View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MEMORANDUM OF DISCUSSION

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held
in the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System in Washington, D. C.,
PRESENT:

Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.
Mr.

on Monday, April 17, 1972, at 4:30 p.m.

Burns, Chairman
Hayes, Vice Chairman
Brimmer
Coldwell
Daane
Eastburn
MacLaury
Maisel
Mitchell
Robertson
Sheehan
Winn

Messrs. Francis, Heflin, Mayo, and Swan, Alternate
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee

Messrs. Morris, Kimbrel, and Clay, Presidents of
the Federal Reserve Banks of Boston, Atlanta,
and Kansas City, respectively
Mr. Holland, Secretary
Mr. Broida, Deputy Secretary
Messrs. Altmann and Bernard, Assistant
Secretaries
Mr. Hackley, General Counsel
Mr. Partee, Senior Economist
Mr. Axilrod, Economist (Domestic Finance)
Messrs. Boehne, Bryant, Green, Hersey,
and Hocter, Associate Economists
Mr. Holmes, Manager, System Open Market Account
Mr. Melnicoff, Deputy Executive Director,
Board of Governors
Mr. O'Connell, General Counsel, Board of
Governors
Messrs. Keir and Pierce, Advisers, Division of
Research and Statistics, Board of Governors

-2

4/17/72

Mr. Wendel, Chief, Government Finance Section,
Division of Research and Statistics, Board
of Governors
Miss Eaton, Open Market Secretariat Assistant,
Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors
Messrs. Parthemos, Taylor, Scheld, Tow, and
Craven, Senior Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of Richmond, Atlanta,
Chicago, Kansas City, and San Francisco,
respectively
Messrs. Bodner and Nelson, Vice Presidents,
Federal Reserve Banks of New York and
Minneapolis, respectively
Mr. Garvy, Economic Adviser, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York
Mrs. Greenwald, Economist, Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston
Chairman Burns noted that at its meeting of March 21, 1972,
the Committee had deferred discussion of three matters.

He had

called today's meeting, in advance of that planned for tomorrow,
to insure that there would be adequate time for discussion of
those matters.
Turning to the first of the items in question, the Chairman
noted that the Secretariat had distributed two memoranda regarding
proposed procedures for making historical Committee records avail

1/
able to the public.

He asked Mr. Broida to comment.

Mr. Broida said the Secretariat recommended that it be
authorized to make certain historical records of the Committee
available for inspection by interested persons through the last
year for which FOMC minutes had been released--at present, 1966.

1/ Copies of these memoranda, which were dated March 14 and
April 11, 1972, have been placed in the Committee's files.

-3

4/17/72

As noted in the March 14 memorandum, such action had been contemplated
for a long time but the matter was being raised now because

a specific

request had been received from Professor Karl Brunner for access to
such records.
Mr. Broida noted that the present recommendation, described
in the April 11 memorandum, called for making records available on
a more limited basis than proposed earlier.

The change had been

made in light of reactions by some Committee members to the original
The Secretariat suggested that it be authorized to make
1/
available the so-called "Group I documents"--mainly the green
and
proposal.

2/
blue

3/
books, eventually the red books,

and their predecessor and

successor documents, if any; and the weekly and monthly reports of
the Manager, but not those of the Special Manager.
In reply to a question by Mr, Mitchell, Mr. Broida said
the Special Manager's reports were not included because they might
from time to time contain sensitive passages--for example, confi
dential information relating to the internal affairs of foreign
central banks--of the sort that had been withheld when Committee
minutes were released.

Any such passages could be identified only

by reading through all such reports, and it did not seem desirable

1/ The report, "Current Economic and Financial Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.
2/ The report, "Monetary Aggregates and Money Market Conditions,"
prepared for the Committee by the Board's staff.
3/ The report, "Current Economic Comment by District," prepared
for the Committee by the staff. This report was initiated in
May 1970.

4/17/72
to devote scarce staff resources to that work at present,since no
requests for access to the Special Manager's reports had been
received.
Mr. Daane said he had some reservations about making the
staff reports--particularly the blue book--public at this time.
He wondered whether the blue book might not be subject to misin
terpretation if users were not fully informed regarding the manner
in which it was used by the Committee.
Mr. Brimmer remarked that he had talked with Professor
Brunner last week about the kinds of materials which he would like
to examine.

While Mr. Brunner had not gone into great detail on

the subject, it was clear that his interest lay in the area of
domestic monetary policy rather than foreign currency operations
and that he would want to have access to the blue books as well as
other regular staff reports relating to that area.

He (Mr. Brimmer)

would not anticipate a problem of the kind that concerned
Mr. Daane since the staff reports in question would be used in
conjunction with the minutes.

The decision to release the minutes

had been the really important one; to make the staff reports
available would be simply to fill out the record.
Mr. Brimmer added that the staff had first begun preparing
a report known as the blue book in the fall of 1965.

Since the

last meeting of the Committee he had examined samples of the

-5

4/17/72

predecessor documents to both the blue and green books and had
concluded that their release would be appropriate.
Chairman Burns observed that to the extent those earlier
documents differed in form from those the staff was currently
preparing, any one consulting them might draw mistaken inferences
about the nature of the current reports.

However, that consideration

could be taken to support a shorter lag in the release of the staff
materials rather than a longer lag.
Mr. Maisel remarked that release of the documents in question
would facilitate studies of the conduct of monetary policy by
economic researchers.

Such studies could be of great benefit to

the System and he thought they should be encouraged.
Mr. Morris agreed with Mr. Maisel.

He added that scholars

probably would find it difficult to understand some parts of the
Committee's policy deliberations as reported in the minutes unless
they had access to the underlying staff documents.
Mr. Robertson commented that release of the staff documents
would clearly be consistent with the spirit of the Public Informa
tion Act.

Personally, he would be prepared to make public not

only the documents covered by the Secretariat's recommendations
but also other Committee materials, withholding only materials
that would reveal information received in confidence from foreign
central banks and governments or that might damage the nation's
international relations.

4/17/72
Mr. Coldwell noted that under the letter of the Public
Information Act release of the documents was not legally required
since one of the statutory exemptions related to internal com
munications, such as inter-agency and intra-agency memoranda.
Messrs. Heflin and Francis expressed the view that the
course the staff recommended was in the public interest.
Mr. Daane said he should note that in his judgment the
staff's present recommendations were much better than those they
had made earlier.
Chairman

Burns remarked that the sentiment of the Committee

appeared to be in favor of approving the recommendations contained
in the staff memorandum of April 11.
The Secretariat's recommendations
for making historical Committee records
available to the public, as contained
in the memorandum dated April 11, 1972,
were approved.
The Chairman then noted that a staff committee consisting
of Messrs. Axilrod, Scheld, and Sternlight, which had been appointed
at the FOMC meeting of January 11, 1972, to study certain issues
relating to repurchase agreements, had submitted its report on

1/
March 7, 1972.

He asked Mr.

Axilrod, who had served as chairman,

to summarize the recommendations of the staff committee.
Mr. Axilrod said the staff committee unanimously recommended
that the FOMC amend the language of paragraph 1(c) of its continuing

1/ A copy of this report has been placed in the files of the
Committee.

-7

4/17/72

authority directive to provide that, unless otherwise expressly
authorized, interest rates on repurchase agreements should be
established by competitive bidding.

At present RP rates were

set by the Desk, subject to the provision of the continuing au
thority directive that they should not be less than the discount
rate or the latest auction rate on three-month Treasury bills, which
ever is lower.

While no upper limit was specified, in practice

RP rates were not ordinarily set higher than the discount rate.
The staff committee thought that the use of an auction technique
would have two main advantages:

It would minimize the possibility

that changes in RP rates would be viewed as signaling future changes
in the discount rate, and it would virtually eliminate the element
of subsidy now involved when the discount rate was low relative
to short-term market rates.
Secondly, Mr. Axilrod continued, the staff committee recom
mended that, if an auction approach were adopted,repurchase agreements
be authorized with both bank and nonbank dealers rather than, as at
present, with nonbank dealers alone.

Bank dealers had been growing

in relative importance in recent years and their positions in
Government securities now amounted to roughly 25 per cent of total
dealer positions.

While the staff committee was unanimous in that

recommendation also, it did not consider the issue to be of major
importance.

-8

4/17/72

Mr. Axilrod noted that a draft of an amendment to para
graph 1(c) of the continuing authority directive, embodying the
two proposed changes, was shown in an appendix to the report.

He

went on to say that the staff committee also had been asked to
review the manner in which the RP instrument had been used by the
Desk.

The evidence indicated that use of the RP instrument had

increased considerably in recent years.

While some reasons for

that development were presented in the staff report, the basic
However, the staff committee

causes were not wholly clear.

believed that open market operations probably could be conducted
with somewhat less use of RP's than during the past year.

At

the same time, it believed that the instrument was serving a
useful purpose in operations, and there appeared to be no
persuasive reasons for abandoning it.
Chairman Burns asked what the consequences might be if
RP's were in fact discontinued.
Mr. Axilrod replied that the market probably would function
less efficiently, in the sense that day-to-day fluctuations in
rates would be greater.

RP's typically were used to meet large

reserve needs that were expected to be highly temporary, and when
they were made the market was aware that the reserves supplied
would be withdrawn again shortly.

If such temporary needs were

met by buying securities outright, dealers involved would not have
the assurance that the large reduction in their positions resulting
from the System's purchases was temporary, and they might well adjust

-9

4/17/72

prices and yields more sharply than if they knew the securities were
shortly to be sold back to them.
Mr. Robertson said he concurred in the staff's suggestion
for making less use of repurchase agreements.

When the FOMC had

first authorized RP's it had indicated that they were to be used
sparingly.

In his judgment, use had not been sparing.

Mr. Mitchell asked whether the staff would expect the Desk to
announce in advance of each auction the amount of RP's to be made.
Mr. Axilrod replied that while such a procedure might have
advantages, the issue seemed to be one of operating technique rather
than of principle.
Mr. Holmes said he was not persuaded that the Desk should
commit itself to making pre-determined amounts of RP's.

Such a course

was likely to result in large movements in RP rates, and sometimes in
lower rates than desirable.
Mr. Daane asked the Manager for his views with respect to the
staff committee's recommendations in general.
Mr. Holmes said he thought the report was a persuasive one
and that the Committee should proceed to experiment with the sug
gested auction technique.

However, he was not sure that the tech

nique would completely eliminate effects of RP transactions on
market expectations.

In any particular auction it was inevitable-

and reasonable--that some, and perhaps most, dealers would be shut
out even though they had bid at what they considered a reasonable

-10

4/17/72

rate--perhaps one at which they had bid successfully in a previous
auction.

And while the System presumably would not announce the

average price set in the auction, market participants would have
a good idea of rates,and the negative reaction of unsuccessful
bidders might have a market effect--particularly

in

tight money

periods.
Mr.

Holmes noted that the staff committee recommended that

RP auctions be open to bank as well as nonbank dealers on equity
grounds.

While he agreed that the extensive use of RP's in recent

years had at times discriminated against bank dealers, he thought
the equity situation was more complicated.

Dealer banks, of course,

had direct access to the Federal funds market and to the discount
window, and they had the tax and loan account payment privilege in
certain Treasury financings.

Perhaps more important, however, was

the ability of a dealer bank to issue "due bills"--that is,
bank's own promises to deliver a specific issue of

the

Treasury bills.

While System RP's had financed from 3 to 7 per cent of nonbank
dealer positions in recent years, due bills had financed from 30
to 40 per cent of bank dealer positions.
In light of those considerations, Mr. Holmes continued,
he had some reservations about opening RP auctions to bank dealers.
However, he saw no objections to undertaking an experiment.

Perhaps

it would be found that bank dealers would not bid aggressively in
such auctions.

-11

4/17/72

Chairman Burns asked whether the inclusion of bank dealers
might not be interpreted as the extension of a special privilege
to the banks involved.

If so, it might be desirable to proceed

cautiously.
Mr. Holmes replied that the inclusion of bank dealers might
well be given such an interpretation.

In any case, the question

of the relationship between bank and nonbank dealers was complicated
by the fact that the Treasury was now considering a request from
a nonbank dealer for permission to obtain the tax and loan account
payment privilege through its clearing bank.

The dealer could then

participate in a Treasury financing with payment to the tax and
loan account in its clearing bank and be compensated by that bank
for the temporary use of the funds.

It was his understanding that

an inquiry had just been received from the Treasury as to whether
or not the Board would interpret such an arrangement as calling
for payment of interest on demand deposits prohibited by Regula
tion Q.

If that was not the Board's interpretation and the arrange

ment was approved by the Treasury, the competitive position of
nonbank dealers would be improved.

That might be an appropriate

occasion for the System to open RP auctions to bank dealers.

Mr. Mitchell remarked that he did not think bank dealers
would consider the right to participate in RP auctions to be very
much of a privilege, considering the number of dealers against
whom they would be bidding.

-12-

4/17/72

Mr. Daane said he would favor experimenting with an auction
approach of the kind recommended by the staff.

However, he was not

sure the auctions should be opened to bank dealers, considering the
alternative sources of funds available to them.

There seemed to be

no necessity to include bank dealers, at least at the outset, and
they could always be included at a later time should that appear
desirable.
Mr. Brimmer asked whether an adequate volume of bids would
be expected if the auctions were limited to nonbank dealers.
Mr. Holmes replied that the volume of bidding would vary
from time to time, since it would depend on the dealers' needs
for funds and the costs of alternative sources.
Mr. Mayo said he was inclined to agree with Mr. Mitchell.
He did not think that borrowing at the discount window should be
considered an alternative source of funds for bank dealers, since
banks with dealer departments in most cases keep the operations of
those departments separate from those of the rest of the bank and
do not borrow at the discount window to finance their dealer positions.
On the whole, the only risk he saw to the inclusion of bank dealers
in the auctions was that of uninformed criticism.
In reply to a question, Mr. Axilrod said the staff committee
had considered the question of possible limitations on the securities
that could be covered by RP's, assuming the auctions were open to
both bank and nonbank dealers.

Two of the three staff members thought

-13

4/17/72

that bank dealers should be permitted to offer only dealer depart
ment securities and not those in the bank's investment portfolio,
and that both bank and nonbank dealers ordinarily should be allowed
to offer securities only from their own positions and not "customer"
securities.
Messrs. Mitchell and Heflin said they would favor such a
limitation.
Mr. MacLaury asked whether the exclusion of customer securi
ties would not be a change from present practice.
Mr. Holmes replied that dealers were now invited to round
up customer securities only when it appeared that the Desk would
otherwise be unable to arrange a sufficient volume of RP's.

The

procedure presumably would be the same under an auction approach.
In reply to a question by Mr. Daane, Mr. Holmes said that
in periods of tight money the use of an auction technique might
produce a ratchet effect, leading to successively higher rates on
RP's.

Whether that would in fact happen could be determined by

experimenting with the technique.
Mr. Kimbrel asked whether the inclusion of dealer banks
would pose a question of equity between those banks and banks
without dealer departments,
Mr. Holmes replied that while such a question might be
raised, he personally would not consider the procedure inequitable

-14

4/17/72

since dealer banks performed a function in making markets for
Government securities.
Mr. Mitchell remarked that enlarging the number of partic
ipants in the auction by including bank dealers would have the
advantage of reducing the subsidy element in the RP rate.
Mr. Robertson said he thought it might well be charged that
the System was extending a special privilege to a few large banks.
Chairman Burns said that superficially, at least, there
would appear to be some validity to such a charge.
Mr. Daane said he thought that opening the auctions to bank
dealers would raise questions of equity not only with respect to
other banks but also with respect to nonbank dealers since, as had
been noted earlier, banks had access to various alternative sources
of funds.
Mr. Maisel observed that if bank dealers had important
advantages over other dealers in obtaining funds they presumably
would not bid aggressively in the RP auctions.
Mr. Robertson said he would not favor permitting bank
dealers to participate in RP auctions at this point since they
might thereby often be able to acquire Federal Reserve funds at
rates below the discount rate.

The Committee could reconsider

the question later, after it had gained experience with the auction
technique.

4/17/72

-15
Mr. MacLaury said it was his understanding that repurchase

agreements were now limited to nonbank dealers mainly because,

with RP rates set by the Desk, it could be said that the System was
subsidizing bank dealers whenever the RP rate was below the discount
rate.

In his opinion, however, if RP rates were market-determined

through competitive bidding, the need for concern on that score
would be eliminated.
In reply to a question, Mr. Axilrod said the staff committee
was not certain about the precise consequences of opening the RP
auctions to bank dealers.

Personally, he would be surprised if

they participated heavily as a regular matter, and he thought the
rates at which they bid would generally be lower than for nonbank
dealers, who did not have direct access to the Federal funds market.
Ordinarily, he would expect competitive bidding to result in an
RP rate a little above the Federal funds rate,
Chairman Burns observed that while he did not feel strongly
about the matter he thought there might be some advantages to per
mitting only nonbank dealers to participate in the RP auctions
initially, without prejudice to the possibility of including bank
dealers at a later point.

He asked whether the staff thought such

a course would create problems.
Messrs.

Axilrod and Holmes responded in the negative.

Mr. Holmes added that the course mentioned would, in fact, simplify
matters from the operational point of view.

-16-

4/17/72

Mr. Hayes said he would favor experimenting with an auction
technique limited to nonbank dealers while reserving judgment with
respect to the desirability of including bank dealers.
The Chairman then remarked that the Committee appeared to
favor experimentation with an auction technique for repurchase
agreements, but sentiment was divided on the desirability of including
bank dealers at the outset.

He suggested that an informal poll be

taken on the latter question.
The poll indicated that a majority of the members favored
excluding bank dealers, at least initially.
By unanimous vote, paragraph 1(c)
of the continuing authority directive
with respect to domestic open market
operations was amended to read as
follows:
To buy U.S. Government securities, obligations that
are direct obligations of, or fully guaranteed as to
principal and interest by, any agency of the United States,
and prime bankers' acceptances with maturities of 6 months
or less at the time of purchase, from nonbank dealers for
the account of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York under
agreements for repurchase of such securities, obligations,
or acceptances in 15 calendar days or less, at rates that,
unless otherwise expressly authorized by the Committee,
shall be determined by competitive bidding, after applying
reasonable limitations on the volume of agreements with
individual dealers; provided that in the event Government
securities or agency issues covered by any such agreement
are not repurchased by the dealer pursuant to the agree
ment or a renewal thereof, they shall be sold in the market
or transferred to the System Open Market Account; and pro
vided further that in the event bankers' acceptances
covered by any such agreement are not repurchased by the
seller, they shall continue to be held by the Federal
Reserve Bank or shall be sold in the open market.

-17

4/17/72

Mr. Coldwell then proposed that the Committee discuss the
suggestion in the staff committee's report that operations might
be conducted with somewhat less use of repurchase agreements than
in the recent past.
Messrs. Hayes and Daane indicated that they did not find
the report to be persuasive on that point.
Mr. Coldwell noted that, according to the staff report, the
Desk had entered into roughly $51 billion of RP's in 1971.

That

figure was substantially above the 1970 volume of $39 billion and
nearly double the $27 billion volume of 1969.

Meanwhile, the

volume of outright transactions declined last year, to about $15.5
billion from about $17.5 billion in 1969 and 1970.

It seemed to

him that the Desk was "meddling" in the market through RP's--that
is, moving in and out to a greater extent than necessary.

He was

disturbed by the implication that the Desk was aiming at highly
precise control of market conditions.

The extensive use of RP's

on Wednesdays, the last day of the statement week, and on Fridays,
just before the weekend, was particularly disturbing in that regard.
Chairman Burns remarked that while he had not studied the
matter closely it was his impression that the Desk was relying a
little too heavily on the RP instrument.

In any case, the sharp

uptrend in the volume of repurchase agreements seemed to indicate
either that RP's were being over-utilized now or that they had
been under-utilized earlier.

-18

4/17/72

Mr. Mitchell said he was not sure such an inference was
warranted.

The volume of RP's probably was most closely related

to the total amount of payments made through the banking system,
and he suspected that figures on the latter for recent years would
show a growth rate about like that for RP's.
Mr. Morris suggested that the step-up in the use of RP's
might be related to growing difficulties in estimating the Treasury's
balance.
Mr. Holmes said he was not sure what factors were most
important.

In his judgment further study of the matter was required.

Mr. Hayes remarked that he would support the proposal for
study, in view of the importance of the question Mr. Coldwell had
raised.
There was general agreement that the staff should study
further the factors underlying the recent increase in the rate of
use of RP's.
Chairman Burns then noted that a memorandum from the Manager,
on the subject of operations in Government agency issues, had been

1/
distributed on March 9, 1972.

He asked Mr. Holmes to comment.

Mr. Holmes observed that operations in agency issues had
proceeded relatively smoothly since they were authorized by the
Committee last August,

and the System's portfolio had been built

1/ A copy of this memorandum has been placed in
files.

the Committee's

-19

4/17/72
up to about $800 million.

There were still some technical problems,

such as the length of time required to complete a go-around, but
they were not serious enough to be disturbing.
However, Mr. Holmes continued, a potential problem was posed
by one of the guidelines governing operations in agencies--number 6,
which limited System holdings of any one issue to 10 per cent of the
amount of the issue outstanding.

That limit had already been reached

for two issues, and System holdings were now 5 per cent or more of
outstandings for another 14 issues.

The Desk was, of course, required

to reject offers of any issue at the limit, even though it might be
priced attractively relative to other issues.
For that reason, Mr. Holmes said, he had recommended in
his memorandum that the Committee revise the guideline in question
to increase the limit on System holdings of individual agency
issues from 10 to 25 per cent of the amount outstanding.

Sub

sequently, however, Mr. Mayo had suggested that if such a change
were made the Committee should concurrently place a 10 per cent
limit on System holdings of the issues of any one agency.

He

(Mr. Holmes) thought that suggestion had considerable merit; it
provided ample leeway for operations while maintaining the principle
that the System should play only a modest role in the market.
Mr. Robertson said the proposed 25 per cent limit struck
him as rather high.

In his judgment some lower limit--such as 20

per cent--would be preferable.

-20

4/17/72
Mr.

Daane concurred in Mr.

Robertson's comment.

In the course of further discussion a number of members
indicated that they favored an amendment to guideline 6 along the
lines of Mr.

Mayo's suggestion.

In response to a question by the

Chairman, a majority expressed a preference for a 20 rather than
a 25 per cent limit on holdings of any individual agency issue.
By unanimous vote, guideline 6 for
the conduct of System operations in
Federal agency issues was amended to
read as follows:
System holdings of any one issue at any one time
will not exceed 20 per cent of the amount of the issue
outstanding. Aggregate holdings of the issues of any
one agency will not exceed 10 per cent of the amount of
outstanding issues of that agency.
Thereupon the meeting adjourned.

Secretary