View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

BOARD

OF GOVERNORS
OF THE

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20551

April

10,

1975

CONFIDENTIAL (FR)
CLASS II FOMC

TO:

Federal Open Market Committee

FROM:

Arthur L.

Broida

In connection with a contemplated discussion at next
week's meeting of the Committee,

there is

enclosed a copy of a

memorandum from the Committee staff, dated today and entitled
"Proposed Procedures With Respect to the Concurrent Resolution."
Also enclosed is a copy of a memorandum prepared in the
Department of Research of the Philadelphia Reserve Bank, dated
April 4, 1975, and entitled "FOMC Response to the Congressional
Resolution on Monetary Policy," which President Eastburn has
asked be distributed to the Committee.

Enclosures

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

CONFIDENTIAL (FR)
CLASS II FOMC
TO:

Federal Open Market Committee

FROM:

The Staff

DATE:

April 10, 1975

SUBJECT: Proposed procedures
with respect to the
concurrent resolution.

This memorandum proposes certain changes in procedures that
the FOMC may wish to consider in light of the concurrent resolution on
monetary policy recently adopted by the Congress.

The full text of the

resolution (H. Con. Res. 133) is shown as attachment A.
The first half of the operative part of the resolution states
the sense of Congress that the Board and the FOMC:

"(1)

pursue policies

in the first half of 1975 so as to encourage lower long-term interest
rates and expansion in the monetary and credit aggregates appropriate
to facilitating prompt economic recovery; and (2) maintain long-run
growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the
economy's long-run potential to increase production, so as to promote
effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate
long-term interest rates."
The second half of the operative part of the resolution goes
on to state that "the Board of Governors shall consult with Congress at
semiannual hearings....about the Board of Governors' and the Federal
Open Market Committee's objectives and plans with respect to the ranges
of growth or diminution of monetary and credit aggregates in the upcoming
twelve months."
The part of the resolution concerned with the substance of
monetary policy in the first half of 1975 does not appear to involve

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

significant questions with respect to Committee procedures.

Growth in

monetary and credit aggregates has rebounded since the early weeks
of the year (when the resolution was being formulated) and the Desk
has already stepped up its purchases of longer-term U.S. Government
securities.

The results of recent policy will be adequately conveyed

through normal reporting of Committee actions in the policy record,
although it may be desirable for the policy record to indicate that--to
the extent consistent with objectives for reserves and the monetary
aggregates--sizable open market purchases of coupon issues were undertaken in an effort to moderate upward pressures on longer-term interest
rates related to exceptionally heavy Treasury and corporate borrowing.
The Committee may also wish to consider the desirability between now
and mid-year of a specific reference to long-term interest rates in the
last paragraph of the directive; such a possible reference is contained
in brackets in the specimen directive shown in attachment B.
Some changes in Committee procedures would appear to be
desirable, however, to take account of the need to consult with Congress
on longer-run objectives for monetary and credit aggregates.

As indicated

above, the specific language refers to objectives in terms of "ranges
of growth or diminution" and to a time period covering the "upcoming
twelve months".
There is nothing in the language to indicate whether growth
ranges should be quantitative or qualitative.

Earlier versions of the

resolution referred to numerical specifications, but the present language
represents a compromise that could encompass either ranges presented in
descriptive language or ranges with numerical bounds.

In the interest

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-3of facilitating communications with Congress, however, the staff
recommends that numerical ranges be presented.
With regard to the width of the range, we would suggest a
relatively limited 2 percentage point spread--e.g. 5 to 7 per cent-although the range might vary depending on the volatility of the
particular aggregate.

Little would be gained, we believe, by utilizing

very wide ranges of, say, 4 to 5 percentage points.

Such wide ranges

would not appear to be responsive to the sense of the resolution.

In

any event, the ranges are subject to continuous review by the System
in light of changing conditions.

The resolution specifically states:

"Nothing in this resolution shall be interpreted to require that such
ranges of growth or diminution be achieved if the Board of Governors and
Open Market Committee determine that they cannot or should not be
achieved because of changing conditions."
A literal reading of the phrase "upcoming 12 months" in the
resolution would appear to require a growth rate that covers 12 months
from the time that the Board consults with Congress.

On the other hand,

there is a good argument for relating monetary growth rates to planning
horizons for fiscal policy (i.e., the fiscal year) or to commonly accepted
periods in business planning or economic forecasting, such as the
calendar year, or years ending with quarter-end months.

A reasonable

compromise under current circumstances would be for the System, at the
present time, to adopt longer-run targets for the year ending March 1976.¹

¹

The
the
for
the

Blue Book would present alternative targets for such a period for
monetary aggregates, and would also include consistent targets
other shorter-run periods as well as for the year as measured from
first quarter of 1975 to the first quarter of 1976.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-4With the Chairman scheduled to testify on May 1 on monetary policy,
such a target would clearly be consistent with the Congressional
resolution.

Moreover, the Committee would be positioned to move its

longer-run target range ahead as time passes to, for example, a year
ending in June or a year ending in September.

It should be observed

that beginning next year the Federal fiscal year will run from October 1
to September 30 of the following calendar year.
While it seems most consistent with other economic information
for the Committee's annual growth targets to refer to years ending with
quarter-end months, that of course does not mean that target ranges
should be reviewed no more than four times a year.

It has been Committee

practice to review longer-run targets at each meeting, though the review
has been more intensive at meetings in which more detailed chart show
projections have been presented.

Continuation of this procedure is

consistent with the Congressional resolution and is, in fact, implicitly
allowed for by the sentence in the resolution, quoted above, that refers
to changing conditions.

Indeed, some changes in the specified growth

ranges are likely to be needed solely on technical grounds, since relationships among the various aggregates will shift with changing interest
differentials and the vagaries of consumer and investor attitudes.
Thus, at each meeting the staff would present alternative
longer-run growth rates for Committee consideration.

When a new quarter-

end month is past, the year could be moved forward by a quarter.

The

Committee would not, of course, be bound to the practice of moving the
target year forward four times per annum.

It may prove to be desirable--

given the incoming flow of new economic information, especially the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

timing of information on the Federal budget--to move the target year
forward less frequently, say, twice a year.

In any event, irrespective

of the particular target period, the specifications adopted would need
to be reviewed and, if necessary, re-adjusted at each meeting.
The concurrent resolution refers to monetary and credit
aggregates in the plural, which also represents a substantial change
from earlier draft versions of the resolution.

The FOMC already sets

longer-run targets for three aggregates--specifically M1, M2, and the
bank credit proxy.

Because there may be unexpected shifts from time

to time among various forms of deposits, and since broader measures of
liquidity have considerable economic significance, the staff recommends
that the Committee set its longer-run targets in terms of an even broader
family of aggregates by the addition of M3, M , and M 5 .
M 3 includes deposits at thrift institutions (as well as
credit union shares).

These deposits are as liquid as the bank time

deposits included in M 2

.

Moreover, deposit flows at thrift institutions

are critical to mortgage market conditions.
M4 is defined as M 2 plus large CD's, and M 5 encompasses M 3
plus large CD's.

Large CD's represent immediately available funds in

the hands of corporations and others.

Thus, they serve the same liquidity

function as other time deposits, and can also--through reserve requirements and the potential reach of Regulation Q--be influenced by Federal
Reserve policy instruments.

The broadest monetary aggregate recommended--

M5--would represent a comprehensive measure of currency plus all deposits
at banks and other financial institutions.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

-6The numerical growth ranges adopted for these several monetary
and credit aggregates would be utilized in the Board's testimony to
Congress in connection with the concurrent resolution.

It would there-

fore also be logical to include them in the FOMC's policy record.

The

record would contain relevant explanatory material, particularly at
times when significant changes were made in the longer-run targets.
As an alternative, the FOMC may wish to consider including
the growth ranges directly in the penultimate paragraph of the directive
since they can be construed as part of the general policy stance described
in that paragraph.

If that were done, the staff believes that the shorter-

run operating targets should also be included as a part of the last paragraph of the directive.

Putting shorter-run targets in the directive

would avoid any possible market confusion that the longer-run growth
ranges apply month-by-month.

It would also make it clear that the FOMC

continues to have both money market and aggregates objectives, and that
it is willing to tolerate relatively wide short-run fluctuations in the
monetary aggregates around a long-term norm.
Use of numerical specifications in the directive would also
eliminate the ambiguities of language in the last paragraph of the
directive whereby, among other things, the span of time referred to with
respect to future and past growth rates for the aggregates is unclear.
The last paragraph would, with specifications included, clearly refer to
the interval between meetings.

A sample draft directive revising the

last two paragraphs to show long and short-run specifications is
attached (attachment B).

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Attachment A

Member)
of
signature
(Original

94th CONGRESS
1st

Sessi

______________________________

on

IN THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES

Mr.

submitted the following concurrent resolution; which was

Rees

referred to the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing

CONCURRENT RESOLUTION
Whereas article

I,

section 8 of the Constitution provides that Congress

shall have the money power,

namely "...to

coin money and regulate

the value thereof";
Whereas Congress established the Federal Reserve Board as its agent,
and delegated to its agent the day-to-day responsibility for managing
the money supply;
Whereas the United States economy is
unemployment and a decline in

now suffering from excessively high

production and the gross national product,

together with inflation;
Whereas the economy's performance in part is

affected by changes in

the rate of growth of the monetary and credit aggregates:
therefore, be it

Now,

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Resolved by the House of Representatives (the Senate concurring),
That it is the sense of Congress that the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System and the Federal Open Market Committee -(1)

pursue policies in the first half of 1975 so as to encourage

lower long term interest rates and expansion in the monetary and
credit aggregates appropriate to facilitating prompt economic
recovery; and
(2) maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates
commensurate with the economy's long run potential to increase
production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long term interest rates.
Pursuant to this resolution, and taking into account the international
flows of funds and conditions in the international money and credit
markets, the Board of Governors shall consult with Congress at semiannual
hearings before the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs of the
Senate and the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing of the House
of Representatives about the Board of Governors' and the Federal Open
Market Committee's objectives and plans with respect to the ranges of
growth or diminution of monetary and credit aggregates in the upcoming
twelve months.

Nothing in this resolution shall be interpreted to require

that such ranges of growth or diminution be achieved if the Board of
Governors and Open Market Committee determine that they cannot or should
not be achieved because of changing conditions.

The Board of Governors

shall report to the Congress the reasons for any such determination
during the next hearings held pursuant to this resolution.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Attachment B

SPECIMEN DIRECTIVE
(Last two paragraphs; growth
ranges shown are purely illustrative)
In light of the foregoing developments, it is the policy of
the Federal Open Market Committee to foster financial conditions conducive to stimulating prompt economic recovery and increased utilization
of the nation's resources, while resisting inflationary pressures and
working toward equilibrium in the country's balance of payments.

For

the 12 month period from March 1975 to March 1976, the following growth
ranges for the major monetary and credit aggregates are presently thought
to be consistent with this objective: M1, 4-7 per cent; M 2 , 9-11; M3,
10-12; M4, 8-10; M5, 7-9; and bank credit proxy, 7-10.
To implement this policy, while taking account of developments
in domestic and international financial markets, the Committee over the
next five weeks seeks to achieve bank reserve and money market conditions
consistent with a weekly average Federal funds rate in a 5¼-6¼ per cent
range and with percentage annual rates of growth during April and May,
on average, ranging between 4 -6

per cent for M1, 7 -9

and 5-7 per cent for the bank credit proxy.

per cent for M 2 ,

[To the extent consistent

with these objectives, open market operations should be conducted in
such a way as to encourage lower long-term interest rates.]

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

April 4,

1975

CONFIDENTIAL (FR)
CLASS II FOMC

TO:

David P. Eastburn

FROM:

Department of Research

SUBJECT:

FOMC RESPONSE TO THE
CONGRESSIONAL RESOLUTION
ON MONETARY POLICY.

INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF CONCLUSIONS
This memorandum lays out a suggested general framework for the
Federal Open Market Committee to respond to the resolution recently
passed by Congress concerning monetary policy.

That resolution brings

to the fore a need for the Committee to reevaluate some of its procedures
for establishing and disclosing policy strategy.

While the Subcommittee

on the Directive will be coming to grips with the fundamental issues of
goals and targets, the Congressional resolution makes it appropriate to
review aspects of these issues at this time.
This memorandum concludes that the resolution represents a useful
affirmation on the part of Congress of the importance of long-term targets
and of the role of Congress as an overseer of the basic objectives and
overall implementation of monetary-policy.

We believe, therefore, that

the FOMC ought to react positively to the basic thrust of the resolution. 1
In addition, we believe that a good-faith response will encourage Congress

In this connection, the staff believes that certain specifics of the
resolution are ill-conceived and counter-productive and these should be
brought to Congressional attention.
In particular, we are concerned with
Congress' apparent misunderstanding of how interest rates are determined.
A detailed discussion of this, however, is beyond the immediate scope of
this memorandum.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

to view specific FOMC criticism of the resolution and suggestions for
improving it as constructive rather than defensive or obstructionist.
As a result of these general conclusions, we make the following
specific recommendations:
1.

That the Committee greet the resolution in the spirit of a
meaningful framework for meeting Congressional objectives.

2.

That the Committee avoid giving any impression of desiring
to evade the intent and spirit of the resolution. In particular, aggregate targets should continue to be set nearly
as specifically as they now are.

3.

That the Committee should adopt the letter and spirit of
the resolution by extending the policy horizon to a full
year.

4.

That the required reports to the Congress reflect the views
of the entire Committee and include dissenting opinions
where appropriate.

GENERAL GUIDELINES
There are a variety of general principles we believe ought to guide
the Committee in its policy procedures.

Two seem particularly relevant to

the Congressional resolution.

Atmosphere of Cooperation
The first of these principles is that the System ought to be as
cooperative as possible in the establishment of a proper Congressional
overview of monetary policy.

Clearly, under the Constitution, Congress

possesses important monetary powers.

Congress has created the Federal

Reserve System to act as its agent in carrying out its monetary policy
responsibilities.

Thus, it is only proper that Congress should attempt

to determine how well its agent carries out delegated duties.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

By adopting a cooperative attitude, the System stands a better
chance of playing a major and constructive role in establishing the
nature and extent of the overview, while at the same time seeing that
the conduct of monetary policy is kept appropriately aloof from political pressures.

Congress seems to be searching for the best way to hold

the Federal Reserve accountable, as evidenced by the looseness of the
wording of the resolution, and would most likely respond favorably to
a positive initiative by the System.
Because of the wide latitude provided to the Committee in interpreting its obligations under the resolution, the practical impact of
the resolution could turn out to be small.

There might be some temptation

to take advantage of its looseness to proceed largely as before.

Thus,

the Committee might respond to the resolution only with great reluctance
and only with further prodding by the Congress.

However, if Congress

were to tire of this struggle, it might be catalyzed into further action.
It could pass even more restrictive legislation that would do neither the
Nation nor the System any good.
Although we recommend a positive response by the System to the general spirit of the resolution, such a response does not imply acceptance
of all its specific provisions.

Indeed, as footnoted on page 1, we believe

there are legitimate objections to parts of the resolution.

But if the

attitude of the Fed is cooperative, Congress probably will be less suspicious of the System's motives in raising objections and the FOMC will be
in better position to play a major role in setting the broad goals of monetary policy and how it should be judged in implementing monetary policy.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Openness of Policymaking
The second general principle is that the System should be as open
as possible about its policies.

Such a stance is consistent with the

characteristics of a democratic society, is responsive to the greater
demand for less secrecy in government, and has potential economic advantages as well.
The issue of disclosing FOMC policy targets goes beyond the narrow
question of whether the letter of the law or of the current resolution
requires the Committee to disclose its targets in an explicit and specific
way.

The real issue is that in our kind of society the presumption should

always favor open government, and that presumption is in sharper focus
now than ever before.

Only if it can be clearly demonstrated that it is

in the nation's best interest should information be withheld.

That is,

the burden of proof rests on those who do not want to disclose information.
It has been argued that timely publication of long-run targets will
(a) worsen the performance of the money markets and make the conduct of
monetary policy more difficult, (b) increase the profit opportunities of
the more sophisticated money-market participants, and (c) confuse the public about policy.

These assertions are largely unsubstantiated, however,

and, therefore, do not make a compelling case for withholding long-run
targets.

In fact, there seems to be more logic on the side of those who

argue that publishing the long-run targets would (a) improve, not worsen,
the performance of money markets, (b) decrease, not increase, the profit
opportunities of the more sophisticated, and (c) enlighten, not confuse,
the public about policy.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

(a)

Disclosure and the performance of financial markets
No one can be certain whether money markets would function better or worse in light of additional information.
Normally, however, more and better information makes
markets more efficient.

In addition, publication of

two-month targets has apparently had no adverse impact
on the functioning of markets.

Moreover, speculation

tends to result from uncertainty.

If market partici-

pants had more information, there would be less undesirable speculation and implementation of monetary
policy could be made easier.

(b)

Disclosure and profit opportunities
Contrary to the view that more information would help
the sophisticated investor to the disadvantage

of the

less sophisticated, the opposite outcome is more likely.
The comparative advantage of the more sophisticated stems
from being able to draw sound conclusions from slim evidence.

Thus, providing more information would probably

be more equitable because information now available in
practice to sophisticated market participants would be
available to all participants.

(c)

Disclosure and public understanding of policy
After a learning period, disclosing longer run targets
would likely provide more, not less, understanding of
policy.

Under present procedures, with only two-month

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

targets published, the public might infer that the Fed's
concern with the aggregates is primarily with short-run
growth and that it does a poor job at achieving this.
Long-run targets, in contrast, are usually easier to
relate to the basic thrust of price and employment policy
and are less difficult to hit.

RECOMMENDED PROCEDURES
With these general principles in mind, we suggest several ways
the FOMC might adapt its current procedures to accommodate the resolution.
We recommend that in following the dictates of the resolution the FOMC
should avoid procedures that could be construed as an attempt to evade the
intent of the resolution.

Thus, the FOMC should not draw back from the

fairly explicit way in which long-run targets are now formulated.

Instead,

it should strive to clarify its targets for the Congress, and to assist
in developing a framework for holding the Fed accountable in hitting its
targets.

Being Specific About Targets
The resolution calls upon the Board of Governors to consult semiannually with the Congress about FOMC objectives for growth of the monetary
or credit aggregates over the ensuing year.

The Congress has apparently

left up to the Committee which of the aggregates it should focus on and
how precise the targets should be.
Targets.

We see no reason why the act of reporting to the Congress

ought to change the aggregates the Committee monitors.

Therefore, until

it is decided on analytical grounds to change aggregates, we recommend the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

FOMC should continue to monitor Ml, M 2 , M 3 , and the Adjusted Credit
Proxy.

Moreover, we recommend that the Committee should continue its

current practice of concentrating most frequently on M 1 and M2, and
should make its reports with this emphasis to the Congress.

The weight

of empirical evidence suggests that these variables are linked to
economic activity more closely than other aggregates.

Furthermore,

introducing too many aggregates may appear as an evasive tactic by the
Federal Reserve to avoid accountability, especially since systematic
evidence seems to suggest that little or no additional information is
obtained by looking at many as opposed to a few aggregates.
Target Ranges.

The resolution also is not explicit about the pre-

cision of the growth rate targets to be reported to Congress.

The reso-

lution requires only a report on ranges of growth targets, without specifying the width of the ranges.

We suggest that the target ranges should

be narrow.
There are two possible rationales for using a target range as opposed to a target number.

The first is that the Committee cannot pre-

cisely hit a predetermined monetary growth rate and so a target range
is used to accommodate likely misses.

The second rationale is that

because of the lack of precision of policymaking the Committee cannot
reasonably make fine distinctions in choosing exactly the right target
growth rate, and a range is used to acknowledge the imprecision of policy.
The second rationale has more merit than the first in our view.

In the

current discussion, targets should be based primarily on what is desirable-not what is easily attainable.

Only by following this approach can the

Committee know when the aggregates growth rates have deviated from the
"ideal," and so be prompted to take corrective action.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

From a review of Committee discussions, it appears that the threshold for discerning policy differences has been about one-half percentage
point.

That is, the Committee has attached importance to the choice among

policies that differ from one another by one-half percentage point.

A

wider range--and certainly a range wider than one percentage point--would
appreciably dilute the significance of long-run targets in the policy
process.
Choosing a narrow target range not only is appropriate from an economic point of view, but it would also be a clear demonstration of a cooperative spirit; whereas, a wide range might evoke suspicion and skepticism
that the FOMC was trying to "beat" the resolution.

No matter how narrow

the target range, it would be entirely consistent to explain to the Congress
the nature of the constraints that can prevent attainment of aggregates
targets.

It would be particularly important, in this regard, to "educate"

the Congress about the existence of a trade-off between attainment of interest rate and aggregates goals.

Congress needs to understand that in-

terest rate constraints can prevent attainment of aggregates targets.
Target period.

The Congressional resolution specifies that the

length of the target period in which Congress is interested is one year.
This is an indication that Congress expects the Committee to lengthen its
horizon for monetary policy planning.
horizon is appropriate.

Such a lengthening of the policy

If the Committee consistently had its sights on

a long-term target, that would provide it with a frame of reference within
which to pursue short-term policy.

The availability of a long-term guide

for monetary policy would assist the Committee in getting back on course.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/3/2021

Therefore, we recommend that the Committee not only set, but actively
use 12-month targets in making policy.

Moreover, we suggest that the

FOMC should revise these targets only infrequently--in response mainly
to changes in basic economic considerations rather than short-term
credit market conditions.

Framing the Report
The resolution calls upon the Board of Governors to speak for the
Committee about intended monetary policy.
statement to Congress is to be determined.

A key issue is how the Board's
Since the policy which the

Board will articulate will be a statement about future Committee policy,
the contents of the statement to Congress should be determined through
Committee debate and decision.

An extended meeting of the FOMC prior to

each report to Congress will probably be necessary for the Committee to
deliberate adequately.

In addition, dissenting views ought to be in-

cluded as part of the statement, as is now done in the published policy
record.

Congress created a central bank with a decentralized structure

with the expectation that a diversity of views makes for wiser policy.
Minority views, therefore, should be aired along with those of the
majority in reporting to Congress.