, and it might be good to mount an effort to
do that on a very systematic and granular basis. More broadly, with the economy turning, I think
it is time to stop looking around for credit spreads to fix. As I said yesterday, our interventions
in some segments of the credit market have reduced the supply of credit to other segments, and
there are always going to be markets in which some spreads are elevated compared with the
spreads that prevail in markets in which we have intervened. That is just always going to be the
case from now on. Moreover, continuing to add market segments or to extend the life of
programs beyond this point in the business cycle could be mistaken for an intention that we will
extend our intervention deeper into the next expansion.
We have talked a lot about exit strategy. But when we have done so, it has been in the
narrow sense of the capacity to manipulate our balance sheet and our policy tools in a way so as
to raise the federal funds rate. Mr. Chairman, you have done a very good job of articulating our
capacity and the tools we have for doing that and, I think, have allayed a lot of concerns in the
public’s mind about our ability. But one byproduct of the way in which we have done that is that
some of the means of doing so allow for the continued coexistence of fairly broad and deep
intervention—in other words, a large balance sheet and raising interest rates on reserves and so
raising the funds rate without reducing our balance sheet.
That leaves open the broader question about our intervention in credit markets. I think
the other sense of exit strategy that we need to ponder is the nature of our engagement in credit
markets and what transition that is going to display over the next couple of years. I am
assuming—I may be wrong as we haven’t talked about this—that at some point in the expansion
we will want it to be the case that we are no longer intervening in any market, even MBS. And I

August 11–12, 2009

132 of 165

think that communicating about that transition would be useful and thinking about it would be
useful as well. We have intervened on the basis that emergencies in credit markets warrant
protecting the economy from damage from credit market malfunctions. And when the economy
recovers and is growing strongly, it seems to me that the compelling need for that will be
diminished. On the other hand, it is not clear that we have articulated principles that would
necessarily lead an observer to believe that in an expansion we wouldn’t be intervening. I refer
again to the list of pros and cons that we heard yesterday about agency ARMs that make it seem
as if elevated credit spreads are a primary consideration for a lot of these programs. So I think it
would useful for us to think more broadly about the transition we intend to make from the
current level of engagement and intervention in credit markets to whatever the sort of normalcy
is beyond that. This sets aside what we want people to expect from us in the next recession,
which is another problem as well and another set of issues we need to grapple with at some
point. But, again, I can support alternative B (revised). Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lacker, I think that there is pretty strong
consensus that we do need to normalize and move out of special intervention as the economy
recovers. And we have taken some steps in that direction, including letting one facility expire,
reducing the size of others, and announcing this week that we are not going to add any categories
to the TALF program. So I think we agree with your perspective on that.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support the revised version of alternative B.
I do want to emphasize, though, that I believe a strong case exists for further monetary stimulus.
This case is amply demonstrated by the unconstrained optimal policy path in the Bluebook,

August 11–12, 2009

133 of 165

which shows the nominal federal funds rate continuing to ease over the next four quarters and
reaching negative 6 percent. Moreover, even in the unlikely circumstance that we are lucky
enough to get robust economic growth over the next few years, it will still be a long time before
the economy is operating close to full employment. And I found it striking that in none of the
alternative scenarios in the Greenbook, even including the most optimistic one, would the
Committee need to raise interest rates this year or in 2010.
With regard to asset purchases, I would not argue for expanding our Treasury purchases.
I think it would be unwise at this time. The bang for the buck from these purchases is probably
pretty small, and our program has had some unfortunate costs. It appears to be contributing to
the growing concern about high long-term inflation. Even though I don’t favor raising our
current target for Treasury purchases now, I consider it important that we avoid completely
closing the door on future Treasury purchases. I would associate myself with Governor Kohn’s
comment that there could certainly come a time when the economic outlook worsens
considerably. We shouldn’t rule out that possibility, and further long-term Treasury purchases
could, in that type of scenario, be needed to stimulate the economy, so we shouldn’t rule out the
use of that policy tool. The revised version of alternative B keeps the option open. I think the
wording of the original version of B would be likely to be read as closing the door to future
purchases, and I don’t think we need the more explicit language in alternative B′ that says that
we are prepared to consider resuming purchases.
With respect to MBS and agency purchases, I am in favor of preserving our optionality,
waiting to decide until closer to when the program comes to a conclusion in the same way that
we did with Treasuries. Again, I wouldn’t want to take anything off the table at this point. If we
were to announce today either scaling back on the amounts we expect to purchase or announce

August 11–12, 2009

134 of 165

that we intend to end those programs, I think it would surprise markets and ratify expectations
that it won’t be too long before we start raising the funds rate.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I favor a continued wait-and-see approach,
which I think is best captured roughly by alternative B, the revised version. I would make some
observations. The modest recovery in GDP is in progress, and the expected peak in the
unemployment rate is six or more months away. The Greenbook and Bluebook measures of our
policy stance suggest to me that they are near policy accommodation stances that close the
resource gaps within three years. I know we could hope to do better, but I think we pushed our
nontraditional policies pretty far, and the remaining fruit is hanging pretty high. I agree with
President Stern when he says that sometimes there is just not a lot more that you can do or that
you should consider doing.
I interpret the prospective resource slack that we are facing to be large, and this is going
to restrain inflationary influences from economic improvements and low policy rates. I thought
Governor Kohn did an excellent job of discussing the inflation prospects and walking us through
inflation expectations and the resource gap and how they are interacting or how we have to take
account of those. It does appear that inflation expectations have remained higher than one might
have expected with this slack. That has been important, I think, for the evolution of inflation.
That said, we are in uncharted territory with respect to the enormous expansion of our
balance sheet and the public’s reaction to this, and so liquidity growth and historic-sized fiscal
deficits as far as the eye can see are going to present a challenge at least from the public’s
expectations. The narrow measures of money that we would look to as very troubling are not yet

August 11–12, 2009

135 of 165

in the broader measures, and I think that that is an important part of what we would be paying
attention to if we saw large inflationary expectations.
For me, our current setting of policy seems appropriately accommodative to balance
these risks. Let’s be patient and monitor the situation more. Until something breaks one way or
the other, I would expect this type of policy outcome. When the situation clarifies, we should
make the appropriate judgments. It could be that the downside risk appears and it is quite bad
and we need to do something or the other way around. I do not see the need to signal an
alternative B about future programs.
So alternative B, the revised version. I didn’t see the tremendous value in mentioning
tapering off for Treasuries, given the deep market that we have, but that doesn’t seem to be
expressed by others. So I am fine with that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, support the revised version of
alternative B. Given the large output gap that I see closing only slowly and an inflation rate
projection that remains low over the forecast period, I am comfortable maintaining the current
level of monetary stimulus. Market participants clearly recognize that our Treasury security
purchases will cumulate to a level near the stated objective around the time of the next meeting.
So it seems appropriate to recognize this in our statement today, to be more transparent about our
intentions, and I think alternative B does that well. Also, as Brian mentioned, it is not necessary
to specify at this meeting changes to our purchases of agency debt and mortgage-backed
securities. So I prefer to wait until our September meeting to comment on those purchases. Like
others, I believe that it is important to leave our options open, and the revised version of

August 11–12, 2009

136 of 165

alternative B gives us, I think, the appropriate flexibility that we need. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I also support alternative B, the revised
version. I think the tapering ideas that have been expressed by the staff are fine, and I also think
that we can think about tapering the MBS program at the next meeting. As you know, I have
suggested growth rates instead of these flat, level amounts, which I find a bit arbitrary. They are
still in this Bluebook with $450 billion in alternative A. You may want to think about moving to
very low growth rates for these programs. You know, a lot of people have expressed the idea
about keeping the programs alive. You can move to very low growth rates, and I’ll talk a little
more about that in a minute. If we did that, we could react more easily if the data came in worse
than expected and we wanted to again expand asset-purchase programs.
On policies to manage excess reserves, that sounds as though we’re planning to rely a lot
on our interest-on-reserves policy. I have a comment on that. I think it sounds expensive. It
could be viewed as a large transfer to banks in an environment where that would be politically
quite unpopular. As I understand it, the Congress opposed interest on reserves for decades
exactly because of the revenue implications. So this is just a caution that it seems as though we
are going down this path pretty rapidly and we are putting a lot of emphasis on interest on
reserves as a way to manage the very extensive excess reserves that are in the system, and it
could be viewed in an unflattering light.
President Stern made some comments about the monetary base, and because I have the
last word and it’s his last meeting, I’m going to comment on that. It is true that, if you run
regressions over the last 25 years on the monetary base, you are not going to get very much. But

August 11–12, 2009

137 of 165

I just want to stress that we are in an absolutely unprecedented situation. We have more than
doubled the size of the monetary base. I do not think you can rely on whatever those regressions
said in the past as to what the outcomes of this experiment might be. So we have to be very
careful in thinking about what the implications are going forward. Of course, it all has to do
with, well, how would that ever get out into the money supply and so on, and what are future
policies? How permanent is it, so on and so forth? How much slack is there in the economy?
All of those things are important, but this is an unprecedented experiment in U.S. monetary
policy.
Let me turn to communication for a minute. I take the lesson of the last 25 years in
macroeconomics to be that it is important to communicate future policy partly because you care
about the future but also partly because it really affects your equilibrium outcomes today. It
informs the pricing today. We do not really have that for this asset-purchase program. I think
we made some progress in talking about exit strategy, and I actually think that was pretty
successful during the intermeeting period. But still, there is a lot of uncertainty about future
policy, say, over the next two years and about what we would do.
I agree with President Yellen that, if we went with alternative B unrevised, it could be
interpreted that the Fed goes on hold. We have said that we are not going to do any more asset
purchases. According to the Greenbook, we are not going to raise the funds rate off zero for a
long time. So we just go on hold for two years. I don’t think that is really the intent of the
Committee, and I would not want to lock us in that direction. As many people have said and I
think Governor Tarullo said, you have a pretty high probability that you will get an outcome that
isn’t very desirable over the next two years. Then the question is what the Fed’s reaction will be,
and I think you have to keep the option open that you might extend the asset purchases at that

August 11–12, 2009

138 of 165

point. The market doesn’t know what we will do; this Committee doesn’t know what we will do.
If we could reduce that uncertainty, that would help us a lot. I would like to make some progress
toward a more systematic policy on asset purchases and more generally a systematic policy while
we are at the zero bound.
Let me just make a couple more comments. Fixed dates for rates at zero—some of the
language in these policy options says things like we will keep rates low until the end of the year
or we will keep rates at zero until the middle of next year. I really prefer not to get into the
particular dates for when we might raise rates. I think it does two things that we don’t like. First
of all, it de-emphasizes the state-contingent nature of optimal policy. Everything depends on the
data. It depends on how the data on the economy come in. So I do not think that we should be
saying, all of a sudden, that we are going to make it non-state contingent and that just at this
certain date we are going to do something. Also, I think it sets up an expectation that we really
will raise rates at that point, and we may not want to do that at that point. This is not in
alternative B, but it is in the other alternatives. I think it is not something we want to get into in
any of our alternatives.
Lastly, I agree with President Plosser and many others who have commented here
concerning the narrative that slack alone will contain inflation pressures going forward, which is
really reflected in paragraph 2 of our statement and has been there for a long time in alternative
B. I think too much reliance on this view could lead to a policy mistake and a repeat of the
1970s experience. There are three problems with the output gap. One is the conceptual
problems that were outlined by President Lacker. Another is empirical fit, as mentioned by
President Stern. No matter how you do the measurement, it just doesn’t help you that much in
forecasting inflation. It helps a little, not much. And the third one, which has not been

August 11–12, 2009

139 of 165

mentioned, is that it is also inconsistent with a lot of our rhetoric about a bursting bubble. If you
think that something went wrong and you had some housing bubble or some other kind of bubble
and this thing collapsed on you, you can’t be saying, well, we want to go back up to this bubble
level of output. When you get into the discussions of potential output, bubbles are out of the
picture, right? But when you’re talking about the economy and the situation today, bubbles are a
big part of the story. So that’s another piece that I think is inconsistent with our current rhetoric
about output gaps. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Just a question about your comment on the base. Why
wouldn’t Japan be a precedent for this experiment?
MR. BULLARD. It is a great example to look at. I don’t think theirs was that persistent,
and so they didn’t get that much inflation. Ours is looking pretty persistent.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me give the background on where I
come out on this. That is, as I mentioned yesterday, the evidence is that we are at or near the
bottom of this cycle. At least the evidence is pointing that way, and in that environment at this
point, we obviously have excess capacity: railroads, 50 percent in use. That is to be expected.
But I think as we look ahead, we are starting to see improvement, and that should continue and
perhaps accelerate, given the fiscal and monetary policy that is in place. So it is not where we
are; it is where we are going that matters importantly as we consider our choices. I am not
suggesting here that we tighten or exit where we are from a current easing policy, but only that
we, as President Lacker said, stop increasing our purchases or increasing our easing process and
back off in that because we can’t exit until we complete our entry into this, and I think it’s time
to complete that. We may not see inflation or asset bubbles now. I think that is clear. But the

August 11–12, 2009

140 of 165

more we pump into this balloon, the larger it will eventually be and the more difficult it will be
to bring back down. And that is what I think we need to begin to think about if we are, in fact,
recovering.
So my view is that we begin to signal that we are. I think that is perhaps what alternative
B (revised) does. Although I would like to see us begin tapering immediately, I would be in
favor of that alternative and that, as soon as possible, we stop purchasing assets and turn to the
TAF and the primary credit facility as means of providing liquidity into the intermediation
process or the banking industry and allow our economy to move more toward normality. So my
immediate goal is to cease purchasing assets and cease growing our balance sheet or allow our
balance sheet to begin to shrink normally. But the reality is that I think alternative B (revised) is
the reasonable place to be at this point. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, support alternative B as revised. Let
me confine my remarks to the asset-purchase discussion in that alternative. First, with respect to
the Treasury purchases, I think that the Treasury purchase experiment has been a testament to the
strengths of this institution. I think we have had differences of opinion going back to discussions
of last December on the merits of this program. We debated it, we all marshaled our arguments,
and we all decided at least publicly to support this experiment. I think the stars have given us an
opportunity to deftly exit the Treasury purchases. Alternative B as revised gives us the
flexibility, if circumstances warrant, to hold hands yet again, but I’d consider the prospects of
that to be quite unlikely. The data of the intermeeting months on the Treasury purchases,
particularly given the question of fiscal sustainability coming from the other branch of
government, have made this particularly problematic for us to undertake successfully. I do think

August 11–12, 2009

141 of 165

the benefits have been outweighed by the costs, but we do have an opportunity to end it in way
that lives up to the commitment that we made some months ago but doesn’t go beyond that. I
think alternative B as revised also does provide that flexibility should the situation change.
On the tapering question that President Evans raised, my own sense is that it would not
be necessary, if we had only Treasuries as part of our asset purchase, to go with the tapering.
Even out of an abundance of caution I don’t think that it would be necessary. The reason that I
suspect it’s a prudent move for us now is that it will be a signal to markets that, when we do
undertake the mortgage-backed security discussion probably at our next meeting, they will have
seen some bread crumbs as to how we could think about exiting or at least about cutting back on
these. So all in all, I would favor the tapering approach, not because of Treasuries but because of
the signaling effect on MBS.
On the mortgage-backed securities, as President Yellen suggested, I think that we should
take advantage of the option value and defer our discussion on that. I would be interested in
staff’s thoughts in advance of that meeting as to what the net benefits are of our continued
presence in that market. So while I do think there were marginal benefits, maybe even
meaningful benefits, at the beginning of the MBS program, we are well past the point of
diminishing returns on that. I look forward to a broader discussion come September.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Given my pessimism about credit availability
and concern about the likelihood of alternative scenarios, I started thinking about, well, if they
came to pass, what policy action might we take. My thoughts are probably further colored by the
time that I have spent with the TALF and with the staff working on the TALF. But as I look at

August 11–12, 2009

142 of 165

the experience with the commercial paper facilities and the ABS markets, I do see signs that the
markets outside of our purchases have improved.
Then as we looked at the RMBS for the TALF, it became clear that the problems in the
private mortgage market were probably beyond our tools to repair. So although we have talked
about a lot of market improvement, the only mortgage market now and for the foreseeable future
is the government-supported market. And I see the very likely need to support the mortgage
market at least through visibility of how the GSEs might be resolved and perhaps even through
that transition, and I hope that we would see some signs of how the private mortgage market
might actually reemerge before we withdraw support to that market.
So the MBS purchases in relation to the total outstanding and the originations right now
are large, but it seems quite likely to me that we will need to extend the support, at least in time
if not in total, well past March 2010. I don’t see a similar need to expand Treasury purchases,
and the tapering certainly prepares the way for a much bigger tapering job ahead with the MBS
purchases. But I think we really do need to look at what we might need to do longer term on the
mortgage market and when we announce what we are going to do on that. And I do support
alternative B (revised).
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. I support alternative B (revised) for a lot of the reasons a lot of you
have stated to this point.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First I want to make two
brief comments, one on the dry tinder concept that we brought up at the last meeting and the
other one on potential changes in the NAIRU. The reason I want to bring these up is that I think

August 11–12, 2009

143 of 165

they are both relevant in terms of our communication strategy and our ability, by consistent
messaging, to keep inflation expectations well anchored. If we do not speak with a relatively
consistent voice, I think we run risks in that dimension.
The last time the view was expressed that excess reserves sitting on banks’ balance sheets
are essentially dry tinder that could quickly fuel excessive credit creation and put the Fed behind
the curve in terms of tightening monetary policy. I have to admit that, in terms of imagery, this
concern does seem compelling. The banks are sitting on piles of money that could be used to
extend credit on a moment’s notice. However, I think this reasoning ignores a very, very
important point. Based on how monetary policies have been conducted for the past several
decades, banks have always had the ability to expand credit whenever they like. They don’t need
a pile of dry tinder in the form of excess reserves to do so. That’s because the Fed has
committed itself to supply sufficient reserves to keep the federal funds rate at its target. If banks
want to expand credit and that drives up the demand for reserves, the Fed automatically meets
that demand in its conduct of monetary policy. So in terms of the ability of banks to expand
credit rapidly, it makes no difference whether they have lots of excess reserves or not. I think it
is an important point.
In terms of the NAIRU, there has been some discussion that the NAIRU may have moved
up. I certainly do not dispute that idea and its implications. But I think there is an implication
that is sort of implied by some that this might be a reason to exit from our current stance of
monetary policy somewhat earlier than otherwise. I think we need to be careful about
exaggerating the potential import of the possibility of a somewhat higher NAIRU. The key
question in a world where the unemployment rate is currently 9.4 percent and likely to rise
higher is how much the NAIRU has increased. To get an idea of what might be in the feasible

August 11–12, 2009

144 of 165

set of outcomes, we looked at the CBO’s estimates of the NAIRU, which extend back 55 years.
I am not saying that the CBO’s estimates of the NAIRU are perfect, but they are an interesting
starting point. We found that the largest three-year increase in their estimate of the NAIRU over
this 55-year period was 0.3 percentage point, and at its highest point in this fifty-five-year
history, the NAIRU was still below 6½ percent.
So what do I make of this? Well, it implies to me that, even if one thinks that the NAIRU
has increased, it is implausible to think that it has increased sufficiently to change the story
meaningfully over the next couple of years. We have a large output gap that is going to take a
long time to close. Thus, arguing that the NAIRU may be higher is likely just to confuse market
participants about the issue at hand unless we can credibly claim that the NAIRU has increased
so much that we are going to hit this very, very quickly. I do not think that claim is plausible.
So I would be counseling people not to make this argument because it is going to confuse people
about how quickly we are going to exit from our monetary policy regime.
With respect to the statement, I favor alternative B as revised. I think the case for
expanding Treasury securities is very weak—first, given the improvement in financial conditions
and the economic outlook. When we did this in March, it was with considerable reluctance, I
think, but it was because the outlook was really quite grim, and the outlook has improved
significantly since then. Second, there are lots of uncertainties about what this would mean for
inflation expectations, and that is the part of the Treasury purchase program that was always
wrought with some peril, and we found out that there was really some risk associated with that in
terms of that dimension. Third, market participants do not expect us to expand it. So I think that
we should stick with alternative B as revised, where we basically say we’re bringing it to an end
with the taper. I think Governor Warsh is absolutely correct that the tapering is not necessary for

August 11–12, 2009

145 of 165

Treasuries but it is a good signaling device to imply what we are likely to do with the other
programs.
Financial conditions have improved considerably since the last meeting. I think that is
important. It means that abstracting from other factors, such as the GDP revisions, the optimal
unconstrained funds rate is considerably less negative now than it was at the last meeting. But it
still remains below the zero bound by most measures at a relatively high degree of confidence.
That suggests to me that a steady-as-she-goes policy for the time being is the right one. That
means keeping the pre-commitment of an extended period in place and completing the purchase
programs that we had committed to earlier. I have a strong presumption that, as we go forward,
we are going to finish the agency MBS program. On the agency debt program, I am sort of
agnostic. I don’t think it is really that important whether we stop at $150 billion or we go all the
way to $200 billion. But with the agency MBS program, the market has a strong presumption
that we are going to do the whole thing, and I would hope at the next meeting, assuming that we
are still on the same economic trajectory that we think we are going to be on, that we would
commit to doing the whole thing at that meeting. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Thank you all. If you recall last March where
we were and our concerns about both the financial system and the economy, we were extremely
aggressive; and whether by dumb luck or prescience or whatever, we seem to have hit the sweet
spot. The economy is improving. The financial markets are improving, and I see little reason to
increase stimulus at this point. At the same time, obviously there is still a lot of uncertainty
about consumption, final demand, and the strength of recovery, and I think I agree with the Vice
Chairman that, by any reasonable calculation at least at this point, there still is a considerable
amount of excess capacity in the economy. So on that basis there is not much case either for

August 11–12, 2009

146 of 165

pulling back on stimulus. At the risk of sounding Nixonian, I think we should stay the course on
our policy and continue along the lines we have been following since March.
I would agree with the majority of the participants in proposing that we go with the
revised version of alternative B. There was little discussion this time of the descriptive
paragraphs, maybe again because we hit the sweet spot—I do not know—but the output
description in particular is a little more upbeat and, I think, conveys the sense that there has been
noticeable improvement even though there are still some important barriers to full recovery.
I think that there is considerable agreement around the table that we should allow the
Treasury program to expire as previously signaled. I think the revised version of alternative B
will be read primarily as saying that the FOMC is allowing this program to expire. There is a bit
of flexibility in the sense that we do not completely rule out a future program, and as Governor
Kohn has pointed out, there could be contingencies in which we might want to consider a future
program. But I think it will be read mostly as just a bit of prudence on the part of the Committee
to leave that potential option open for the future. Again, I think the primary signal will be that
the program is being allowed to expire.
I agree with the Vice Chairman that the tapering aspect is useful as a signal. It is going to
essentially provide a bit of foreshadowing to the markets about how we may exit from the larger
agency program. We discussed today and I gave a lot of thought to announcing a tapering of the
agency programs today as well. I found it very difficult to write that in a way that didn’t sound
as though we were conclusively ending those programs or going to the full extent. What I would
propose—along the lines of President Stern’s parting advice, which is always wise—is to do no
harm. I propose that we have at the next meeting a robust discussion of exactly how we want to
exit or proceed with the agency MBS program. And long the lines of what President Bullard

August 11–12, 2009

147 of 165

said, one possibility would be to extend it—to reduce the rate of purchase and extend it out. It
might be more effective in the sense that we would not be dominating the market as much but
maybe have a longer horizon.
Those are the kinds of issues that I think we ought to talk about in the next meeting. On
that basis, I think it is a bit wiser to leave the status quo on the agencies for this meeting, and that
is also consistent with Brian Sack’s memo, which suggests that we do not yet have to begin the
tapering process in the agency markets. So my recommendation would be that we allow the
Treasury program to expire and that we adopt the revised version of alternative B. And before
we go further, let me just turn to Brian Madigan for a moment because there was an issue he
would like to highlight on the directive related to B.
MR. MADIGAN. Yes, Mr. Chairman. I wanted to note two things for the Committee on
the directive for B, which is on page 60 of the Bluebook. First of all, of course, the directive
would indicate now that the Desk is expected to purchase about $300 billion of Treasury
securities rather than “up to,” and it includes language indicating that the Desk is to gradually
slow the pace of purchases. The other point I want to make is that the following sentence is a
little modified from the corresponding version in the previous directive. The previous directive
and the past few directives have indicated that the Committee anticipates that the combination of
outright purchases and various liquidity facilities outstanding will cause the size of the Fed’s
balance sheet to expand significantly in coming months. With the liquidity facilities coming
down pretty significantly, I think that it doesn’t make sense to continue to describe them as
causing an increase in the balance sheet. So we have suggested deleting the reference in that
sentence to the liquidity facilities.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Question?

August 11–12, 2009

148 of 165

MR. LACKER. Do we anticipate our purchases to expand the balance sheet significantly
in coming months in view of recent history?
MR. MADIGAN. Well, certainly we expect the purchases to continue to add to the
balance sheet. That is laid out in our projections in the Bluebook.
MR. LACKER. Haven’t we missed on our liquidity facility forecast?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. As you point out, President Lacker, we are getting close to
the zero bound on that side. So it looks like a good bet that we will continue to see an increase in
the overall balance.
MR. LACKER. So is it in the intermeeting period? In the intermeeting period do we
expect to drive this down to zero and on that basis? Is that why we are expecting the balance
sheet to expand?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Brian, do you have a reply?
MR. MADIGAN. This is the monetary base that I am referring to, but as shown on
page 51 of the Bluebook, our baseline projections show growth of 97 percent in August, 116
percent in September, and 60 percent in October. So there is still pretty significant growth
overall.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any other questions or comments? Yes.
MR. LACKER. Excuse me, I just want to be clear about the question. You have
described the forecasting procedure that goes program by program and neglects any
consideration of the demand for reserves. And we keep missing on that basis in a way that
suggests that the demand for reserves is driving demand for liquidity facilities, not the other way
around. So I just raise the question. That is why I was asking. Mr. Chairman, you called for a
robust discussion next meeting of the MBS program; I think that is great. This consideration,

August 11–12, 2009

149 of 165

which we have been discussing, deserves some attention there, too. What staff work could be
done on that might be useful as well.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, the staff will look at that. I think it is an interesting
question, how much is pure substitution and how much the general improvements in markets are
changing demand as well. Any other questions or comments either for me or for Brian? Seeing
none, Debbie, would you call the roll?
MS. DANKER. Yes. This vote encompasses the language of alternative B (revised) for
the August FOMC statement and the directive from page 60 of the Bluebook.
Chairman Bernanke
Vice Chairman Dudley
Governor Duke
President Evans
Governor Kohn
President Lacker
President Lockhart
Governor Tarullo
Governor Warsh
President Yellen

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. The next meeting is Tuesday and
Wednesday, September 22 and 23. There is a buffet lunch available. There will be no further
business or presentations. So if you are able to stay, please do, and I guess we will be seeing
each other next in Jackson Hole. Thank you very much. The meeting is adjourned.
END OF MEETING