View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

PRIN CIPLES OF BUDGET DETERMINATION
Richard A. Musgrave, professor of economics, University of
Michigan
The people of the United States are generally agreed that the econ­
omy is to be organized on the premise of free consumer choice, that
production is to be carried on by privately owned and operated firms,
and that the market should be relied upon where possible to transm it
the desires of the consumer to these firms. This being our basic form
of organization, why is it that a substantial p art of the economy’s
output is provided for through the budget? This question must be
answered to begin with, if we wish to say something about the
“proper” scope or composition of the budget.
The budgetary activity of the Government is needed because the
ricing system of the market cannot deal with all the tasks th at must
e met in order to operate a sound economy and a healthy society.
Certain tasks must be performed by government. Some may deplore
this fact and dream of a setting where everyone could live in peace
without any kind of governmental activity; others may feel th at the
necessity of social and economic policy at the governmental level en­
riches the challenge of social life and makes for a more balanced
society. Whatever one’s values in this respect, the nature of things
is such that budgetary activity is needed. The question then is under
what circumstances and why this need arises.
The answer to this question is too complex to permit a simple and
uniform solution. In my own thinking I have found it useful to dis­
tinguish between three major functions of budget policy, including—
1. The provision for social wants, which requires the Govern­
ment to impose taxes and make expenditures for goods and serv­
ices, to be supplied free of direct charge to the consumer;
2. The application of certain corrections to the distribution of
income as determined in the market requiring the Government to
add to the income of some by transfers while reducing the income
of others by taxes; and
3. The use of budget policy for purposes of economic stabili­
zation, rendering it necessary under some conditions to raise the
level of demand by a deficit policy and under others to curtail
demand by a surplus policy.
I shall comment briefly on the nature of each of these three functions,
and on how they are interrelated.

E

P

r o v is io n f o r

S o c ia l W

ants

When I say that the Government must provide for the satisfaction
of social wants, it does not follow that the Government itself must
carry on the production of the goods and services which are needed to
satisfy these wants. This may be necessary in some cases, as for in108




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

109

stance with the provision for police protection, which can hardly be
left to a private agent, but this is the exception rather than the rule.
In most cases there is no such need. I f new planes or government
buildings are to be provided for, they may be purchased from private
firms. The essence of budgetary provision for the satisfaction of
social wants, therefore, is not production by government. I t is pay­
ment for goods and services through budgetary finance, and supply
of such services free of direct charge to the consumer.
W hat, then, are the social wants which must be provided for in
this fashion? Some people have argued that they are wants which
in a mysterious fashion are experienced by the Nation as a whole, and
thus reflect the desires of the collective entity. This makes little sense
in our setting. The desire for the satisfaction of social wants is ex­
perienced by individuals, no less than that for the satisfaction of p ri­
vate wants. This is not where the difference lies. The basic problem
of social wants arises because their satisfaction, by their very nature,
requires that the goods and services in question must be consumed in
equal amounts by all. Social wants differ in this important respect
from private wants, where each consumer may arrange his personal
pattern of consumption such as to satisfy his own personal tastes.
Thus, I may go to the market and purchase whatever amounts and
type of clothing, housing, or food may suit my tastes and resources;
but I must be satisfied with the same municipal services as are re­
ceived by my neighbors, or with the same degree and type of foreign
protection as is granted to all other citizens of the United States. This
crucial fact, that certain services must be consumed in equal amounts
by all, has important consequences.
One consequence is that you cannot apply what I like to refer to
as the exclusion principle.1 Since all people must consume the same
amounts, no one can be excluded from the enjoyment of services
aimed at the satisfaction of social wants. Everyone benefits, whether
he contributes little or heavily to their cost. Now you might say that
this is not too difficult a problem. Let the tax collector see to it that
everyone pays. Unfortunately this overlooks the real difficulty. The
real difficulty is not that people are unwilling to pay unless forced
to; it is that of determining just how much various people should be
called upon to contribute.
This difficulty does not arise with the satisfaction of private wants
in the market. Here the individual consumer is forced to bid against
others in order to get what he wants. The pricing mechanism, as it
were, is an auctioning device by which things go to those who value
them most, as evidenced by what they are willing to pay. People
must bid to get what they want, and thereby provide the producer
with the necessary signal of what to produce. In the case of social
wants this signal is not forthcoming. Consumers know that they can­
not be excluded and that their own contribution will weigh very
lightly in the total picture. Thus they will not reveal their true pref­
erences on a voluntary basis and offer to pay accordingly. Therefore
it is no easy task to determine just what social wants should be rec­
ognized and how much each should be called upon to contribute.
1 A second consequence, which has been pointed out by Professor Samuelson, is th a t there
would be no single best solution to the budget problem, applying the usual criterion of
econom ic efficiency, even If the preferences of a ll Individuals were known. T his aspect Is
•omitted from the present discussion,

97733—57------9



110

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

A further difference is th is: F o r goods supplied in the satisfaction of
private wants, competition sets a uniform price in the market. In ­
dividual consumers, depending on their personal tastes, can buy dif­
ferent amounts at that price. F or goods supplied in the satisfac­
tion of social wants, all must consume the same amount, and those who
value public services more highly must pay a higher unit price.
This much is clear, but the question is just what should be supplied
and just how much each should pay. The market cannot give the
solution and a political process is needed to accomplish this task. By
choosing among various budget programs, including various expend­
iture plans and various tax plans to cover the costs, the voters can
express their preferences in the matter. Since they know th at the
law, once decided upon, will apply to each of them, they will find it
in their interest to reveal their preferences and to vote for the plan,
or the approximation thereto, which is most appealing to them. Thus
preferences are revealed through the political process. While the
minority might be dissatisfied, and strategies m ight be used in voting,
an acceptable approximation to the preferences of the individual
members of the group is reached.
All this is somewhat of an oversimplification. Individuals do not
vote personally on each issue. Rather, they elect representatives who
vote for them. Thus, the function of the representative is to crystal­
lize public opinion with regard to such issues, budgetary and other,
and to find groups of issues on which their constituents can agree.
The Member of Congress is a go-between, whose function it is to work
out compromises and solutions which are acceptable to the majority.
By saying this I do not mean to slight the educational function of
political leadership, nor do I wish to underestimate the importance of
the contribution to be rendered by the executive branch and by the
civil service. All these are important, but the basic process is one
of transforming individual preferences into social wants.
In taking this view of social wants, I am thinking in the framework
of what since Adam Smith has been referred to as the benefit principle
of taxation. In other words, budget policy should provide for goods
and services in response to the social wants of individuals, and to
make this possible, individuals should contribute as closely as possible
in response to their evaluation of these social wants. The great value
of this approach, from the point of view of the economist, is th at it
requires us to determine public expenditures together with the revenue
side of the budget. In this basic sense, there can be no theory of
public expenditures without a theory of taxation, and vice versa.
W hat does the benefit approach mean regarding the distribution of
the tax bill between people with different levels of income ? I will not
attempt to answer this in a categorical form, but I can point to the
considerations on which the answer should depend: This is whether
the goods and services supplied for the satisfaction of social wants are
largely in the nature of necessities or luxuries. I f they are largely
in the nature of necessities, the answer leads to regression; if they are
prim arily in the nature of luxuries the answer points to progression.
I f people wish to spend the same fraction at all levels of income the
answer leads to proportional taxation.2 While a moderate degree of
3 In technical terms, the tax structure w ill be proportional if the income elasticity of
social w an ts is unity, progressive if it is greater than unity, and regressive if i t is sm aller
than unity.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

111

progression would seem the reasonable answer, this is by no means the
only consideration entering into the distribution of the total tax bill.
Finally, a word about the m atter of budgetary balance. Insofar as
the satisfaction of social wants is concerned, the budget must be bal­
anced, in the sense th at goods provided for through the budget must
be paid for over their useful life. This merely reflects the fact that
resources used for the satisfaction of social wants cannot be used for
other purposes, and someone must bear the cost. A t the same time,
we shall see that this is only one among other considerations. I t does
not follow that the total budget must be balanced.
I need hardly add that this brief disi ussion of social wants does not
cover the entire picture. Not all public services are supplied in
response to the individual preferences of the consumers. There may
be instances when the majority decides that certain wants of indi­
viduals should be satisfied, even though these individuals would prefer
to be given the cash and use it for other purposes. Free education or
hospital services may be cited to illustrate this case. This type of
public service requires a different explanation. However, note that
the benefits derived from such services extend beyond the specific bene­
ficiary, and thus approach what I have described as the central type
of social wants.
A

d ju s t m e n t s in

the

D

is t r ib u t io n o f

I

ncom e

I now turn to the second function of budget policy, which is to pro­
vide for adjustments in the distribution of income. We are all agreed
that it is the responsibility of society to undertake certain adjustments
in the distribution of income, which results from the forces of the
market, the laws of inheritance, and differences in abilities to acquire
income. Babies must be assured adequate food, the sick and the aged
must be given proper care, and so forth. Beyond this, some hold to an
idea of the good society which requires a fairly extensive degree of
income equalization, others would favor a moderate degree of equali­
zation, while still others might oppose any such measure and favor
a high degree of inequality. These are matters of social philosophy
and value judgment on which we all have our own views. Moreover,
consideration must be given to the interrelation between income dis­
tribution and the total income which is available for distribution.
My concern here is not wTith the question as to which is the best set
of values. While I happen to feel that progressive taxation is fair,
this is not the point. My point is that if society wishes to make dis­
tributional adjustments, it is desirable as a matter of economic policy
to make them through the tax-transfer mechanism of the budget. This
is preferable to distributional adjustments via manipulation of p a r­
ticular prices, be it of products or of factors of production. Certainly,
we cannot accept the stricture that the purpose of taxation is to finance
public services and nothing else, and that, therefore, they “must not”
be used for distributional adjustments. There is no such law in the
order of things. Indeed, where distributional adjustments are to be
made, this is the logical way in which to make them.
The determination of the desired degree and type of distributional
adjustment is, again a m atter of political process, and I will not discuss
it here. Let us suppose that some degree of income equalization is to
be accomplished. This calls for taxes on some people with incomes



112

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

above the average and for transfer payments to some people with
incomes below the average. Insofar as distributional adjustments are
concerned, the budget must again be balanced. Now you may argue
that such a general tax-transfer scheme does not appear in the budget,
except perhaps in the social-security programs, and th at our budget
does not engage in distributional adjustments. This is not the case.
The distributional adjustments are implicit in a distribution of the
overall tax bill in a way which is more progressive than would be
justified on the basis of assigning the cost of social wants on a benefit
basis. In other words, the budget as we know it and as it is enacted
reflects the net result of various component policies. More about this
in a moment.
Ju st as my discussion of allocating the cost of social wants moved in
the context of a benefit approach to taxation, so does the problem of
distributional adjustment belong in the sphere of ability to pay and
equal sacrifice doctrines. The two approaches are wholly compatible
if each is viewed in its own context. The argument th at the cost of
public services should be allocated in accordance with ability to pay
sounds nice, but it gives us no foundation on which to decide what
public services should be rendered. This can be done only in relation
to individual preferences and implies the spirit of benefit taxation.
I can see no other approach that leads to a sensible solution. A t the
same time, it is non sequitur to argue th a t progressive taxation is out
o f order because (assuming this to be the case) benefit taxation requires
proportional rates. The element of progression may be called for in
order to implement distributional adjustments, which is quite a differ­
ent matter.
Failure to distinguish between the problem of distributional adjust­
ment and the problem of providing for the satisfaction of social wants
leads to confusion on both counts. I f the degree of distributional
adjustment is tied to the level of the budget, some may favor an
increase in the level of public services as a means of extending distri­
butional adjustments, even though they do not support budget expan­
sion on the basis of benefit taxation; and others, who would favor an
expansion of the budget on this basis will oppose it because in practice
it is related to an extension of distributional adjustments. Moreover,
these relationships change with the level of taxation and the existing
tax structure. While there was a time when the marginal taxpayer
was the fellow with the large income, we are now in a situation where
increased levels of public services largely involve increased tax contri­
butions from (or exclude tax reductions for) people in the middle or
middle to lower income groups. Thus the politics of the fiscal problem
are changed and essential public services will go begging in the
process.
B

udget

P

o l ic y

and

S t a b il iz a t io n

I now turn to my third function of budget policy, which is the use
of tax ajid expenditure measures as a means of economic stabilization.
The great achievement of the fiscal-policy discussion of the last 26
years is the by now fairly general recognition th a t fiscal policy must
play an im portant role in economic stabilization. The old view that
the budget should be balanced is applicable only if we consider our
first and second functions of budget policy, and even here some tem­
porary exceptions may arise. Once the stabilizatioh function is intro


ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

113

duced, deficit finance is called for under conditions of potential de­
pression, and surplus finance is called for under conditions of
potential inflation. The point to be noted here is th at the stabiliza­
tion objective of budget policy can be achieved without contradicting
the other requirements of budget policy, namely, efficient provision
for social wants and the application of distributional adjustments.
Regarding the proper level of public services, this means th at there
is no excuse for make-work expenditures during a depression, just as
there is no excuse for cutting essential public services during periods
of high activity. Precisely the same fallacy is involved in both cases.
An increase in public services during the depression is in order, only
to the extent th at the decline in private expenditures for some pur­
poses (such as investment) frees resources which people may wish to
allocate in p art to the satisfaction of social wants; and!a decrease in
public services is in order during the boom only to the extent th at
people wish to divert resources from public use to meet an increased
demand for resources for other uses. This sets the limits of the
permissible adjustment: There is no justification for raising the level
of public services merely to increase aggregate demand, since this
can be done also by lowering taxes; and there is no justification for
cutting public services merely to curtail demand since this can be done
also by raising taxes.
Moreover, there is no need for permitting considerations of sta­
bilization policy to interfere with desired distributional adjustments.
Thus it was argued frequently during the thirties and forties that
taxes on lower incomes should be avoided because this would under­
mine demand and that therefore a more progressive tax structure
was needed; and vice versa for the current case of inflation where it
is held that progression should be reduced to secure a shift of re­
sources from consumption to investment, thus providing for increased
capacity in order to check inflation. The argument makes sense in both
cases if we assume that the total level of tax yield is given, but it
breaks down if we allow for adjustments in the level of taxation. The
level of taxation which is required for purposes of stabilization should
depend upon the distribution of the tax bill, and not the other way
round.
N

et

B

udget a nd

S e p a r a t io n

of

I

ssu es

To bring my point into focus, let me exaggerate a little and assume
th at there are actually 3 different budgets, pursuing respectively my
3 functions of budget policy. First, there is the budget to provide for
the satisfaction of social wants, where taxes are allocated m line with
a benefit principle of taxation. By its nature, this budget is balanced
over the useful life of the services which are supplied. Secondly,
there is the budget to provide for distributional adjustments, involv­
ing tax and transfer payments. By its nature, this budget is balanced
as well. Then there is the budget designed to stabilize the level of
demand. By its nature, this budget involves either taxes or transfer
payments, proportional to what is considered the proper state of
income distribution.
We may think of these budgets as being determined in an inter­
dependent system, where the manager of each of the three branches




j

114

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

takes the action of the other branches as given.3 Having determined
the three budgets, the Government may proceed to administer each
budget separately. This would involve various sets of taxes and/or
transfers for any one person. To simplifj7matters, it will be desirable
to clear the tax and transfer payments against each other, and thus to
administer one net budget policy only.
The actual tax and expenditure plan enacted by the Congress in any
one year reflects such a net budget. This is of advantage as a m atter
of administrative convenience, but it blurs the issues. While it may
be difficult as a m atter of legislative procedure to determine inde­
pendently each of the three subbudgets noted in my discussion, some
lesser steps may be taken in the organization of the budget process, on
both the executive and the legislative side, to move the problem into
a better perspective. To say the least, an understanding of the three
objectives as distinct issues is prerequisite to efficient budget planning.
The preceding discussion will suffice to show th at it is exceedingly
difficult to establish a simple set of principles by which to secure an
8 T o illu s tra te , le t me assum e t h a t th e re are tw o ta x p a y e rs only, X an d Z. A ssum e
f u r th e r t h a t th e fu ll em ploym ent incom e equals $100, an d t h a t X ’s earn in g s a re divided
such t h a t X receives $70 w hile Z receives $30. Now suppose t h a t th e D istrib u tio n B ran ch
im poses ta x e s of $10 on X an d p ay s $10 of tr a n s fe rs to Z, th e d esired d is trib u tio n being
such t h a t X is to receive 60 p ercen t an d Z is to receive 40 p ercent.
N ext, le t me suppose t h a t w ith a n incom e of $100, d istrib u te d in th is fa sh io n , p riv a te
ex p en d itu re on consum ption equals $60 an d th a t ex p en d itu res on in v estm en t equal $30.
M oreover, th e m an ager of th e S ta b iliz a tio n B ran ch is inform ed t h a t e x p en d itu res f o r th e
sa tis fa c tio n of social w a n ts equal $22. T h is m eans t h a t to ta l e x p en d itu res equal $112
an d a re $12 above th e fu ll em ploym ent level. To sim plify m a tte rs, le t us hold in v e stm e n t
c o n sta n t. In o rd er to low er consum ption by $12 th e S ta b ilizatio n B ran ch w ill im pose
ta x e s of $20, i t being assum ed t h a t th e ra tio or consum ption to incom e is c o n s ta n t a t 60
p ercen t. In o rd er n o t to in te rfe re w ith th e d istrib u tio n a l a d ju s tm e n t, $12 w ill be p aid
by X an d $8 by Z.
The incom e of X now equals $70 —$ 1 0 —$12 = $48, w hile t h a t of Z equals $30 + 10 —$8
= 3 2 . Now suppose t h a t both w ish to spend 27.5 p ercen t of th e ir income on th e sa tis fa c ­
tio n of social w an ts. T h u s fo r th e sa tis fa c tio n of social w a n ts ta x e s equal $13.20 fo r X a n d
$8.80 f o r Z, w ith to ta l ex p en d itu res fo r th e sa tis fa c tio n of social w a n ts equal to $22.
T h e th re e su bbudgets involve th e follow ing tra n sa c tio n s :
X

Z

Total

Satisfaction of social wants:
Taxes................................................................................... ..

13.2

8.8

22.0
22.0
00.0

Distributional adjustment:

10.0

10.0

10.0
10.0
00.0

Stabilization adjustment:

12.0

8.0

20.0
20.0

Net budget:

35.2

6.8

42.0
22.0
20.0

Instead of collecting 3 separate taxes from X it will be more convenient to collect the total of $35.20; and
instead of collecting 2 taxes for Z and paying 1 transfer, it will be more convenient to collect net taxes of
$6.80. We thus have net tax receipts of $42 which after allowingfor goods ajld service expenditures of $22
leave us with a surplus of $20, equal to the surplus in the stabilization operation. A similar illustration
might be given where the stabilization operation involves a deficit, in which case there appears a correspond­
ing deficit in the net budget. Finally note that the distribution of the tax bill in the net budget is more
progressive than that for carrying the cost of social wants, but less progressive than that involved in the
distributional adjustment only.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

115

efficient determination of public expenditures. This task involves the
determination of the total budget plan, including the revenue as well
as the expenditure side, and it comprises quite distinct sets of objec­
tives or functions of budget policy. The issues involved are the more
difficult as they cannot be solved, or be solved in p art only, by the
ordinary tools of economic analysis. The political process of decision­
making becomes an inherent p art of the problem.
A t the same time, the complexity of the problem establishes 110 pre­
sumption that the use of resources for the satisfaction of social wants
is less efficient than its use for the satisfaction of private wants. This
must be kept in mind if we are to see the problem of social-want satis­
faction in its proper perspective. While it is obvious that any ex­
penditure objective, once decided upon, should be accomplished at
minimum cost, the objective of efficiency in public expenditure plan­
ning must not be confused with minimizing the level of such expendi­
tures. By the very nature of the budget as an allocation problem, the
danger of inefficiency arises with insufficient as well as with excessive
outlays.