View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VARYING PU B L IC CONSTRUCTION AND H O U SIN G TO
PROM OTE ECONOM IC S T A B IL IT Y
Sherman J. Maisel, professor of business administration, University
of California (Berkeley)
A periodic reexamination of old theories is useful. Changing
times, new institutions, increased knowledge all call for significant
reinterpretations of even well-established ideas. The task of this
paper is to review, in the light of experience since the passage of the
Employment Act of 1946, the basic principles and criteria relating
Federal spending for construction and housing to the maintenance
of economic stability.
R

esum e

General agreement exists as to certain basic propositions. The
Government spends large sums of money. Because of the magnitude
of its expenditures, both their level and any changes in that level
affect vitally the economy’s income, production, and prices.
Any increase in Government expenditures has a direct inflationary
(antideflationary) effect, but expansion of income is far from identical
for each dollar spent. The type of governmental expenditure,
whether for public construction, durable or nondurable goods, p u r­
chases of services or of financial assets, or transfer payments may
lead to widely divergent results.
The individuals and corporations receiving the Government’s money
differ as do the sectors of industry and sections of the country. The
total increase in production and prices depends on how these groups
alter their production or inventories, how much they spend of their
new receipts, how fast, and on what. Some may spend it all imme­
diately. Some may save it all. In addition to affecting the produc­
tion and the spending desires of their recipients, higher governmental
expenditures may also influence the spending decisions of third parties
who may be encouraged or discouraged from using their funds. The
total inflationary effect of a dollar of Government spending depends
on the new output purchased directly by the Government plus the
total amount of induced expenditures (the m ultiplier).
Examination shows some governmental expenditures whose timing
pattern may be altered without a significant loss in public welfare
or efficiency. The economic justification of others depends upon their
not competing with high private expenditures. They are beneficial
only if planned so as not to increase inflationary tendencies and not
to raise the total cost structure unduly. In contrast these expenditures
have a heightened value if made during periods of underemployment.
Labor and other factors will be employed which would otherwise be
underutilized. Advantageous indirect effects will accrue as this added
income percolates through the economy.
382



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

383

This then leads to the conclusion that a successful formula for
varying Government expenditures—one that would lower spending
in booms and raise it in deflations—would help to insure the best use
of resources and would aid in maintaining the proper level of employ­
ment as well as preventing price inflations.1 The indirect effects of
Government spending on the total economy occur whether desired or
not. They are so important th at the Government should not neglect
them in its spending decisions. They must enter into any careful
determinations of budget policy.
The application of this principle in any concrete situation is com­
plex. A decision to cut spending requires agreement: (a) that an
inflationary situation exists and that it will continue unless expendi­
tures are lowered; ( b) that it is preferable to cut expenditures rather
than to raise taxes; and (c) th at a specific type of outlay should be
reduced. This last means accurately measuring the relative value of
separate categories to determine which is needed least, and assurances
that the resources made available will serve to reduce inflationary
pressures in general while not dislocating a specific industry so as
to raise its costs.
To date, the knowledge on which to base such decisions has been
deficient. Only slight improvement has been made in measuring the
relative priorities of separate needs. The actual mechanism of in­
flation is too uncertain to allow accurate tracing of the consequences
of a proposed expenditure or curtailment. As a result, conflicts of
the following type cannot be resolved.
Many observers are convinced that the current need for houses and
public construction is overriding and that if demand must be reduced
to ease inflationary pressures, it can be cut as effectively for other
goods as for these either through taxes, specialized borrowing, or p ar­
ticular monetary controls. I f these assumptions are correct, it fol­
lows that a proper policy would maintain spending for public con­
struction while cutting it in other less essential parts of the economy.
On the other hand, some experts assign lower utilities to building
than to other items the economy has been eagerly purchasing. They
believe that problems of raising taxes or of invoking special monetary
controls to cut other types of spending make it simpler and cheaper
to cut demand for housing and construction. I f these contrary as­
sumptions are the valid ones, it follows th at a proper policy will aim
at curtailing spending in the sphere of construction.
W ithout the requisite knowledge to decide which set of assumptions
is correct, the basic principle that spending should be reduced to
counteract inflation does not offer a method of selecting one line of
action in preference to another. Proper policy for the future will
depend upon success in gathering more valid data so as to apply the
existing criteria intelligently.
Much more effort has been expended on the analysis of expanding
spending in deflations. The result of such studies has been to dimin­
ish the importance placed on contracyclical public works expendi­
tures. The problems of forecasting, resource use, administration, and
technical timing are all complex. Except for periods when excess
resources exist prim arily in the construction industry, analysis of the
1 F o r a m ore com plete exposition of th is e n tire th e o ry s e e : S. J . M aisel, F lu c tu a tio n s,
G row th, an d F o re c a stin g (W iley, New York, 1957), chs. 14, 21, a n d 22.




384

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

difficulties involved in such a program have tended to lower the prior­
ity assigned to it in battling depressions. Conversely, added utility
has become apparent for programs either to maintain fiscal stability
or to increase tax remissions, transfer payments, and public spendingon less durable goods or services in periods of deflation.
Rather than constituting a major weapon for economic stability,
the following analysis indicates that the fluctuation of public works
and housing is prim arily useful in periods of extra high construction
demand, in serious and lengthy depressions, or when the demand and
T
supply situation within construction is in basic disequilibrium.
M

ethods of

A

l t e r in g

S

p e n d in g

The Government can curtail or increase expenditures in the field
of public construction or housing by several types of action.
Most obvious are its powers over the directly budgeted Federal
spending programs. In recent and past inflationary periods, at­
tempts to decrease the level of public construction have been made
through spreading out, cutting, or completely halting existing or pro­
posed programs. Expenditures on Federal buildings, dams, airports,
parks, etc., have been curtailed. The opposite policy has been fol­
lowed in depressions. Programs administered directly by the F ed­
eral Government are the easiest to control and react most readily to
a shift in policy.
Secondly, Federal action can alter a large volume of spending
not appearing in the current budget. Many programs, such as those
for housing, construction of public buildings, expansion of plants,
and urban redevelopment are carried on through a wide variety of
credit, grant, and subsidy aids. Their support may come from a
pledge of Federal credit, a long-term lease, or a promise of annual
subsidies. Adjustment of the terms on which aids are granted can
increase or decrease demand sharply.
A third type of control is exercised through monetary policy.
While most analysts agree that monetary changes can do little to­
ward increasing demand in a deflation, its powers appear much
stronger in a boom. Construction goods are extremely durable.
Because a higher percentage of construction activity is financed by
borrowing than is true of other goods, policies aimed at increasing
interest rates have their greatest impact on this type of spending.
Experience has shown, as theory predicts, that housing and local
government investments are more vulnerable to tight money than
are other expenditures, such as those on producers or consumers
durables or on public-utility expansions.
Because general monetary policy is effective, the Government must
decide whether or not to interfere with its operation in specific fields.
I f it is satisfied with the degree of curtailment brought about by
monetary stringency, no additional action is required. If, 011 the
other hand, it decides that alterations in the interest rate are not a
proper method of rationing resources among potential users, it can
decide to take counteracting steps and must select among them.
The laws and instructions to the Federal Reserve System can be
changed to require that the qualitative as well as the quantitative as­
pects of monetary policy receive attention. Monetary policy can be



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

385

shaped so as to control demand specifically. Such action has been
taken in the past.
Another possibility is to offset the effects of general monetary pol­
icy by altering the level of spending through’other means. There has
been wide support recently for programs aimed at counterbalancing
the effect on housing of the deflationary interest rate through direct
Veterans’ Administration loans or by increased purchases of the Fed­
eral National Mortgage Association or Government trust funds.
Similarly, school subsidies would cut down the effect of high interest
rates on school construction. On the other hand, much pressure has
been generated behind suggestions to eliminate such programs en­
tirely so as to reinforce rather than offset monetary policy.
B

a s is o f

C r it e r ia

for

P

o l ic y

D

e c is io n s

An axiom for Government expenditures is that a dollar should be
spent on a specific project by the Government when the marginal so­
cial benefit derived is as great as or greater than could be obtained by
spending the dollar elsewhere either in the private or public sphere.
Two criteria for policy appear most important. The first is really
that of efficiency—the direct comparison of costs and utilities for the
specific item purchased. How does the proposed spending policy affect
the use of resources and the benefits gained thereby? Every expendi­
ture entails certain costs and gains, but some produce proportionately
more goods and services at a lower cost than others. One object of a
spending decision must be to maximize this direct gain.
The second criterion can be thought of as effectiveness, a measure of
the indirect effect of the spending on the production and price picture
for the total economy. The ability of a spending policy to achieve its
aims depends on the direction of its impact, on the accuracy of fore­
casting, on the time it takes to get underway and to finish, and on the
problems of administration. Some, although lacking force, may be
started and stopped quickly. Others may reach high peaks of de­
mand but only after considerable delay.
In applying these criteria, some actions may rate high on one and
low on the other. In such a case no objective economic basis need
exist for choosing one over the other. As in most decision functions,
the proper weighting of the separate criteria must be a political de­
cision reflecting the desires of the Nation as a whole.
T

he

V

alue

(E

f f ic ie n c y

)

of

F

ederal

S

p e n d in g

Much of the uncertainty concerning proper spending policies arises
from our present inadequate measurements of the true efficiency of
public spending. For example, assume that a cutback in housing and
public construction could effectively free resources for other purposes.
Should such a slice in spending be made ? The answer depends upon
the importance to public welfare of the housing compared with that
of the uses to which the freed resources would be put if it were cut.
Government expenditures cover a wide area of public consumption of
goods. Moneys for defense, basic research, agriculture, education,
health and welfare, public construction, and housing are only a few.
Resources consumed for any goods may mean fewer available for
other purposes or for private consumption and investment.



386

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

In theory, allocating resources should not be difficult: The Commit­
tee for Economic Development recently stated that decisions could be
arrived at by answering the following questions:
Is the program necessary to enhance the security and wel­
fare of our citizens? Can these needs be reasonably accom­
modated by the States and local governments or by private
business? Is the expenditure worth more to the Nation than
an equivalent reduction in tax rates? Can the program be
undertaken with the available resources or will it simply
add to existing shortages and increase prices ? 2
In practice our national budgeting system is not adequate to allow
clear decisions on these facts. The measurement of benefits is far
from complete.
The comparison to private spending

In a boom or inflationary period, a major difficulty is th a t of weigh­
ing the value of projected governmental spending compared to th at
of leaving equivalent purchasing power in private hands. Some ob­
servers argue th at when private spending is adequate, high govern­
mental spending must be wasteful per se. In their opinion, the
Government always spends too much. Because expenditures are paid
for by taxes rather than out of an individual’s own pocket, they expand
too fast. On the theory th at everybody’s business is nobody’s busi­
ness, public money, they believe, is spent less efficiently. Increased
values are always received for moneys spent by private decisions.
Others disagree violently. The fact of high demand does not remove
the need for proper spending priorities. The optimum point of
spending for any dollar is not necessarily in either the public or
private sphere. The very existence of governments is proof th a t some
spending can always be done best in a collective manner.
Full employment of resources does mean, however, that spending
cannot be justified by its secondary effects. These consequences are
now inflationary and unwanted. The added welfare effects gen­
erated by public spending in periods of deflation are not now bene­
ficial. Some programs justifiable on the basis of these secondary
effects in other periods may have to be cut because of them during
boom times.
The basic problem of adequately measuring the relative benefits
remains. The fact th at people are willing to pay for the resources
to increase the average length of their private autos by a foot or two
does not lessen the need for public highways or parking spaces. The
advantages of public education received from larger and more nu­
merous TV sets need not outweigh those obtainable from larger and
more numerous schools. A splurge of office building does not reduce
the value of decent houses.
This lack of accurate measures means th at under our democratic
system decisions as to the most valuable or efficient spending must
remain prim arily political—in the best sense of the term. The people
through their votes make known their preferences. Economists and
public administrators, by demonstrating the real costs of alternative
policies, can aid them and their elected representatives in forming
2 C om m ittee fo r E conom ic D evelopm ent, T a x R eduction an d T a x R eform — W hen a n d
H ow (N ew York, M ay 1957), p. 15.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

387

proper judgments. Better data would narrow the limits of contro­
versies, although they would not completely eliminate them.
The relative efficiency of different types of public spending

Policy problems in deflations are likely to be of a different type
from those described above. Private and public spending are now
not competitive, and increased public expenditures will be worthwhile
for both their prim ary and secondary effects.
Early studies put most of their stress on stepping up the publicworks program. The idea that high spending during deflations
should be brought about by expanded programs of public construction
and housing still enjoys wide acceptance. B ut is there any reason to
believe that the public will benefit more by increasing spending in these
two categories than elsewhere in the wide range of public programs ?
The answer seems to be “No.”
Public works appeared especially desirable because they are durable.
The Government ends up with useful goods to show for its money.
Deficits could be justified as simply borrowing to invest, like any cor­
poration. Furthermore, increased public construction might be
merely an expansion of normal policy. Because expenditures made
at other periods and under other circumstances, furnished proper
benchmarks, efficiency could be judged more accurately.
Only gradually was it recognized that other types of spending might
have equal or even greater value. Durability is not a sound basis for
measuring the worth of an expenditure to the public. I t makes little
sense to build beautiful schools and then to close them because of
unwillingness to pay the teachers to staff them. Defense expenditures,
cut because of budget stringency, might well have a high priority if
additional expenditures become possible. Money spent to feed hungry
people is likely to offer a greater return than beautiful monuments.
Backlogs o f needs

The discussion and analysis of the past 10 years has removed much
of the fear that the scope of public spending could not be expanded in
a deflation without spreading into inefficient areas. As an example,
the backlog of public construction, over and above that which would
be built at existing rates during the next 10 years, has been estimated
as at least $100 billion to $150 billion (in 1957 dollars).3 Similarly
large estimates exist for urban redevelopment and housing.
One might well ask why such huge backlogs do not disappear in the
face of recent record levels of public construction. The reason is that
effective economic demand falls far short of the projected needs.
These estimates reflect the ideas of the experts formulating them on
how much government expenditure it would take to raise the level of
capital in their own areas of interest to some predetermined standard
of adequacy, usually based on engineering, educational, health, or
similar grounds. Under existing institutional and political pressures,
we are unwilling to build up to these standards. Some fields lack a
clear decision as to which level of government should attack the back­
log. In other cases the fiscal ability is inadequate. Some are needs
8 R. Newcomb, P u b lic W orks an d E conom ic S tab ilizatio n , P roblem s in A ntirecession
policy (C om m ittee fo r Econom ic D evelopm ent, New York, 1954), an d M. A. E dw ards,
R equirem ents fo r S ta te an d L ocal P ublic W orks C onstruction, C o n stru c tio n Review, M ay
1955.




388

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

which the economy feels should rate a low priority in periods of high
private investment. They may be desirable, but not in boom times.
Im plicit in most of these statements is an assumption that in
deflations many of the forces separating demand from need.would
disappear. Local fiscal difficulties would vanish as Federal aid came
forth. Government expenditures would have an increased marginal
utility, because instead of competing for resources, they would lead,
through the multiplier, to the employment of otherwise wasted private
means.
Finally, in a depression the sphere of' legitimate public spending
might broaden. This would be particularly true in the housing field,
where the line between public and private has fluctuated widely with
the existing economic and political climate.
Costs o f institutional change

Another possible source of inefficiency arises if the cyclical fluctua­
tion of expenditures creates heavy costs for institutional change.
For example, the present Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System has objected strenuously to receiving instructions which would
require them to consider the specific (or qualitative) results of their
action in contrast to their overall (or quantitative) effects. Recalling
th at in the past when they used selective credit controls they were
subject to much criticism and pressure, they recommend th at if the
country believes the present situation with respect to any market to be
unsatisfactory, action should be taken by Congress or other branches
of the Government, rather than by themselves. They concede th at
if particular markets are being exceptionally hard hit, methods of
altering the situation could be devised, but they don’t want the
responsibility.
A vocal opposition refutes these Federal Reserve views. The cost
of such institutional changes will be less than the gain. We do not
abolish police or building departments because they are subject to
pressure and at times create enemies by enforcing worthwhile laws.
The popularity of the Federal Reserve Board is not necessarily a
measure of its success.
A further possible source of inefficiency originates in the increased
role which the Government must play if it intervenes to increase the
level of construction in both a boom and possible deflation.
There has been much disagreement over whether or not the Govern­
ment should attempt to hold back high demand in a booming but not
inflationary period in order to save some for the future. Increased
capacity has been needed to handle a backlog plus a high current level
of demand. People worry that when this backlog is used up, the
industry may have too much capacity. The resources attracted in
the boom will be unemployed. This is the fam iliar case of over­
expansion due to the acceleration principle. Many feel that no real
problem exists. I f a deflation occurs, governmental action can increase
the demand.
B ut at this point, an institutional problem arises. Private demand
has fluctuated widely in the past and probably will again. Is there
a hidden cost in using government action to make up for the lack of
such demand in a deflation? Would it be cheaper instead to have the
Government hold back some of the demand in high periods?



389

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

A cost, somewhat similar to the above is the possible inefficiency
o f having to expand and contract the governmental organization
rapidly. Some feel that the Government should simply attempt to
hold its expenditures as constant as possible, on the theory that a113’
gains from spending at better times will be offset by the lowered or­
ganizational efficiency.
T

he

E

f f e c t iv e n e s s o f a

P

u b l ic

C o n s t r u c t io n P

rogram

The previous sections have discussed some o f the problems o f
the efficiency to be lost or gained by expansions or contractions o f
public works. The remainder o f this paper examines the second
criterion— that o f effectiveness. The effectiveness o f a program de­
pends on its purchasing or freeing the right resources in the appro­
priate period. Can a contracyc-lical policy succeed in raising and
lowering demand in the correct places and at the proper times ? 4

Forecasting
A ny change in expenditure patterns to improve economic stability
must be based on a forecast o f economic conditions. Unfortunately,
if, the economy moves in the opposite direction to that predicted, a
worse situation will develop than if no shift in spending had been
undertaken at all.
The record o f forecasts made since the Employment A ct o f 1946
has been only fair. Shorter forecasts fo r 1 or 2 quarters have been
better than the longer ones covering a year or more.
The consequence o f failure to perfect forecasting skills is an in­
creased relative effectiveness fo r spending which can be started and
stopped rapidly and which can be tied to the more accurate shortrun forecasts. I f the forecasts prove wrong, the spending stream
can be cut off. Public construction programs do not meet this con­
dition. They are both slow to start and hard to stop once they get
rolling. Forecasting lias to be more exact and farseeing. I f public
construction programs had been undertaken to combat tlie recessions
o f 1948-49 and 1953-54, they would have poured out their funds after
the recessions were over. Their primary effect would have been to
interfere with later attempts to contain inflationary pressures.

T h e availa b ility o f resources
F or an increased public spending to have the desired effects, it
must hire resources being underutilized and avoid using resources
already in short supply. The more homogeneous are resources and
the greater their transferability, the higher will be the effectiveness
o f a program. Public construction and housing use rather special­
ized resources. Furthermore in many categories, they normally pur­
chase a high proportion o f the existing supply.
Tables 1 and 2 list the m ajor resources used by new construction
activity in 1956. They also show that widely different resources
* C f . : E . J . H o w e n s tin e , C o m p e n sa to ry P u b lic W o rk s, J o u r n a l o f P o li tic a l E co n o m y
( J u n e 1 9 5 1 ) a n d P u b lic W o rk s P r o g ra m m e s a n d F u ll E m p lo y m e n t, I n te r n a tio n a l L a b o r
R ev iew ( F e b r u a r y 1 9 5 6 ) : I n t e r n a t i o n a l L a b o r Office, P u b lic I n v e s tm e n t a n d F u ll E m p lo y ­
m e n t (M o n tre a l, 1 9 4 6 ) : S. J . M aise l, T im in g a n d F le x ib ility of a P u b lic W o rk s P ro g ra m ,
R ev iew o f E c o n o m ic s a n d S t a tis tic s (M ay 1 9 4 9 ) ; J u liu s M a rg o lis, P u b lic W o rk s a n d
E c o n o m ic S ta b ility , J o u r n a l o f P o litic a l E c o n o m y (A u g u s t 1 9 4 9 ) ; J . A. M ax w e ll, F e d e ra l
G r a n ts a n d th e B u s in e s s C ycle ( N a tio n a l B u re a u o f E c o n o m ic R e s e a rc h , 1 9 5 2 ), a n d
R. N ew co m b , op. c it.




390

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

are required for an equal value of work in the major-building cate­
gories. Even a casual glance at the tables reveals th at the various
types of construction differ radically from each other. Still clearer
is the fact that the resources used have little bearing on other areas
of the economy which m ight be depressed, such as farming, textiles,
autos, etc.
Examination of such data has led to rather pessimistic views on
stabilizing value. An expansion of Government spending adequate
to fill much of a gap in private demand if it merely multiplied exist­
ing programs would use fa r too many resources of some types and
fa r too little of others.
Any expansion, to be of much use, would have to be carefully
planned. While a program to utilize all unemployed resources of
the construction industry could probably be worked out, it could not
merely be a replication on a larger scale of existing public construc­
tion programs. Attempts to utilize resources unemployed in other
industries would be fa r more difficult and would probably not be very
successful.




T a b le 1.— R elation sh ips of building m aterials required f o r specific typ es of construction in 1956
E stim ated percentage d istribution in 1956
M aterial

T o tal in
units

P u b lic

P ercen t

20,700
15,900
460
50
6,300
2.000
4,700
260
660

B uilding

H ousing

O ther

P ercen t

P ercen t

6
12
4
14
15
2
6
6
11

54
9
51
30
48
16
81
12
65

30
59
39
53
29
5
12
30
18

W orks

100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100

B uilding

160
124
163
885
420
5
2, 086
26
346

H ousing

1956
average,
all con­
struction

P ercen t

10
20
6
3
8
77
1
51
6

317
21
460
437
310
10
7,230
12
500

O ther

209
177
414
935
225
4
1,317
35
165

228
97
348
580
252
25
3,456
38
300

1952). T able 3: U . S. D ep artm en t of L abor, V alue of N ew C onstruction P u t in Place
1946-56 (revised M ay 1957).

AND

1 Includes all public construction except building.
Source: U . S. D e p artm e n t of Commerce, C onstruction and B uilding M aterials (M arch

STABILITY




P riv ate

P ublic

GROWTH

L u m b er..............................
. . ..m illio n board-feet .
.th o u san d tons .
Steel________________________
. .th o u sa n d to n s ..
W ire nails an d staples.
. . .
.m illio n sq u ares..
A sphalt roofing..............................
m illion bricks.
B rick . . . .
................... .
..th o u s a n d to n s..
C lay sewer p ip e ...........................
O ypsum board and la t h . . .
. m illion square feet.
P o rtla n d cem ent............................. . . m illion barrels Cast-iron p ip e ...........................
. ..th o u s a n d to n s ..

P riv ate

ECONOMIC

W orks 1

E stim ated consum ption required for equal values of work in
place (public w orks=100)

C
O
O

.

.

CO

.

C
O

T a b l e 2 .— R e la tio n s h ip s o f labor re q u ired f o r sp e c ific ty p e s o f c o n str u c tio n m 1 9 5 6
E stim a te d labor required for equal values of w ork in placc
(public works=100)

E stim ated percentage distribution in 1956
m an-hours
(in m il­
lions)

Labor

P ublic

P lasterer....... ............................ .......
- ................P lu m b er.............................................................................
Sheet-m etal w orker_____ ...... .............. .
All o th er............................................................................

P ercen t

Building

Housing

O ther

P ercen t

P ercen t

1956
average,
all con­
struction

P riv ate

Public

P ercen t

W orks

B uilding

H ousing

O ther

290

5
8
11
58
18
5
6
10
1
7
4
24

13
8
13
5
19
14
11
19
10
11
15
12

53
47
20
6
6
59
51
4
63
41
38
15

29
37
56
31
57
22
32
67
26
41
43
49

100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100

499
201
231
18
215
519
378
403
1,686
332
1,040
106

492
277
87
5
16
497
424
18
2, 485
293
623
32

323
259
293
32
188
221
322
421
1,216
357
832
122

361
230
169
33
107
328
325
202
1, 535
282
628
81

290
1,380
200
290
140
20
240
140
100
170
iO

10

36

39

100

157

131

171

140

1,250
530

24
36

9
6

22
17

45
41

100
100

75
36

46
24

112
69

80
54

T o tal____ ___________ _____ - ____________
N onm anu al. .................
. . ..........................

1,780
220

27
32

8
17

21
18

44
33

100
100

60
111

37
29

95
63

70
61

5, 340

19

10

30

41

100

108

79

127

101

G rand to ta l

_____ - -

-

................... ......................................

1 Includes all public construction except building.




D epartm ent of L abor B ulletin No. 1146, table 20. International L abor Review (F eb ru ary 1956) table I,

STABILITY

14

T o t a l _________ - ________

AND

3, 340

Semiskilled an d unskilled:
L aborer. ..........................................................................
All o th er................................. ... .................- ....................

GROWTH

Skilled:
B ricklayer-------------------------- ----------------------G 'arpenter______________________ _______ ______
E lectrician
_______________
........................
E quip m en t operator............... .......................................
Ironw orker.............................................................-.........
L ath er .............. - .................. ......... ................ . ........ P a in te r.................. - ................. ................................

P rivate

ECONOMIC

W orks 1

tsD

ECONOMIC GROWTH AJSfD STABILITY

393

Administration and timing
The administration o f public works programs is complex and time
consuming. Public construction is a melange o f Federal, State, and
local responsibilities and authority. Housing is even more complex
since it falls more completely in the sphere o f private enterprise.
Construction requires prior plans, surveys, investigations, and studies
o f needs and sites. In addition to blueprints and specifications, land
must be acquired. Present legal methods are slow. P rior acquisition
is usually difficult.
W ork has been done on systems o f prior planning o f public works
to cut the lag between the start o f a program and expenditures. Re­
sults indicate that important savings in time are possible i f enough
work is done in advance. T o date, however, progress in the speeding
up o f non-Federal programs has been slight.
Advance planning has failed because a really large-scale expansion
would require a change in political and institutional relationships.
States and localities have a perverse financial ability. They cannot
finance appreciable, expansions during contractions even i f they so
desire. Furthermore, their planning and engineering staffs are not
equipped for advance planning. Increased responsibility for leader­
ship, planning, and financial assistance in any depression would
devolve on the Federal Government.
A new and different type o f program would be even more necessary
to permit enlargement of urban redevelopment and housing programs.
Private demand in this sphere is almost certain to decline precipi­
tously if adverse winds blow in the general economy. The small addi­
tional flexibility available tinder present programs by easing financial
terms or other aids would not be sufficient to do much good.
The time patterns o f public construction and housing programs
va n ’ widely even after a program has been started. In addition to
planning and land problems, contracting delays may occur. Projects
move toward completion at widely divergent rates. W ork on soil
conservation, roads, airports, levees, repairs and rehabilitation o f
existing buildings can be started and completed fairly rapidly. On
the other hand, m ajor engineering projects, large-scale buildings,
and housing all move slowly.
These technical differences in timing, in resource use, and in ad­
ministration all affect the successful planning o f an anticyclical con­
struct on program. Most o f these factors mean that it is more difficult
to shape an effective program fo r public works than for other types
o f public spending. That is why so many who have looked into the
possibility have been skeptical o f the usefulness o f a public works
program.
On the other hand, Howenstine and Newcomb, who have spent
the most time on these problems, are still relatively optimistic. They
believe that, providing enough time and effort were put into its plan­
ning, an effective program could be developed. Newcomb has esti­
mated that with existing techniques Federal construction spending
could be expanded by about a third in a year. Even with preplanning
and new institutional arrangements, the expansion o f State and local
spending would be somewhat slower. Still with adequate prepara­
tions, a public construction and housing program probably could




394

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

raise the level of spending in these fields by about a quarter at the
end of a year. Expansion could then continue more rapidly.
This seems to indicate th a t expansions of public construction can
be used prim arily in cases of long contractions—when total demand
stagnates and long-run programs are called for to raise the equilib­
rium spending level. The technical problems of shifting construc­
tion make it extremely difficult to coordinate it with programs aimed
at stabilizing shorter employment fluctuations.
T

he

E

f f e c t iv e n e s s o f

P

rogram s

To

C

urb

C

o n s t r u c t io n

In contrast to improved knowledge of the factors involved in ex­
panding public construction in a deflation, little progress has been
made on theories applicable to inflationary periods.
We have already noted the inability to measure the relative in­
efficiency of cutting out particular spending items. F u rth er dis­
agreement exists over the effect of the proposed curtailments. W hat
will happen if construction demand drops ? Repercussions will be of
two types: (a) The specific (micro) effects on costs, prices, and in­
comes in the industry itself; and ( i ) the overall (macro) results
which depend not only upon these specific happenings but also on
the interrelationships of demand and supply for the entire economy.
Specific effects
Few object to cutting back demand when construction resources
are inadequate. Such inflationary situations should be halted. A
possible alternative to halting demand would be increased action to
augment supplies, but the few attempts along this line have not been
very effective.
More controversy arises over attempts to lower demand when the
resources in construction are merely fully employed or perhaps some­
what underemployed. This reflects the general analytical uncer­
tainty as to the cause of recent inflationary tendencies. Two rather
strong opposing points of view exist.
One holds th a t spiraling costs and prices in construction result
from a very inelastic supply curve. When demand rises, prices are
driven up. When demand falls, prices should fall. Any tendency
for prices to rise is taken as a signal that construction’s specific de­
mand is too high for supplies. This then means th a t construction
resources are-inadequate and demand should be cut.
The opposition believes th at rising prices in building have little to
do with the specific demand and supply situation of the industry, but
are simply the result of the general cost-push forces at work in the
economy. They point to increases in steel prices with falling steel
demand and to rising wages in industries with growing unemploy­
ment. They feel that holding back demand in this specific field will
have but slight impact on the general forces causing the cost push.
They go further and state th at under existing conditions a cut in
building demand wil lead to higher costs and prices. This they be­
lieve will occur because their concept of the suply curve for construc­
tion, and especially for housing, is one in which costs decrease with
volume. Curtailing demand will raise costs and prices both im­
mediately and far into the future. They point to many years when
housing has greatly increased its production with slight or nonexistent



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

395

price rises. Housing’s one experience with lower prices came with an
increase in scale and a shift from a contract to an operative basis.
Contract firms tended to minimize overhead, land development, and
forward planning. The postwar period of sustained strong demand
brought forward larger, stronger operative firms with lower costs.
Because of problems of overhead and of land and community develop­
ment, these firms need a lead time of assured demand. The uncer­
tainty brought about by Government action to curtail demand has
particularly penalized these firms with a larger planning horizon and
more future commitments. The result has been to raise costs by
hindering or removing the most efficient type of producers.
Overall effects

A policy has also been suggested of lowering demand in construction
as a means of combating the general inflationary situation. Here
the issue is not what happens to building prices, but how spending in
this area affects other demand. I f surplus resources exist in the hous­
ing field, would it be improper to employ them on the assumption that
any additional spending would increase the total pressure on the
economy ?
The overall inflationary effect of spending in a specific field depends
on the source of funds and on the multiplier. Construction paid for
by creating purchasing power will have an inflationary effect as it
spills over from its initial spending purpose into other areas. How­
ever, if the purchasing power already exists and is simply taken from
other uses, an inflationary impact need not occur. Its effect on prices
will depend on the total consequences of the expenditures in their
new channels as contrasted to how this money would have been spent if
not taxed or borrowed to increase construction demand. (The results
will, of course, be more inflationary than if the Government had
taken the purchasing power and saved it.)
Provided there are underutilized resources in the industry or its
supply curve leads to falling prices with increased volume, spending
money for housing even in a period of high aggregate demand is likely
to be deflationary. The purchasing power absorbed cuts back on the
demand for all other goods. This money instead employs resources
which otherwise would be wasted (assuming they could not easily be
moved into high-demand areas). The result is to augment the total
amount to goods produced. Aggregate prices will fall because total
purchases have not been increased while the total utilized supply has.
Another erroneous impression is that there is a necessary difference
between the effect of purchasing power taken through taxes and that
borrowed. Provided the Federal Reserve maintains a constant level
of credit (and contrary to their statements), borrowing to increase
housing demand by the Government may have a deflationary effect.®
F or example, when the Federal National Mortgage Association bor­
rows in the money market to lend to house purchasers, this may raise
interest rates and stop other potential borrowers. The available funds
might, if not borrowed, have augmented consumer expenditures or
business purchases of durables. Expenditures in areas with shorter
supplies could lead to larger price increases.
6 U. S. Senate Subcommittee on Housing of the Senate Banking and Currency Committee.
Hearings on Housing Amendments of 1957 (85th Cong., 2d sees.), p. 279.



396

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

The overall results will depend also on the effectiveness with which
the funds are taken. But little effort has been made to judge the
relative costs of using programs of taxes, borrowing, or qualitative
monetary controls to obtain funds for specific fields, even though each
may have definite advantages in a certain situation. I f important
differences prevail in the secondary effects of money spent in separate
fields, then these must also be taken into account. No obvious diver­
gent secondary effects appear to exist, however.
A c t u a l M o v e m e n t s of E x p e n d it u r e s

The history of shifting Government expenditures in the postwar
period bears out the previous analysis. There has been a great deal
of difficulty in determining when it would be efficient to expand or
cut public construction. As a result, with the exception of the housing
field, only mild action has been taken to promote stability by varying
expenditures in this sphere. The few attempts have not been very
effective.
In the recession of 1948^49, increased Government spending and
decreased Government taxes played a significant role in maintaining
stability. Because of poor forecasting, however, most of this occurred
in an unplanned manner. Moreover, as would be expected in a short
recession, the best results were achieved by nonconstruction items.
The excess of Government “withdrawals from” over “additions to”
the income stream dropped at an annual rate of $13.3 billion between
the first halves of 1948 and 1949, the period when such a drop was
most desirable. Of this sum income taxes decreased by $4.3 billion,
and $1.6 billion was from other falls in revenue. The largest increase
in spending, at a rate of $2.4 billion a year, occurred in payments
to farmers through loans and crop purchases. Purchases for foreign
aid went up at the rate of $2.1 billion. Other increases totaling $2.9
billion were spread among unemployment compensation, wages, higher
defense spending, and a few miscellaneous categories. D uring this
most critical period, public construction expanded somewhat, but at
less than its normal postwar recovc
'
TT ' lg slumped. As a
construction and
result, the desired expansionary
housing were less than normal.
Again in the recession of 1953-54, public construction played only
a slight role in halting the decline. In this period, although the Presi­
dent apparently issued instructions to speed up public works, Federal
construction actually fell.6 State and local construction expanded
slightly, while housing did make an important contribution to income.
Other Federal expenditures contracted sharply. The sharp fall in
m ilitary expenditures was, of course, one of the major causes of the
general decline.
One other lesson can be drawn from the postwar experience. In the
initial planning under the Employment Act of 1946, it was hoped that
public housing and urban redevelopment could make important con­
tributions to anticyclical policy. The Housing Act of 1949 contained
specific authority for the President to speed up these programs if neces­
sary to promote stability.
e Cf., the article by It. J. Donovan, New York Herald Tribune, May 4, 1956.



397

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Table 3 shows the time required to complete expenditures of the first
year’s authorizations under this act. From this record, there appears
to be slight likelihood th at these items could become an im portant
anticyclical device. Redevelopment was a brand new program that
had to set up new organizations and establish new procedures. Con­
tracts fo r the spending of the first year’s authorizations of Federal
grants took over 4 years to write, and the period for contracting loans
was more than 7y2 years. Over 8 years elapsed before the funds were
finally disbursed. Clearly, this time will be cut in the future if the
agencies stay in operation. Even so, considerable time must elapse
between authorizations and contract approvals. Furthermore, the
average lag between contract and expenditure, which depends more on
technical problems, was from 2 to 3 years. Only one project was
actually completed in the program’s first 8 years.
T a b l e 3 . — Time to complete 1st year’ s program authorized under the Housing

Act of 1949
Years from passage
of act
Average
(median)

T otal

P u b lic housing (135,000 dwelling u n its): i
2.0
3. 7

3.0
4.8

3.3
6.0

4.3
8.1

5.1
7.2

7.5
3 8.5

U rban redevelopm ent:
C apital g rants ($100,000,000):
Project loans ($250,000,000):

1 Program was delayed 2 to 5 m onths by K orean war.
E stim ated.

2

Source: U . 8. H ousing and H om e Finance Agency, Housing Statistics.

Because the housing program was actually in operation, the initial
steps for this program went much faster. Even so, it was about 4 ^
years (correcting for the delay of Korea) from authorization to com­
pletion of the first year’s program. The physical construction lag was
about 20 months from start to completion of construction.
These programs seem to show again that public construction cannot
be speeded up so as to increase stability in any but fairly long, severe
depressions. Since the additional efficiency of these programs is also
in doubt, recent policy statements putting greater stress on adjust­
ments of other types of Government spending and receipts seem
sensible.

97735—5i7------27