View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

T H E U SE O F NATURAL RESOURCE E X P E N D IT U R E S TO
PROM OTE GROW TH AND S T A B ILITY IN T H E AM ER­
ICAN ECONOMY
Lawrence G. Hines, professor of economics, Dartmouth College
Seldom has a statistical projection excited so much enthusiasm as
the trend line of American economic growth. Like the rainbow
with the pot of gold, although it describes no descending arc, the
growth trend promises leisure and plenty in the not distant future.
Economic growth, generally indicated by increasing gross national
product, is more often than not advanced uncritically as an important
and laudable goal of American economic activity. Morever, econ­
omists find themselves in unusual agreement on the major requisite
for promoting economic grow th: Maintain (or create) ample oppor­
tunities for investment. Of course there are minor discords over the
precise role to assign to consumption and investment, but the historic
16 or 17 percent investment component of gross national product gen­
erally has been accepted as a reasonable benchmark of how much
capital formation we must have to prevent a serious dip in the growth
trend. A t the same time, investment of this magnitude is thought
to provide the necessary underpinning of the economy and facilitate
the achievement of the somewhat antithetical goal of stability. But
at this point more caution must be observed.
Although economic growth usually has been achieved with a stable
capital-output ratio, it is not a sound inference th at economic growth
can be endlessly stimulated by raising the capital side of the equation—■
or more properly, it i*
a reasonable premise to assume that capital
accumulation can be indefinitely increased.1 Capital accumulation
must be based on sound technological innovation, new markets, or
other demand-increasing avenues of profit-making opportunities else
the rise in output will founder on the diminishing marginal produc­
tivity of later capital installations. In short, a boom level of invest­
ment may overreach the optimum ratio. But if the innovation or
“newness” achieved by capital rationalization is underwritten by con­
sumer purchases, we can tilt the growth line more sharply upward.
I t is commonplace for economists to avoid the question of the
social worth of economic activity (at least when viewing the output
of the market economy) but certainly Government policy cannot ig­
nore this question. Assuming that we can push the rate of growth m
the American economy substantially above its present level, or for
that matter, maintain it at its present level—should this be an over­
riding objective of Federal policy? Although growth in one sense is
inseparable from the announced objective of stability, th at is, in its
1 See A. H. Hansen, Economic Growth and Stability, Federal Tax P olicy for Economic
Growth and Stability (W ash in gton : Joint Committee on the Economic Report, 84th Cong.,
1 st sess., November 9, 1955).




683

684

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

counteraction to a downturn in economic activity, some of the increase
in economic output of the American economy is devoted prim arily to
satisfying the consumer’s passion for keeping up-to-date: pointed
shoes, and Easter-egg cars. Moreover, consumer acceptance—even
clamour—to spin the economic wheel of wealth faster to keep from
going backward should not blind us to the fact that such consumer
demand is largely implanted by the producer. Although economists
may understandably feel uneasy if called upon to appraise the worth
of such accelerated obsolescence, a critical choice may confront the
Government policymaker in deciding between alternatives th at will
have less growth stimulation for the American economy, but which
may possess intrinsic merit or strengthen the economy in important
areas. A t the same time, capital growth is itself temporarily re­
sponsible for a decrease in consumers goods. The drive for newness
in capital stock necessarily reduces the production of consumers goods
during the period of capital creation. I f this accelerated obsolescence
is produced prim arily by a jockeying for position among major pro­
ducers, the resultant consumer benefit may be slight indeed and at
times have virtually no effect upon the positions of the competitive
contestants.
To meet the requirements of public policy, the economist’s crude
dollar measure of productivity (or growth) of the economy must be
refined by further analysis. Depending upon the preeminent objec­
tives of society at the time, e. g., increased capacity for war, enhance­
ment of public welfare, improvement of international goodwill, etc.,
some types of economic and noneconomic activity may contribute
more to the acomplishment of these objectives than others. Thus, it
is impossible to ignore the fact that equal units of national income
are not equally productive in attaining given objectives. Although
it may not be possible in many cases to substitute one type of resourceusing activity that promotes a given societal goal at the expense of
another resource-using activity that has a neutral or negative effect,
we should recognize th at some of the most productive activities under­
taken in our society have little effect upon the generation of gross
national product. For example, secondary and tertiary effects of con­
sumer spending and induced private investment may be very meager
from a program to increase educational opportunities and stimulate
the arts. Indeed, gross national product may initially fall as re­
sources are withdrawn from the labor market for a time and the net
(crude) effect of such a program may be to stimulate the economy
much les than investment that calls forth a demand for brick, mortar,
and machines. But if not now, at least eventually we may reach an
imbalance in the accumulation of brick, mortar, and machines in re­
lation to the opportunities for cultural expression and development.
We may even reach the conclusion th at transfer payments may sub­
stantially enhance productivity if they result in equipping a segment
of our society to contributing more satisfactorily to the accepted goals
of our society. I t is the continuing obligation of our governmental
organizations to prevent such an imbalance from seriously impairing
the productivity of our society.
The twin goals of growth and stability are to a large extent the
product of preoccupation with problems of the great depression and
post-World W ar I I eras. We want to avoid a return to the economic
distress of either, but in our concentration on problems of the past



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

685

we may fail to recognize more important needs of the future. A t the
same time we are sometimes inclined to deplore any divergence from
stability and treat moderate inflation and deflation as equivalent
evils. Quite possibly we fear inflation too much, at least the type of
inflation that has mildly harassed the American economy during the
past 10 years. Although we can posit a constant growth rate and a
dead level of stability, such a situation seems so unlikely that it is
better to err on the side of mild inflation than moderate deflation.
Such a course has its disadvantages and inequities: The fixed income
group may be seriously distressed, employers may face the pinch
of a tight labor market,2 tax adjustments upwards may cause discon­
tent, etc., but there are compelling compensating factors in the gen­
eral strengthening of the economy and the ascendancy of lower in­
come families to higher income positions. Compared with the last
period of normalcy of the 1920’s, our society is better off economically
in almost every w ay: Home and farm ownership has increased, sav­
ings per family has virtually doubled, inequality in income distribu­
tion has decreased. On the basis of rational economic choice, mod­
erate inflation does not appear to be too great a price to pay for such
developments. This does not mean that public policy should be
unconcerned about checking inflation and indifferent to the singular
hardship it may cause among certain groups. We should maintain
an interest in stability of our economy and stability of the purchas­
ing power of the dollar, but we should be more than critical of a
program that is willing to abandon stability of relatively full em­
ployment to attain neat stability of purchasing power. We should
in turn devise special programs to meet the needs of those groups
particularly distressed by a mildly ascending price level.
T

he

T

heory

of

P

u b l ic

E

x p e n d it u r e s

In a short time we have come a long way from the dictum of Jean
Baptiste Say that “The very best of all plans of [public] finance is to
spend little.” In approximately 25 years, spanning 1929 to 1955,
total Federal, State, and local expenditures have moved from less
than 10 percent of gross national product to slightly over 25 percent,
with 1943 and 1944 war expenditures coming close to half of the
gross national product for those years. Moreover, the rise in govern­
ment expenditures over this period has occurred almost entirely at
the Federal level, with State and local expenditures in 1929 over
twice as high as Federal expenditures—7.3 percent of gross national
product for State and local and 2.5 percent for Federal, while in
1955 the State and local proportion of gross national product had
risen only 0.2 of 1 percent to 7.5 percent, but Federal expenditures
had increased to 17.7 percent of gross national product.
W ith combined Government expenditures constituting slightly over
one-fourth of total gross national product, it has become a widely
accepted truism that one of the most important forces for inflation or
deflation lies in the taxation and expenditure policies adopted that
affect this decisive portion of our national product. In short, the
role of public expenditures has changed over the last 20 years from
* See Paul A. Samuelson, F ull Employment Versus Progress and Other Economic Goals,
Income Stabilization for a Developing Democracy (New H a v e n : Yale U niversity Press,
1953, M. F. M illlkan, ed .).
97735— 57-------15




686

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

relatively minor outlays for activities that could not easily be under­
taken through the private economy to a myriad of governmental
functions and duties involving a different level of expenditure. This
change has created a new threat and a new opportunity. I f this
quarter portion of gross national product can be brought under ra ­
tional, decisive control, it may greatly assist in alleviating the prob­
lems of insecurity and instability that have plagued us in the past.
I f it cannot, we may be attempting to predict and control the course
of an economic tumbleweed. But in either case, we can no longer
view public expenditures purely from the standpoint of whether p ar­
ticular outlays are desirable or undesirable in their own right; we
are forced to think in terms of the magnitude of the total expendi­
tures and the fiscal appropriateness of particular outlays. Another
dimension, which has various subdimensions, has been added to the
problem of the selection of Government activities.
Briefly, these well-known major fiscal dimensions may be separated
on the point that divides inflation and deflation. Historically, of
course, our original concern with the countercyclical features of pub­
lic expenditure programs was directed toward deflation and generally,
since public expenditures demonstrate a pronouncedly greater flexi­
bility m an upward direction, we have thought of expenditures as ap­
propriate prim arily as a means of stimulating economic activity rather
than dampening down its upward thrust. Taxation and monetary
controls have been relied upon and prescribed with more success in
meeting the problems of inflation. B ut it is impossible to ignore the
fact that public expenditures of one-quarter of gross national product
cannot really be thought of as neutral or passive, even if income and
outgo are perfectly balanced. I t makes little difference whether a
deficit is created by lack of taxes or excess of expenditures, or that an
overbalance of receipts over outlays is the result of curtailed expendi­
tures or increased taxes. The important fact is that large expenditures
do provide an opportunity for curtailment, although there may be
compelling reasons for not pressing this fiscal advantage. A rational
approach to public expenditure policy cannot ignore the consideration
of the suitability of different types of public expenditures for fiscal
contol, although the decision may sometimes be th at certain govern­
ment functions are so important that they must be maintained irrespec­
tive of their fiscal inappropriateness.
Countercyclical fiscal policy as a means of combating deflation was
embraced tentatively during the later period of the great depression.
The experience during this period was somewhat inconclusive, but the
trial maneuver was long enough to provide clues to the requisites and
limitations of positive fiscal policy. The concern of this paper is
with expenditure policy, although it is unrealistic to ignore the im­
portant role of taxation and borrowing.
The prim ary lesson of the depression appears to be th a t the magni­
tude of deficit expenditures (and/or tax relief) must be sufficiently
great to compensate for the decline in consumer purchasing power.
Moreover, the public expenditure must carry with it sufficient stimulus
to encourage the private economy to take up again the full employ­
ment level of investment, else the recovery will be tentative and
short lived. In other words, public expenditures must not only fill the
gap resulting from decreased private consumption and investment, but
provide a rejuvenating force that will restore these activities to their



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

687

previous vigorousness. I t is apparent from a close inspection of our
experiences during the great depression that our expenditure policy
was not sufficiently vigorous to achieve this goal. During the early
eriod of the depression total expenditures by State, local, and Federal
Government for public-works projects were actually below the levels
of the late 1920’s, largely as a result of drastic curtailment of State and
local outlays. This cut heavily into the normal government contribu­
tion to national product. A t the same time tax increases, rather than
tax relief, helped to counteract the possible stimulus to recover from
deficit spending. Partly because of the insufficiency of government
deficit spending, partly because of fiscally inappropriate tax policies,
and partly because of the hostility and suspicion of this new tool of
deficit finance, the American economy had to wait for recovery to be
achieved by the deficits of World W ar II.
A lesson not so apparent from the experience of the great depres­
sion is that public expenditure policy is a cumbersome and unwieldy
thing. I t is sometimes assumed that the time required to initiate a
full-scale Federal public works (expenditure) program during the
great depression was largely the result of indecision and lack of expe­
rience with compensatory finance. Certainly the unfamiliarity with
this new tool must account for considerable delay in its use, but even
after spending decisions have been made and allocations of funds
achieved, a distressing delay must take place before the funds cir­
culate in the economy in amounts sufficient to have any significant effect
in raising the level of economic activity. Ideally, public expenditures
should be subject to the smallest possible controlled variation during
a given expenditure period: 3 to 6 months’ lag between decision to
spend and the accomplished fact of spending. Actually, public ex­
penditures do not lend themselves to anything like the precision of
control necessary to promote great confidence in their use. I t is a
misconception to believe that the lag in the stimulating effect of public
expenditures can be overcome by having an administrative organi­
zation ready to undertake projects and a shelf of plans already certi­
fied. The lag between appropriation or allocation time and the peak
impact of spending is so great that had we attempted to counteract
the recessions of 1948-49 and 1953-54 with extensive expenditure
programs the peak impact of such activities would have occurred in
time to add further embarrassment to our attempts to control rising
prices. Although some types of public expenditures lend themselves
to more sensitive control than others, for the most p art the use of
public expenditures as a counteracting influence for anything other
than a well-established, serious depression does not appear appropri­
ate. The more resilient approach through tax policy seems to offer
prospects of greater success.
The sluggishness of public works is well illustrated by public hous­
ing expenditures, frequently designated as a desirable objective of
Federal expenditures, partly because of the stagnation in the construc­
tion industry which generally accompanies a recession. Persuasive
arguments appear to favor stimulation of the construction industry
through some form of public housing program : The administration
organization for undertaking a Federal housing program exists in
at least a modified form; our Federal Government has probably as
much experience in housing public works as any other large-scale
undertaking; housing construction uses large amounts of manpower

g




688

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

and materials, hence promising secondary and tertiary stimulation
of the economy; to some extent housing projects can be undertaken
in localities where the depressed condition of the construction industry
is greatest and where the greatest benefits from stimulation may be
expected; Federal assistance for housing development and community
slum clearance is a generally accepted function of the Federal Govern­
ment, affording the opportunity for Federal cooperation with State
and local governments.
The great disadvantage of a large-scale housing project is the lapse
of time between the allocation of the funds for the program and the
time at which the expenditure finally affects the private economy. As
is shown in chart I, a timelag of 2 years occurs before any significant
effect on the private economy can be expected from public housing
expenditures. This timelag is partly the result of proolems peculiar
to housing programs—for example, condemnation proceedings nor­
mally require from 2 to 3 years—and partly a characteristic of largescale contracting.




689

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
C h a r t I. P e r c e n t a g e o f F u n d s E x p e n d e d i n E a c h
V a r io u s P r o g r a m s

6 - M o n th P e b io d b y

Months

Delay between
deflation and
allocation:

Allocation=day

6

Average Weight­
ed Program

m

II

5

2 7 25

Public
Buildings

n

Reclamation &
U.S. Engineers

12 18 24 30 36 4 2 48 over 48

12

II

6 23

rt

0

11

n

n

m

i—» n

17 9

6

4

2

10

5

3

n n n n

5

1

n

n

II

16

II

11

7

7

3

2

2

2

1

1

11 n

3

Time for forecast­
ing. political
support, administra
tion. planning.

Conservation.
other

3

5

Roads, Highways
& Airports

0

5

0

36 37 14

L

A0 5

Hosoitals

Housing & Urban
Redevelopment

I"!

1

pi

n

5

5

3

----------

fl

n

n

r-.

0

0

2 4 35 22

8

7

4

0

23 32 23

n

fl n

n
10 8

n
4

Local Programs

1

...

S o u rce: Reproduced w ith permission from S. J. Maisel, Timing and F lexibility of
a Public Works Program, The Review of Economics and S tatistics, vol. 31, No. 2 (May
1949), p. 151. Reproduced by perm ission of the Harvard U niversity Press. Compiled from
J. K. Galbraith, Economic Effects of the Federal Public Works Expenditures, 1933-38
(N ational Resources P lanning Board, W ashington, D. C., 1940), pp. 74—106; E. J.
H owenstine, Jr., D ovetailing Rural Public Works Into Employment Policy, The Review of
Economics and S tatistics, vol. 28 (1946), pp. 1 65-169; International Labor Office, Public
Investm ent and F ull Employment (Montreal, 1946), pp. 1 3 4 -1 4 6 ; U. S. Congress: Special
Senate Committee on Postw ar Economic Policy and Planning, hearings, pt. V ; S. Res. 102,
p. 1111 (W ashington: 78th Cong., 2d sess) ; S. J. Maisel, unpublished study based on
FPH A Report S-100.




a*

T a b l e I .— F e d e ra l G o ve rn m e nt e xp e n d itu re s f o r the developm ent o f n a t u r a l re so u rce s

CO

O

[In millions]

1941

1943

1944

1945

1946

1947

1948

1949

1950

1951

1952

1953

1954

1955

1956

1957
(esti­
mate)

1958
(esti­
mate)

$25

$27

$32

$39

$49

$285

$241

$237

$346

$341

$317

$244

$286

$305

$579

$636

337

247

163

162

333

505

756

884

948

1, 038

1,122

960

815

803

940

1,070

27

27

32

36

38

43

53

61

66

78

81

95

107

117

118

138

163

186

6

9

19

26

23

21

24

26

29

34

36

35

38

37

37

38

88

99

7
14

8
13

8
8

7
5

8
4

8
5

11
11
1 174
10

12
17

18
19

23
24

26
30
2
18

30
33
5
21

34
30
3
25

38
33
1
27

43
35

45
44

64
76

61
76

3
3
4
13
16
34
2
2
3
10
Total natural resources expend
351
282
665
411
467
431
272
916 1,143 1,395 1,486 1, 599 1,675 1,457 1,367 1,409
tures2.................................. .............
Total Federal budget expenditures.. 13,387 34,187 79,623 95,315 98,703 60,703 39, 289 33,069 39,507 39,606 44,058 65,410 74, 274 67,772 64,570 66,540

1,925
68,900

2,126
71,807

2.8

3.0

Resource expenditure percent of
total budget_____
________

3.0

1.4

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.5

1.7




2.9

3.5

3.4

2.4

2.3

2.1

.2.1

2.1

Source: Compiled from various issues of Bureau of Census, Statistical Abstract of the
United States and Bureau of the Budget, The Budget of the U. S. Government,

STABILITY

1 Development and control of atomic energy.
2 This category differs from the United States budget “Natural resources'’ category
by the addition of “Conservation and development of agricultural land and water.”

2.8

AND

$27
381

GROWTH

$26
302

ECONOMIC

Conservation and development of
agricultural tend and waterresources.
Conservation and development of
land and water resources. _
.
Conservation and development of
forest resources.................................
Conservation and development of
mineral resources.............................
Conservation and development of
fish and wildlife...............................
Recreational use of natural resources.

1942

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

691

Quite as important as whether a public works program can be
initiated quickly is the question of whether the project is susceptible
to wide variation in expenditures upon short notice and quick term i­
nation. Projects that involve considerable prior planning and large
units of construction, such as housing, flood control, and reclamation,
are generally extremely inflexible. Once a housing or slum clearing
project is initiated, for example, strong community pressure may be
exerted to continue the undertaking even though it may no longer
be fiscally appropriate.3 Aside from these pressures, termination of
a partially completed housing development, flood-control dam, or
reclamation project is generally not feasible if the project is to provide
any benefit from the original investment. As a result, only in cases
where the portent of the future is clearly for a prolonged depression
is it safe to risk undertaking such projects for their countercyclical
influence.
Aside from the activities of the Bureau of Reclamation and the
civilian functions of the Army engineers, as indicated in chart I, ex­
penditures for conservation activities are relatively good candidates
for counterfiscal projects. The prime advantage of such expenditures
is that the appropriations flow into the money stream of the economy
rapidly. The larger portion of natural resource expenditures goes
for the purchase of labor services and involves the use of easily avail­
able equipment. The process of spending natural resource allocations
is largely that of adapting existing organizations to the task of in­
creased activities and recruiting workers to perform the services
required. During a recession the recruitment of labor is generally
simple, but the location of the greater bulk of the unemployed in
eastern urban areas may retard the initiation of projects that are
undertaken in less densely populated regions of the country. As a
result, the problem of mobility is a major disadvantage of natural
resource expenditures as a countercyclical influence. Additional dis­
advantages are that expenditures for resource development usually
involve the use of little machinery and equipment, hence reducing
the secondary and tertiary influence of such spending, and rarely
employ manpower at the skills practiced prior to unemployment.
These are serious disadvantages that restrict the potential impact of
such programs and decrease their attractiveness to the unemployed
worker. Many resource development activities, such as the improve­
ment of watersheds, small upstream flood-control projects, reduction
in forest-fire hazard, and the like, provide some gain, however, even
though a whole area is not covered or the original plan is not fully
completed.
3 Professor Abbott describes well, it somewhat cynically, the forces th a t work against
curtailm ent of exp en d itu re: “Spending begets an organization of spenders— an adm inistra­
tive staff as a minimum, supported by an adm inistrative budget, to supervise the outlay
of the appropriation. Spending necessarily produces records, and records in the Govern­
ment seem to have a w ill and an ability to survive and perpetuate them selves th at are
alm ost independent o f the desires or actions of the recordkeepers. Very often It results
in the acquisition by the Government of assets th at must be preserved and m aintained—
office furnishings, If nothing more. Alm ost alw ays It fath ers ‘projects’ which w ill take
some m onths or years to complete and which m ust be continued or else result in a complete
w aste of the public moneys already spent. By Its nature It develops, from out of its own
adm inistrative organization, experts who can, from their fam iliarity w ith the records that
they them selves keep, assem ble more fa cts In its defense than can be brought to bear by
its opponents who do not have ready access to the Information. Above all, spending
establishes a host of vested interests th at range from the employees actually on the payroll
to the business firms and local government bodies in the d istricts where the funds are
spent.” (B y permission from Management of the Federal Debt, by C. C. Abbott. Copyright,
1946, McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., p. 166.)




692

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T a b le

II.— State expenditures for natural resources
[In millions]
1915

Natural resource expenditures................
Total State expenditures........................
Resources expenditure (percent of
total)......................................................

1925

1930 1937* 1940

1941

1942

1943

1944

1945

132
56
74
59
101
119
123
119
144
3
448 1,603 2,275 2,629 4,569 5,491 5,515 5,510 5,709 5,775
.67
1946

3.6
1947

3.3
1948

2.2
1949

2.2
1950

2.2
1951

2.2
1952

2.1
1953

2.3
1954

2.5
1955

762
207 244
290
477
518
548
531
Natural resource expenditures...............
166
793
Total State expenditures......................... 6,216 7,953 10, 211 11,557 12,907 15, 020 15,834 16, 850 36,607 40,375
Resources expenditure (percent of
3.4
3.2
2.1
2.4
2.5
3.5
total)....................................................
3.5
2.0
2.7
2.6
1 Financial Statistics of States not published in 1935.
Source: Unless otherwise indicated, “Natural Resource" expenditures from Bureau of Census, Summary
of State Government Finances, and “Total State Expenditures" from Statistical Abstract of the United
States, 1915-40, vol. 64 (1942); 1941, vol. 65 (1943); 1942-48, vol. 71 (1950); 1949-50, vol. 73 (1952); 1951-52, vol.
75 (1954); 1953, vol. 76 (1955); 1954-55, vol. 78 (1957). “Natural Resource” expenditures for 1953-55 from
Statistical Abstract. Tne revised data for the years 1942,1944,1946, and 1948, issued in Bureau of Census,
Revised Summary of State Governmental Finances, 1942-50, has been disregarded to emphasize data
consistency within a year period as opposed to comparability over a period of years.

F or the most part, State expenditures for the development of
natural resources (recorded in table I I ) cover activities similar to
those of the Federal Government, although a large component of such
expenditures is generally for agricultural assistance. I t is ques­
tionable whether much of the assistance to agriculture by both the
State and Federal governments can be legitimately classified as de­
veloping natural resources. Even an expenditure, such as the socalled soil-bank program which is defended as a conservative measure,
largely an expedient to achieve other objectives: reduce surplus agri­
cultural output by withdrawing acreage from cultivation and increase
some farmers’ income (generally the more articulate) through govern­
ment subsidy.
Although both the legitimacy of such subsidies as natural resource
development expenditures and the soundness of such a program of
income redistribution can be questioned, it remains th at such ex­
penditures usually can be accomplished without the time lag that char­
acterizes most construction projects and other activities for which
there is not an existing, well-operating bureaucracy. Aside from the
important question of whether it is desirable to perpetuate misallocation of resources in the agricultural industry, which frequently ex­
hibits a deficiency of mobility from the field, these types of pay­
ments—like any subsidy that requires negative or no action—lend
themselves well to counter-cyclical manipuation. One great disad­
vantage is the tendency of such payments to be built into our system
and become “normal” government expenditures, especially in those
portions of the agricultural industry exhibiting more or less chronic
depression. Moreover, it is possible th at the various subsidy pay­
ments to agriculture have already reached a magnitude th a t prohibits
very much upward flexibility without compounding seriously the
problem of inequity in the distribution of farm income and the prob­
lem of the imbalance of reseources between the agricultural and nonagricultural industries.



693

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Certain types of expenditures, such as Federal aid to State and
local governments that encourage decision-making and administration
by the lower units of government, may have special advantages over
purely Federal actions—particularly if the Federal-aid system re­
quires financial participation by the lower unit of government. I t
is sometimes argued that at the lower level of government the citizen
is better acquainted with “local” issues and more likely to arrive at a
“rational” decision.4 Even if we accept the above thesis, two fac­
tors appear to restrict the extent to which the advantage of “local
rationality” can be exploited: the inability of State and local govern­
ments to keep pace or “match” Federal expenditures during deflation
and, as the data in tables I I I and IY indicate, the size of such expendi­
tures is not very impressive.
By adapting the share to be matched by the non-Federal agency
to the financial capacity of the lower governmental unit, however,
it may be possible to increase expenditures during deflation periods on
projects that bring greater participation by State and local units of
government. An example of the type of program that might be ex­
panded is found in the W ater Pollution Control Act of 1956, Pub­
lic Law 660, which provides Federal assistance to municipalities for
the construction of water pollution abatement systems. Although the
amounts appropriated for 1957 and 1958 are comparatively small, a
serious approach to the problem of control of water pollution in the
United States may provide expenditure opportunities of a quite dif­
ferent order of magnitude. The fiscal experience of the somewhat
experimental recent approach to the control of water pollution is
tabulated in table V.
T able

III. — Grants-in-aid to State and local governments for natural-resource
development
[In millions]
1950

1951

1952

1953

Agriculture: W atershed
protection and flood preNatural-resource

develop-

17

18

20

23

1954

1955

1956

Resource aid, percent of

1958 *

6

10

16

20

28

25

26

26

37
2

39
3

7

62

Construction'of waste-treatTotal grants-in-aid, shared
revenues, loans, and re-

1957 i

2,269

2,434

2,604

2,857

2,657

3,124

3,753

3,317

3,848

.75

.74

.77

.80

1.2

1.2

1.1

1.9

3.4

l Estimated.
Source: Bureau ol the Budget, The Budget of the U. S. Government.
* See R. A. Dahl and C. E. Lindblom, V ariation in Public Expenditure, Income Stabiliza­
tion for a Developing Democracy, op. cit.




694
T a b le

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

IV.— Federal aid to State and local governments for natural resources,z
fiscal years 1950, 1952, 1954-37
[In thousands]
1956
1957
(esti­
(esti­
mated)3 mated)3

1952

1954

1955

Total aid to States and local govemmcnts- $43,654

$57,280

$75, 045

$83, 202

$86,570

$108, 547

16,957

19,755

24, 940

25, 934

25,983

36, 550

150
10,465
300
10,880
4,188

150
10, 465
3.000
11,700
4,035

1950

Aid for natural resources

9,466

10, 037

9, 800

108
9,509

7,491

9,518
200

12, 848
2,293

12, 796
3,522

Proposed legislation:
Partnership projects (Defense, Army

5.000

Partnership projects (Interior Depart-

Proceeds to States, sales of public lands,
Boulder Canyon project, payments to Ari­
zona. Nevada............................. ..................
Oregon Mid California land-grant fund, to
Coos Bay Wagon Road grant lands, Oregon.
Oil and gas royalty payments, Oklahoma,
Migratory Bird Conservation Act,

to

National-forest fund, to States for counties-.
National-forest receipts, Arizona, New
Flood Control A c t ..........................................
TVA, payments in lieu of taxes.. ...............
Loans and repayable advances (net of collec-

2,200
26,697

37,525

50,105

57, 268

60,587

69,797

28
185

28
288

35
349

33
352

31
370

37
368

5

118
(*)

67
1

86
1

134
3

246
2

600

600

600

600

600

600

1,762
44
4
11,325

3,172

6,422

6
15,108

9
18,741

11,756
143
12
22,189

9,000
43
7
24,940

8,755
50
8
26,917

3 1,991

255

7,753

13,993

471
26
18,695

564
26
16,471

547
26
19,428

550
26
26,089

61
468
2,471

107
813
3,036

123
989
3,579

103
1,053
3,878

114
1,190
4,152

115
1,250
4,786
2,200
2,200

* Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding.
* In the budget of the United States Government for the fiscal year ending June 30,1957.
3 Part of a larger appropriation account.
* Less than $500.
S o u rce: Bureau of the Budget, The Budget of the U. S. Government, 1957, pp. 1148­
1149 ; 1956, pp. 1192-1193 ; 1954, pp. 113 2 -1 1 3 3 ; 1952, pp. 996-997.
T a b l e V .— Fiscal data on water pollution control appropriations
[In thousands]
1957

General headquarters activities, including Sanitary Engineering Center at

1958

$2,000

$3,000

2,224
50,000

3, 500
45,000

54,224

51,500

Source: U. S. Public Health Service.

This program is selected for special attention B because it is pre­
eminently a m atter of resource development (or resource rehabilita­
BA sim ilar problem resulting from urban concentration, air pollution, m ight have been
chosen as an illustration of a Federal grants program for resource development, but the
air-pollutlon program even more than the w ater pollution control program is In its
Infancy. Public Law 158, 84th Cong., 1955, established “An act to provide research and
technical assistance relating to air-pollutlon control.” A t the present tim e expenditures
have been concentrated prim arily upon research and study carried on w ith States, Federal
agencies, and universities. The program is administered by the U. S. Public H ealth
Service and has the follow ing appropriation record : 1956, $1,784,000; 1957, $2,740,000;

and 1958, $4,000,000.



695

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

tio n ); it involves' a resource whose use extends to the most varied
directions (industrial, agricultural, domestic, and recreational) ; it
involves issues of interstate jurisdiction that compel Federal partici­
pation and possible initiation, but require decisions and construction
at the local level; and it appears to have favorable countercyclical
fiscal characteristics. Construction of pollution-abatement installa­
tions take place in local communities, with greater need for such
abatement installations generally coinciding with the more highly
industrialized, heavily populated urban centers. The local organiza­
tion for administering such installations (local waterworks or sewagedisposal authorities) are frequently available to undertake such
programs.6 The engineering design for pollution-abatement systems
is relatively standardized and the installations themselves are not
subject to unique local specifications or wide stylistic variations, such
as is the case with housing developments, school plans, fiood-control
projects, and the like. The construction of pollution-abatement
systems uses large amounts of concrete, moderate quantities of steel,
and specialized pumping equipment, thus promising some degree of
stimulation to investment as well as to consumption. Finally, al­
though such systems operate most successfully when construction is
completed to capacity design, it is possible to terminate construction
somewhat short of the optimum plan and still obtain benefit from the
installation.7
C

r it e r ia fo r t h e

S

e l e c t io n o f

P

N

atural

R

eso u r c e

D

evelopm ent

r o je c t s

“Crab and all sorts of things * * * plenty of choice, only make up
your mind.”
Alice’s problem of choice was small compared with decision making
in the formulation of public policy. Complications occur in making
up the public mind as a result o f : (1) The necessity for a small num­
ber of individuals (legislators and administrators) to decide on the
basis of imperfect information what other people would like; (2) the
special nature of conflicting public policy objectives, such as the
goals of stimulation of economic activity or improvement of resource
allocation,8 which do not lend themselves to decisions on the basis of
personal experience; (3) the lack of a ready mechanism, such as the
market economy, that can be relied upon more or less automatically to
assemble a consensus from conflicting opinions.
fl A serious and increasingly im portant reservation should be noted in the case of the
available community adm inistrative organization for undertaking w ater pollution-control
projects. The growth of m etropolitanism , i. e., the spread of residential developments
beyond the boundaries of existing community adm inistrative organization, m ay be expected
to create more rather than less adm inistrative no man’s land.
7 Pollution-treatm ent plants are usually designated as “primary” or “secondary.”
Primary treatm ent consists of settlem ent and secondary treatm ent involves filtration and
biological reaction. F lexibility in pollution treatm ent may be obtained by treating less
than the total volume of the community’s w aste water and through progressive expension
of pollution treatm ent from primary to secondary coverage. Although it is generally
conceded th a t virtu ally all com m unities should provide primary treatm ent as a means of
w ater-pollution control, the practice is far from universal, thus providing an opportunity
for extensive expenditure. Further exibility is available in the decision to advance from
primary to secondary treatm ent.
8 T hus the payment of subsidies to farmers for not producing m ay be a more flexible
form ofcountercycle stim ulation than housing projects, but at the same tim e m ay enhance
the m isallocation of the economy’s productive resources.




696

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Although the problem of decision making in public policy is by no
means new, with each enlargement of the variety and extent of gov­
ernmental activities the impact of public policy upon the economy
becomes more significant. Growth in size and variety of Government
undertakings has stimulated interest and research in developing
procedure by which public-policy decisions will be more nearly in
accord with defensible standards of choice.9 The most refined attempt
to provide a basis for economic evaluation of public expenditures by
a governmental agency is found in the Report to the Federal In ter­
agency Eiver Basin Committee on Proposed Practices for Economic
Analysis of River Basin Projects10 by the subcommittee on benefits
and costs. This document has been prepared through the cooperation
of the Departments of Agriculture, Commerce, and Interior, the
Army Corps of Engineers, and the Federal Power Commission. These
departments and agencies represent most of the important Federal
Government units that carry on programs for the development of
natural resources. Although skepticism is undoubtedly justified in
appraising the influence that some parts of the interagency report
have had upon either the participating Federal agencies or Congress,
it provides an accepted framework for the presentation and analysis
of economic data for most federally sponsored water-control projects.
As a result, adherence to the philosophy and procedures advanced in
the interagency report are sometimes im portant features in the com­
petition for appropriations and the justification before Congress of
agency expenditures. Briefly, project justification relies heavily upon
benefit-cost analysis, which in turn is very closely identified with the
standards of value established in the private market economy. For
example, the interagency report holds that—
* * * In order for the effects of a project to have economic
value in terms of benefits or costs it is necessary th at there be
a need or demand for the goods and services produced by or
used for the project.
The most practicable measure of the relative desirability
of goods and services for meeting the various needs and de­
mands which exist is the market price in dollars. * * * To
the extent th at project effects can be assigned an actual or
estimated market value, they may be defined as benefits and
costs in terms of the market value in dollars of the increases
or decreases in goods and services that are expected to result
if a project is undertaken.11
’
Although the interagency report is studded with careful disclaimers
that private market data alone should not serve as the basis for deter­
mining the acceptability of a Federal project, the very nature of
•M ajor contributions to the investigation of policy determ ination in governm ental
natural resource-using projects have been made by S. V. Ciriacy-W antrup. Resource Con­
servation : Econom ics and Policies (B erkeley: U niversity of California, 1 0 5 2 ): 0 . Eck­
stein. Benefits and C osts: Studies in the Econom ics of Public Works E valuation (Cam­
bridge: Ph. D. thesis. Harvard U niversity, April 1 9 5 5 ): R. N. McKean, Cost-Beneflt
A nalysis and Efficiency in Government (Santa M onica: RAND Corp., 1955). The m ost
thoroughgoing Federal agency studv of th is problem is to be found in Proposed P ractices
for Economic Analysis of River Basin P r o je c ts: Report to the Federal Interagency River
Basin Committee (prepared by Subcomm ittee on Benefits and Costs, W ashington, D. C.,
May 1950). This report is generally known as the Green Book.
10 Cited above, note 9.
* Ibid., pp. 7 -8 .




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

697

the benefit-cost ratio, which is the end product of the benefit-cost
analysis, creates an almost irresistible temptation to place primary
emphasis upon this succinct and ready means of comparing different
projects. Unfortunately the admonitions to evaluate projects in
terms of their appropriateness from the standpoint of the public
viewpoint may be rather futile if the benefit-cost ratio excludes con­
siderations that are not expressed by data translated from or into
the parameters of the private market economy. In such a case the
decisive point is the dividing line between so-called tangible and
intangible benefits, with the former comprising the benefit side of the
ratio and the latter “described with care” and “recognized and con­
sidered apart from the analysis of monetary values.” 12 The inter­
agency report distinguishes between tangible and intangible effects
as follows:
The tangible effects of a project are, for the purposes of
this report, defined as those measurable in monetary terms,
and the intangible effects are those which cannot be measured
in monetary terms. Most of the effects of most projects,
whether benefits or costs, can be evaluated on the basis of
market prices. Some tangible effects cannot be evaluated di­
rectly on the basis of market prices, but their values may in
some cases be derived or estimated indirectly from prices
established in the market for similar or analogous effects or
may be derived from the most economical cost of producing
similar effects by alternate means. Other effects cannot be
evaluated in monetary terms by any satisfactory device and
so are called intangible.13
I t is understandable that the typical Congressman, harried by a
nagging conscience to try to cut Federal expenditures, should be at­
tracted by a benefit-cost ratio that purports to reveal clearly and
quickly whether a particular public project in natural resource devel­
opment is worth the Government expenditure that is requested. The
answer is seemingly simple: if the ratio of benefit to cost is greater
than unity, the Government is getting its “money’s worth.” Projects
that have a higher ratio of benefit to cost must be better Government
“investments” than undertakings with a lower ratio. Although it is
of course possible to look behind the benefit-cost ratio to the analysis
of the data and the description of the intangible features of a given
project, those activities that do not lend themselves to monetary inter­
pretation are at a greater competitive disadvantage in the struggle
for congressional appropriations—especially in the press of Washing­
ton decision-making.
In view of the strong emphasis in the interagency report on the
use of private market data as measures of benefits and cost and the
frequent allusion that the cost to the community of resource use by
the Federal Government is the output consequently foregone by p ri­
vate production, it is surprising that participating agencies do not
necessarily consider the benefit-cost ratio to provide information on
whether resources should be shifted from the private to the public
sector of the economy. One would expect—and most reviewers have




698

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

assumed—that the emphasis upon private market data and standards
has been prim arily for the purpose of facilitating comparison between
public and private direction of resources and providing a measure
of effeciency.
Two major aspects of project cost accounting prevent the benefit/
cost ratio from indicating whether it is economical to shift resources
from the private to the public sector of the economy: (1) the use of a
21/2 percent interest rate and (2) the unsatisfactory arrangement for
tax allowance. Although a low rate of interest may correspond to
the long-term Federal Government borrowing rate, thus in a partial
sense representing the risk to the lender, such a rate can hardly reflect
adequately the economic hazard of investment in a given resource
development project. Indeed, if the repayment history of some irri­
gation developments is indicative of “return on investment,” a
phenomenally higher rate of interest might be required to attract
resources away from the private economy for such activities. I t may
be unnecessary to point out th at the Federal Government borrowing
rate is largely disassociated from the risk and uncertainty of the
projects that it undertakes and therefore provides no basis for relating
private and public investment.
In considering the proper treatment of taxation in the benefit-cost
analysis, the interagency report is concerned prim arily with the aggre­
gate effect of such levies upon the tax capacity of the economy or the
pertinent region. I t is apparently not concerned with the impact
that a given method of tax accounting may have upon the scale of
development of resource use in public as compared with private under­
takings. Although portions of the report’s consideration of tax ac­
counting are subject to conflicting interpretation, apparently an allow­
ance for taxes comparable to that encountered in similar private
investment is made through reduction in price (but not to measure
benefits), rather than addition to cost. Since benefits are measured
when possible by the prevailing market price, the allowance for taxes
via price reduction in effect permits the Government investment to
exploit a lower portion of the demand curve. In other words, it is
simple to justify larger capacity than comparable private installations
if the benefits for the public installation are measured by the price
obtained by the private installation, and if the Government price and
cost actually does not include a tax allowance equivalent to the tax-cost
outlay by the private firm. The effect of this accounting technique—
including tax outlays in establishing project benefits and excluding
them in computing project costs—is to provide a purely artificial basis
for the expansion of Government installations. This stimulus to
expansion will of course cause the greatest distortion in resource allo­
cation vis-a-vis the private economy when the activity involved is
subject to significant economy of scale.14
14 The relevant portions of the interagency report appear to be the fo llo w in g :
“* * * ^ h e primary effect of a river-basin project on local governm ent u nits arises from
changes in the real-estate tax base. The local governm ent revenues may in some cases
be reduced to a greater extent than the corresponding reduction in the costs of the serv­
ices it provides. In other cases, the local tax revenues may be increased* by the project
proportionally more than are the costs of providing services to such an area. When
decreases in tax revenue in a given taxing unit are offset by decreases in the costs of
governm ental services, no allowance needs to be made in project costs. Also when in ­
creased revenues are sufficient ju st to cover both any increased costs of service and any
losses in tax revenues from lands withdraw n from the tax base, no allowance needs to
be made in project costs. A tax-adjustm ent problem arises when an adversely affected
taxing d istrict cannot benefit from the increased tax returns in other areas which may




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

699

The justification for including taxes on the benefit side and deduct­
ing them when computing government project costs may be the result
of an analytical misconception. I t may be argued, for example, that
since the shift of resources between private and public activities occurs
from “marginal” private investment, the taxation issue “washes out”
because the marginal firm does not bear taxes. The misconception
involved here is that although the marginal firm may not bear taxes—
in the sense that such levies must be compensated for by price adjust­
ment—the effect of the higher private price is to curtail private invest­
ment at the same time that it enhances the benefit figure for public
projects and increases the latter's scale of operation.
The net effect of the use of such a double standard for the treatment
of cost outlays in government and private investment renders invalid
the use of the benefit-cost ratio as a measure of the economic appropri­
ateness in terms of private market appraisal of shifting resources from
the private to the public sector of the economy.
Quite aside from the technical inadequacies of benefit-cost analysis,
however, the appropriateness of using private market standards for
determining public investment is questionable. A t times a half-ad­
ministrative, half-economic argument is made in defense of the use of
these types of evaluation that hold up government expenditures and
investment to the assumed rigorousness of the private market. I t is
contended that although the standard is not perfect, it helps to hold in
check those Federal agencies that are adept at creating local pressuregroup support for their functions and most frequently the benefici­
aries of “pork barrel” appropriations. More often than not, however,
the benefit-cost analysis results not in restraining the agencies that
have built empires of bureaucracy, but merely hamstringing other
agencies that have not yet developed such an effective entree to the
Federal purse.
Although benefit-cost analysis is not intended to provide the only or
main basis for project justification, very frequently it has attained an
influence in decisionmaking quite out of keeping with its proper role—
even if the analysis were performed satisfactorily. The acceptance of
the private market standard as a criterion for Federal project justifi­
cation places the public interest in a peculiar double jeopardy. The
private market standard, i. e., justification of public investment on
the basis of whether it can yield a return commensurate with private
investment, ignores the critical difference between the purposes of p ri­
vate and public economic activities. Moreover this procedure confers
on resource allocation decisions of the private market an economic and
ethical omniscience unfortunately not possessed by the market econ­
omy. Although the American economy has an impressive record by
pragmatic test of its ability to increase national output, it does not
follow that its ordering of resource allocation represents the apogee
of output and efficiency. There are areas in the American economy
where its efficiency is under restraint and other areas where the direc­
have their tax base raised by the project * * *. The total reduction in net tax revenues
in adversely affected taxing d istricts may be regarded as a project benefit, and may be
accounted for as a deduction from tax charges included in associated costs.
“ * * * When the benefits of a Federal projects [sic] are evaluated on the basis of
the cost of producing sim ilar products from an alternative private source, the estim ate of
private costs should include taxes th at would be payable. Proper comparison may also
be obtained if project costs for given purposes are compared with the charges less taxes
for comparable products and services from private sources” (ibid., pp. 30, 3 1 ).




700

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

tion of resources seem to falter. The efficiency of the market economy
is retarded by various monopoly restrictions of business and labor, by
certain subsidies and controls imposed by government, by an institu­
tional background that affects mobility of resources, by less than com­
plete consumer knowledge, which sometimes makes the “consumer sov­
ereignty” doctrine read backward.
But even if the view is accepted that the market economy cannot
be excelled in the excellence of its efficiency, we are confronted with
the fact that the private market must avoid those activities th at are
not susceptible to the precept that price must cover cost. The result
is well known. Such functions as education, public health, and na­
tional defense must be carried on outside the framework of the private
market. Moreover, the pattern of resource allocation th at results
from consumer choice cannot be sanctified with ethical justification.
The production arrangements and the distribution of goods and serv­
ices in the American economy conform to no higher ethical standards
than those implicit in the underlying distribution of wealth and in­
come in our society. I t appears strangely inappropriate th at the value
system of the private market should be accorded such importance in
the selection and justification of Federal projects when one of the
main functions of government is to initiate or supplement activities
that cannot be adequately performed by the market. Such a partial
view of the problem of project selection as th at presented by the
benefit-cost ratio acts as a Procrustean mold to eliminate noncon­
formity with the decisions of the market economy. To point out
the inadequacy of this approach, however, is not to decry the use of
economic analysis for project justification. The remedy for this sit­
uation is more, not less, economic analysis—but an analysis th at does
more than mirror the value judgments of the private market. Eco­
nomic analysis must include a careful consideration of the public
interest.