View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held
in the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System in Washington, D. C., on Tuesday, April 29, 1969, at
9:30 a.m.
PRESENT:

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

Martin, Chairman
Hayes, Vice Chairman
Bopp
Brimmer
Clay
Coldwell
Daane
Maisel
Mitchell
Robertson
Scanlon

Messrs. Francis, Heflin, Hickman, and Swan,
Alternate Members of the Federal Open
Market Committee
Messrs. Morris, Kimbrel, and Galusha,
Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks
of Boston, Atlanta, and Minneapolis,
respectively
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Broida, Deputy Secretary
Messrs. Kenyon and Molony, Assistant
Secretaries
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Brill, Economist
Messrs. Axilrod, Baughman, Eastburn, Green,
Hersey, Partee, Solomon, and Tow,
Associate Economists
Mr. Coombs, Special Manager, System Open
Market Account

4/29/69

-2Mr. Sherman, Consultant, Board of Governors
Messrs. Coyne and Nichols, Special Assistants
to the Board of Governors
Mr. Wernick, Associate Adviser, Division
of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Mr. Keir, Assistant Adviser, Division
of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Mr. Bernard, Special Assistant, Office
of the Secretary, Board of Governors
Miss Eaton, Open Market Secretariat
Assistant, Office of the Secretary,
Board of Governors
Messrs. Taylor, Jones, and Craven, Senior
Vice Presidents of the Federal Reserve
Banks of Atlanta, St. Louis, and San
Francisco, respectively
Messrs. Eisenmenger, Sternlight, and
Snellings, Vice Presidents of the
Federal Reserve Banks of Boston,
New York, and Richmond, respectively
Mr. Davis, Adviser, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York
Messrs. Geng and Shotwell, Assistant
Vice Presidents of the Federal Reserve
Banks of New York and Cleveland,
respectively
Mr. Kareken, Economic Adviser, Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
By unanimous vote, the minutes
of actions taken at the meeting of the
Federal Open Market Committee held on
April 1, 1969, were approved.
The memorandum of discussion for
the meeting of the Federal Open Market
Committee held on April 1, 1969, was
accepted.

4/29/69

-3
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the

members of the Committee a report from the Special Manager of the
System Open Market Account on foreign exchange market conditions
and on Open Market Account and Treasury operations in foreign
currencies for the period April 1 through 23, 1969, and a supple
mental report covering the period April 24 through 28, 1969.
Copies of these reports have been placed in the files of the
Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Coombs
said the Treasury gold stock remained unchanged and gold holdings
of the Stabilization Fund had now risen to nearly $570 million as
a result of purchases of another $100 million from the Bank of
France.

In London and Zurich, the free market price of gold had

fluctuated somewhat above $43--today it was $43.55--with buying
pressure from France being offset by continuing South African
sales.

He estimated that such sales by South Africa during the

first quarter of the year might have come to roughly $100 million,
about one third of current output.
On the exchange markets, Mr. Coombs observed, the French
franc had been weak throughout the month and France's total reserve
losses had approached $600 million.

The French trade figures for

March showed a further deterioration and the capital flight

4/29/69

-4

continued despite the controls.

Against that background, there

was considerable concern both here and abroad that the resignation
of the French government after defeat in the referendum last
Sunday might set off a new wave of speculation on a devaluation
of the franc, possibly in conjunction with parity changes in the
mark and other currencies.

Fortunately, however, the market

reaction so far had been relatively mild.

Yesterday, the Bank of

France lost roughly $75 million, but today it was holding even.
It might be that the results of the referendum had already been
rather fully reflected in reserve losses earlier in the month.
Today there also seemed to be some feeling in the market that
the caretaker government headed by Couve de Murville would find
it difficult, if not impossible, to change the parity, thus
giving the market another month or six weeks in which to hedge.
More generally, the retirement of General de Gaulle might have
relieved earlier fears of a breakdown in international financial
cooperation and revived hopes for an orderly, gradual solution
of the French financial problem.

But the present situation was

extremely fragile and could easily give way to renewed speculation
from one day to another.
There also had been much concern that speculation on the
franc might have serious side effects on sterling, Mr. Coombs
continued.

The sterling rate in fact plummeted by roughly 50

-5

4/29/69

points at the opening on Monday but it subsequently recovered
strongly and was holding around $2.3880 today.

Last-minute

buying by oil companies with royalty payments to make, together
with month-end positioning, helped considerably to turn the
situation around yesterday, and today sterling was benefiting
from the easing of pressures on the franc.
More generally, Mr. Coombs said, sterling had continued
to profit from the heavy seasonal earnings of the overseas
sterling area countries.

During the first quarter, for example,

the Bank of England took in roughly $700 million, most of which
was devoted to debt repayment.

But during the same period the

overseas sterling area countries, taking advantage of the
dollar guarantee given by the British government last September,
increased their balances in London by $450 million.

Since the

British had drawn on the Bank for International Settlements under
the Second Sterling Balance Arrangement to finance earlier
liquidation of the sterling balances, they now had to repay $450
million to the BIS before the end of June.

In effect, much of

the dollar intake of the Bank of England since the turn of the
year had represented a substitution of new debt for old.

The

favorable seasonal influences normally ran their course during
May and during the second half of this year the British would
face the dual problem of an adverse seasonal trade pattern and
very heavy debt amortization.

4/29/69
Mr. Coombs noted that the mark had risen sharply since
the French referendum and during the past two days the German
Federal Bank had had gross inflows of roughly $260 million.
The Federal Bank had recycled the bulk of the inflows to the
Euro-dollar market by providing special swap facilities.

He

had the impression that there was a general swing of opinion in
Germany in favor of a mark revaluation as the only practicable
However, there was continuing insistence at the

way out.

official level that such a revaluation would have to be
accompanied by changes in several other currency parities and,
in any event, could not be undertaken until after the September
elections.
Thus, Mr. Coombs commented, a curious situation existed
in the exchange markets at present.

It was generally assumed

that the mark would eventually have to be revalued and the French
franc devalued, with a major question mark hanging over sterling.
At the same time, it was still accepted that the mark parity
would remain unchanged until next fall and that no action would
be taken on the French franc for another month or six weeks.
That paradoxical situation was unlikely to last very long; the
first signal of a shift in official intentions regarding the
parity relationships of the mark and franc could set off another
massive wave of hedging such as had occurred last November.

In

-7

4/29/69

the interim there was little that central banks could do except
to honor their commitments while awaiting political developments.
It was to be hoped that issues relating to international financial
matters would be dealt with discreetly in the coming French
election campaign.
By unanimous vote, the System
open market transactions in foreign
currencies during the period April 1
through 28, 1969, were approved,
ratified, and confirmed.
Chairman Martin then invited Mr. Daane to report to the
Committee on developments at the April Basle meeting.
Mr. Daane remarked that the discussion at the Governors'
sessions in the afternoon and evening of April 13 had focused
primarily on developments in the Euro-dollar market.

The

Governors were unanimously of the view that the restrictive stance
of U. S. monetary policy, while the source of the difficulties
in the Euro-dollar market, was both necessary and desirable.

At

the same time, considerable concern was expressed about interest
rate developments and about the defensive measures that had been
required in some countries, and several of the Governors raised
the question of whether there were any actions the System could
take to alleviate the situation.
were still mixed.

However, attitudes on the matter

The Belgians were the most vocal in expressing

concern; evidently the Euro-dollar situation posed a problem with

-8

4/29/69

respect to their domestic budgetary financing.

Others, including

the Germans, indicated that Euro-dollar developments had been
helpful domestically in facilitating moves in the direction of
monetary restraint.
Mr. Daane added that the matter had been discussed further
at the meeting of Working Party 3 in Paris this past week.

He

understood that Mr. Solomon would comment on that meeting later
today.
In response to an inquiry by the Chairman, Mr. Coombs
remarked that his recommendations were confined to those contained
in his memorandum of April 22, 1969, entitled "Renewal of swap

1/
drawings by the Bank of England and the Bank of France."
In brief, he recommended renewal of a number of drawings by those
Banks that would mature soon, if requested by the other party.
The drawings in question were listed in the table on the first
page of the memorandum; they consisted of seven by the Bank of
England, totaling $800 million and maturing in the period May 20
2/
June 4, 1969,
and four by the Bank of France, totaling $281
million and maturing May 19-20.

1/ A related background memorandum by the Board's staff,
entitled "Bank of England and Bank of France swap debt to the
Federal Reserve System," was distributed on April 23, 1969.
Copies of both memoranda have been placed in the Committee's files.
2/
As a result of an error in transcription, the last of the
seven Bank of England drawings referred to--a $50 million drawing
maturing June 4, 1969--was incorrectly shown twice in the table.

-9-

4/29/69

As indicated in his memorandum, Mr. Coombs continued, the
swap line with the Bank of England had been in continuous use
since July 1, 1968 and that with the Bank of France since June 5,
1968.

Accordingly, renewal of the drawings for further three

month periods would require special authorization by the Committee,
under the provisions of paragraph 1D of the authorization for System
foreign currency operations.

That paragraph, Mr. Coombs said,

provided that the swap lines should be fully liquidated after
one year of continuous use unless the Committee, because of
exceptional circumstances, specifically authorized a delay.
It was highly unlikely that the British would experience
an inflow of dollars that would enable them to repay all outstand
ing drawings by June 30, Mr. Coombs remarked.

Moreover, on the

basis of discreet inquiries he had concluded that there was no
possiblity of repayment through funding operations under which
the U. S. Treasury, the IMF, or foreign central banks would take
over the British debts to the System.

Accordingly, he thought

there was no practicable alternative to renewal of the drawings.
There was some possibility that the Bank of France would be able
to repay its drawings in May and June with funds borrowed from
other central banks under the credits arranged at the Bonn
conference in November 1968.

Whether or not that proved feasible

-10

4/29/69

would depend on developments; the chances would be reduced if
there were a new wave of speculation against the franc during
the coming election campaign.
Mr. Coombs then said he might add some comments on a
point not covered in his memorandum of April 22.

The language

of paragraph 1D of the foreign currency authorization was
originally adopted by the Committee in May 1963 in an amendment
to a predecessor instrument--the "Guidelines" for System foreign
currency operations.

At the time of that action Mr. Shepardson

had expressed concern about a process he had described as
"leapfrogging"--under which a party to a swap arrangement would
make new drawings for the purpose of repaying earlier drawingswith the result that credits under the swap line could in fact
be of a medium-term rather than of a short-term nature.

He

(Mr. Coombs) thought that neither the Bank of England nor the
Bank of France could be charged with "leapfrogging" operations
if they requested renewal of the present drawings, since there
had been two separate waves of speculation against both the pound
and the franc--the first in late spring and early summer of 1968,
and the second at the time of the November crisis.
Mr. Robertson said he concurred in Mr. Coombs' recommen
dations.

The need to renew the British drawings was clear,

since no alternative means of financing were available to them.

-11

4/29/69

The French did have the alternative of drawing on the IMF, but in
view of the existing political situation in France he thought
it would be unrealistic to press them to take that step at the
moment.

At the same time, he thought it would be desirable to

discuss with the U. S. Treasury the general question of the
appropriate roles of the System and the Treasury in connection
with central bank debts that were running on for longer terms.
In response to a question by Mr. Mitchell, Mr. Solomon
noted that details of French use of their swap line with the
System were contained in Appendix V to the Board staff's memo
randum.

Briefly, from June through September 1968 the French

had drawn a total of $450 million.

They had repaid $75 million

in October, drawn $196 million in November, and repaid $278
million in December and January.

Subsequently, they had drawn

$168 million in February and March and repaid $25 million thus
far in April.
Mr. Solomon then observed that the pattern of alternating
drawings and repayments did not imply an intent on the part of
the Bank of France to engage in leapfrogging operations.

There

had been no requirement for the French to make repayments in
September, December, and January, since their total drawings had
remained well within the leeway allowed under the swap arrange
ment.

It seemed clear that they should not be penalized as a

consequence of those repayments.

-12

4/29/69

Mr. Mitchell remarked that he was prepared to approve
Mr. Coombs' recommendation on the British drawings.

However, he

did not think the French should be permitted to draw continuously
on the swap line for more than a year.

The System found itself

in an unfortunate situation with respect to the British as a
result of an unduly tolerant attitude earlier, and he would not
want to repeat that mistake in the case of the French.
Mr. Coldwell commented that he was concerned about the
System's continuing exposure in connection with large credits
to the British.

If the Committee were to make an exception to

the one-year rule at this time it might be desirable to do so
only on the condition that any further renewals by the British
would come under close surveillance, to be maintained as long
as the line was in continuous use for more than a year.

His

concern focused not so much on the question of leapfrogging as
on the fact that the swap lines were intended to offer short-run
accommodation for dealing with reversible market situations.
The staff memorandum noted that a large volume of individual
British drawings would have been outstanding for a full year in
November 1969.

Since it was quite possible that the British

would again be requesting large renewals then, he thought it
particularly important to consider whether a condition should be
attached to any present renewals.

4/29/69

-13
Mr. Daane said he concurred in Mr. Coombs' view that

there was no practicable alternative to renewing the swap
drawings in question, and he did not think any useful purpose
would be served by attaching conditions in the case of the
British.

He added that, as Mr. Coombs' memorandum noted, the

British might soon make a new drawing on the IMF and use part
of the proceeds to pay down their debt to the System.
Mr. Mitchell observed that it might be desirable for
the Committee to face up to the fact that the British debt
represented a frozen asset, and agree to fund it by increasing
System holdings of guaranteed sterling.
Mr. Coombs responded that in his judgment it would be
less desirable to fund the debt by that means than to renew it
on a short-term basis.

As to Mr. Coldwell's suggestion, he

(Mr. Coombs) thought a case could be made under particular
circumstances for attaching conditions to use of swap lines;
indeed, he had offered a similar suggestion last May in connec
tion with the British swap line.

However, he thought there was

less to be gained by such a course under the circumstances of
the moment than at times in the past.
Chairman Martin observed that in a recent lengthy
discussion with the Managing Director of the Fund he had learned
that the IMF was putting a substantial amount of pressure on

-14

4/29/69
the British.

He (the Chairman) thought the Fund was an

appropriate source of such pressure, and that additional
pressure from the System at this time would serve little
purpose.
Mr. Hickman commented that he would favor the course
Mr. Robertson had recommended--namely, agreeing to renewal of
the drawings in question on the understanding that discussions
would be undertaken with the U. S. Treasury about possibilities
for funding the French and British swap debts to the System.
Mr. Brimmer asked whether the possibility of an inter
mediate course was not implied by the Board staff's memorandum.
He had in mind the passage which read as follows:
"Although the British swap line will have been in
continuous use for one year on July 1, 1969, the
first drawing presently outstanding to reach its one
year limit is a $50 million drawing which will be
one year old on September 4, 1969. Another $50
million drawing will be one year old on September 9,
1969. If the British can acquire the $100 million
to repay these drawings on their first anniversary,
then their problem of acquiring funds to reverse the
remaining outstanding drawings will be deferred
until late November 1969, when $750 million of
drawings reaches the one-year limit."
If possible, Mr. Brimmer continued, it would be desirable,
in his judgment, to maintain the one-year limit while buying time
for discussions with the Treasury with respect to procedures for
the longer run.

He personally would attach great weight to the

-15

4/29/69

desirability of avoiding continuous use of the swap lines for
more than a year.

And, as he had indicated on a number of

occasions recently, he had hoped that discussions with the
Treasury would be in process by this time.
Mr. Coombs observed that he had held some discussions
of the matter with Treasury officials, but with little result.
He added that the "intermediate course" to which Mr. Brimmer
had referred would not relieve the Committee of the necessity for
deciding today whether there were special circumstances that
warranted authorizing renewal of the French and British drawings
that would mature shortly, since further three-month periods
for those drawings would mean that the respective swap lines
would be in continuous use for more than a year.

He could not

forecast the situation that would be prevailing in November;
while he hoped that no individual swap drawings would remain
outstanding for more than a year, he was not optimistic about
the British case in view of the heavy debt repayments they
faced.
Mr. Brimmer said the basis for his earlier comments was
his belief that the System should indicate somewhat greater
reluctance to renew the swap drawings in question at this time.
Mr. Daane observed that he did not share Mr. Brimmer's
view; as Chairman Martin had indicated, the IMF already was

4/29/69

-16

placing a good deal of pressure on the British.

He agreed that

it would be desirable to continue discussions with the Treasury,
although he did not think the prospects were good that the
Treasury would be prepared to take over the British debts in
the near future.
Mr. Brimmer then suggested that it would be helpful to
have the views of the Board's staff.
Mr. Solomon observed that the position the Board's staff
had taken in its memorandum was not essentially different from
that of Mr. Coombs.

He (Mr. Solomon) thought the Committee could

justify permitting the two swap lines in question to remain in
continuous use for more than a year on the grounds that exceptional
circumstances made it desirable to interpret the one-year limit
in the present instances as applying to individual swap drawings.
He certainly agreed with Mr.

Coombs that when individual British

drawings reached the end of one-year terms next November the
British might not be in a position to repay them.

However,

the

Committee did not have to decide today what course of action it
would follow in November if that should prove to be the case.
Chairman Martin said he thought that there was no
practicable alternative to renewing the maturing swap drawings,
but that, as Mr. Robertson had suggested, discussions should be
pursued with the Treasury.

-17

4/29/69

Mr. Hayes commented that he shared the views expressed
by Chairman Martin and Mr. Daane.
Mr. Coldwell asked whether the Committee would not be
making a change in policy if it abrogated the one-year rule.
Chairman Martin remarked that the Committee clearly had
no alternative to authorizing renewal of the drawings in question
unless it were prepared to turn its back on the other parties
involved.
Mr. Hayes said he did not think the Committee would be
abandoning its general position regarding the short-term character
of swap drawings; rather it would be making an exception to the
one-year rule in light of special circumstances.
Mr. Coombs noted that paragraph 1D of the foreign currency
authorization specifically provided for delays beyond one year
in liquidating drawings on swap lines when the Committee thought
exceptional circumstances justified such a course.
Mr. Mitchell commented that he planned to vote against
authorizing renewal of the maturing swap drawings by the Bank of
France, and thus permit their continuous use of the swap line for
more than one year.

As he had indicated earlier, he thought the

System had followed a mistaken course in connection with drawings
by the Bank of England, and he wanted the record to show that he

-18

4/29/69

opposed a repetition of that mistake in connection with French
drawings.

One possible alternative course--noted in the staff

memorandum in connection with the British debt to the Systemwould be to ask the Congress for an appropriation that would
permit the Treasury to refund such debts on a long-term basis.
Mr. Brimmer said he planned to vote against authorizing
renewal of the maturing drawings by both the Banks of England
and France.

In his judgment there was a practicable alternative

to renewal--to have the Treasury take over the British and
French debts to the System.
After Mr. Solomon noted that Mr. Brimmer's statement
seemed inconsistent with the latter's earlier suggestion that
an intermediate course be followed, Mr. Brimmer remarked that
on further thought he had modified his position.

At some point

the System had to call a halt and turn to the Treasury.
Mr. Maisel remarked that he was inclined to agree with
Mr. Brimmer on the principle at issue; indeed, on earlier occa
sions he had advanced a related argument to the effect that the
Treasury should be asked to take the responsibility, either
directly or by requesting Congressional action, when swap
drawings became intermediate-term credit.

Having failed to

persuade the Committee on those occasions, however, he was
prepared to vote favorably on Mr. Coombs' recommendation today.

-19

4/29/69

Mr. Coldwell observed that while he planned to vote
favorably on the recommendations he would do so with reluctance
in view of his concern with the System's exposure.
With Messrs. Brimmer and
Mitchell dissenting, renewal for
further periods of three months,
if requested, of the four swap
drawings by the Bank of France
maturing in the period May 19-20,
1969, and totaling $281 million,
was authorized.
With Mr. Brimmer dissenting,
renewal for further periods of
three months, if requested, of
the seven swap drawings by the
Bank of England maturing in the
period May 20-June 4, 1969, and
totaling $800 million, was
authorized.
Chairman Martin then remarked that he would say a few
words about the annual meeting in Williamsburg of the Governors
of Central Banks of the Western Hemisphere that had begun with
a dinner on Saturday (April 26).

On the whole, he thought the

meeting had been successful and quite worthwhile.

He was

particularly pleased that three Reserve Bank Presidents--Messrs.
Coldwell, Hayes, and Heflin--had been able to be present at the
opening dinner, as well as all members of the Board except
Mr. Daane, who was abroad.

Mr. Heflin had been helpful in con

nection with the arrangements for the meeting.

His own function

-20

4/29/69

as Chairman had been made particularly pleasant by the willing
ness of participants to enter into the discussions.

There was

a marked difference in that respect from the first such meeting
held a number of years ago in Antigua--a difference which was
attributable in good part to Mr. Mitchell's enthusiastic ap
proach to the project.
The Chairman then said that he wanted to thank all of
the System people who had helped make the meeting a success.

He

knew that their efforts had been appreciated by all participants.
Mr. Hayes added that he thought Mr. Martin should be
commended for the effective manner in which he had chaired the
meeting.
Before this meeting there had been distributed to the
members of the Committee a report from the Manager of the System
Open Market Account covering domestic open market operations for
the period April 1 through 23, 1969, and a supplemental report
covering April 24 through 28, 1969.

Copies of both reports have

been placed in the files of the Committee.
In supplementation of the written reports, Mr. Sternlight
commented as follows:

Financial markets in the past several weeks have
experienced a somewhat unusual aftermath to the further

restrictive steps announced by the System near the begin
ning of the interval--namely, the one-half percentage

4/29/69

-21-

point increases in discount rates and in reserve re
quirements against demand deposits.
In contemplating
appropriate open market operations to accompany these
moves, there seemed to be a fairly widespread feeling
in early April that such operations might have to
"cushion the blow" somewhat so that markets would not
be jolted too severely. One widely read market
commentary headlined its report on these actions as
the "end of gradualism" and many observers shared this
sentiment.
In fact, however, the market's reaction to the
System's overt moves was notably mild--so much so that
open market operations, in order to preserve and under
score the intended tone of restraint in the market,
shaded toward the firmer side with respect to day-to
day conditions. This tendency was reinforced as the
period went along, as increasing evidence became
available of stronger-than-expected growth in bank
credit. Given the volatility of recent month-to-month
changes in total member bank deposits--the credit
proxy--the proviso clause of the April 1 directive was
activated only marginally and tentatively at first.
But as additional weekly data confirmed the evidence
of excessive growth--even after making some allowance
for the effect of certain statistical peculiarities
around the Easter weekend--increasing weight was placed
on the proviso.
The impact of this policy approach was most readily
visible in the day-to-day Federal funds rate. Where the
expectation at the time of the last meeting had been that
funds would range around 7 per cent or somewhat above,
the recent range of effective rates has been 6-3/4 to
7-7/8 per cent--and typically anchored to the high side
of 7 per cent. Funds traded at high rates on a number
of days about midway in the period when a low point in
Treasury cash before the mid-April tax date and System
action to mop up reserves through matched sale-purchase
transactions produced a lopsided distribution of reserves.
But high funds rates have been permitted to return again
in the last few days of the interval, although reserves
have been more evenly distributed, as greater strength
in bank credit has become evident.
The markets in intermediate- and longer-term fixed
income securities have shown surprising strength recently
in the face of more evident determination to proceed with
monetary restraint. One reason for this strength--which
has seen prices on long-term Treasury, municipal, and

4/29/69

-22-

corporate issues rise several points--is the belief that
real progress will be made soon in de-escalating the
Vietnam war. It is a hope we can all share fervently
but one that we cannot comment on knowledgeably. Another
reason for the firm bond markets during the period was
the conviction that because the authorities are now even
more vigorously engaged in combatting inflation, chances
of success are better assured and there is a better
likelihood that interest rates will decline over the
long pull. This also is a difficult factor to appraise,
but I wonder if the adherents to this view are not making
too quick a leap from the strong determination of the
authorities to combat inflation to the achievement of
that objective. It seems to me that in getting from
"here" to "there" there could be some more painful times
ahead for the bond markets.
But at the moment a number
of market participants seem inclined to shrug off these
considerations, some even to the extent of taking
speculative positions in bonds. Others in the market
take a more cautions and restrained view, in some cases
because they feel that high costs of day-to-day financing
could offset the effect of eventual price advances for
longer-term holdings even if interest rates are now at
or near their peaks. To the extent that greater fiscal
restraint is in prospect, there would seem to be better
founded optimism about the future of bond prices, but
here too the prospects seem uncertain as we contemplate
possible suspension of the investment credit on one side
but also a possible reduction in the tax surcharge. The
primary dealers in Treasury securities have followed a
fairly cautious approach thus far and generally have
refrained from building inventories of intermediate- or
longer-term issues, although some may be awaiting the
forthcoming refunding as an opportunity to stock up.
This is the cloudy background against which the
Treasury will announce its financing terms, probably
tomorrow afternoon. The prevalent market expectation
is that the Treasury will offer holders of May and June
maturities an exchange into a note in the 6- to 7-year
area and a shorter-term option in the 15- to 21-month
area. Rates in the range of 6-1/4 to 6-3/8 per cent, or
perhaps a shade higher, appear to be needed. Public
holdings of the May and June issues amount to nearly
$6 billion, so there is an opportunity to achieve some
useful debt extension if the offerings are well received,

4/29/69

-23-

but also a vulnerability to considerable attrition if the
reception is no better than for the last quarterly refund
ing. There has also been some market discussion of the
possibility of pre-refunding the heavy October 1, 1969,
maturity, of which $5.5 billion is held by the public.
The System holds $511 million of the May and June
maturities and $319 million of the October's. If the
Treasury presents a choice of two options, the Account
Management would propose to exchange the System's holdings
about in proportion with anticipated takings by the public.
The market in Treasury bills has been subject to
diverse and offsetting influences in the past several
weeks, and this may well continue in the weeks to come.
Rates rose briefly in the immediate aftermath of the
discount rate and reserve requirement moves, and also
increased in the mid-month tax period when many banks
sold off recent awards of "strip" bills and dealers
faced higher financing costs. But during much of the
period there was persistent investor demand from a
variety of sources that succeeded in erasing all or most
of the rate increase effects just noted. In yesterday's
bidding, average rates of 6.05 and 6.04 per cent for the
3- and 6-month bills, respectively, were down 1 and 9
basis points from four weeks earlier.
Looking ahead, good investor demand for bills may
well continue, bolstered by the prospective reinvestment
of attrition money from the May refunding and prospective
reinvestment of part of the June coupon-issue maturity
and the June tax-bill maturity. On the other side, a
persistence of high Federal funds rates and related
high dealer financing costs could serve to limit the
potential decline in bill rates, although some dip from
current levels could not be ruled out. A decline to
levels that would permit significant creation of new
CD's does not seem likely, however.
Finally, I would like to call to the Committee's
attention the recent formation of an association of
primary dealers in U. S. Government securities. The
purpose of the new association is to promote high stand
ards of conduct in the industry, to serve as a medium
for considering problems of common concern to the dealers,
and to serve as a channel of communication--but not the
exclusive channel--between the primary dealers and the
Treasury and Federal Reserve. The association was

-24

4/29/69

developed at the initiative of the dealers, against a
background of encouragement from the Federal Reserve
and Treasury. At present the association includes 21
of the 22 dealers that are now on the list of those
reporting daily position, trading, and financing
statistics to the System--including all the dealers
with which the Desk has a trading relationship.
Mr. Mitchell referred to the sentence in the first para
1/
graph of the draft directive- which read:

"In the first quarter

of the year bank credit changed little on average and the money
supply grew at a sharply reduced rate, but in early April both
measures increased substantially, partly as a result of temporary
factors."

He recalled that in a discussion of the causes of the

bulge in demand deposits in early April at a meeting of the Board
a few days ago, staff members had suggested that certain temporary
developments over the Easter weekend provided part of the explana
tion.

He asked for Mr. Sternlight's views on the subject.
Mr. Sternlight replied that the developments were so recent

that it was difficult to appraise them with any degree of certainty.
His first impression had been that special and temporary factors
rather fully explained the early-April bulge in demand deposits.
However, the more recent behavior of such deposits had raised the
possibility that something more than temporary influences might
also be at work.

1/ The draft directive submitted by the staff for consideration
by the Committee is appended to this memorandum as Attachment A.

4/29/69

-25
Mr. Mitchell inquired whether such an expansion in bank

deposits was consistent with the Committee's objective of limit
ing growth in bank credit.

His question, he noted, was not

meant as a criticism of recent Desk operations.

He was trying

to determine how likely a self-reversal of the deposit bulge was
considered to be.
Mr. Sternlight replied that if such expansion persisted
it would probably not be consistent with the Committee's objective.
As he had noted in his prepared statement, information concerning
the bulge in deposits had become available only gradually in the
period since the previous meeting.

Early in the month the Desk

had begun to obtain some indications that growth in bank credit
might be more rapid than was expected at the time of the last
meeting.

However, since the deposit series were so volatile--as

evidenced by the swing in the proxy series from a decline at an
annual rate of 6 to 7 per cent in March to an increase of
comparable magnitude in April--the Desk had hesitated to move to
a vigorous implementation of the proviso clause on the basis of
the initial information.

When subsequent evidence tended to

confirm the large size of the April bulge, the proviso was imple
mented more actively.

He still did not have a full explanation

-26

4/29/69

1/
of the bulge, but as noted in the blue book,

the Board staff

expected a reversal in May if the money market conditions pre
vailing recently were maintained.
Mr. Maisel noted that the proviso clause was expressed
in terms of bank credit and not money supply, and that the level
of the bank credit proxy at the end of April currently was
expected to be considerably below the level projected at the
time of the Committee's previous meeting.

Since he thought

the basic issue was whether bank credit was at the level the
Committee had desired, he would not consider a temporary bulge
in private demand deposits to be a particularly relevant
consideration.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that he was trying to establish
whether the deposit increase in early April was a temporary
aberration or likely to be sustained.

1/ The report "Money Market and Reserve Relationsips,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff. The passage
"The sharp average annual rates
referred to read as follows:
of expansion in money supply and the bank credit proxy for April
are not likely to be repeated in May--and some reversal could
develop--given prevailing money market conditions. These
conditions can be taken to comprise a Federal funds rate generally
fluctuating in a 7 - 7-3/4 per cent range, member bank borrowings
$900 million to $1.2 billion, and net borrowed reserves $800
million to $1 billion. The 3-month Treasury bill may fluctuate
in a 5.90 - 6.20 per cent range.... The bank credit proxy
(including Euro-dollars) may decline in May in a 2 - 5 per cent,
annual rate, range."

-27

4/29/69

Mr. Morris observed that a significant portion of the
recent increase in bank credit had taken the form of a rise in
security loans.

He wondered how much was known about that rise

and how long it was likely to last.
Mr. Sternlight replied that part of the rise reflected
an increase in loans to Government securities dealers, who had
been absorbing bank sales of Treasury bills in the period
around the mid-month tax date.

Such loans had been worked down

more recently.
In response to another question by Mr. Mitchell,
Mr. Sternlight indicated that dealer holdings of Treasury coupon
issues had not changed significantly in recent weeks.
Chairman Martin said he wanted to warn the Committee,
as he had at other recent meetings, about the dangers of
relying too heavily on projections and thus succumbing to
"statisticitis."

It was important that members exercise their

own judgment about the outlook in arriving at policy decisions.
Recent history amply demonstrated the risks of treating too
1/
literally projections given in the green book
or blue book.
Mr. Robertson remarked that the statement in the draft
directive indicating the bulge in bank credit and money in
early April was "partly" temporary implied that part was expected

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.

-28

4/29/69
to be permanent.

Since it appeared that the factors underlying

the bulge were not fully understood, he thought a rewording of
the statement would be desirable.
Mr. Holland said the language in the draft directive
reflected the staff's considered judgment that technical factors
were involved in the deposit bulge but that there also were
some demand factors at work.

Preliminary weekly money supply

data reported in the blue book indicated, for example, that a
complete reversal from the early April bulge had not occurred
as of the statement week ending April 23.1/
By unanimous vote, the open
market transactions in Government
securities, agency obligations,
and bankers' acceptances during
the period April 1 through 28, 1969,
were approved, ratified, and con
firmed.
The Chairman then called for the staff economic and
financial reports, supplementing the written reports that had
been distributed prior to the meeting, copies of which have
been placed in the files of the Committee.

1/ The weekly money supply data in the blue book for the period
in question were as follows:
March 26
April 2
9
16
23

$194.6 billion
195.2
"
p 198.0
p 196.4
"
p 196.1
"

-29-

4/29/69

Mr. Brill made the following statement concerning economic
developments:
After vigorous monetary restraint has been in
force for several months, it is only natural to seek
earnestly for some signs that this restraint is begin
ning to bite into the economy. And it is only natural
to be disappointed at the scant evidence of slowing
revealed in the recent and current statistics. Our
inflationary problem is stubborn and persistent. The
pace of advance in real activity, while modest in
terms of the longer-run growth potential of the
economy, is still too rapid for the current balance
of resource availability and demands, and prices
are still rising rapidly.
Nevertheless, there are some grounds for
encouragement in the prospective situation, leading
to a counsel of patience but perseverance in the
application of monetary restraint. As I noted a
moment ago, this encouragement does not stem from
the recent performance of the economy. Private domes
tic final demands soared in the first quarter, and
it was largely a slowing in the inventory build-up,
coupled with the effects of the dock strike on net
exports, that kept growth in total GNP from rebounding
sharply.
The official but still preliminary figures on
first-quarter GNP, released at about mid-month, do
indicate a slight slackening in the rate of real
economic growth, but these estimates were put
together before the March statistics on net exports
and inventories were in hand. Foreign trade data
now available indicate a more rapid unwinding of
dock strike effects than had been anticipated, and
indications are that the net export component of
GNP will have to be revised upward. March inventory
data are still not available. For a variety of
technical reasons, the experts here and at the
Office of Business Economics do not expect much,
if any, upward revision from the preliminary
estimates. Nevertheless, it would not take much
upward adjustment in any of the components to wipe
out what now is shown as a slight decline in the

4/29/69

-30-

pace of real economic activity, and thereby to wipe
out any mild satisfaction we might be led to feel from
the effects of restoring monetary restraint last
winter,
If there is any encouragement in the picture,
it is not in current economic performance so much as
in the few clues we have with respect to prospective
performance of those elements of the economy that
recently have been pressing hardest on resource
availability. The principal element has been business
spending for fixed capital, which has been advancing
at about a 20 per cent annual rate since last fall.
Business plans for capital spending over the balance
of this year must be pretty well jelled by now; the
earlier survey indicating a rise of about 14 per cent,
year over year, is substantially confirmed by the more
recent McGraw-Hill survey. Given the surge in actual
spending in the first quarter, further increases in
spending over the balance of the year should be small;
in real terms, the increases would be negligible.
Moreover, these spending plans were formulated
in an atmosphere of greater confidence about the
availability of financing and prior to the Adminis
tration's request for repeal of the investment tax
credit. The business community may well be taking
monetary policy a bit more seriously now, and if
repeal of the tax credit has any effect on spending
this year, it would likely be to dampen it. With
the effective cost of capital significantly higher,
reflecting both higher borrowing costs and the
proposed change in tax treatment, and with a margin
of excess capacity available in many industriesdespite folklore to the contrary--it seems to me fair
to assume that the tempo of the business investment
boom, a major contributor to recent inflationary
pressures, is going to be much more muted from here
on out.
Turning to another key element, consumer spending,
the rebound in the first quarter was not entirely
unexpected, although it carried somewhat further than
earlier projections. It was not fueled by a surge in
incomes, as was the case a year ago when both personal
and disposable incomes advanced at an annual rate of
over 10 per cent. This past quarter, disposable
income rose at only a 4 per cent rate in nominal

4/29/69

-31-

terms--at a rate of less than 0.5 per cent in terms
of real purchasing power--and maintenance of the rise
in consumption required a significant drop in the
saving rate, down to levels we haven't seen since 1965
before the Vietnam war heated up. Some rebound in
disposable income growth is in prospect, particularly
at mid-year when the Federal pay raise becomes effec
tive. But by and large, with some upcreep in
unemployment for two successive months now, with the
work-week drifting off, with some edging down in the
rate of advance in hourly earnings, and with growth
in employment expected to moderate, increases in
incomes available for spending are likely to be
moderate. And with the saving rate already on the
low side of recent experience, the safest prediction
would seem to be for sustained strength but not
overexuberant growth in consumer demands.
Turning to an area that has been a principal
cause of instability in the past, Government spending,
the fiscal posture for the remainder of this year is
more encouraging now--if the program proposed by the
Administration is carried through by the Congress.
You will recall that, earlier in the year, the
staff was concerned by prospects of the budget on a
national income accounts basis slipping back into
deficit after midyear, given the patterns projected
in the January budget for Government spending and
revenues. But the hold-down on spending increases
now contemplated and the higher revenues projected
to accrue from the faster pace of GNP are expected
to keep the NIA budget in surplus--perhaps in the
order of $6 billion--in the second half of the year.
We have been burned so often in the past by
projections of fiscal moderation that some skepticism
now is understandable. The temper of the Administration
and the Congress suggests, however, that some progress
toward fiscal restraint will indeed be maintained
during these critical quarters, although the impact
may be diluted later in the year by the commitment
to reduce the surcharge at year-end.
Finally, the housing area seems at last to be
performing according to projections, with an initial
surge in starts early in the year followed by two
successive months of large declines. Given maintenance

4/29/69

-32-

of monetary restraint, we see no reason to modify our
expectation of an erratic downtrend in housing
activity and expenditures, not of the 1966 pace or
extent, but still of some significance in terms of the
effect on aggregate demands.
If these prospects for the key elements of
activity are realized, the pace of real growth would
drop further to levels that should dampen the rise in
costs and prices. The cooling-off process would
probably continue to be agonizingly slow, but it would
be a pace that should permit a relatively smooth eco
nomic adjustment.
This seems to me a legitimate target for policy.
Gradualism in policy, however, cannot guarantee a
gradual response from the economy. Somehow, I can't
shake the feeling that the future is likely to be
marked by shifts in the course of the economy as abrupt
as in the past. The weight of combined fiscal and
monetary restraint could, for example, puncture infla
tionary expectations sooner than we now expect, with
significant consequences for the private economy's
spending propensities and the degree of tension in
financial markets. Alternatively, a marked change in
the level of hostilities in Asia--in either directioncould touch off a domestic buying wave and an outburst
on the price front. But the strategy of policy
requires playing the best odds, not the outside chance,
and I think the course we're on is the safest. I hope
the System can stick to it and not be goaded by the
more vociferous market observers or tunnel-vision
analysts into unnecessarily intensifying the degree of
monetary restraint, or seduced into premature relaxa
tion by the faintest sign of economic cooling or
extravagant promises of support on the fiscal front.
Mr. Partee made the following statement regarding financial
developments:
The looseness of the linkages among financial
variables, at least in the short run, was vividly
illustrated by the developments of the past month.
Although the Federal Reserve on April 3 announced what
were generally thought to be important new monetary
actions of a restrictive character, bond markets

4/29/69

-33-

subsequently rallied substantially in price as inves
tors re-entered such markets in volume. And although
money market conditions, as reflected in day-to-day
money rates, funds flows, and member bank borrowings,
have been appreciably tighter during April than
earlier in the year, the banking aggregates have
expanded considerably more this month than was projected
at the Committee's last meeting.
Given these unexpected developments, one may wonder
whether the financial markets are signaling something
new about the economy, and whether another notch of
tightening in monetary policy is needed to counteract
what has been happening. The answer to both questions,
I believe, is negative. The recent strength in both
the bond markets and in bank credit seems to me to
reflect the temporary factors that are unlikely to be
repeated in the period ahead. The more fundamental
trend is toward growing constraint in terms of the cost
and availability of credit, the gradual evolution of
which appears entirely appropriate to the immediate
economic outlook as outlined by Mr. Brill. It is hard
to say at this point how far this restraint should go
or how long it should be pursued, but there is nothing
in the situation as of now to indicate the need for any
modification in the System's basic policy.
Indeed, some say that the marked improvement in
bond investor sentiment reflects a growing consensus
that fiscal and monetary restraints will work and that
inflationary pressures in time are bound to be dampened.
This view may well have colored investor attitudes
recently, since it is also the consensus that interest
rates are historically very high and that the opportu
nity to capture these yields in portfolio will not last
forever. The urgency of the timing problem for
investors is heightened by the possibility of some
major peace break-through in Vietnam, rumors about which
have also been a feature of the past month or so.
Despite these positive psychological factors en
couraging investment commitments, I am inclined to feel
that the bond markets still have some rocky road to
travel. The decline in interest rates this month has
brought forth a very large volume of new issues, including
offerings postponed earlier. Some backing off from this
exceptional volume is to be expected but, looking ahead,

4/29/69

-34-

capital financing needs in both the corporate and
municipal areas clearly remain very heavy. Mean
while, investors have had available for commitment
not only their current flows but also funds withheld
from the market earlier this year. As the backlog
in commitable funds is used up, and assuming that new
bond offerings continue relatively large, a renewed
upward trend in yields would seem the most probable
outcome. Indeed, some of this already appears to be
in process; the rally has run out of steam and some
price markdowns have occurred in recent days.
As for the surge in bank credit, preliminary
estimates now indicate a rise in April of about 7 per
cent, annual rate, both in the daily-average proxy
series (including Euro-dollars) and in the end-of-month
loans and investments figures. The increase was attrib
utable in part to larger average bank holdings of
Governments and securities loans, partly reflecting the
Treasury bill-strip financing at the end of March. But
much more important in the expansion was the very strong
upsurge in business financing needs over the mid-April
tax date. Such needs were reflected not only in unusu
ally heavy direct borrowings from the banks, but also
in increased bank lending to finance companies and
securities dealers.
Staff estimates indicate a much larger total for
corporate tax payments than for tax accruals on profits
in the second quarter, mainly because two payment datesApril and June--fall within the quarter and call for an
increasing proportion of the year's corporate tax total.
Otherwise, there is nothing to indicate an appreciable
further rise in external financing needs. Similarly,
no additional Treasury cash financing is expected this
quarter; indeed, debt repayment and attrition on refundings
may total about $11 billion. Thus, there is no reason to
expect a further surge in bank credit, at least before
mid-June, and some liquidation of the April increase
would appear probable.
The April increase in bank credit was accompanied
by an upsurge in demand deposits, and the money supply is
now indicated to have increased on average this month at
an astounding 15 per cent annual rate. Again, however,
special factors appear to account for most of this
increase. First, the four-day Easter weekend in Europe
had the effect of sharply reducing cash items in process
of collection at the New York banks, and hence increasing

4/29/69

-35-

net demand deposit totals, though only for a short
period of time. Second, there appears to have been an
unusually large buildup in private cash balances just
prior to the tax date, reflecting the larger tax lia
bilities to be paid by both corporations and individuals
this year. Business tax financing at the banks was
exceptionally heavy, as noted, and there was a sharp
rundown in individual savings balances at the banks and
also apparently at thrift institutions in the days
leading up to mid-April. But this buildup also should
be unwinding with the presentation of tax checks in the
latter part of April and perhaps on into May. I can
see no reason for a more fundamental increase in the
public's demand for cash balances, with interest rates
remaining high, the stock market relatively calm, and
transactions needs, if anything, expanding somewhat less
rapidly than during the winter.
On balance, therefore, I conclude that the April
developments in bond markets, bank credit, and money
supply do not call for any special recognition in terms
of modifying the thrust of monetary policy. They all
seem attributable to special factors, and all are likely
to be reversed shortly. The imminent major Treasury
refunding, in any event, dictates an even keel policy
for most of the period until the next meeting of the
Committee.
It might be noted, however, that the money market
conditions to be maintained are historically very
restrictive ones. With Federal funds averaging well
above 7 per cent and member bank borrowings around
$1 billion or more, we would expect continuing pressure
on bank reserve positions and some decline on average
in the bank credit proxy next month. I think that the
decline projected--2 to 5 per cent, annual rate--would
be an entirely appropriate outcome, and should be
welcomed as an offset to the unexpected April expansion.
It seems to me important also that the bill rate be
held up within the 5.90 - 6.20 per cent range specified,
even if this should require a somewhat more restrictive
reserve position than now contemplated. This would help
to guard against a resurgence of bank credit again in
June, and to prevent any public misconstruction of System
policy as the large April monetary aggregates become more
generally known.

-36

4/29/69

In reply to a question by Mr. Mitchell, Mr. Partee
said he personally thought it was highly likely that the
April bulge in the monetary aggregates would prove largely
self-reversing.

The pattern of movement in weekly data

around the tax date--which was particularly marked in the
figures for country banks--lent strong support to the view
that the bulge was related to needs for cash to pay income
taxes, and that private cash balances would decline again
as the Treasury cleared the checks involved.
Mr. Solomon said most of his remarks today would be
concerned with developments at the meeting of Working Party
3 last week, but he would first make a few comments about
recent balance of payments developments.

There was not much

one could say about recent U. S. trade developments, since
the data were substantially affected by the U. S. dock
strike.

In particular, not much emphasis could be placed

on the improvement in the trade balance recorded for March.
As the green book indicated, however, the trade balance was
likely to move into a substantial surplus in the second
quarter with the unwinding of the effects of the dock strike.
With respect to the over-all payments balance on the liquidity
basis, a large deficit--of $1-3/4 billion--had been incurred
in the first quarter.

It was not clear what interpretation

-37

4/29/69

the public would put on that development when the figures
were published.

Apparently another large deficit was being

incurred on the liquidity basis in April.

On the official

settlements basis, there was a surplus of $1 billion in the
first quarter and evidently a further surplus in April.
The shift in the liquidity balance from surplus in
the fourth quarter to deficit in the first seemed to be
primarily attributable to two factors, Mr. Solomon continued.
The first was the recent deficit in the trade accounts
associated with the dock strike.

The second was a large

outflow of direct investment capital, reversing in part the
net inflow of the fourth quarter.

It was possible that

some U. S. corporations were returning funds to Europe as
a result of the attractive rates in the Euro-dollar market,
although the outflow might have occurred in any event.
Mr. Solomon then made the following statement:
Last week's meeting of Working Party 3 focused
(1) the pull of tight money
on two related subjects:
in the United States on the Euro-dollar market and
the repercussions on interest rates, financial condi
tions, and reserves in other countries and (2) the
connections between balance of payments adjustment
and the need for reserve creation in the form of SDR's.
Today I propose to summarize for the Committee
the main points involved in these two issues.
While there was much discussion at the meeting
about the impact of U. S. monetary conditions on other
countries, support for present U. S. monetary policy
was strong. No one questioned the need for it. If

4/29/69

-38-

anything, there was skepticism about the determination
of American authorities to persist with sufficiently
firm monetary and fiscal policies. This skepticism
was expressed not only in Europe but also among Latin
American central bank governors at Williamsburg in the
past two days.
Thus, the WP-3 discussion was concerned not with
the posture of U. S. monetary policy but with whether
the United States should not do something to temper
the effects of its tight money policy on the Euro-dollar
market.
Among the countries represented at the WP-3
meetings only two or three were concerned about the
effect on their own financial conditions. The Belgians
are most vocal here--though their reasons are not very
clear.
The Dutch complained mildly that high Euro
dollar rates are resulting in less credit availability
within the Netherlands than is planned by the
authorities, but it was not explained why the
Netherlands Bank cannot offset this shortfall unless
it is worried about its reserves.
The representatives
of Sweden, Switzerland, Japan, Canada, and Germany
either welcomed or are willing and able to live with
present conditions in the Euro-dollar market. The
French complained but stated that they were not being
affected. Germany has not been experiencing an outflow
of short-term funds--given the large forward premium
on the mark--and welcomes the leeway to raise its own
short-term rates.
Although several Europeans insisted that their
reserves are adequate and they are not concerned about
their reserves, their actual arguments belied their
statements in this regard.
For example, the Belgian, Dutch, and German
representatives stated that they are experiencing a
shortage of intervention currency--that is, freely
usable dollars. They had to be reminded by the
Swedish and Swiss delegates that a shortage of dollars
can be relieved by selling gold. If countries are
reluctant to sell gold, it is difficult to maintain
that they are not concerned over reductions in their

reserves.

One answer given here was that the reduction

in reserves is temporary and countries are hesitant
to sell gold to relieve a temporary shortage of dollars.

4/29/69

-39-

Again the Swiss delegate provided a helpful answer by
pointing out that a number of countries did not hesitate
to buy gold earlier when dollars flowed in.
On the basis of the general discussion, one can
say that the case for action by the United States to
temper the pressure of U. S. monetary conditions on the
Euro-dollar market is as follows:
(1) To some extent interest rates in
Europe may be driven up more than is desired
by European monetary authorities. This would
be unfortunate in its effects on economic
conditions in Europe and it may be followed
by too much delay, later, in getting European
rates back down.
(2) The larger the inflow of Euro-dollars
to the United States now, the greater the
potential back-flow when monetary conditions
change in the future. This would depress the
value of the dollar on exchange markets and
have unfortunate effects on confidence. In
other words, the United States does not need
such a large surplus now, especially in view
of the unsatisfactory structure of its balance
of payments.
For our part we pointed out that the Euro-dollar
inflow is a by-product of U. S. policy and not a delib
erate objective. The inflow does not undermine U. S.
monetary policy. We also noted that even if the Euro
dollar market did not exist, European short-term money
would no doubt be coming directly to the United States
under present conditions.
Furthermore, if the Federal Reserve were to adopt
measures to discourage U. S. banks from borrowing from
their branches, there are other channels through which
Euro-dollars can flow to the United States (as is pointed
out in the paper the staff recently circulated to the
Committee 1/).
Thus, though it may be possible to

1/ The memorandum referred to, dated April 16, 1969, and
entitled "Measures to Affect Use of Euro-dollars in the United
States," was distributed to the Board of Governors and Reserve
Bank Presidents on April 17. A copy has been placed in the
Committee's files.

4/29/69

-40-

slow down the inflow, it is impractical to think of
stopping it in a world in which most countries do not
use exchange controls. We reminded the Working Party
that in the earlier 1960's, when monetary conditions in
Europe were tight, part of Europe's surplus reflected
short-term capital inflows.
On this subject, the Working Party was left with
the impression that the United States is sensitive to
the effects of its policies on other countries and is
willing to consider all practical measures, in a spirit
of cooperation, to deal with such problems.
On the other major subject--the relationship be
tween the adjustment process and reserve creationI believe that further progress was made. The simple
arithmetic is that if the United States is in official
settlements balance--and therefore not creating
reserves in the form of dollars--if the United Kingdom
and France are in surplus--as will be necessary if
they are to repay debt--and if the less developed
countries continue to add to their reserves year by
year--then the other developed countries and Europe in
particular must be losing reserves unless new reserves
are created. There is no escape from this arithmetic
necessity. Yet if the other developed countries resist
such losses of reserves, it will not be possible for
the United Kingdom, France, and the United States to
achieve their balance of payments objectives.
The argument was summed up very well by one dele
gate who said that if it is seen that the United States,
France, and the United Kingdom have adopted the policies
that are necessary to start the process of balance of
payments adjustment, then there is a good case for
early activation of SDR's as a means of facilitating
the accommodating actions by other countries.
In reply to a question by Mr. Daane, Mr. Solomon said that
Japan had accumulated about $1 billion of reserves during the past
year and the Japanese expected their payments position to remain
strong.

Japan's reserve gains, of course, added to the pressures

on the reserve positions of other countries.

4/29/69

-41Chairman Martin then called for the go-around of comments

and views on economic conditions and monetary policy, beginning
with Mr. Hayes, who commented as follows:
Nearly all recent data confirm that the business
situation and outlook remain decidedly inflationary.
The earlier signs of weakening consumer demand and a
resulting inventory problem have apparently faded away.
Housing starts have been off somewhat, but the March
decline may have been largely a reaction to the un
usually high rate of starts during the winter. It may
perhaps also have reflected a temporary interruption
in the flow of mortgage money from thrift institutions
awaiting a reading on their deposit performance in the
past interest and dividend crediting period. The
proposed repeal of the investment tax credit would
probably reduce only to a modest extent the inflation
ary stimulus arising from plant and equipment spending.
On the other hand, consumers and corporate spenders
alike will be encouraged by the prospect of a lower tax
surcharge after the end of 1969. Our GNP projections,
even though they include a sizable further rise in the
saving ration which may not be realized, suggest only a
modest further slowing of real economic growth and only
a very small dent in the rate of price inflation by the
end of this calendar year.
It is hard to avoid a feeling of disappointment
over the absence to date of any appreciable effect of
policy measures on the real economy. However, the
importance of lags has doubtless been underrated, and
I still believe the cumulative underlying effect of
fiscal and monetary actions will become visible later
in the year.
On the balance of payments front the prospects
appear equally gloomy. Since the beginning of 1969 the
U. S. liquidity balance has been almost constantly in
heavy deficit. Granted that much of the first quarter's
very poor showing reflects the partial reversal of the
huge year-end inflows of corporate funds--with the
relative import and export effects of the dock strike
termination also an adverse factor--it is hard to fore
see anything but a large liquidity deficit for the full
year.

4/29/69

-42-

Already there are signs of a slower pace in the inflow
of foreign funds into our stock market. So far, of
course, the official settlements balance has been in
comfortable surplus because of the continuing heavy
borrowings by U. S. banks from their branches abroad.
In good part because of this situation, the
dollar remains in a reasonably strong position in the
foreign exchange markets, as it has been for many
months. At the same time we must recognize the cur
rent sensitivity of the exchange markets, reflecting
major uncertainties with respect to the German mark,
the French franc, and sterling. We cannot rule out
a crisis which would once again involve the dollar.
From a longer-run point of view it is a bit unnerving
to contemplate the effects on our official settlements
balance of any future turn to easier money in this
country and a consequent heavy reversal of the inflow
of funds from foreign branches.
As usual, the current banking and monetary statis
tics are somewhat difficult to interpret because of
temporary "technical" and special developments. Thus,
the strong rise in the bank credit proxy projected for
April partly reflects a temporary buildup of Treasury
deposits, and the proxy is expected to weaken again in
May as these deposits are run off. At the same time,
however, the conventional proxy measures understate
the flow of credit through the banking system as
banks reduce both their assets and liabilities by
loan sales to foreign branches and to parent one-bank
holding companies. While the degree of understate
ment does not appear to be serious yet, it could
quickly become serious if additional major banks join
the loan sales game. The very rapid spurt in the
money supply now estimated for April is clearly
unfortunate. Apparently only a part of this outsized
increase is due to technical--and temporary--factors.
Publication of the numbers will no doubt complicate
the System's "credibility" problem.
It is hard to reach a judgment as to the degree
to which banks and other financial markets, and the
public generally, have yet accepted that policy is
seriously restrictive and will continue to be so until
there is a significant stabilization of the economy.
While recent policy measures have helped to strengthen

4/29/69

-43-

convictions as to the System's intentions, there has
at the same time been some feeling in the financial mar
kets that interest rates have peaked; also, many banks
seemingly continue to look upon the current tightness
as a temporary situation that will not persist for long,
and they are preoccupied with finding new techniques to
avoid having to take too restrictive an attitude toward
their customers.
Under all the circumstances I have outlined, I see
no alternative to an open market policy of at least
maintaining the degree of tightness that has developed
in the money market since the last FOMC meeting. With
the terms of a Treasury refunding expected to be
announced tomorrow, even keel considerations preclude
and major policy moves for the time being.
In suggesting that open market operations be aimed
at maintaining the firmer tone that has recently
developed, I have in mind a Federal funds rate range
of roughly 7-1/4 to 7-3/4 per cent, borrowings in
the range of $900 million to $1.2 billion, and net
borrowed reserves of between $800 million and $1.0
billion. With special seasonal factors tending to
depress the bill rate, we must expect a continuing, and
perhaps even widening, gap between this rate and most
market interest rates. Because of the continuing
seriousness of the inflationary threat I would hope that
the Manager would tend to operate toward the upper end
of the target ranges I have mentioned.
I would accept the directive proposed by the staff
as accommodating such a tendency. A proviso clause
should be retained and should be implemented vigorously
if the expected reversal of the April bulge in the
credit proxy does not materialize. I would suggest
a very modest revision in the opening lines of the draft
directive to change the emphasis slightly. Specifi
cally, I would insert the word "only" after "moderated,"
and place the statement about prices and costs in a
new sentence beginning with the phrase "at the same
time." The opening sentences would then read, "The
information reviewed at this meeting suggests that
expansion in real economic activity has moderated
only slightly since the fourth quarter of 1968. At
the same time, substantial upward pressures on prices
and costs are persisting."

-44-

4/29/69

Mr. Morris said it was his conviction that the Committee
was.on the right track with respect to policy and that if it
adhered to its present course it should expect to see some
meaningful results in the real economy before the third
quarter was over.

That judgment did not suggest that he was

afflicted with "statisticitis" since he had not as yet been
able to find any significant support for it in the economic
statistics.

The decline in March in the composite index of

leading series, which received so much notice in the press
this morning, unfortunately was not large enough to have much
statistical significance in itself; and certainly the improved
tone in the bond market was a fragile thing.

Nonetheless,

those were the sorts of things which should be happening now
if there was going to be an inflexion point in the economy
five or six months hence.
Mr. Morris said he had invited the presidents and the
chairmen of the leading Boston banks to lunch yesterday in
order to get a feel for their thinking.

In general, they

were convinced that the System's current policy would be
successful, although they had cautioned against expecting to
see immediate results.

None of them, however, advocated a

more restrictive policy designed to get results at a faster
pace.

-45

4/29/69

Mr. Morris went on to say that when he had asked the
bankers what the System might do that it was not now doing,
he received one idea from Roger Damon, Chairman of the First
National Bank of Boston, which he thought had enough merit to
bring to the Committee's attention.

Mr. Damon suggested that

some sort of voluntary restraint program should be initiated
relating to bank loans for the purpose of facilitating mergers
and acquisitions.

He argued that the acquiring firms typically

had enough financial leverage to make it difficult for the
individual bank to turn them down without some sort of
official crutch to lean on.

He felt that that sort of financ

ing was particularly unfortunate because much of the resulting
new money flowed into the stock market.

He also felt, and

Mr. Morris agreed, that a significant break in stock prices
was probably a necessary condition for a break in inflation
psychology.

It was for that reason that Mr. Morris believed

Mr. Damon's idea was worth exploring by the Board of Governors.
In general, Mr. Morris thought the degree of financial
restraint now in force was appropriate and he supported the
staff's draft directive.

However, he shared the concern that

Messrs. Hayes and Mitchell had expressed about the ballooning
of the monetary aggregates in April, and he endorsed Mr. Hayes'
suggestion that the proviso clause be implemented vigorously if
the expected reversal did not develop.

4/29/69

-46Mr. Coldwell reported that economic activity in the

Eleventh District showed increased momentum in March.

Indus

trial production was up 1 per cent, employment rose seasonally,
and unemployment was at the irreducible minimum in the District's
large cities.

There was some slowing in retail sales, but auto

registrations were rising.

Agricultural conditions reflected

rainfall delays, and winter wheat production was estimated to
be down 6 per cent from 1968.
With respect to District financial conditions,
Mr. Coldwell remarked, there still was evidence of restraint,
but also of continued loan accommodation.

A recent survey of

large savings and loan associations in the District reflected
divergent patterns of savings flows and commitments.

Most,

however, expected the change in savings flows to be similar
to or below that of last year and future commitments to be
below those of 1968.

Rates charged had increased in recent weeks

to 8 per cent.
Nationally, Mr. Coldwell observed, economic conditions
still reflected growth and upward wage and price changes remained
large.

Despite some bank restraint the demands for credit were

heavy and many were still being met.

Consumer and business

psychology appeared to have been shaken only slightly and deci
sions were being made on the basis of inflationary expectations.

-47-

4/29/69

As to policy, Mr. Coldwell continued, he recognized that
the Treasury would be engaged in a refunding.

Within the context

of the refunding he would recommend maintaining at least the
degree of restraint that had been achieved and resolving any
doubts on the side of restraint.

Recently he had also suggest

ed that the System make a direct appeal to banks for restraint
on loans and he continued to advocate that step partly for the
reason Mr., Morris had just offered--banks were unable to exercise
the necessary restraint themselves without some official support.
Turning to the directive, Mr. Coldwell said he would favor
Mr. Hayes' suggestion with respect to the opening sentence.

In

addition, he would delete the statement regarding first-quarter
changes in bank credit and the money supply, which at this point
was of only historical interest, and expand the statement regard
ing the large increases in April.

For the latter purpose, he

would propose a sentence reading, "In early April both bank
credit and the money supply increased substantially, largely as
a result of the change in Treasury balances, sharp tax-date
borrowing, and seasonal deposit shifts around Easter."
Mr. Swan remarked that the pace of business activity in
the Twelfth District picked up in March, both absolutely and
relative to the nation as a whole.

The pick-up, which was

-48

4/29/69

reflected in such measures as employment, unemployment, housing
starts, and bank loans, appeared to be broadly based.

The

unemployment rate had dropped from 4.5 per cent in February to
4.3 per cent in March despite a continuing decline in employment
in the aerospace industries.

Business loans at banks had begun

to rise more rapidly in mid-March and were very strong in
subsequent weeks.

While major District banks had remained net

sellers of inter-bank Federal funds, the margin of their net
sales had narrowed considerably and they expected to be net
buyers in the current week.

On the other hand, borrowings from

the Reserve Bank, while fairly well maintained in dollar terms,
had been under 10 per cent of the national total in each of the
six weeks since March 12, reversing the pattern of the preceding
weeks.

In short, an assessment of conditions in the Twelfth

District simply reinforced what had been said about the national
picture.
As to policy, Mr. Swan agreed the Committee would have
to maintain an even keel in view of the Treasury financing.
However, in light of the April developments in bank credit and
money, he certainly agreed that the Committee could not afford to
relax the present degree of restraint.

He also shared the view

that firmer conditions should be sought, to the extent feasible,
if the April developments were not reversed.

Accordingly, he

4/29/69

-49

saw very little reason for a two-way proviso clause in the
directive, and would recommend a one-way proviso instead.

He

favored the change Mr. Hayes had suggested in the first para
graph.

Also, he would either adopt Mr. Coldwell's suggestion

for the statement regarding bank credit and money or simply
delete the reference to "temporary factors."

One or the other

of those changes seemed desirable because, as had been indicated
earlier, the language of the sentence in the draft was equivocal.
Mr. Galusha commented that the story of the Ninth District
economy in April was very much the same as that of the national
economy, so he could pass on almost immediately to Committee
policy.

He did want to note, however, that mortgage commit

ments of District savings and loan associations had decreased
in March, despite an essentially unchanged inflow of funds.
That was the first decrease in commitments in some time, but it
was far from clear that a new trend had started.

Construction

employment, seasonally adjusted, also decreased in March, but
he was inclined to regard that change as a statistical aberra
tion.

A good deal had been heard of late about a changing

seasonal pattern in District construction.
With the Treasury about to announce its refunding terms,
Mr. Galusha said, a policy of even keel would seem appropriate.
He accepted the monetary targets given in the blue book.

With

-50

4/29/69

respect to the directive, both the language change proposed by
Mr. Hayes and the deletion of the phrase regarding temporary
factors suggested by Mr. Swan seem to him to be improvements.
The latter change struck him as particularly desirable since the
precise nature of the "temporary factors" referred to was not
clear at the moment.
Mr. Scanlon reported that the general economic picture
in the Seventh District continued to reflect rising activity and
expectations of further increases in demand and prices.

Midwest

business economists appeared generally to concur with that
evaluation of the current situation.

They also appeared to be

in agreement that slower growth in spending would be evident
in the second half, especially if money and credit expansion
continued moderate and the Federal budget continued to move
toward surplus.
A few local developments tended to support the view that
a slowing in aggregate spending would be evident some months
hence, Mr. Scanlon said.

There were scattered reports of busi

ness expenditures being postponed because of an inability to
obtain credit on satisfactory terms, especially construction
loans.

Farm machinery sales had continued below year-ago levels

in the recent months of seasonally small volume, and there had
been some reports of reduced recruiting of hard-core unemployed
for training programs.

4/29/69

-51
Nevertheless, Mr. Scanlon continued, there was little

slack in the economy of the Seventh District.
times were lengthening further.

Order lead

Employers reported intentions

to hire more workers in the near future and, incidentally, the
Reserve Bank's Personnel Department reported a record number of
unfilled requisitions on hand.
increase inventories.

Most firms were attempting to

Steel mills in the Chicago area were

working at practical capacity, with output near the record
level reached in March last year.

Orders from a wide variety

of steel users had offset the seasonal decline in demand for
steel for passenger cars.

In the Detroit area, production had

declined since mid-March.
In the first half of April, Mr. Scanlon observed, loans
to businesses at weekly reporting banks in the District rose
more than last year but somewhat less rapidly than for the
country as a whole.

A number of those banks, especially in

Chicago and Milwaukee, continued to show very low liquidity
positions.

Euro-dollar liabilities had risen, net Federal funds

acquired remained near record highs, and liquidation of both
Treasury and municipal securities had continued during the past
month.

Loan-deposit ratios of the largest Chicago banks, exclu

sive of Federal funds sales and adjusted for cash items, now
averaged over 80 per cent, with one bank over 100 per cent--

4/29/69

-52

well above the peaks reached in 1966.

Those banks had not been

borrowing much at the discount window.
At smaller member banks, Mr. Scanlon continued, loans
had risen very rapidly since the end of February, while
liquidation of Governments had been less than acquisitions of
other securities.

Loan demand appeared very strong at those

banks and they still had relatively low loan ratios.

There

was some sale of loans to the smaller banks by the money
market banks but he had no measure of how much.

Some of the

District's banks were using large amounts of Euro-dollars.
One bank had liabilities to foreign branches equal to 21 per
cent of its "deposit" liabilities and to about 10 per cent of
the total of liabilities to foreign branches for all U. S.
banks.

That fact was of some concern to him.
Although past monetary and fiscal policies appeared to

have contributed to some slowing in the economy, Mr. Scanlon
said, the rate of economic advance was still resulting in an
intolerable rate of inflation.

He was somewhat disturbed,

therefore, by the relatively large increase in bank credit and
the money supply now estimated for April.

He had been reasonably

satisfied with the rate of monetary and credit expansion achieved
in the first quarter of the year and would like to hold fairly
close to those rates.

In view of the increases in April, the

4/29/69

-53

current projections of money supply and bank credit for May
appeared acceptable as goals of policy.

The draft directive,

with the amendments suggested by Messrs. Coldwell and Hayes,
was acceptable to him.
Mr. Clay observed that the fiscal measures recently
announced by the Administration, if carried out, should prove
constructive in the effort to provide a more balanced pattern
of economic activity.

At the same time, it was essential

that the firmness of monetary policy be continued.

Evidence

of moderation in economic activity thus far was relatively
limited and was not sufficient to give assurance of policy
success.

Moreover, cost-price pressures continued virtually

unabated.

While there had been substantial financial response

to credit restraint, no relaxation would be appropriate in
view of the developments in the real economy.
Mr. Clay thought that monetary policy targets for the
period ahead might include a Federal funds rate of 7-1/4 to
7-3/4 per cent, member bank borrowing of $800 million to $1.2
billion, net borrowed reserves of $800 million to $1.1 billion,
and a Treasury bill rate of 6.0 to 6.20 per cent.
The April growth in bank credit was considerably larger
than anticipated, Mr. Clay said.

Now a Treasury financing opera

tion was approaching, and that entailed the usual risk of

-54

4/29/69

creating bank credit beyond expectations.

There was a substan

tial difference between the Board and the New York Reserve
Bank staff projections of the member bank credit proxy for May,
assuming continuation of prevailing money market conditions.
Mr. Clay noted that while the blue book suggested the
likelihood of higher intermediate- and long-term interest
rates over the next few weeks, it mentioned the possibility
of strong expansionary effects on monetary aggregates should
market anticipations of higher bond prices develop because
of evidence of weakening economic activity or progress toward
peace.

No concern need arise over a very modest growth in

bank credit of perhaps 2 or 3 per cent.

Strenuous restraint

efforts would be called for if a faster rate of growth appeared
in the making.
The draft policy directive appeared to Mr. Clay to be
satisfactory.
Mr. Heflin observed that the business advance in the
Fifth District appeared to have abated little, if any, in recent
weeks, although the Richmond Reserve Bank's latest survey
suggested a few more signs of developing moderation than had
been present earlier in the year.

The District textile industry

remained in the doldrums and the latest information indicated
that residential building outlays might have topped out.

-55

4/29/69

Moreover, business respondents in the Bank's survey expressed
somewhat less exuberance about the future than they had in
February and March.

Nevertheless, retail trade and nonresiden

tial construction continued strong and, on balance, most of
the Bank's latest information remained generally bullish.
At the national level, it seemed to Mr. Heflin that
the preliminary Commerce Department data for the first quarter
reflected no slowdown at all from the fourth-quarter pace.
The small indicated reduction in GNP growth was less impressive
than the large increase in final sales and the sharp step-up
in the pace of consumer spending--which, incidentally, came
in the face of a considerably less congenial tax situation.
The figures on final sales and inventories suggested to him
that businessmen might not have reached their inventory
targets last quarter and, given the current price environment,
he would not be surprised to see another surge of stockbuilding
in the weeks ahead.

Moreover, while the first-quarter increase

in business fixed investment was unusually large, he was not
confident that subsequent quarterly gains would be cut back
as sharply as the green book projections indicated.

The strong

rally in the bond market over the past three weeks suggested
that, despite the System's tight posture, there was still an
abundance of funds in the market to finance business spending

4/29/69

-56

plans.

Repeal of the investment tax credit could help, but

with inflationary expectations continuing strong he believed
it would be a mistake to expect any significant restraining
effect from that quarter over the next six months.
It now seemed reasonably certain that residential
construction outlays would decline in the near future and that
more fiscal restraint was in prospect, Mr. Heflin remarked.
Moreover, the recent slowdown in the automobile industry
appeared to be continuing, if not deepening.

Nonetheless,

viewing the over-all picture, he thought it would be premature
to conclude that there was substantive evidence of any signifi
cant moderation in the business advance.
Although he realized that the Desk had faced a
difficult job in the latest period, Mr. Heflin said, it seemed
to him that the indicated rates of growth in the credit proxy
and money supply in April were not consistent with the policy
posture the Committee had tried to project.

Recent developments

in the bill and bond markets indicated to him that, despite the
System's tough posture over the past four months, a substantial
residue of liquidity remained in the economy.

Under the

circumstances, he thought it was imperative that bank credit
and money growth be kept under close control and he was inclined
to view as excessive any annual growth rate much above 2 or 3
per cent.

-57

4/29/69

Over the coming period, Mr. Heflin continued, the
Committee faced a dangerous, if not critical, situation in the
international exchanges as well as an even keel constraint.
On both counts, it could afford little in the way of an overt
tightening move.

Yet he thought pressure should be kept on

the banking system and on the market, about in line with
conditions obtaining last week rather than in the two weeks
immediately preceding.

Federal funds rates, it seemed to him,

should average 7 per cent or higher, with both borrowings and
net borrowed reserves in the neighborhood of $1 billion.

He

also thought that bill rates should not be allowed to move
much below current levels.

He favored making the change in

the draft directive that had been suggested by Mr. Hayes.

And,

if he correctly understood the comments of Messrs. Sternlight
and Partee regarding the April bulge in bank credit and money,
he thought that in the phrase "partly as a result of temporary
factors," the word "partly" might be changed to "largely."
Mr. Mitchell said he thought System policy was on the
right track.

It was unfortunate that recent policy had not

yet produced more in the way of results, but results should not
have been expected this soon.
Turning to the directive, Mr. Mitchell remarked that the
question of how the early April bulges in bank credit and money

-58

4/29/69
were described was important.

In light of Mr. Partee's

comments he would suggest language reading ".

. but in

early April both measures increased substantially, apparent
ly as a result of self-reversing factors."

It would be

desirable to include the word "apparently" because at this
juncture one could not be certain about the indicated self
reversal.

With respect to the second paragraph, he concurred

in Mr. Swan's view that a one-way proviso clause was desirable,
and would suggest language reading ".

.

. provided, however,

that operations should be modified, to the extent permitted
by the Treasury financing, if bank credit growth does not
moderate substantially from the estimated April rate."

In

his judgment a one-way proviso was needed because there was
a real risk that bank credit and the money supply would
prove to be stronger than projected in May, for the reasons
noted in the blue book passage to which Mr. Clay had
referred.

He thought the Desk would have to take aggressive

action if bank credit growth did not moderate substantially
in May.
Mr. Daane said he agreed in general that monetary policy
was on the right course, but he had some doubts as to whether
that course was being pursued vigorously enough.

Were it not

for even keel considerations, he would suggest that the System

-59

4/29/69

act a bit more aggressively in applying restraint, and hold
back even more than it had on the supply of reserves relative
to demand.

The Treasury financing limited what could be

accomplished at this juncture, but within the even keel con
straint he would hope that any errors would be on the side of
restraint and that the Desk would take advantage of every
opportunity to move in that direction.

He would not be

disturbed if the money market variables went beyond the tight
end of the ranges given in the blue book; he had always
considered blue book specifications as general guideposts
rather than rigid targets.

He would accept the change

Mr. Hayes had suggested for the first paragraph of the direc
tive, and he shared the sense of uncertainty some members had
expressed with respect to the implications of the April
developments in the monetary aggregates.
Mr. Maisel said he would support the draft directive
in the form submitted by the staff.
Mr. Brimmer remarked that he agreed with the policy
course indicated by the staff's draft directive, and favored
retention of the two-way proviso shown in the draft.

He

thought the changes Mr. Hayes had suggested in the first
paragraph were desirable.

-60

4/29/69

Mr. Brimmer then said that Mr. Robertson's comment on
the need for revision of the statement in the draft regarding
the early-April bulges in bank credit and money had prompted
him to attempt a reformulation.

He gathered from some notes

Mr. Axilrod had prepared at his (Mr. Brimmer's) request that
the bulge in private demand deposits was associated in large
part with technical accounting considerations related to the
effect of the long-Easter weekend on the roll-over of Euro
dollar borrowings by U. S. banks.

And, as had been noted in

the discussion today, domestic tax-date borrowing also was
an important factor.

Hopefully, those developments would be

reversed, but that was not certain.

If the statement were

to be revised, it might be best to pin-point the reasons for
the early-April developments in a separate sentence concern
ing them.

He would suggest dividing the statement into two

sentences, as follows:

"In the first quarter of the year

bank credit changed little on average and the money supply
grew at a sharply reduced rate.

In early April both measures

increased substantially, influenced in part by large tax-date
borrowing and deposit bulges around Easter."
Mr. Hickman said it was difficult to find any
substantial evidence of easing in terms of current spending
flows in the economy.

The decline in durable goods orders

-61

4/29/69

in March--which was confined chiefly to the aerospace industryand some slowing in labor force and employment growth last month
might be only straws in the wind.

Although real growth in both

retail sales and disposable personal income had declined sharp
ly, higher taxes had had a large impact in the first quarter.
Moreover, even though economic activity might be slowing in
real terms, the preponderance of recent business and financial
news did not suggest much relaxation in inflationary pressures.
It would take still more time before slackened growth in the
real sector would be translated into a diminished rate of
inflation.
Given the decline in the bank credit proxy in the first
quarter, Mr. Hickman believed that the growth in April was not
inappropriate--although it clearly exceeded the Committee's
intent, and if sustained over a longer period would be
inconsistent with his prescription of moderate growth for bank
credit.

Modest growth in bank credit in the second quarter would

be necessary to provide a sustainable base for the economy,
especially if the rate of expansion in the real sector actually
was slowing.

However, the Committee should make sure that the

gains in the credit proxy remained moderate and did not acceler
ate, just as it should have been concerned about the too rapid

-62

4/29/69

gains in the last half of 1968 and the too rapid decline in the
first quarter of 1969 as a whole.
Mr. Hickman commented that those sharp swings in policy
should be avoided if at all possible.

In particular, the

Committee should not attempt to cancel out in May the 7 per
cent growth in bank credit now expected for April, but rather
should seek a small sustainable rate of growth.

The thrust

of the President's fiscal program, coupled with gradual growth
in the reserve and credit aggregates, should be sufficient to
turn the tide in inflationary expectations.

It was neither

necessary nor desirable to precipitate a monetary crisis in
order to achieve that objective.

With that in mind, as well

as the Treasury financing that would be announced shortly, he
supported the staff's draft directive, calling for even keel.
Mr. Bopp remarked that his problem in formulating a
policy position today was in striking a balance between near
term and longer-term considerations.

For the near term, solid

evidence of strength in the economy was prevalent.

Thus, the

preliminary figures for gross national product in the first
quarter and the March increase in consumer prices and in
industrial commodities prices at wholesale were disappointing
to those who had looked for greater moderation by now.

In light

of the strong first quarter, further advances in industrial

4/29/69

-63

production, retail sales, and personal income were likely.
Despite the drag from tax reconciliation payments, there now
seemed to be little question of considerable strength in the
economy during the current quarter.

The staff at the Philadelphia

Reserve Bank was projecting a gain in GNP of more than $14 billion,
with final sales growing only a little less than in the first
quarter.
Mr. Bopp noted that the Reserve Bank's April business
outlook survey indicated that the region's economic posture was
still one of strength, with a majority of respondents expecting
higher levels of business activity six months from now.
However, the survey also indicated that the number planning to
hire additional employees or to extend the workweek during the
next half-year had declined since the first quarter of this
year.

Apparently some of the District's regional manufacturers

saw an easing in the rate of business expansion ahead.
So much for the near-term outlook, which he read as
over-all strength, Mr. Bopp said.

The troublesome policy

considerations were the longer-term ones.

First, since the

beginning of the year, bank credit had contracted and the fore
cast was for more of the same in May.
declined.

Bank reserves also had

Secondly, the President's proposed program for

additional fiscal restraint, if enacted, would add a fiscal

-64-

4/29/69
bite to the monetary bite.
proposals was uncertain.

Of course, the fate of the fiscal
But even if they were not implemented,

the bite of monetary policy during the past four months was
bound to be felt later on.

If, in addition, fiscal restraint

did materialize, the combination of the two might prove too much.
Complicating monetary management, Mr. Bopp continued, was
the Committee's ignorance about the ability of financial institu
tions to adjust to restraint.

At the last meeting of the

Philadelphia Reserve Bank's Board, one director had commented
on the growing concern of several large insurance companies
about policy loans.

A check with several large companies in

the Third District revealed that their policy loans were consid
erably higher than at the 1966 peak.

So far in 1969, they were

running at substantially higher rates than in 1968, as the green
book indicated was also the case nationally.
Mr. Bopp continued to be impressed, however, by the
resiliency of financial institutions and by their ingenuity in
finding escape valves.

That resiliency was corroborated by the

findings of last week's conference call of discount officers.
Nevertheless, while the adjustment thus far had proceeded with
out major disruption, the performance of the money and credit
aggregates had been such that the threat of a crunch could not
be wholly discounted.

That was an additional reason--although

-65

4/29/69

he believed secondary to the longer-term considerations--for
not adding further restraint to that which had been cumulating
since the beginning of the year.
Mr. Bopp noted that even keel would be operative for most
of the period between now and the next meeting.

He favored the

directive with the modifications suggested by Messrs. Hayes and
Mitchell.
In a concluding comment Mr. Bopp said he was not sanguine
about voluntary credit restraint programs.

They presupposed

greater wisdom than the System might have as to what was
"productive" credit.

He was reminded of the history of the

real bills doctrine.

Not every take-over was "unproductive" in

real terms.

Not every borrowing to purchase goods and services,

especially those in short supply, was productive in real terms
or noninflationary.

Selective credit controls might appear a

tempting road to some; to him they were a slithery path to be
avoided if possible.
Mr. Kimbrel reported that voluntary credit restraint
by major banks had been the subject of considerable corridor
comment at the recent spring council meeting of the American
Bankers Association at White Sulphur Springs.

The bankers

hoped that the Federal Reserve System would provide a crutch
for declining to make loans.

He was not unmindful of the fact

4/29/69

-66

that such an approach might be good in theory and could produce
prompt results.

For his part, however, before advancing such

a suggestion for consideration by the Board of Governors, he
had asked his staff to refresh his memory about the short
comings experienced in the last effort at voluntary credit
restraint.

Pending the results of that staff work, he associated

himself with the views expressed by Mr. Bopp.
Mr. Kimbrel then noted that member banks in the Sixth
District apparently had come under some increasing pressure in
March and the first half of April.

However, the pressure had

been relatively mild and fairly well confined to a few of the
larger banks.

Although member bank borrowing increased some

what, the amount during the week ended April 23 averaged only
$48 million and was confined to a relatively few banks.

On

the other hand, purchases of Federal funds averaged in the
$500-$575 million range during March and the first half of
April.
That the pressure had not been great, however, was
suggested by the excess of sales of Federal funds over purchases
for the District as a whole, Mr. Kimbrel continued.

Most of the

funds were coming from the country banks, with Florida account
ing for three-fifths of the total.

Deposit growth continued in

March in contrast to the national pattern.

Early April showed

-67

4/29/69
further expansion.

Loan growth continued strong, with liquida

tion of investments confined fairly well to the large banks.
Mr. Kimbrel remarked that on April 1 the District's
Tennessee member banks had been freed from certain interest
rate restrictions that had handicapped them in competing for
time deposits.

Not only had Tennessee banks been limited as

to what interest rates they could charge; they also had been
limited as to what they could pay.

Thus, they had not been

able to compete effectively for large-denomination CD's nor to
offer competitive rates for consumer-type CD's.

The banks had

responded to the new legislation permitting them to pay rates
equivalent to those set forth in Regulation Q by immediately
offering consumer-type CD's and bidding for large-denomination
CD's.

One result was an increase in outstanding CD's at large

Sixth District banks as a group for the first time in several
months.
Mr. Kimbrel said he wished he could report that there
was more evidence in the nonfinancial news from the Sixth
District that major pressures were being placed upon the expan
sion.

That simply was not the case.

Nonfarm employment might

have slowed down a little in March, according to incomplete
data, but construction activity remained strong, as did most
measures of income and spending.

-68

4/29/69

There was little he could add to what was being said
today about the national economic scene, Mr. Kimbrel observed.
He had been cheered by the good news that the wholesale prices
of industrial commodities rose only one-tenth of 1 per cent
from March to April.

Even though lumber and plywood prices

were almost entirely responsible for the slowdown, any slowdown
was welcome.
Under those conditions, there seemed to Mr. Kimbrel to
be no alternative to keeping as tight a rein as possible under
the circumstances.

He hoped that the Committee would not,

either intentionally or unintentionally, lighten the pressure.
With the Treasury refunding and even keel considerations, that
might be hard to do.

During the period when the System was

free, he would like to see a focus on keeping money market
rates in the upper range of those specified in the blue book
and invoking the proviso clause promptly in the event that
bank credit appeared to be stronger than projected.
Mr. Kimbrel said he would be willing to leave construc
tion of the directive in the hands of others, hoping again that
any errors in implementing it would be on the side of restraint.
Mr. Francis commented that total demand for goods and
services had remained excessive with resultant upward pressure
on prices.

There were few encouraging figures in that respect.

4/29/69

-69

The recent data, including the jump of prices in March, should
simply reinforce the System's determination to follow a course
of monetary action that would slow inflation.
There was considerable evidence from past experience
that monetary actions influenced economic activity with a lag,
Mr. Francis observed.

Consequently, the Committee should not

become disturbed that total spending and inflation had not yet
slowed much in response to the tighter monetary stance of the
first quarter.

Much of the effect of the first-quarter actions

would be felt later if reacceleration could be avoided, as
possibly presaged by April developments and any forthcoming
even keel.

Today, the Committee needed to determine what

monetary actions in the immediate future would be conducive
to desirable growth of total spending and real product two
quarters or so from now.
Mr. Francis thought the System's actions in the first
quarter, as measured by the rate of expansion in the money
supply, bank reserves, and the monetary base, had been appropri
ate.

The money supply, after growing at about 7 per cent annual

rate from January 1967 to July 1968, increased at about a 5 per
cent rate from July to December and at a 2.3 per cent rate in
the first three months of this year.

Slowing in the demand

deposit component was somewhat greater.

That was a policy of

4/29/69

-70-

gradualism in view of the so-far unrelenting inflation problem
with which the System had to deal and in view of a trend growth
of money of about 2-1/2 per cent per year.
As to the future course of action, it seemed to
Mr. Francis that if the Committee desired to have reasonable
assurance that the rate of growth of total spending during the
last half of the year would be held to about a 5 or 6 per
cent rate, as compared to the excessive 7-1/2 per cent rate
of the past two quarters, it should undertake to hold the
growth of monetary aggregates to relatively low rates for the
next six months.
Mr. Francis thought it was desirable that the Committee
consider a time horizon of as much as three months since it was
not practical, and probably not desirable, to ask the Desk to
achieve targets in terms of so short a period as three or four
weeks.

Of course, as the Committee met each three or four

weeks it should reconsider the target each time and restate it
in terms of three months or longer.
Mr. Francis said studies at the St. Louis Reserve Bank
indicated that, if the money stock were to be unchanged from
the first to the second quarter and thereafter increased at a
2.5 per cent annual rate, total spending would most likely slow
from the recent 7-1/2 per cent rate to about a 6 to 6-1/2 per cent

4/29/69

-71

rate in the second quarter and further to a 5 to 5-1/2 per cent
rate or less in the last half.

He suggested that the System

control Federal Reserve credit, the monetary base, and member
bank reserves so as to cause the money stock to follow such a
course.
Limiting the growth rate of money to zero from the first
to the second quarter and then to 2-1/2 per cent would be only a
moderately tight policy judged in terms of experience,
Mr. Francis continued.

For nine months in 1966 the stock of

money had been on a virtual plateau.

From that action the

Committee had achieved a needed, although unfortunately
unsustained, deceleration in spending.

In the twelve years

from 1953 to 1964 money grew at an average 1.8 per cent rate.
If the System should follow a policy of no growth in
the monetary aggregates for a limited time, followed by moderate
expansion, Mr. Francis thought it should not be concerned if
initially there was not much abatement of the inflation in the
early stages of deceleration of total spending.

Also, if the

demand for loan funds declined with the slowing in total spending
as it usually did, the System should not interfere with the
resultant decline of interest rates.
In conclusion, Mr. Francis said, it seemed to him that
policy in the first quarter was appropriate.

However, he was

-72

4/29/69

concerned over the marked rise in money during April.

Some of

the rise was probably a temporary fluctuation in the data, but he
was disturbed, though not surprised, to note that other System
actions more than offset the effect of the increase in reserve
requirements.

Also, it now appeared that, with the recent rise

in Government demand deposits, and if the Committee encumbered
itself with even keel considerations, there was a strong possi
bility that monetary aggregates would rise again in May.

Adding

to his concerns were statements in the blue book that "The System
is expected to supply a substantial volume of reserves over the
next three weeks,"

and ".

.

. it is quite possible that a

strong demand pull would be exerted on monetary aggregates.

In

this event, bank credit and money supply in May could turn out
to be stronger than projected. . ."
As for policy, Mr. Francis suggested a firm resolve to
stop now the rapid monetary expansion of April.

Money should be

kept on a plateau near $195 billion for the next three months
with a view to attaining a growth of total spending at about a
5-1/2 per cent rate in the last half of 1969.

In order to pre

vent money from rising, the monetary base should be kept at
about $77 billion.

He felt that this was one period when it

was so important that monetary restraint be imposed that even
keel considerations should be secondary.

4/29/69

-73Mr. Francis said he strongly endorsed Mr. Bopp's comments

with reference to additional voluntary credit restraint programs.
Mr. Robertson said he would summarize the remarks he had
prepared and ask that the full text be included in the record.
then summarized the following statement:
Given the fact that we are once again in an even
keel period, a vote to keep monetary policy basically
unchanged is in order. But, in view of the infla
tionary climate that still surrounds us, I think we
should want the Manager to keep conditions as tight
as he could within that even keel range.
The sharp wholesale and retail price increases,
continued strong expansion of private demand, and
persisting inflationary expectations all argue for
capturing and holding every bit of financial
restraint we have been able to achieve. The addition
al tightening actions taken on both the monetary and
fiscal side since our last meeting may have given
public policy a little more grip on the situation, but
business momentum seems too strong to be brought
under control easily or quickly.
Accordingly, I would like to see the Manager
hold member bank borrowings around the billion-plus
level recently reached, and keep the funds rate well
above 7 per cent. Furthermore, I would favor his
running these measures even tighter if needed to
counterbalance any tendency for the three-month
bill to fall significantly below 6 per cent, for
the latter rate movement might begin to permit
significant bank CD sales once again--and that, in
combination with the bond market rally we have already
seen, could foster a renewed sense of credit accomoda
tion that would be distinctly counter-productive. I
am prepared to hold the line from now until our next
meeting, but I want it to be a tough line that we are
holding.
With these views in mind, I would be willing to
to vote for the draft directive as suggested by the
staff.

He

4/29/69

-74Mr. Robertson added that the change in the draft directive

proposed by Mr. Hayes and some of the other suggested changesincluding the shift to a one-way proviso in the second paragraph
were acceptable to him.
Chairman Martin said he agreed that an even keel posture
was called for in the period immediately ahead.

He favored

maintaining about the recent degree of pressure.

Although one

could not be sure, he was inclined to think the System's policy
was on the right course, and that patience was required at this
juncture.
The Chairman then noted that while he had been prepared
to accept the directive as drafted by the staff, he thought the
change suggested by Mr. Hayes was an improvement.

He also

agreed that there was a problem with respect to the phrase in
the draft reading "partly as a result of temporary factors."
If the Committee wanted to include a more detailed statement
about the April developments, he thought the modification
suggested by Mr. Brimmer would be appropriate.

Alternatively,

the Committee might want to adopt the language Mr. Mitchell had
suggested.

He personally would have some question about the

formulation Mr. Coldwell had proposed.
Mr. Brimmer observed that he was prepared to accept the
directive in the form submitted by the staff, and had made his

-75

4/29/69

suggestion for revision simply because the question had been
raised.

In any case, he would not favor the language

Mr. Mitchell had proposed.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that either his own suggested
language or Mr. Brimmer's would be acceptable to him.
Chairman Martin asked whether there would be any objec
tion to accepting the changes proposed by Messrs. Hayes and
Brimmer, and none was heard.
The Chairman then noted that the remaining open question
with respect to the directive was the choice between the two
way proviso clause shown in the draft and the one-way clause
Mr. Mitchell had proposed.
Mr. Hayes expressed the view that a two-way clause would
be preferable.

As he understood it, those who favored a one-way

clause were concerned about the April bulge and were seeking to
tighten the instruction for firming should a reversal not devel
op.

In his judgment, however, that objective would be better

served by retention of the two-way clause.

For example, if bank

credit appeared to be growing at a 2 or 3 per cent annual rate in
May, a two-way clause such as was contained in the staff draft
presumably would be implemented--subject to the constraint of
the Treasury financing--since such growth would represent a
significant deviation from the projection for a decline in May

4/29/69

-76

at an annual rate of 2 to 5 per cent.

On the other hand,

growth at a 2 or 3 per cent rate could be interpreted as a
moderation from the April rate, and thus would not necessarily
call for implementation of a clause of the type suggested by
Mr. Mitchell.
Mr. Mitchell observed that a two-way clause was accept
able to him.
Mr. Robertson commented that he also would find a two
way clause acceptable, so long as the Manager understood the
Committee's intent.
Mr. Hayes then said that he would add his support to
Mr. Bopp's comments regarding a voluntary credit restraint
program.

New York banks had been interested in having the

Federal Reserve provide them with a crutch for some time, but
he would be reluctant to see the System follow such a course,
essentially for the reasons Mr. Bopp had mentioned.
Chairman Martin then suggested that the Committee vote
on a directive consisting of the staff's draft with the changes
that Messrs. Hayes and Brimmer had proposed.
By unanimous vote, the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York was author
ized and directed, until otherwise
directed by the Committee, to execute
transactions in the System Account in
accordance with the following current
economic policy directive:

4/29/69

-77-

The information reviewed at this meeting suggests
that expansion in real economic activity has moderated
only slightly since the fourth quarter of 1968. At
the same time, substantial upward pressures on prices
and costs are persisting. Long-term interest rates have
generally declined in recent weeks, but most short-term
rates have risen somewhat. In the first quarter of the
year bank credit changed little on average and the
money supply grew at a sharply reduced rate. In early
April both measures increased substantially, influenced
in part by large tax-date borrowing and deposit bulges
around Easter. The outstanding volume of large-denomi
nation CD's has continued to decline and there was a
net outflow of consumer-type time and savings deposits
from banks and other thrift institutions in the first
half of April. A sizable deficit reemerged in the
U. S. balance of payments on the liquidity basis in the
first
quarter but the balance on the official settle
ments basis remained in surplus as a result of large
inflows of Euro-dollars. In this situation, it is the
policy of the Federal Open Market Committee to foster
financial conditions conducive to the reduction of
inflationary pressures, with a view to encouraging a
more sustainable rate of economic growth and attain
ing reasonable equilibrium in the country's balance
of payments.
To implement this policy, while taking account
of the forthcoming Treasury refunding, System open
market operations until the next meeting of the
Committee shall be conducted with a view to maintain
ing the prevailing firm conditions in money and short
term. credit markets; provided, however, that operations
shall be modified, to the extent permitted by the
Treasury refunding, if bank credit appears to be
deviating significantly from current projections.
Chairman Martin then noted that the final report of the
Joint Treasury-Federal Reserve Study of the U. S. Government
Securities Market had been distributed to the Committee on

-78

4/29/69
1/
March 21, 1969.

A memorandum from Mr. Maisel entitled

"Recommendation on Report of Treasury-Federal Reserve Study of
the U. S. Government Securities Market" 2/ had also been
distributed.

In his memorandum Mr. Maisel had suggested that

before the report was published some changes were needed in
general, but particularly in connection with the discussion of
possible outright System operations in

Federal agency securities.

Mr. Maisel had also suggested that the recommendation in the
report concerning agencies not be adopted but that instead a
new committee be established to make recommendations as to
whether or not broad public policy objectives would be enhanced
by outright operations in Federal agency issues.
Chairman Martin observed that the Steering Committee had
been working on the report for a long time and his own inclina
tion was to publish it as soon as practicable.

While he was not

opposed to a further study by a new committee, he noted that a
good deal of information had already been assembled on the
subject of the Federal agency market.

Accordingly, if the Open

Market Committee so desired, the next step might be to consider
whether experimental operations in agency issues should be

1/ A copy of this report has been placed in the files of the
Committee.
2/ A copy of this memorandum, distributed on April 8, 1969,
has been placed in the files of the Committee.

-79

4/29/69

authorized for the purpose of gaining the kind of experience that
would be useful in making a judgment on the longer-run desirabil
ity of such operations.

However, there had not yet been an

opportunity to discuss the subject with the new Administration.
For that reason he would suggest that the Committee defer
consideration of the question until its meeting scheduled for
May 27. in the expectation that that would provide an opportunity
for Mr. Robertson and himself to explore the matter with the new
Treasury officials.
Mr. Maisel said he had no objection to a postponement of
the Committee's discussion.

He added that it had been his

intention that the new study committee he had recommended would
make its report within a month or two.

He believed that the

Steering Committee's report needed editing to make clear that
it dealt only with questions of the technical functioning of
the market.

He felt that the publication of the report in its

present form could do serious harm to the Federal Reserve,
particularly since some critics might conclude that the System
was tending to give undue weight to problems of technical market
functioning in its decisions on what were far broader public
policy questions.
Mr. Daane agreed that the discussion of possible outright
operations by the System in Federal agency issues should be post
poned until the matter could be discussed with the new Treasury

-80

4/29/69
officials.

However, he demurred from the view that the Steering

Committee, of which he was a member, had not considered the
public policy aspects of the subject.

It had done so in terms of

both specific System objectives and the general public interest.
Mr. Hayes, who was also a member of the Steering
Committee, expressed views similar to those of Mr. Daane.
At Chairman Martin's invitation, Mr. Axilrod outlined a
number of possible changes in the Steering Committee's report
which he thought might go some distance in accommodating
Mr. Maisel's objections to the manner in which the subject of
agency issues was treated.

For example, he noted, the statement

concerning the more general considerations relating to System
operations in Federal agency securities, for which no detailed
analysis was given in the body of the report, might be eliminated.
Also, certain language changes could be made in the statement of
conclusions regarding operations in agencies that would be consis
tent with the specific focus of that part of the report.
Mr. Mitchell indicated that while he had no objection to
such editorial changes, he did have reservations about the
propriety of editing the report of the Steering Committee,
particularly since several members of that Committee were no
longer associated with the Treasury or the Federal Reserve.

-81

4/29/69

Mr. Daane commented that he would want to look very care
fully at any proposed changes, since the report had already been
approved by the Steering Committee.
Mr. Robertson said he thought the report was useful,
and he had no objections to changes of the type Mr. Axilrod had
outlined.

However, in his judgment what was now needed was

action to authorize experimental System transactions in Federal
agency issues for the purpose of gaining experience.

He hoped

to distribute a memorandum on that subject to the Committee
before the next meeting.

1/

Mr. Hayes said he had substantial reservations concern
ing the wisdom of System operations in Federal agency securities,
at least in the near future.

Although he agreed that the

question should now be explored with the new Treasury officials,
he recalled that there had been little enthusiasm for the idea
among either System or Treasury officials serving on the
Steering Committee.

At the time of their review, members of

the Steering Committee had indicated that certain of their
technical reservations would be reduced if individual Federal
agencies were to consolidate their new issues into fewer but
larger offerings.

Such consolidation would make larger and

1/ Mr. Robertson's memorandum was distributed to the
Committee on May 5, 1969. A copy has been placed in the
Committee's files.

4/29/69

-82

more tradeable blocks of individual issues available in

the

market and would thus reduce the risk that System operations
would have undesired effects on prices.

For the present, he

favored publication of the Steering Committee report as soon
as feasible, bearing in mind that such publication had already
been long delayed.
The members then discussed the precise responsibility
of the Federal Open Market Committee for the Steering Commit
tee's report.

Chairman Martin suggested that the editorial

changes being drafted by Mr. Axilrod should be circulated to
the Steering Committee for its approval.1/ He (Chairman
Martin) proposed that, contingent upon such approval, the
Federal Open Market Committee authorize the publication of
the Steering Committee's report.
There were no objections to the Chairman's proposal.
It was agreed that the next meeting of the Committee
would be held on Tuesday, May 27,

1969,

at 9:30 a.m.

Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary

1/ Copies of a memorandum from Mr. Axilrod on this subject
were distributed to the Steering Committee, and for information
to the members of the Open Market Committee, on May 1, 1969.
A copy has been placed in the Open Market Committee's files.

ATTACHMENT A

CONFIDENTIAL (FR)

April 28, 1969

Draft of Current Economic Policy Directive for Consideration by the
Federal Open Market Committee at its Meeting on April 29, 1969
The information reviewed at this meeting suggests that
expansion in real economic activity has moderated slightly since
the fourth quarter of 1968, while substantial upward pressures
on prices and costs are persisting. Long-term interest rates
have generally declined in recent weeks, but most short-term rates
have risen somewhat. In the first quarter of the year bank cred
it changed little on average and the money supply grew at a
sharply reduced rate, but in early April both measures increased
substantially, partly as a result of temporary factors. The
outstanding volume of large-denomination CD's has continued to
decline and there was a net outflow of consumer-type time and
savings deposits from banks and other thrift institutions in the
first half of April. A sizable deficit reemerged in the U. S.
balance of payments on the liquidity basis in the first quarter
but the balance on the official settlements basis remained in
surplus as a result of large inflows of Euro-dollars. In this
situation, it is the policy of the Federal Open Market Commit
tee to foster financial conditions conducive to the reduction of
inflationary pressures, with a view to encouraging a more
sustainable rate of economic growth and attaining reasonable
equilibrium in the country's balance of payments.
To implement this policy, while taking account of the
forthcoming Treasury refunding, System open market operations
until the next meeting of the Committee shall be conducted with
a view to maintaining the prevailing firm conditions in money
and short-term credit markets; provided, however, that opera
tions shall be modified, to the extent permitted by the
Treasury refunding, if bank credit appears to be deviating
significantly from current projections.