View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

T H E IM PA CTS OF NATIONAL SEC U R ITY E X P E N D I­
TU R E U PON T H E S T A B IL IT Y AND GROW TH OF T H E
AM ERICAN ECONOMY
George H. Hildebrand, professor of economics and director of the
Institue of Industrial Relations, University of California, Los
Angeles, and Norman V. Breckner, assistant professor of economics,
University of California, Los Angeles
This paper evaluates the influence of national security expenditure
from the twin standpoints of stability and growth. By “stability”
we refer prim arily to the absence of major short-run movements in
output and employment, and, to a less extent, prices. By “growth”
we mean both the realized and potential long-run rates of increase in
real gross national product.
Framework o f the analysis

Gross national product serves as a focal point of analysis because it
measures the realized aggregate of both government and private sec­
tor demands upon resources for production. So viewed, security
spending is a major component of aggregate demand, accounting fo r
about 10 percent of gross product currently and as much as 42 percent
in 1944.1 When the rate of security spending persists at a given abso­
lute level, it induces a corresponding rate of output and employment
from the defense sector, while through its income-generating effects
it also contributes indirect support to investment and consumption
as a whole. When security demand changes markedly, it exerts direct
effects upon production and employment in the defense sector. B ar­
ring independent offsetting movements in investment and consump­
tion, changes in security spending will also induce wider parallel
movements in these private components of aggregate demand.
Largely under the stimulus of increased security spending, Govern­
ment demand as a whole (including State and local) has risen to
claim now almost 20 percent of gross national product at full em­
ployment. This fact has much significance both for stability and
growth.
Government demand in general and security demand in particular
are largely independent either of the level, or of changes in the level,
of private consumption and investment. They are, so to speak, insu­
lated from forces producing fluctuations in the private sector because
most Government spending is determined by different considerations.
Thus the level of security spending is governed by the climate of in­
ternational politics and the state of the military art, and it changes
1 All d a ta fo r g ross n a tio n a l p ro d u ct an d its com ponents, in cluding n a tio n a l se cu rity
dxpenditure, h av e been ta k e n from U. S. D ep artm en t of Commerce, N a tio n a l Incom e. 1954
ed itio n (W a sh in g to n : G overnm ent P rin tin g Office, 1 9 5 4 ); Survey of C u rre n t B usiness,
v a rio u s iss u e s; J o in t E conom ic C om m ittee an d Office of S ta tis tic a l S ta n d a rd s. B u reau of
th e B udget, H isto ric a l an d D escriptive S upplem ent to Econom ic In d ic a to rs (W ash in g to n :
G ov ern m en t P rin tin g Office, 1955 a n d 1957) ; an d Council of E conom ic A dvisers, Econom ic
In d ic a to rs, v ario u s issues.
A n n u al eq u iv alen ts of q u a rte rly values fo r gross n a tio n a l p ro d u ct an d i ts com ponents a re
seaso n ally ad ju ste d unless otherw ise indicated.




523

524

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

with these forces. This is not to say th at security demand is always
stable; only that there is no obvious mechanism that compels it to
move in disastrous parallel with swings in investment and consump­
tion. As with most of total Government demand, there is a good
chance that it will prove relatively stable in the midst of movements
originating in the private sector, particular in the shorter term.
This relative stability of security spending tends to dampen swings
in gross product and employment, in particular to check contractions
emanating from the private sector by providing a continuing steady
flow of income-generating expenditure. In more technical language,
it reduces the variance of gross product because security spending is
not closely correlated with investment and consumption and because
it frequently shows more stability than these other major variables
influencing gross product. Again, however, it must be cautioned that
security demand itself can shift sharply for sustained periods. I t
may do so either at the “rig h t” or the “wrong” time, depending upon
the strength of forces operating upon expenditure in the private sec­
tor.
I t will be noted from our review of 1939-57 th a t when security
expenditure has significantly changed, gross product and its other
major determinants have not consistently or promptly responded
either in the same direction or degree. This is hardly surprising.
On some occasions the reason may well be th at firms have anticipated
changes in security purchases well before they became recorded fact,
given th at much knowledge about shifts in procurement programs
is necessarily disseminated in advance. Perhaps a more basic reason
is th a t investment and consumption also reflect the independent
strength or weakness of the private sector. They may move with
security expenditure, as in late 1945 and mid-1953, or they may move
against it, as in mid-1946 and early 1950. Accordingly, it is p ar­
ticularly difficult to isolate the actual impacts of security spending
from a context in which the independent strength or weakness of in­
vestment and consumption is often so obscure. This is only another
way of saying that the aggregate demand for gross national product
is determined by a composite of interacting variables whose behavior
is not yet fully known. I t follows th at it is necessary to guard against
simple cause-and-effect reasoning. While at times swings in security
spending have proved decisive, they are not the sole factor producing
changes in investment and consumption.
I t should also be pointed out that security spending is not the only
component of total government demand. A t times sinces 1939 it has
dominated shifts in government demand, while at others its move­
ments have been offset or complemented by swings in the other cate­
gories of government purchases. In 1944 security purchases ac­
counted for 91.8 percent of all government demand, as against 43.7
percent in 1948 and 52.9 percent in 1956.
Because security spending is commingled with other government
demands and with demands from the private sector, it is particularly
difficult to determine how much product it has absorbed by displacing
these other forms of demand. I f there is serious unemployment and
idle productive capacity, as prevailed between 1939 and mid-1942,
security spending probably involves no significant diversion of re­
sources from other productive uses. Indeed, it may well contribute



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

525

to higher levels of investment and consumption at such times. In
fact we cannot even be finally certain that resources would have been
fully employed at all times during the long boom from mid-1942
through mid-1957 if security spending had fallen well below’ the rates
actually established. In some years it may have increased investment
and consumption demand, rather than displaced it, and at the same
time it may have displaced potential increases in the other types of
government demand.
Furthermore, as we show later, security expenditures undoubtedly
have contributed valuable side benefits to private enterprise, increasing
private product by fostering efficiency, investment, and growth
through promoting the development of new products and technologies.
On this count as well it would be a serious mistake to consider security
expenditure a complete economic loss, granted that it is costly and
does divert productive resources from other potential uses.
W ith this approach in mind, we shall consider next the influence of
security spending upon the economy since 1939. This section begins
with a few facts regarding the trend of such spending to date. There
follows a review of six intervening and mostly short-term movements
in gross product, where their ranges, lengths, and turning points are
compared with the behavior of security spending.
I m pacts

of

N a t io n a l S e c u r it y E x pen d itu r e U pon S t a b il it y , 1939-57

The trend o f security expenditure

Between 1939 and 1956, security expenditure rose from $1.3 billion
to $42.4 billion annually, or almost 32 to 1. I f the intervening extreme
years of the period are ignored, this implies a compound rate of
growth of about 20 percent per year. Since the rate of security spend­
ing has varied sharply with shifts in international tensions, and to a
lesser degree with developments in weapons technology, this 20 per­
cent rate of increase cannot safely be projected into the future.
The trend in the cost of national security is indicated by table 1.
Between 1939 and 1944, the share of national production claimed by
security spending rose from a negligible 1.4 percent to almost 42
percent. By 1956 it had fallen to a modest 10.2 percent, about equal
to the 1946 share and exceeding only the low levels of 1947-50. The
drop in the defense share from 1944 to 1956, which was interrupted by
the Korean war, reflects increased real national output and reduced
levels of security spending. On a per capita basis, national security
in 1939 cost each American $9.92; by 1944 it had soared to a peak of
$640.19, dropping back to $252.12 in 1956.




526

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T a b l e 1.— The changing cost of national security expenditure, 1939-56

[Current dollars]
National security expenditure
Y ear1

1939.................................................
1944............. .......................... ........
1953........................................ ........
1956................................................

Total
(billions)2

$1.3
88.6
51.5
42.4

Percent
of gross
national
product
1.4
41.9
14.2
10.2

Percent
of all Gov­
ernment
purchases *
9.7
91.8
61.0
52.8

Per capita
cost of
national
security
$9.92
640.19
322.61
252.12

Per capita
disposable
personal
income

$538
1,060
1,568
1,708

1 Tbe data per national security expenditures begin with 1939. The years 1944 and 1953 were peaks for
such expenditure in the intervening period.
2 Includes outlays for military service, international security and foreign relations, atomic energy, mer­
chant marine, defense production and economic stabilization, and civil defense. Figures represent Fed­
eral purchases for national security as included in gross national product accounts.
3 Federal, State, and local combined.
Source: U. S. Department of Commerce.

Considering the period as a whole, the big increases in security
spending came during 1941-44 and 1951-53, when the Nation was at
war. Each surge involved considerable price and wage inflation, for
which the increased money supply invoked mainly by deficit financing
of war expenditure was a major cause. Some qualification must be
made for 1950-51, however, when speculative borrowing for inventory
expansion, financed by easy credit, touched off a price-wage infla­
tion well before defense spending got fully underway.
Although the absolute cost of national security remains very high
today and is rising, the burden of these costs is much less than it was
at the wartime peaks of 1944 and 1953. During 1954 and 1955 it fell
about 20 percent below 1953, but it turned upward again in 1956, ris­
ing to an equivalent annual rate of $46.3 billion in the second quarter
of 1957. For a population of 170.4 million, this represents a per capita
cost of $271.71. I f we make the heroic assumption that all security
expenditure could be completely abolished with no change in gross
national product and with no offsetting increases in the other com­
ponents of government demand, we could say roughly that per capita
disposable personal income (after taxes) in 1957 could then be in­
creased from $1,757 per annum to $2,028, or by 15.4 percent. In a crude
way this measure indicates the average amount of income each citizen
must forgo as the price of national security in 1957. However, calcula­
tions of this type assume no decline of national product if security
expenditure were wholly abolished.
How does the cost of national security compare with other coun­
tries? According to the comparative national income accounts pre­
pared by the OEEC for 1954, the shares of gross national product
assigned to defense expenditure were 8.5 percent for the United K ing­
dom, 7.3 percent for France, and 11.4 percent for the United States.
Although the dat a are not strictly comparable, defense expenditure in
the Soviet Union in 1948 (the latest available year) were 8.2 percent
of gross national product.2 Although the relative share is consider­
ably larger for the United States, it must also be remembered that
• D a t a f o r U n ite d K in g d o m a n d F r a n c e fr o m O r g a n iz a tio n f o r E u r o p e a n E c o n o m ic Co­
o p e ra tio n , O E E C S t a t i s t i c a l B u lle tin s , G e n e r a l S ta tis tic s , N o. 2 ( P a r is , A p ril 1 9 5 6 ) ; f o r
th e S o v ie t U n io n fro m A b ra m B e rg so n a n d H a n s H e y m a n n , J r . , S o v ie t N a tio n a l In c o m e a n d
P r o d u c t, 1 9 4 0 -4 8 (N ew Y o r k : C o lu m b ia U n iv e rs ity P r e s s , 1 9 5 4 ), ta b le 6, p. 25.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

527

per capita income levels here are double or more what they are in these
other nations.
Wartime expansion, 1939-J+5

There can hardly be any doubt that the enormous increase of se­
curity expenditure that began in the last quarter of 1940 finally ended
the long depression of the thirties, propelling the economy into boom
times by mid-1942 and compelling continued high-pressure expansion
until almost the end of the war. Once these expenditures started to
take hold, they induced large increases in private investment, drawing
up consumption demand through the accompanying rise of personal
incomes. Here is the clearest case on record to show security spending
in particular, and government spending in general, in the decisive
role of a stimulator to economic expansion. For later movements in
the postwar years, however, the evidence is considerably more mixed
regarding the causal importance of these expenditures.
The wartime experience is important in two other respects. Rela­
tively effective price and wage controls, coupled to a rapid increase in
money supply prim arily occasioned by deficit financing, compelled
a large accumulation of idle cash held by business firms and the pub­
lic. Restrictions upon production of investment and consumers’ goods,
which also promoted the growth of cash balances, built up an impres­
sive backlog of postponed demands. Undoubtedly, the wartime leg­
acies of increased cash holdings and deferred demand together pro­
vided powerful support for total demand in the reconversion period
that followed the end of the war.
Reconversion , 191^5-^7
Beginning with the third quarter of 1945, security spending began
a steep 2-year drop from a peak annual rate of $90.8 billion in early
1945 to $11.7 billion in later 1947, a decline of 87.1 percent. Total
government purchases also fell sharply until mid-1947, although their
contraction was checked somewhat by offsetting gains in nonsecurity
spending. By the final quarter of 1947 total government purchases
were running at a $30 billion annual rate, two-thirds below their peak
in 1945.
Despite official predictions of heavy postwar unemployment with
the inevitable collapse of security spending, unemployment rose only
slightly, reaching a maximum for the reconversion years of 2.7 million
persons in February 1946, or 4.9 percent of the civilian labor force.
Thereafter unemployment dropped sharply.
The twin inheritance of large cash balances and unsatisfied invest­
ment and consumer demands, aided further by continuing easy credit,
carried the economy through reconversion with a minimum of diffi­
culty from the side of demand, although the transition was accom­
panied by considerable inflation. Private gross investment expanded
over fourfold between 1945 and 1947, while even inventories gave no
real trouble after a brief and modest liquidation in the closing months
of 1945. Despite a small drop in disposable personal income in the
last half of 1945, consumption expenditure rose rapidly in 1946 and
1947. This increase was strongly augmented by a rapid drop in the
abnormally high personal savings rate of wartime. W ith this un­
usually strong support from business and consumer demand, gross
national product fell only slightly in 1946, rising sharply again in



528

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1947. This recovery, which began in the spring of 1946, has particular
interest because it set in against a continuing rapid decline in security
spending.
The first postwar recession, 19^9-50

Measured by volume and rate of unemployment, this recession be­
gan in January 1949, and ended after the first quarter of 1950. How­
ever, industrial production had stopped rising in the last half of 1948,
fell through the first three quarters of 1949, then started upward again
in the first quarter of 1950. Gross domestic investment reached its
peak in the third quarter of 1948, declined through the next 5 quarters,
and then turned up strongly in the first quarter of 1950, surpassing its
previous peak with the second quarter of 1950. Helped along by con­
sumption and government demand, gross national product continued
to increase in the last half of 1948, thereafter dropping moderately
through all quarters of 1949. By the first quarter of 1950 it had over­
taken its previous peak attained in the final quarter of 1948.
Security spending ended its lengthy postwar contraction when it
reached its low in the third quarter of 1947 with an annual rate of
$11.7 billion. Thereafter it rose throughout the next 7 quarters,
reaching a peak annual rate of $20.5 billion in the second quarter of
1949, well after the recession had started. D uring the last 2 quarters
of 1949 and the first 1 in 1950, security spending fell off 17.1 percent
from its 1949 peak, turning up again thereafter. Total government
demand reached its postwar low at $27.7 billion in the second quarter
of 1947, after which it rose strongly to a $44.4 billion peak annual rate
in the second quarter of 1949. Thereafter it held steady in the rest
of 1949, dropping slightly during the first half of 1950.
This recession was brief and also shallow. I t lasted for 15 months
and the decline in gross product from the preceding peak to its lower
turning point was only 3.2 percent. By contrast, the start of the
downturn in security expenditure lagged 2 quarters behind the peak
for gross product in 1948, while it dropped 17.1 percent from its
second quarter high in 1949 to its low point in the first quarter of 1950.
More important, both security spending and total government demand
continued to increase strongly during the first half of 1949, while the
downturn in gross product was already in progress. A fter leveling
off in the last half, both categories of government purchases dropped
sharply during the first half of 1950, although the lower turning point
in gross product had been reached 6 months earlier and was followed
by a sharp upturn in the first 2 quarters of 1950. Thus it is difficult
to establish any direct causal connection between movements either in
security spending or total government demand and the upper and
lower turning points of the recession itself.
This conclusion is reinforced by scatter diagram tests. Plotting of
absolute quarterly values (for annual rates) for gross product against
total government demand in 1948-50 shows no close relationship,
either on a current basis or with government demand lagged one
quarter. No improvement in fit was obtained by plotting inventory
accumulation against net changes in security spending, either with
current values or with a one-quarter lag for security spending.
Two further points should be made about this recession. First,
the continuing high absolute levels of security spending and total
government demand, despite certain intervening movements, may well



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

529

have contributed some support to aggregate demand, providing a floor
for the recession. However, the onset and pace of the following re­
covery suggests th at demands in the private sector had considerable
independent force. Second, consumption showed remarkable strength
throughout the recession. Helped by contracyclical stabilizers such
as the personal-income tax and unemployment compensation, dis­
posable personal income declined only slightly. Even more, con­
sumers drastically cut personal savings, from a peak annaual rate of
$12.6 billion in the third quarter of 1948 to a level of only $3.2 billion
at the end of 1949. Thus consumption in calendar 1949 actually rose
$3 billion over the preceding year, despite the recession in employment
and production.
We conclude that security spending probably had more influence
in checking the depth of recession than in determining either its turn­
ing points or its length.
The Korean War , 1950-53
Significantly, economic expansion had gotten well underway ap­
proximately 6 months before the outbreak of the Korean W ar without
additional stimulus from either increased security spending or total
Government purchases. During the last half of 1950, gross product
continued to rise rapidly, helped along by a sharp increase in prices.
An easy money policy was in force and credit advances to businessmen
and consumers expanded rapidly, drawing up prices and wages in their
train. Large jumps occurred in private investment, centering in in­
ventories and producers’ durable equipment. In the final quarter,
net expansion of inventories soared to a $14.7 billion seasonally ad­
justed annual rate, stimulated by rising prices and expected increases
in procurement contracts. Rapid inventory accumulation continued
over the first three quarters of 1951. Price inflation reached its
peak in March.
F or the first three quarters of 1950, national security expenditure
showed surprisingly little change, while total Government purchases
actually fell slightly. W ith the fourth quarter, security spending
jumped $4.3 billion, or 24.2 percent. Thus began an almost unbroken
rise through the second quarter of 1953, carrying this spending from
its 1950 low of $17 billion to a postwar peak of $53.3 billion, an in­
crease of more than three-fold. The buildup of defense spending
proceeded most rapidly between the fourth quarter of 1950 and that
for 1951, after which the rate of increase fell off markedly. Total
Government demand moved in similar fashion.
Undoubtedly this lengthy series of increasing injections of security
expenditure worked strongly to push the economy upwards at boom
levels for nearly 3 years. I t did so directly by increasingly powerful
impacts upon aggregate demand and indirectly by promoting expan­
sion of the money supply through deficit financing. Yet it must be
remembered that the lower turning point of the first postwar reces­
sion occurred in the fourth quarter of 1949, with recovery continuing
strongly for 9 months before significant increases in security spending
had set in and 6 months before war had actually broken out. Evi­
dently independent forces were already effectively at work in the pri­
vate sector of the economy, although rising military budgets soon ac­
celerated the rate of advance.



530

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Two other facts should be noted about the Korean war boom.
First, direct controls were neither as extensive nor as effective as in
W orld W ar II. Thus there was much less carryover of suppressed
inflation and postponed demand when hostilities ended. Second,
military claims on gross national product never approached the deep
42 percent cut achieved in 1944. A t their second quarter peak of
1953, they absorbed slightly less than 15 percent of total output. This,
too, meant much less diversion of private civilian demand, hence much
less postponed claims for the period following.
The second postwar recession, 1953-5b
The Korean armistice was executed Ju ly 27, 1953, whereupon ex­
penditures on national security began a lengthy contraction lasting
over 18 months. From their peak annual rate of $53.3 billion in the
second quarter of 1953, they fell steadily to $40.1 billion in the last
quarter of 1954, a drop of almost 25 percent. Total Government de­
mand declined over the same period, though at a much slower rate,
dropping from an annual rate of $85.5 billion in the second quarter
of 1953 to $74.2 billion at the end of 1954, or by 13.2 percent. The
$13.2 billion decline in security spending during this period was p ar­
tially offset by a substantial increase in purchases by State and local
governments.
In timing, the onset of this recession in the th ird quarter of 1953
corresponds closely with the downturns in security spending and total
Government demand, while, as scatter tests indicate, there was also a
clear association between the downward course of both types of Gov­
ernment purchases and th at for the economy as a whole, lasting
through the last half of 1953. Gross national product dropped $9.9
billion between the second and fourth quarters, or by 2.7 percent.
Thereafter it remained level for the first three quarters of 1954. In ­
vestment in business inventories contracted sharply in the th ird quar­
ter of 1953, turning strongly negative in the fourth. Inventory
liquidation continued until the fourth quarter of 1954, although sub­
stantial renewed accumulation did not occur until the beginning of
1955. The relationship between the behavior of inventories and of
security spending was direct and rather close. Some connection is also
evident between gross domestic business investment and security
spending during the last half of 1953, but not thereafter.
The connection between security spending and overall economic
activity is much less clear for 1954. The former continued to contract
at a rate of about $2.3 billion each quarter, while gross product held
level for the first three quarters, turning up very strongly in the last
and even more sharply at the beginning of 1955. Clearly, the re­
cession was over with the end of 1954.
Thus this recession shows a marked asymmetry in behavior. Its
downward and initial phase of decline corresponds well with the drop
in security spending and in total Government demand, and it is rea­
sonable to attribute an important causal role to the contraction of
security spending here. By contrast, the subsequent upturn and sus­
tained recovery exhibit no direct connection with security spending
or Government demand. This suggests that, as in 1949-50, recovery
was invoked by the strength of forces initiating in the private sector
of the economy. The evidence for this is quite conclusive. Gross
private domestic investment experienced sharp increases in the second




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

531

and fourth quarters of 1954 and again in the first quarter of 1955,
largely under the influence of the construction boom which set in
with the second quarter of 1954 and the cessation of inventory liquida­
tion at the end of the year. Consumption also offered powerful sup­
port to aggregate demand. Throughout the recession, it fell ab­
solutely only once—in the last quarter of 1953, when the drop was
negligible. Consumption rose throughout 1954 on an average of $2.7
billion per quarter (annual rates). The favorable behavior of con­
sumption reflected three influences: The support afforded to dispos­
able personal income by the contracyclical stabilizers; an increased
propensity to consume rather than to save income; and easy credit
for consumption loans.
W hat, then, can be said about the impacts of security expenditure
upon the recession as a whole ? First, the timing and rate of its de­
cline were the main reason for the initial 6 months’ drop in total
economic activity. This suggests that sudden sharp changes in gov­
ernment purchases can invoke broader effects in the same direction.
Second, while the drop in security spending was severe, it reached
bottom at $40 billion, propping up total government demand at a
minimum of about $75 billion, or 21 percent of gross product in 1954.
We may view the fluctuations in both classes of government spending
as falling within a band whose outer limits in these times have con­
sistently represented a large component of total demand. The rela­
tive stability of government demand and its relatively high proportion
of aggregate demand means that the government sector has put a
firm floor under the whole economy. On this interpretation govern­
ment demand very probably checked the depth of the contraction, in
this way shortening the length of the recession while also keeping
it relatively shallow. P u t differently, the underlying strength of
government demand probably contributed to the resiliency and vi­
tality of forces operating upon aggregate demand from the private
sector of the economy. However, sudden sharp changes within the
Government sector can invoke corresponding movements in the whole
economy, notwithstanding government’s overall contribution to sta­
bility.
The investment boom, 1955-57

The upsurge in production in the closing quarter of 1954 continued
even more strongly throughout 1955. During this time security spend­
ing ran steadily at about a $41 billion annual rate. Total government
demand jumped $2 billion in the first quarter, staying at $76 billion
for the next 2 quarters, then rising moderately in the last. Despite
the strong tide of expansion, which lifted gross national product from
$367.1 billion (annual rate) in the last quarter of 1954 to $401.9 bil­
lion in the last quarter of 1955 (up 9.5 percent), relatively little stim­
ulus came from the Government sector other than the continuing broad
basis of support afforded by the stability of security spending and total
government purchases.
W hat actually occurred was an impressive boom in private invest­
ment, aided by a strong collateral rise in consumption. Between the
closing quarters of 1954 and 1955, gross private domestic investment
soared from an annual rate of $51.5 billion to one of $65.1 billion, or
by 26.4 percent. This growth rested upon large increases in pro­
ducers’ plant and equipment, business inventories, and new construc­
tion.



532

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

During 1956, the expansion continued. Gross product rose an addi­
tional $24.1 billion between the final quarters of 1955 and 1956, or at
the somewhat slower rate of 6 percent. Moreover, p art of this in­
crease reflected rising prices, which started upward after mid-1955.
Gross private domestic investment stopped rising for the first three
quarters of 1956, jumping upward again in the last. Producers’
plant and equipment continued to record large gains, while inventory
accumulation moved irregularly and new construction stayed level.
Security spending held constant for the first half, but started upward
in the last, reflecting, in good part, rising prices for hardware and
materials. Total government demand rose slowly but steadily
throughout the year. D uring the first half of 1957, both components
of government demand moved upward strongly once more. By con­
trast gross investment dropped, reflecting declines in construction
and inventory accumulation, although plant and equipment held
steady.
The turn upward and subsequent marked increase in production
and employment th at began with the final quarter of 1954 appear to
have little direct connection with the behavior of security spending
and total government demand until the end of 1955. However, it
must be noted again th at the stability of the Government sector at
this time probably contributed indirectly to the buoyancy of demands
originating in the private sector. From mid-1956 to mid-1957, the
resumed rise in security purchases doubtless helped to prolong the
boom at a time when gross private investment had stopped increasing.
Total government purchases had the same broad effect, in somewhat
larger degree.
I m pacts

of

N a t io n a l S e c u r it y E x pen d it u r e U po n E co n o m ic
G r o w t h , 1939-57

The impacts of security spending upon long-term expansion in the
economy pose two main problems. First, what is the connection be­
tween such spending and the realized rate of growth since 1939?
This question requires evaluation of the issue whether security spend­
ing has prim arily supported and supplemented or has mainly dis­
placed private demand. Second, have security expenditures for
research and development had any significant influence upon tech­
nology, investment, and economic efficiency within the sphere of p ri­
vate enterprise ? This problem deals mainly with the contribution of
government-sponsored research and development programs to the res­
ervoir of economically usable inventions, hence to the productivity
and potential growth of the economy.
Security expenditure and realized growth , 1939-57
Suppose there had been no increase in security spending after 1939:
would private investment have recovered sufficiently to have carried
expansion forward either at the rate actually realized or perhaps at
an even faster rate ? Or suppose th at security spending had remained
at the $11 billion annual rate to which it had declined by late 1947 in­
stead of quadrupling thereafter: would subsequent growth have
achieved or exceeded the rate actually realized ?
These questions go to the issue of whether security spending merely
displaced an equivalent or perhaps even greater amount of private




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

533

spending, particularly investment, or instead mainly supplemented
such spending and thereby stimulated higher levels of production and
demand than otherwise would have occurred. Admittedly, no final and
conclusive answer can be devised, for it is impossible to determine how
investment, consumption, and other categories of government demand
would have behaved if security spending had not reached the levels it
actually did. Nonetheless, some speculation is in order.
I f we appeal to the past, we can say that the history of the American
economy does contain periods of rapid and sustained expansion with­
out benefit of substantial expenditure on national security. However,
we would then have to recognize also that depressions have followed
these past expansions, reflecting the instability of private investment.
Even more, we have to confront the deep and protracted depression
of the thirties, which, prior to the advent of the war-induced boom,
seemed to have no visible end.
The development of a point of view regarding the role of security
spending in overall growth after 1939 depends directly upon how one
regards the strength of the inducement to private investment, since
the hypothetical reduction of the actual levels of security spending
implies a large potential increase in absolute savings. Either private
investment would have absorbed fully these additional savings or the
economy would have faced either continued depression or eventual
deflationary collapse. Followers of what Fellner calls the KeynesHansen pessimism and the Schumpeterian pessimism point to alleged
weaknesses in the inducement to invest, which suggests that security
spending actually supported a higher rate of growth.3 On the KeynesHansen reasoning, capital tends to accumulate more rapidly than pop­
ulation and natural resources, which lowers the rate of return on new
investment and weakens the inducement to invest. By contrast, the
Schumpeter argument points to the rise of the modern ideology of se­
curity and of greater income equality, suggesting that it gradually
takes the profits out of innovation while also making innovations them­
selves more difficult to introduce.
Neither of these views is unassailable, either in reasoning or in sup­
porting evidence. However, this is not the place to consider them in
detail. I t need only be said that the ultimate question they imply is
still moot and probably will remain so.
Even if one does not adopt either of these pessimistic views, there
is a persuasive argument for the contention that during 1939-57
security spending promoted a higher realized rate of growth than
otherwise would have occurred. First, it can hardly be denied that
the lengthy series of increasing injections of military demand begin­
ning in late 1940 ended the protracted depression of investment and
production prevailing throughout the thirties. While the banking
and international monetary system undoubtedly compelled extreme
liquidation with its attendant general mood of deep pessimism in
that decade, the rapid rise of security spending was the decisive force
invoking revival and prosperity within the context of given monetary
institutions. Accordingly, it follows that security spending hastened
and intensified recovery, making a higher growth rate possible at
least in the forties.
3 William Fellner, Full Use or Underutilization : Appraisal of Long-Run Factors Other
Than Defense, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, XLIV: 2 (May 1954),
pp. 424, 428-431. For an evaluation of the stagnation hypothesis, see also George H.
Hildebrand, Defense Expenditures and the Problem of Deflation, ibid., pp. 419-420.



534

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Second, the normal experience of the American economy in the
more remote past has included the boom-depression sequence. Yet
no depression intervened during the long boom after 1942, while the
three downturns th a t did occur (1945^6, 1949-50, and 1953-54)
proved remarkably mild both in depth and duration. I t is reasonable
to conclude that the continuing high absolute levels of government
demand, of which security spending has been at all times an impor­
tant and often dominant part, has at certain times offset weaknesses
in the private sector and at others has contributed to the buoyancy
of private demands. I f so, then the realized rate of growth since
1942 has been higher than what would have been attained with much
lower levels of security spending and of total government demand.
Finally, the research and development programs supported by se­
curity spending had led to a large group of fundamental inventions,
as we show in the next section. This new body of technology has
permitted economies in existing types of production, while at the
same time opening up a whole range of new products and even new
industries. This has meant increased private investment and con­
sumption, leading in turn to more rapid expansion in the private
sphere itself. Here again, therefore, the rate of overall growth has
been promoted by security spending.
The contribution o f security expenditure to research and technology

W riting in 1952, S. Colum Gilfillan, a lifelong student of techno­
logical change, declared:
The most striking change th at has come over invention, a
change that is universally overlooked * * * is th a t inven­
tion has latterly come to be chiefly pursued by the Federal
Government and sometimes other noncommercial organiza­
tions, so th at patenting is now a rare motivation, having
force perhaps for 15 percent of all invention. * * * Inven­
tion has followed the path of science, except th a t funda­
mental civil inventions, the most valuable of all, are still
nobody’s baby.4
Testifying in 1955 before the Subcommittee on Economic Stabili­
zation of the Jo in t Committee on the Economic Report, Dr. A. V.
Astin, Director of the National Bureau of Standards, stated th at
“the great majority” of the current developments in scientific re­
search and its practical applications could be credited to war and
defense expenditures.5 Looking at the rise of war-borne tech­
nologies, Dr. Yannevar Bush has observed that—
W hat is new is an accelerated pace in the application of
new techniques in industry. And this is p art of a very im­
portant general movement, namely the planned applica­
tion of scientific results in an economic manner for the in ­
crease of man’s physical well-being.6
Clearly, the needs of modern warfare have brought about a close
union of government, research, and business enterprise—a union
centered upon the planned application of science to the creation of
4 S. Colum Gilfillan, The Prediction of Technological Change, Review of Economics and
Statistics, XXXIV : 4 (November 1952), p. 374.
6 Automation and Technological Change, hearings before the Subcommittee on Economic
Stabilization of the .Toint Committee on the Economic Report, 84th Cong., 1st sess., p. 584.
«Ibid., pp. 613-615.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

_

535

practical new technologies, promoted in large p art by government
funds, and laden with major implications for the American economy.7
Atomic energy is the best known of the new technologies, and, of
course, is now the classic illustration of this new alliance. Here pop­
ular interest has centered upon atomic power, although the allied
production of radioactive substances is finding important new uses in
food preservation, agronomy, medicine, and industrial chemistry.8
Two other war-inspired technologies, automation and electronics, had
their inception in problems of fire control, missile guidance, and pro­
duction of precision parts.9 In all these instances the knowledge pro­
vided by theoretical science has been translated into practical tech­
nologies largely by the support of military funds. Similar impetus
has been given the rapidly developing technology of synthetic chem­
istry, with its new plastics, fibers, ceramic materials, and metal alloys.
Dollar measurement of the contribution of security spending to
research and development is particularly treacherous, mainly because
it is impossible to draw a precise distinction between expenditure on
research and development as such and on testing, procurement, and
modification of military end products. Moreover, it is necessary arbi­
trarily to exclude or include common overhead costs borne by the
Department of Defense, and these are substantial. To illustrate, the
National Science Foundation, using a restrictive definition, estimated
that the Department would spend $1.6 billion on research and devel­
opment in fiscal 1956-57, but found that with the inclusion of certain
allied costs the figure would rise to almost $5.2 billion.10
Proceeding from the conservative estimates developed by the Foun­
dation, it will be found that research and development expenditure
by the Department of Defense was only $26.4 million in fiscal 1940.
W ith the inclusion of outlays by the Manhattan Engineer District
(Atomic Energy Commission from 1947) beginning in fiscal 1943,
total research and development spending in the national security cate­
gory soared to $1,372 million by 1945, or 86 percent of all Federal
expenditure for research and development purposes. A sharp drop
occurred through fiscal 1947, followed by rapid expansion again dur­
ing the Korean war. For fiscal 1957 total outlay was projected at
$2,145 million. In recent years, major increases have centered in
missile development and atomic research. Together, the Department
of Defense and the AEC now account for about 85 percent of all Fed­
eral research and development expenditure.11 Research outlays by
private industry are now running at about $3 billion. I f the indirect
expenditures of the Department of Defense are included, total govern­
7 For a thoughtful analysis of the long-run possibilities in these developments, see The
Scientific-Industrial Revolution, a study published in 1957 by the investment house of
Model, Rowland & Stone, 120 Broadway, New York, N. Y.
8 Dr. W. F. Libby, member of the Atomic Energy Commission, recently reported to a
UNESCO conference in Paris that radioisotopes were currently saving American industry
about $406 million a year and might reach $1 billion a year by 1963. W. F. Libby, The
Economic Aspects of Radioisotope Utilization, release dated September 17, 1957.
9 According to Dr. Astin, ENIAC, the first all-electric digital computer, was connected
with the formulation of bombing and firing tables in World War II. Automation drew
powerful impetus from the Army's Rockford ordnance plant, which was conceived in 1941
for production of complicated metal parts in a fully automated process. Automation
hearings, op. cit., pp. 569, 587.
10 National Science Foundation, Federal Funds for Science, V : The Federal Research
and Development Budget, fiscal years 1955, 1956, and 1957 (Washington Government
Printing Office, 1956), p. 19.
w Ibid., pp. 46-47.




536

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

ment and private outlays in 1957 may well reach $9 billion, with gov­
ernment accounting for about two-thirds.12
There is no precise way to measure what the dollar impacts of
national security spending on research and development have been
and will be for the economy, granted that they have already become
im portant and promise even more for the future. That they are
fostering continued growth is undeniable. From the side of in­
vestment in the private sector, four main effects can be discerned.
First, the emergence of the new technologies is invoking investment
in new industries. Electronics is the foremost example here. Second,
these technologies are enabling existing industries to develop a new
range of equipment, instruments, and materials, replacing, improving
or extending old types of production. Computing machines, con­
trol devices, and synthetic chemicals well illustrate this case, where
private investment is induced to create new or modify old plant and
equipment. Third, the tools and materials forthcoming from the new
technologies are making possible economies of production in other
industries, calling forth new investment to finance cost-saving inno­
vations and increased output. Automatic equipment and controls for
the factory and on the railroads, and computers and recordkeeping
equipment in the office, all exhibit this effect. Finally, looking some
distance ahead we can expect considerable indirect investment in­
duced, for example, by changes in the location of industry made pos­
sible by the new technologies.
To date, the impacts upon investment have probably been relatively
small, save, perhaps, for the current investment boom. A similar
verdict is indicated for consumption, where expansion of existing de­
mands becomes possible with lower costs and improved quality, and
an array of new demands emerges with the appearance of new prod­
ucts.
I t would be a mistake to credit the whole of these advances to mil­
itary support for research and development, or to conclude th a t secur­
ity spending is the only means to continue their promotion. The
prim ary role of theoretical science and the collateral contributions of
private research must also be recognized. W hat can be said, however,
is that security spending has made, and is continuing to make, a large
contribution to a technological development of great pending im­
portance to the private-enterprise sector and to the economy as a
whole. M ilitary expenditure is not all dead loss, by any means.
While it can be argued th a t some of these advances might well have
emerged from private sources without benefit of any government sup­
port, it seems equally clear th a t the risks and large costs of initial
experimentation and development in some of these fields did make
government aid essential to their successful exploitation. Atomic en­
ergy and radioactive products are a strong case in point. F u rth er­
more, it seems equally obvious th a t the urgencies of modem warfare,
whether hot or cold, when backed by ample funds, have proved de­
cisive in invoking the close union between systematic research and its
practical application, setting off the revolutionary chain of technical
advances recorded since the eiarly forties. In consequence, the poten­
tial rate of growth in the economy may well be even higher in the next
two decades.
13 Executive Offices of the President, Economic Report of the President, transmitted to
the Congress, January 27, 1957 (Washington : Government Printing Office, 1957), pp. 59, 60.



537

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
S e c u r it y E

x p e n d it u r e ,

S

t a b il it y , a n d

G

ro w th in

the

F

uture

Security expenditure as a tool for fiscal policy

Assuming, with the Employment Act of 1946, th at fiscal policy is
to serve as an instrument for maintaining short-run stability and
long-run growth of employment and production, how does security
spending fit these purposes ?
I t must be conceded at the outset that security spending is a dis­
cretionary type of demand of relatively large size, dependent upon
appropriations from Congress and recommendations and decisions
by the executive branch. I t does not significantly change automati­
cally when national income increases or decreases. By contrast, con­
tracyclical stablizers, such as the personal income tax and unemploy­
ment compensation, do automatically tend to increase or decrease dis­
posable personal income in a way that dampens swings in national
income. Instead, security spending today is determined by decisions
taken by government authorities a year or more in the past. A t times,
such spending may hold steady when the economy is either expanding
or contracting, while at other times it may change, either contracyclically or perversely, with business swings. When security spending
moves contracyclically, it helps to dampen business movements; when
it moves perversely, it intensifies them. Thus it can be either a stabi­
lizer or destabilizer for the economic system. Moreover, the stabiliz­
ing or unstabilizing role of security spending is now largely
determined by forces independent of the level of business activity,
which narrows the scope for discretionary action.
Two forces, basically, control decisions about security spending.
The principal one is the state of international tensions, while the
development of weapons technology comes second. Neither factor
has a close or direct connection with the level of employment and pro­
duction. About the only influence business activity has upon security
spending is to impose a rather indefinite ceiling with full employment
and inflation in peacetime. Even here, the independent rationale for
a given policy of national security imposes certain rigidities in security
purchases, rigidities that recently have forced up security outlays,
feeding the inflation.
.
This fact has important implications for fiscal policy as a tool for
promoting economic stability and growth. First, shifts in security
spending are likely to be erratic relative to business fluctuations. They
may well prove unstabilizing at times, feeding booms or contractions
rather than helping to offset them. Second, if security expenditure
were to be used to reduce swings in business activity, it would pose a
serious prediction problem because of its discretionary nature. The
future course of the business swing must be foreseen in time, decisions
to spend and appropriations must then be shaped accordingly and in
time, and the desired impacts to follow must arrive in time to help
offset the developing course of economic change. Here, successful
results are threatened by the possibility of erroneous prediction,
which would make the change in security spending unstabilizing, by
the lengthy lag between the initial decision and its later effects, and
by the inherent rigidity of most security requirements. Actually,
most of these handicaps confront any discretionary policy of public
spending, such as public works, but the inherent rigidity of defense



538

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

expenditure presents an added handicap not present in a public-works
program.
These considerations provide a strong case for allowing security
spending to be governed mainly by the requirements of America’s
world strategy, rather than atemptmg to use it also as a device for
deliberately promoting stability and growth. F o r the latter purposes,
security spending must compete with other, more flexible, discretionary
tools, such as public-works spending, changes in taxes, and monetary
policy. The scale of public works can be more readily adjusted to
business conditions, while the works themselves are more likely to pro­
vide genuine public benefits then would m ilitary expenditures not
independently justified by strategic requirements. F or slumps, tax
reductions clearly add to public benefits, because they permit the
public itself to buy more goods and services of its own choosing.
Accordingly, an efficiently administered security program would be
guided by its prim ary and exclusive purpose; national defense in an
uncertain and rapidly changing world.
Impacts o f a major cut in security expenditure

I f the requirements of national security were to drop greatly with
an outbreak of major disarmament and international peace, what
problems would be posed for economic stability and growth ?
F o r the short run, a serious deflationary situation would confront
the entire economy, with particularly severe impacts upon communi­
ties heavily committed to the production of armament. If, as seems
reasonable, we assume a multiplier of 2.5, then even a $10 billion cut in
security spending would imply a decline of $25 billion in gross national
product, barring offsetting increases in private investment, consump­
tion, or other components of Government demand. Since national
product must increase about $15 billion a year at constant prices to
maintain full employment with a growing labor force, a defense cut
of this scale would require extensive Government actions to support
aggregate demand. Unlike 1945, there would be no large-scale carry­
over of postponed investment and consumption demand to fill the gap
occasioned by the drop in security spending. Undoubtedly, the prob­
lem would require prom pt tax reductions to avoid excessive budget
surpluses and to stimulate private spending, along with the stimulus
of easy money and, probably, programs for increased Government
spending.
Even if the initial transition to a much lower level of security
spending were successfully made, there is little doubt that the prob­
lems of stabilization and continued growth would become more diffi­
cult thereafter. The reason is th at the economy would then be more
vulnerable to fluctuations in private investment than at any time since
the twenties. Since private investment has proved very volatile his­
torically, the risk of recurrence of major business cycles necessarily
increases with the loss of a considerable part of the supporting strength
now afforded by Government demand. If, to some extent, the sav­
ings from reduced defense outlays could partly be used to provide
additional Government works and services now necessarily deferred
with the continuing high costs of national security, then the stability
problem would become less acute for this, perhaps, fanciful future
world. Since the savings on defense would not likely be absorbed



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

539

fully in this way, fiscal-monetary management would have to be
particularly sagacious as well as fortunate if it is to maintain stability.
Clearly, too, the outlook for continued growth in such circumstances
would depend more heavily upon the long-run strength of the induce­
ment to private investment. From the Keynes-Hansen or Schumpeter
points of view, the prospects are not encouraging, barring a substan­
tial permanent rise in Government spending. Even short of these
types of pessimism, there is always the risk that the flow of laborsaving capital improvements of recent years may not continue forever.
Against this possibility is the high promise of the new technologies,
which justifies some optimism about the prospects for a sustained high
level of private investment and growth for some years to come. Any
final view must necessarily be speculative, although it is certain that
the tasks of fiscal and monetary management with a greatly reduced
level of security spending would be harder, rather than easier, than
they are now.
C

o n c l u s io n s

This lengthy review of experience since 1939 suggests several infer­
ences about the impacts of national-security expenditure upon the
economy, in the past and in the future. These are summarized under
the headings of stability and growth.
Stability
1. When major contractions in security spending can be foreseen, as
at the end of wars, they are likely to induce a downward turning point
in total production, as occurred in the third quarters of 1945 and 1953.
The impact is transmitted mainly through inventories and, to a lesser
extent, through new construction.
2. The timing of turning points into recovery bears no close con­
nection with upturns in security spending, although anticipations
of such upturns can occur, as in mid-1950. Slow but steady expan­
sion occurred for seven quarters beginning in 1939 before a marked
advance of security spending was recorded. Recovery set in strongly
in the second quarter of 1946 while security spending was still sharply
contracting. Recovery started again in the first quarter of 1950,
while security spending failed to advance until the fourth.
3. A sharp and sustained contraction in security spending, when
foreseen, will induce a collateral fall in general activity, with the
length of this collateral drop dependent upon the independent strength
or weakness of demands in the private sector. In 1946 these demands
were unusually strong, and the general downturn lasted only 9 months,
beginning with the third quarter of 1945. In 1953-54 the parallel
movements lasted for only 6 months; after 1953 gross product leveled
off for three quarters and then rose strongly, while security spending
continued to contract throughout 1954.
4. A sharp and sustained increase in security spending can induce
general expansion, although the latter can also occur independently.
The stimulating effect of increased security spending is shown for
1940-44; from the last quarter of 1950 through the second quarter
of 1953; and, to a lesser extent, during the last half of 1956 and first
one of 1957. By contrast, general recovery proceeded for 9 months
in 1950 without direct support from increasing security spending;



540

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

the same was true for 18 months beginning with the fourth quarter
of 1954.
.
5. The rise of total government demand, strongly helped by in­
creased security spending, to a probably enduring level of 20 percent
of gross national product has contributed considerably to the stability
of aggregate demand. The reason is that government demand is shel­
tered from contractions emanating from the private sector. This does
much to explain the brevity and shallowness of the three postwar con­
tractions and the absence of a major depression since 1941. Govern­
ment demand also contributed to the buoyancy of private demands in
the postwar years.
...
.
6. By promoting full employment and exhibiting rigidity in its
claims upon total physical product, security spending has contributed
to inflationary movements of wages and prices at certain times. This
is true of 1941-45, 1950-53, and to some extent of the current inflation
of 1955-57. However, all of the inflationary movements since 1939,
including that during 1945-48, have also involved a rapid increase of
money supply and some associated increase in money velocity.
7. Security spending is determined prim arily by international ten­
sions and the state of the military art. Thus it is both inflexible
relative to general economic movements and at the same time suscep­
tible to sudden changes th at might well prove unstabilizing for the
economy. As a discretionary tool for promoting stability, it has
much less to commend it than public-works programs, tax changes,
and monetary policy. If, by reason of major disarmament, security
spending could be greatly reduced in a short period, it could provoke
a severe deflation problem. B arring an offsetting increase in other
types of government demand over the longer run, a major cut in secur­
ity spending would make the tasks of fiscal and montary management
considerably more difficult than they are even now, granted that the
savings would be welcome from other points of view.
Growth

1. Judgments about the effects of security spending upon the longrun rate of growth in the economy since 1939 depend, basically, upon
a choice of speculative views regarding the strength or weakness
of the inducement to private investment. The issue of progress
versus stagnation is unresolved and probably will remain so. While
no definitive answer to this issue can be supplied, there is a persuasive
argument that security spending did raise the realized rate of growth
since 1939. First, the rapid increase of military demand from late
1940 very probably hastened the end of the great depression. Second,
the sustaining force of security spending and government demand
probably did much to keep the postwar contractions brief and shal­
low, while it is noteworthy that no major depression has appeared
since 1941. Finally, m ilitary spending for research and development
undoubtedly fostered the growth of new technologies and products,
aiding private investment and consumption and promising much more
for the future.
2. There has been a close connection between mililtary expenditures
for research and development and the emergence of automation, elec­
tronics, synthetics, atomic energy, and radioactive substances. These
discoveries have created new industries and have brought about



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

541

new products and methods in old ones, provoking an unprecedented
current interest in systematic research. On this count alone, security
spending has not been a complete economic loss. However, there are
alternatives to security spending as a means for the Government to
promote research, and the contributions of theoretical science and of
private industry to these developments should not be overlooked.
Nonetheless, the defense program and the urgencies of modern war­
fare have played a decisive role in promoting the revolution of pro­
duction technology since 1940. The effect may well be an increase in
the potential rate of growth of the economy in the future, and at the
same time an increase in the rate actually achieved.