View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

T H E G R O W T H O F G O V E R N M E N T O Y E R T H E P A S T 50
Y E A R S : A N A N A L Y T IC A L R E V IE W
A rnold M. Soloway, assistant professor o f economics, Harvard
University
I

n t r o d u c t io n

Although American citizens are largely inured to the colossal and
spectacular, they are acutely aware o f the spectacular growth o f gov­
ernment in recent decades— higher taxes, increased spending, more
government regulation, and so forth. The statistics o f growth, how­
ever expressed, are always overwhelming, and it has already become
a cliche to point out, for example, that today’s interest charges on the
national debt are more than four times total government spending
only 50 years ago.
Only slightly less obvious is the fact that our whole conception o f
government’s responsibility is far different today from what it was
in 1900. Compare, for example, the follow ing excerpts from two
messages to Congress: 1
*
* * I do not believe that the power and duty o f the
General Government ought to be extended to the relief o f
individual suffering which is in no manner properly related
to the public service or benefit. A prevalent tendency to dis­
regard the limited mission o f this power and duty should, I
think, be steadfastly resisted, to the end that the lesson should
be constantly enforced that though the people support the
Government, the Government should not support the people
(Grover Cleveland, February 16, 1887).
The human problems o f individual citizens are a proper
and important concern o f our Government. One such prob­
lem that faces every individual is the provision o f economic
security fo r his old age and economic security fo r his fam ily
in the event o f his death. T o help individuals provide for
that security— to reduce both the fear and the incidence o f
destitution to the minimum— to promote the confidence o f
every individual in the future— these are proper aims o f all
levels o f government, including the Federal Government
(D w ight D. Eisenhower, January 14,1954).
The overall growth o f government in the United States implied in
this contrast o f views, and the distribution o f that growth among all
three levels o f our government— Federal, State, and local— have had
tremendous impact on the whole economic climate. It is the purpose
o f this paper to examine (1) the aggregate growth o f government in
the United States over roughly the past 50 years; (2) the basic causes
1 Cited in Social W elfare in the United States, Poyntz Tyler, editor, the Reference Shelf,
vol. 27, No. 3, H. W . Wilson Co., New York, 1955, p. 10.




19

20

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

of government’s growth; (3) the relative growth of Federal, State,
and local governments.
This analytical review will, it is hoped, provide some strong impli­
cations, if not conclusions, about the future course of government ac­
tivity in the United States.
M

easures of

G

row th

There are a number of different indexes by which the growth and
importance of government in the total economy can be gaged.2 One
such measure is government’s absorption of productive resources—
labor and capital. W ith respect to labor, in 1900, Federal, State, and
local governments together employed less than 1.2 million people,
about 4.2 percent of all employed workers. In 1956, total government
employment was just under 10 million, roughly 17 percent of total
full-time employment.* Thus, government growth, as measured by
increased direct employment, was over 700 percent. I t can also be
summarized as follows: In 1900, 1 out of every 25 employed workers
worked for the government; in 1954,1 out of every 5.9 employed work­
ers worked for the government.
The growth of government’s share of the national stock of capital
goods has been little less impressive than its growth in direct employ­
ment. Government’s share of total investment from 19732 to 1946 was
32 percent, almost one-third, and its share of total national capital
asset value increased from 6.6 percent to 20.6 percent.4 Thus, while in
1902 the total value of government property, excluding m ilitary assets,
roads and streets, and land was $6.7 billion, by 1946, the latest year
for which data are available, such property was valued at $45.3 billion
(1929 prices).' Measured in constant prices, from 1902 to 1946 gov­
ernment’s capital asset holdings, including land, grew by 326 percent.*
In addition to the labor and capital government employs directly,
it also absorbs great amounts of these resources through its purchases
of goods and services from the private sector of the economy. To
measure the total volume of resources absorbed by government, we
must add to the labor and capital directly employed the value of gov­
ernment’s purchases of goods and services from the rest of the
economy.
In 1903, government purchases of goods and services from the p ri­
vate sector were about $752 million, and in 1956 they were some $80.2
billion.1
a Great contributions to the understanding of the growth of governm ent have been m ade
recently in : The Trend of Government A ctivity in the United S tates Since 1900, Solomon
Fabricant, N ational Bureau of Econom ic Research, Inc., New York, 1 952; Am erica’s Needs
and Resources, a New Survey, Dewhurst and A ssociates, T w entieth Century Fund, New
York, 1955, ch. 1 8 ; A Century and a H alf of Federal Expenditures, M. Slade Kendrick,
N ational Bureau of Economic Research, Occasional Paper 48, New York, 1955.
8 Government employment and total employment for 1956 are in full-tim e equivalent
numbers, but, for 1900, w e used the census figure for “Em ployed,” cf. Fabricant, op. cit.,
appendix B ; series D -6 2 -7 6 , H istorical S ta tistics of the United States, 1789-1945, a
supplem ent to the S tatistical Abstract of the U nited States, Census Bureau ; Survey o f
Current Business, July 1957.
4 Fabricant, op. cit., table 4. p. 20.
6 Ibid., table 3, p. 19. M ilitary assets, roads, streets, and land are excluded from these
comparisons except as noted.
6 This figure includes land, but excludes roads, streets, and related assets, and assets of
defense corporations. Ibid., table 6, p. 24.
7 Government purchases of goods and services prior to 1929 are estim ates derived from
Fabricant, op. cit., table 5, p. 22; gross national product for 1913 is K uznets’ estim a te;
other data computed from Survey of Current Business, July and A ugust 1955.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

21

As a share of gross national product, government purchases of goods
and services rose from 3.6 percent in 1913 to 9.7 percent in 1956. Thus,
the fraction of total national output (GNP) absorbed by government
through its purchases from the private sector of the economy was
almost 3 times greater in 1956 than it was in 1913. The magnitude of
the absolute increase again looms clearly when we recall that in the
same period the gross national product itself grew 10 times larger,
from $40 billion in 1913 to over $414 billion by 1956.
The inputs of labor and capital for the production of government
services together give a total measure of government’s absorption of
productive resources. I t is estimated that total real resources put
into government’s nondefense activity rose over 400 percent between
1900 and 1949; and into all government activities, “probably over
700 percent”.8 Even with a most liberal allowance for error, it is
patently clear th at the growth of government measured by its absorp­
tion of productive resources has been very great indeed; but, at the
very best, this measure alone is too restricted for our purpose. We are
here concerned with the growth of government in a broader sense than
that which measuring only inputs of labor and capital affords.
Total government expenditures is a more inclusive measure because
it includes expenditures for transfer and net interest payments in addi­
tion to the value of government’s absorption of productive resources.9
Although transfer and net interest payments do not represent addi­
tional absorption of real resources, they reflect, just as much as any
other expenditures, increases in government activity called forth by
the complex of national circumstance. Therefore, total government
expenditure is, for us, a more useful index of government growth.
Total government expenditure in current dollars rose from $1.5
billion in 1902 to $104 billion in 1955, an increase of 69 times, while the
gross national product increased by roughly 20 times in the same 54year period.10
Although government expenditure provides the most inclusive index
of the quantitatively measurable growth in government, obviously it
falls far short of measuring the full growTth of government’s impact on
the Nation’s economy. The effects of new legislation, court decisions,
and administrative regulations, in such fields as labor relations, in­
dustrial organization, agriculture, natural resources, and transporta­
tion, is not easily measured in dollar terms.
F or a full evaluation of government’s growth, however, these aspects
of government activity should be considered along with the growth
in government expenditure. Although we cannot give them quanti­
tative significance we shall have them in mind as we turn to a brief
analysis of the underlying causes of governmental growth.
8 These estim ates are given, and should be taken, only as rough approximations. Aside
from the many sta tistica l problems inherent in the construction of such a broad index over
so long a period, some of the vital data— value of m ilitary assets used by Government, for
exam ple— are not available. For our purpose, however, the possible margin of error
involved in these estim ates is of little consequence.
9 F abricants’ expenditure figures include an imputed net rent of 4 percent on the 1989
book value of governm ent nonm ilitary capital assets, but in m ost calculations, as he points
out, in terest on the public debt is taken as the measure of the services of governm ent capi­
tal. or these services are ignored (pp. 12. 2 6 ). We are follow ing conventional procedure
and using the Departm ent of Commerce figures for total government expenditures, which,
therefore, w ill exceed Fabricant’s measure of total input by the difference between h is
imputed rent and n et interest paym ents on the public debt, and by the addition of transfer
payments.
10 The gross national product for 1902 is estim ated a t some $20.7 billions on the basis
of K uznet’s figures for annual average gross national product in current prices for the
decades 1894-1903 ($15.7 billion) and 1899-1908 ($21.6 b illion ).
Cf. K uznets, S.,
National Product Since 1869, N ational Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1946.




22
S

ome

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
M

a jo r

E

lem ents

U

n d e r l y in g

E

th e

G

row th

in

G

overnm ent

x p e n d it u r e s

Population growth

Between 1900 and 1957 the population of the United States grew
from 76 million to 170 million. Although a larger citizenry does not
ordinarily require an equal proportionate increase in expenditures for
all types of government activity, this population increase of 217 per­
cent obviously would itself cali forth a sizable increase in aggregate
government expenditures. For the period 1913-50, for example, it
is estimated that population growth alone was responsible for $4.6
billion, or 6.9 percent, of the total government expenditure increase of
$66.4 billion (1950 prices).11 This estimate, however, does not take
into account im portant changes in population characteristics and
therefore understates the effect of population changes on government
expenditure.
Among the changes in population characteristics which also imply
greater government expenditures there is, for example, the fact that
the median age of the population rose from 22.9 years in 1900 to 30.9
years in 1950. The greater proportion of older people in the 1950
total is underscored by the fact that the percentage of those over 65
years of age almost doubled—from 4.1 percent in 1900 to 8.1 percent by
1950. Although the proportion of school-age people—5 to 19—■
dropped from 36.7 percent in 1900 to only 23.3 percent in 1950, the
actual number rose from 27.9 million persons to 35.1 million persons,
and the proportion attending school rose from 62.6 percent to 79
percent.
Even more significant than the change in age distribution in terms
of its effect on government costs, was the shift of population from rural
to urban status. In 1900, the population of the United States was
divided 60 percent rural and 40 percent urban. By 1950, the propor­
tions had more than switched: 64 percent urban and only 36 percent
rural.12 The move from a dominantly rural status also involved a
multiplication of urban centers, and while in 1900 we had only 38
centers of more than 100,000 population, by 1950 we had 107. Simi­
larly, the proportion of people living in communities of more than
10,000 grew from 31.7 percent in 1900 to 49 percent by 1950.
A related factor with definite cost implications for government is
th a t the growth of population was not evenly spread through the
Nation. From 1900 to 1950 the Northeast lost 1.5 percent of its pro­
portion of total national population; the South lost 1 percent; the
North Central region lost 5.2 percent; and the West gained 13.1 per­
cent. Although the day of the Indian wars and two-gun desperadoes
had passed by 1913, it would seem that the growth of population in the
relatively newly settled West called forth larger amounts of govern­
ment expenditure than would have been required had population
growth been restricted to the older, established areas of the country.
Price level changes

The secularly rising price level has been another obvious influence
raising the dollar volume of government expenditure. The longperiod decline of the purchasing power of the dollar, in evidence
11 D ew h u rst, op. cit., p. 595.
u New census definition. A ll d a ta in th ese com parisons from Census of P o p u latio n .




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

23

since about 1850, has continued through the present. There has been
some irregularity, occasioned by cyclical ups and downs, but, for the
period as a whole, the purchasing power of the dollar has moved in a
downward direction. F or example, a 1939 consumer dollar had the
purchasing power equivalent of $2.58 in 1850, $1.80 in 1900, and only
$0.52 in 1953.13 The wholesale dollar moved somewhat less dram ati­
cally over the past 100 years but it, too, has definitely tended down­
ward—from a 1939 purchasing power equivalent of $1.23 in 1850 to
$0.45 in 1953.
Neither the consumer nor wholesale price index is completely ade­
quate, however, for accurately translating government expenditures
into dollars of constant buying power and thus making expenditures
in different years comparable without distortion from price changes.
This is so because the effect of price changes on government expendi­
ture varies with the different proportions of special kinds of goods
and services which make up the government expenditure total. F or
example, a 1913 dollar spent on education would have bought $3.94
worth of service in 1950, but a 1913 dollar for interest on the debt
would have purchased only $0.86 worth in 1950. Similarly, a 1913
dollar for current supplies would have bought $4.72 worth in 1950,
but a 1913 dollar for construction would have bought only $2.32 worth
in 1950.14 Because of such variations a composite index is not an
accurate guide for deflating government expenditures. Fortunately,,
however, separate price indexes for 27 major categories of government
expenditures have been computed for several benchmark years with
1950 as the base year.15
Using these indexes, government expenditures in 1950 dollars in­
creased 7.2 times from 1913 to 1950, while in current dollars the in­
crease was 22.4 times. I t is estimated also that 31.2 percent of the
total dollar increase (of $66.4 billion) of government expenditures
between 1913 and 1950 was due to price level changes alone.16 That
is, some $20.7 billion of a total 1950 expenditure of $69.5 billion was
due solely to the upward movement of prices since 1913.
Increased services

Increased services was the greatest single cause of the rise in gov­
ernment expenditure over the past half century. The expansion of
existing services and the introduction of new services alone caused a
rise of $27.1 billion (1950 dollars) in government expenditure be­
tween 1913 and 1950.17 Thus, while population increase accounted for
6.9 percent, the expanded scope of government services accounted for
40.9 percent. The remaining 21 percent of the increase in government
expenditure is attributed to the interaction of all three causes: popu­
lation growth, price-level change, and increased services.
Increased services is not only the most important single cause of the
growth in government expenditures over the past decades, it is also
much the most interesting.
13 E stim ates from Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor S tatistics, and the Industrial
Conference Board.
14 Cf. Dewhurst, op. cit., pp. 590—593. A ll follow ing estim ates are also from this.
16 These indexes were constructed by Owen C. Gretton of the Census Bureau, in consulta­
tion w ith Kilpatrick & Drury. Cf. D ewhurst, op. cit., p. 590.




24

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T

h e

P

u b l ic

D

em and

When we study people’s behavior in the private sector of the econ­
omy we use certain concepts, such as consumer demand and consump­
tion function, which help us to understand why people spend their
money as they do. We have learned, for example, th at the proportion
of an individual’s income which he will spend on consumption goods
and services is related, among other things, to his present level of
income, his past income, experience, and his future expectations. We
know, too, that as a person’s income increases he spends a greater abso­
lute amount on consumption goods. He not only buys more clothing,
entertainment, and medical care, but he also tends to buy better qual­
ity products. Also, as income rises, people spend more on new kinds
of purchases. They carry more and different types of insurance, they
increase the amount of their charitable contributions, and in general
they tend to exploit more fully the opportunities of life in an ad­
vanced society.
Much of what the study of consumer demand in the private econ­
omy has taught us about people’s private behavior is also applicable
to their communal behavior. The spending patterns of private indi­
viduals are not determined by influences which are restricted uniquely
to the private sector of the economy. Indeed, not only is the public
spending pattern largely determined by the same general influences,
but public and private spending often are complementary in a high
degree. There would be little sense, for example, in spending a large
amount privately for a high-speed, low-slung, 304-horsepower auto­
mobile if we did not also spend publicly for the superhighway on
which it could be driven.
W hat, then, were the major influences on spending—public and p ri­
vate—over the past half century ?
The single most pervasive economic fact of the past 50 years has
been the great rise m our national output. The value of goods and
services produced per man-hour of labor in the private sector of the
economy rose from 75.5 cents to 203.1 cents (1950 dollars) between
1900 and 1952.18 This 170-percent increase in man-hour productivity
is reflected in the growth of national income from 79.7 billion in 1909
to $274.7 billion in 1953 (1950 dollars).19 Per capita disposable in­
come rose from about $775 in 1909 to about $1,350 by 1953 (1950
dollars). There is also ample evidence of a marked upward shift in
the income distribution of family units, particularly since the 1930’s.20
All of this means th at increased output has made us collectively, as a
nation and as individual and family consuming units, much richer
now than we were at the tu rn of the century.
I t was not possible for our society to become so much richer with­
out experiencing, a t the same time, other significant changes. We
could not have our increased productivity and keep everything else as
it was. In the process of becoming richer, life in our society, and for
us as individuals, became more complex. Today’s techniques of pro­
duction in industry and agriculture require bigger, more complicated,
18 D ew hurst, op. cit., p. 89, table 30.
10 Ibid., appendix 4 -2 , table B, pp. 959-960.
20 Cf. Goldsmith, Jaszi, K aitz, Goldenburg, Size D istribution o f Incom e Since the Mid­
T h irties,” Review of Econom ics and S tatistics, February 1954, also for 1944 to 1954,
Incom e Distribution in the United StateB, A Supplem ent to the Survey of Current Business,
U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of B usiness Economics, W ashington, D. C., 1953.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

25

and more expensive machinery. To organize efficiently production
and distribution of the things we produce, we use larger plants and
business units today than we did in 1900. From the standpoint both
of the supply of labor and the provision of concentrated market areas
for our increased output we had to leave the pastoral countryside and
move to congested urban centers. Urbanization was in this respect
basic to the great technological progress we have had; but, in fact,
the whole technology of life has changed.
The greatly increased volume and variety of goods and services we
consume not only have raised our standard of living; they have also
changed our way of life.
Another major, though not unrelated, influence on the national
spending pattern is the fact th at we have become a high-preparedness
nation. From 1952 through 1955, for example, we spent annually,
on the average, about $45 billion on Government purchases of goods
and services for national-security purposes. I f this was only a shortperiod budgetary phenomenon, it would still exert great influence on
the Nation’s spending, but there is considerable likelihood th at this
is a condition which will be with us for many years to come. As
p art of the indefinite future, it will continue to shape a large p art of
our private as well as public life, even though m ilitary spending is
cut back a few billions or stretched out over a longer period. No
im portant economic or political issue is unaffected by the need for
maintaining a high state of national preparedness over the coming
years.
How have our increased wealth and income, urbanization, tech­
nological advances, and national-security requirements influenced
public and private spending ?
The evidence is clear that as we grew richer we spent privately a
smaller proportion of our income on necessities and a larger share
on luxuries and semiluxuries. Measured in constant dollars of 1950
buying power, per capita consumption expenditures rose from $840
in 1909 to $1,400 in 1952, or 66 percent. Spending increased on all
major categories of consumption goods and services but the relative
gains were substantially different for different classes of goods and
services. Percentage gains, measured in current dollars, between 1909
and 1952, were as follows: 21
Food, liquor, and tobacco------------------------------------------------------------------695
53-5
Clothing, accessories, and personal care_______________________________
H ousing and utilities________________________________________________
360
Household equipment and operation__________________________________
810
Consumer tran sp o rtatio n ____________________________________________ 1,500
Medical care and insurance__________________________________________ 1,100
Recreation---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 1,060
Education (p riv a te )_________________________________________________
750
Religion-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------330
W elfare (p riv a te )---------------------------------------------------------------------------100?

The large percentage increases in expenditure for consumer trans­
portation, that is, the automobile, and for medical care and insurance,
and recreation, are clearly consistent with our increased income and
wealth status. W ithin the categories where percentage increases were
not as outstanding, however, there were also substitutions of more
21 Dowhurst, op. cit.. pp. 101-105. This volume contains a comprehensive analysis of
consumption trends. See chapters 4 through 13, especially table 33, and appendix tables
4 -4 and 4-5, from which most of the follow ing data is taken.




26

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND- STABILITY

luxury-type expenditures for traditional necessities. The composi­
tion of food purchases changed, for example, so th at while the annual
per capita consumption of potatoes and grain products went down
from 473 pounds in 1910-14 to 270 pounds in 1951-52, the consump­
tion of dairy products, eggs, citrus fruits, leafy vegetables, sugar,
coffee, tea, and cocoa, all rose. The rise in real incomes has increased
the relative consumption of more expensive foods ( although p art of
the increases was also due to urbanization, education-induced changes
in our eating habits and other factors).22 Similarly, while expendi­
tures on clothing, accessories, and personal care have remained much
the same as a proportion of total consumption expenditures, there has
been a relative rise in spending for sports clothes, cosmetics, and
beauty-parlor services, and a mild decline in the demand for staple
articles of clothing. The same general pattern is in evidence for
virtually all the major fields of consumption expenditure. As we
grew richer, we consumed more “rich man’s” goods and services.
The combined effect of increased wealth, urbanization, and tech­
nological advances, on private-consumer spending patterns has been
profound, and is in general quite obvious. We now have different
standards of “necessity,” and as a nation we have higher consumption
aspirations than we had in the past.
The same facts, not surprisingly, also hold with respect to our
public spending. Ju st as we have come to demand more and better
quality products from the private sector of the economy, we have come
to demand more and better quality “products” from government—
the public sector. We want more and better quality schools, roads,
hospitals, and recreational facilities, more adequate provision for the
aged, unemployed, infirm, and needy children, increased attention
to our natural resources, more provision for public safety, etc. As
a consequence of this growth in public demand, virtually every gov­
ernment function has been expanded since 1900. This is true whether
the expansion is measured by workers employed, capital assets, or
expenditures (allowing even for price changes).23 Furthermore, the
composition of the expansion by government functions clearly re­
flects the influence of increased income and wealth, urbanization, tech­
nological advances, and defense requirements. Government’s per
capita expenditure on education, for example, measured in 1950 dol­
lars, increased by almost 200 percent between 1913 and 1950.24 I t is
significant, too, that spending for higher education grew by 29 times,
in current dollars, while expenditure on elementary and secondary
schools grew less than 12 times. The public demand has been for
more and better physical plant, for better trained teachers, and for
expansion of public education at the college and professional school
level as well as for vocational training, kindergartens, and other
special educational services. We want these added educational serv­
ices because we are richer, but we also need them to insure the supply
of adequately trained personnel for our complicated production ma­
chine. We need people also to man our Defense Establishment, who
cannot only read and write, but who are technically trained. In ­
33 Ibid., table 44, p. 131, and ch. 5.
MFabricant, op. cit., pp. 82-83.
24 Dewhurst, op. cit., table 263, p. 632.
637.




Follow ing data also from th is source, pp. 625 to

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

27

creased income and technological progress in peace and war activities
together underlie the public demand for more and better education.
Similarly, measured in 1950 dollars, per capita expenditure on
health and community facilities increased by 176 percent between
1913 and 1950. In this category, increased expenditures for health,
hospitals, and public housing, reflect an increased sense o f social re­
sponsibility which grew with our wealth. It also reflects, as do more
clearly our increased expenditures on public water supply, local utili­
ties and sanitation, the growth o f public demand stemming from
urbanization. These last items, and other local services, would not
have figured as heavily in the growth o f public demand had we re­
mained prim arily a rural people. Sanitation, sewerage, water supply,
even the protection o f life and property, are problems which a farmer
largely meets by himself, but the conditions o f city life are such that
government must take the responsibility in order to safeguard the
general health and well-being o f the people.
W ithout laboring the point unnecessarily, it should be apparent
that the same set o f related influences— increased wealth, urbanization,
technological advances, defense requirements— have caused us to in­
crease also our expenditures for public welfare (397 percent), regula­
tion o f business and labor (149 percent), transportation (115 per­
cent), agriculture and natural resources (more than 1,000 percent),
social insurance (more than 1,000 percent) and national defense
(865.1 percent).25
This upward trend o f government expenditure has not, o f course,
proceeded at an even annual rate. Like the growth o f our national
product, it has been sporadic or steplike. W ars and depressions,
though they have been most important through their influence on
Federal expenditures gave the total upward movement some strong
boosts in particular years.28 Despite some irregularity, however, the
increased interdependence o f all groups and individuals in the econ­
omy, a hallmark o f our economic growth, and the high state o f inter­
national tension, now presumably a fixture in our daily lives, have
added directly and indirectly to the demand fo r an expanded scope
and scale o f government.
In brief, the growth o f the public demand which underlay the
growth o f government stems from the same basic causes that led to the
growth o f big business, big labor, big agriculture, big wars— and big
depressions.
This, then, is the essence o f the public demand which has brought
about the great growth o f government over the past half century.
But, the general tendencies which we have explored were not some­
thing new to America, or to the 20th century.27 Although we have
25 A ll p e rc e n ta g e in c re a s e s r e f e r to th e p e rio d 1 9 1 3 -5 0 . T h e y a r e on a p e r c a p ita b a sis
c o m p u te d in 1 9 5 0 d o lla rs . C f. D e w h u r s t, op. c it., ta b le 263, p. 632.
28 C f., f o r e x am p le, A C e n tu ry a n d a H a lf o f F e d e ra l E x p e n d itu r e s . M. S la d e K e n d ric k ,
O c c a s io n a l P a p e r 48, N a tio n a l B u re a u o f E c o n o m ic R e s e a rc h , In c ., N ew Y ork, 1955.
27 C h a r le s ,T. B u llo c k , S e le c ted R e a d in g s in P u b lic F in a n c e , 3d e d itio n , G in n & Co., 1924,
ch. I l l , in c lu d e s s u m m a rie s o f s tu d ie s by o th e r w r ite r s on th e s r o w th o f g o v e rn m e n t
e x p e n d itu re s in E n g la n d , F r a n c e , B elg iu m , S w itz e rla n d , R u ss ia , I ta ly , f o r th e 1 9 th c e n tu ry
a n d so m e tim e s e a r lie r . T h e r e la tiv e g ro w th o f g o v e rn m e n t a n d th e p r iv a te econom y a re
n o t c le a r, h o w e v er, b e ca u se w e la c k d a ta o n th e m e a s u re s o f t o ta l e conom ic g ro w th
w e ll
a s o th e r e le m e n ts su ch a s w e d is c u s s e d ab o v e. T h e d a ta a r e u s e fu l a n d in te re s tin g ,
n e v e rth e le s s , a n d p ro v id e som e g r e a te r h is to r ic a l p e rs p e c tiv e o n th e issu e . B u llo c k ’s ow n
e s tim a te s o f th e g ro w th o f F e d e ra l G o v e rn m e n t e x p e n d itu re s in th e U n ite d S ta te s show a
ris e in p e r c a p ita te rm s from . $1 .1 7 in 1 8 0 0 to $ 6 .3 6 in 1900, w ith d e fin ite a c c e le ra tio n o f
th e r a t e o f in c re a s e in th e p o s t-C iv il W a r p e rio d .
T h e re is a lso a n in c re a s in g flo'v o f d a ta fro m o th e r c o u n trie s f o r r e la tiv e ly re c e n t tim e s.
O n e s tu d y , T h e T r e n d o f P u b lic E m p lo y m e n t in G re a t B r ita in a n d th e U n ite d S ta te s , M oses




28

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

no comparable statistical measures for earlier times or other countries,
there is considerable evidence th at the growth of government has been
a regular concomitant of general economic progress.
F or example, as table IV indicates, for 14 countries for which we
have data, in the fiscal year 1951, there was a distinct correlation be­
tween per capita national product and per capita national government
expenditures; the wealthier countries spent more per capita and
the poorer countries spent less.28 T hat the United States is not far
out of line with other nations’ experience is also clear. The ratio of
National Government expenditures to gross national product was
lower in the United States at 15.1 percent than it was in 11 of the 14
countries cited. The exclusion of State and local expenditures, how­
ever, understates government spending more in the United States than
in other countries. Inadequate data for many of the countries pre­
clude comparing other than national government spending, but using
per capita total taxes of all levels of government the same general con­
clusion emerges. Taxes relative to gross national product were lower
than in the United States only in those countries (Denmark, Iceland,
Portugal, Greece, and Turkey) having either very small defense
expenditures or very low income.
W agner’s celebrated “law of the increase of state activities” : 29
Comprehensive comparisons of different countries and
different times show that, among progressive peoples, with
which alone we are concerned, an increase regularly takes
place in the activity of both the central and the local gov­
ernments. This increase is both extensive and intensive; the
central and local governments constantly undertake new func­
tions, while they perform both old and new functions more
efficiently and completely. In this way the economic needs of
the people, to an increasing extent and in a more satisfactory
fashion, are satisfied. * * *
assumes real meaning when the emphasis is placed on “progressive
peoples”—which implies economic growth—-and on the influence, es­
pecially in a political democracy, of the “needs of the people.”
T

he

R

e l a t iv e

G k o w th o r F ederal a n d S
G overnm ents

tate a n d

L

ocal

A t the beginning of this century, the Federal Government collected
38 percent of all tax revenues, the States, 11 percent, the local govern­
ments, 51 percent; and, the distribution of government expenditures
corresponded closely to these relative shares of tax receipts. In 1956,
the Federal share of all taxes was about 71 percent and its share of
total government expenditures was 65 percent. The States and local
governments shared almost equally the remaining 29 percent of tax
collections and spent 35 percent of the government total.
Abramovitz and Vera Eliasberg, American Economic Review, vol. X L III, No. 2, May 1953,
finds, for example, th at in Great Britain, “toward the end of the 19th century, not 1
worker in 25 w as on the Government payroll. In the middle of the 20th century, 1 in 7
w as working in a regular Government agency and nearly 1 in 4 either in such an agency
or in a nationalized industry or service" (p. 2 0 5 ). Cf., also in the same journal, Lyle C.
F itch, Trends in Federal, State, and Local Government Expenditures Since 1890, pp.
216—233
^ D ew h u rst, op. cit., table 236, p. 579.
29 Grundlegung dor politischen Oekonomie, book VI, ch. 3 (3d edition, 1893), cited in
Charles J. Bullock, ibid.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

29

The changeover from a State-local to a Federal dominated public
fisc did not follow a smooth or consistent trend line. Two W orld W ars
and the great depression gave dramatic boosts to the Federal role, but
wars and depression alone fall far short of adequately explaining the
changing pattern of intergovernmental relations. F o r an under­
standing of the growth of the role of the Federal Government it is
hardly sufficient only to point to the great rises in Federal expendi­
tures which occurred under war and depression stimuli. Why, for
example, did the Federal Government grow so much in power and
prestige in the depressed thirties and State and local governments lag
so far behind ? The depression alone, though it was the most serious
in our history, did not resolve the course of intergovernmental events
in that unhappy decade.
Throughout these past 50 years there was at work, as there is now,,
a complex of economic and political forces which, though subject to
alteration by great events, are fashioned fundamentally by more con­
sistent threads of the historical process. Improved communication
and transportation, the growth of a national economy, urbanization,,
increased wealth, all the elements which led to the growth in the pub­
lic demand, were p art of this historical process.
The great events, wars and depression, give us, however, some con­
venient focal points for analysis. Accordingly, to facilitate our dis­
cussion we have divided the period roughly as follows: 1900-29,1930­
40, 1941-46, 1946-56. The major breaks after the turn of the cen­
tury come, therefore, at the start of the great depression, the start and
the end of World W ar II.
Federal Government expenditures: 1900-1929

The United States emerged as a full-fledged great power during
this period, particularly after World W ar I, but the rise in Federal
Government expenditures only partially reflected the tremendous eco­
nomic and population growth of the Nation in the same years. Total
Federal expenditure increased from about $521 million in 1900 to
$2,900 million in 1929, but as a fraction of gross national product
remained virtually the same: 2.9 percent in 1900 and 3.0 percent in
1929.30 Total per capita expenditures, measured in 1926 prices,
roughly doubled, from $12.31 in 1900 to $24.76 in 1929.31
W orld W ar I contributed more by far than any other factor to the
expenditure rise. Total Federal spending in 1914, for example, was
on the order of $735 million; in 1919 it was 25 times greater at
$18,448 million, and although it fell sharply in the next decade the
lowest point it ever reached was $2,774 million—in 1927—still some
3.8 times higher than prewar. Increased spending for defense and on
war-connected charges—mainly veteran’s benefits and services and
interest on the debt—accounted for about 85 percent of the total ex­
penditure increase between 1900 and 1929. But, aside from defense
30T h e s e p e rc e n ta g e s a re fr o m K e n d ric k , op. c it., b u t th e y a p p ly to a s o m e w h a t d iffe re n t
y e a r t h a n th e r e s t o f o u r d a ta .
A c tu a lly , t o t a l e x p e n d itu re s f o r th is c o m p u ta tio n
r e p r e s e n t a n a v e ra g e o f th e tw o fisc al y e a r s w h ic h in c lu d e th e c a le n d a r y e a r . T h is a d j u s t ­
m e n t does no v io le n c e to o u r c o m p a ris o n s, h o w e v e r, b e c a u s e o f th e tim e in te r v a l in v o lv e d .
31 E x p e n d itu r e fig u res in th is s e c tio n a r e a lso fr o m K e n d ric k , op. c it., e x c e p t a s o th e rw is e
n o te d . D e fla tio n to c o n s ta n t 1 9 2 6 d o lla rs w a s a c c o m p lis h e d by K e n d ric k w ith th e u se of
t h e B . L . S. W h o le sa le P r ic e In d e x . A lth o u g h w e h a v e p re v io u s ly in d ic a te d th e in a d e q u a c y
o f s u c h a c o m p o site in d e x , i t does s e rv e a s a c ru d e m e a s u re o f p ric e -le v e l c h a n g e s a n d is
a c c e p ta b le f o r th e w o rk a t h a n d w h ic h d o es n o t re q u ire a h ig h d e g re e o f a c c u ra c y . T a b le s
1 a n d 4 (b e lo w ) w e re c o n s tr u c te d by a p p ly in g th e sa m e in d e x to S t a t e a n d lo c a l g o v e rn ­
m e n t e x p e n d itu re d a ta .
97735_57----- 4




30

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND' STABILITY

and war charges there was little change in the volume of Federal
spending.
Expenditures for civil purposes, i. e., other than defense, veteran’s
benefits and services, international affairs and interest on the debt—
increased in all only by some $657 million. In constant 1926 prices
this amounted to a rise of $3.13 per capita. Most of this increase went
for transportation and communication facilities—mainly the provi­
sion of navigational aids, and grants-in-aid to the States for high­
way development—and general government. Somewhat more atten­
tion was being paid to the development and improvement of agri­
culture and natural resources, aid for the aged and infirm, the pro­
motion of public health, and crime prevention and control. But for
civil functions, clearly, Federal expenditure was not very much dif­
ferent in 1929 from what it had been at the dawn of the century.
Furthermore, the bulk of the Federal Government’s growth took
place in the first 20 years of the period. A fter W orld W ar I, the
return to normalcy was accompanied by a drop in total Federal
spending during most of the twenties as debt charges and veter­
ans’ costs incident to the war decreased.
G rants-in-aid

Although Federal Government expenditure in this period was char­
acterized by an extension of regular Government services and there
was little innovation of quantitative budgetary importance, there were
clear indications that the forces of change were strongly affecting
its role. Federal aid to the States for highways increased under the
Federal Aid Koad Act (1916), from nothing in 1900 to $81 million
by 1927; for education, from less than $1 million to $11 million,
including assistance to States in paying the salaries of teachers of
vocational education (Smith-Hughes Act of 1917); and there were
also small increases for other purposes as well as some aid paid di­
rectly to the local governments. Small as these aid programs appear
in retrospect, they mark a growing realization of the national nature
which some of the traditionally State and local functions were assum­
ing under the pressure of general economic growth. Similar signs
were evidenced by the participation of the Federal Government in the
cost of agricultural extension work (Smith-Lever Act of 1914) in ad­
dition to the annual cash payments already offered land-grant col­
leges under the second M orrill Act (1890) ; the extension of Federal
assistance to States for forest-fire protection (Weeks Act of 1911);
and in the years from 1916 to 1921, by aid offered the States to com­
bat venereal disease, for the rehabilitation of persons injured in in­
dustrial accidents, and for maternal and child health.
In summary, Federal aid to the State and local governments rose
from some $7 million in 1902 to $12 million in 1913. From 1913 to
1922 there was a much more substantial rise, to $108 million, and
then a period of consolidation but little expansion so th at by 1927
the total of aid payments to State and local units was $116 million.
I t is clear, too, that the increased flow of aid payments closely paral­
leled the rising need for highways as the automobile transformed
our national transportation system. All other aid programs, especial­
ly public welfare, did not fare nearly as well as the highways.32
32 F o r a f u ll d is c u s s io n o f th e d e v e lo p m e n t o f th e g r a n ts - in - a id p r o g r a m see J a m e s A .
M ax w e ll, T h e F is c a l I m p a c t o f F e d e ra lis m in th e U n ite d S ta te s , H a r v a r d U n iv e r s ity P r e s s ,

1946.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

31

State and local government expenditures: 1900-29

State and local government expenditures increased more than Fed­
eral expenditures, both in absolute amount and relatively, for the
first three decades of the century. Per capita State and local ex­
penditures, measured in 1926 prices increased by $44.85 from 1902 to
1927 (in contrast to Federal increases of $13.21). As a fraction of
gross national product State and local expenditures grew from 5.2
percent in 1902 to 8.7 percent in 1927 (in contrast to Federal growth
from 2.3 to 3.1 percent).
The greatest increases in State and local expenditures were for
education and highways which together accounted for more than
half the total increase. The impact of the automobile on govern­
ment finances is clearly indicated by the more than tenfold increase
in highway expenditures during the 25 years from 1902 to 1927. The
increased expenditure on education was a function of the population
increase and the demand for more and better schools which we have
discussed above. There were also substantial additions to expendi­
ture on hospitals, sanitation, police, and fire protection—on almost
every established function of State and local governments. And as
urbanization progressed, other local functions such as the provision
of utilities and transit facilities emerged with new importance.
In brief, increased expenditure on schools, highways, and local
services were the most important cause of increased government ex­
penditure—Federal, State, and local—during the period 1900 to 1929,
and the role of the State and local governments, measured by ex­
penditures, significantly increased relative to that of the Federal
Government during this period. From 1902 to 1927, for example, the
State and local share of all government expenditures rose from about
69 percent to 74 percent; and for civil functions only, from 88 percent
to 92 percent. The State and local governments clearly dominated
the public fiscal scene.
Beyond expenditures

In addition to participating in the costs of more State and local
functions through the use of grants-in-aid, the Federal Government
established a number of agencies to deal directly with developmental
and regulatory programs which had become important largely as a
result of general economic growth and the increased interdependence
which marked the development of a national economy. Some of the
more significant w ere:
Bureau of Standards (1901)
Bureau of Reclamation (1902)
Forest Service (1905)
National P ark Service (1906)
Federal Bureau of Investigation (1908)
Bureau of Mines (1910)
Bureau of Foreign and Domestic Commerce (1912)
Children’s Bureau (1912)
Federal Reserve System (1913)
Conciliation Service (1913)
Federal Trade Commission (1914)
National Advisory Committee for Aeronautics (1915)



32

ECONOMIC GROWTH A N D S T A B IU T T

F arm Credit Administration (1916)
Women’s Bureau (1918)
Federal Power Commission (1920)
There were, thus, significant changes in the scope of the Federal
Government which tend to be understated somewhat in statistical
time series, and especially by per capita comparisons of expenditure,
because they did not loom large in the Federal budget. While there
was little deviation from the traditional laissez-faire line in public
pronouncements th at the business of government was governing—in
a narrow sense—there was considerable expansion in the actual range
of government activity, and even more m the potential range for
government action.
I t is important, too, to observe the kinds of functions in which the
Federal Government took a stronger hand. Although the Federal
Reserve System, for example, had strong roots in our history, many
of the other activities which the Federal Government entered into
had been more exclusively the preserve of the State and local govern­
ments. W elfare activities, like those involved in the Children’s
Bureau, had been a traditionally local function since the time of the
Elizabethan poor law s; labor conditions and industrial-relations prob­
lems had been a m atter prim arily for State or local action; law en­
forcement, likewise; and more or less similarly for the regulation of
domestic trade, conservation—insofar as it was practiced—and power
development. I t is only fair to say, too, th at none of these activities
was undertaken by virtue of an autonomous decision on the p a rt of
the Federal Government. Strong pressures were required before the
Government, under either political party, entered any of these fields.
And underlying the pressures for extending the scope of Federal
Government activity were some of the basic forces discussed above—
the development of a national economy in which State and local bound­
aries had progressively less economic significance, rapid industriali­
zation, and urbanization, a growing sense of social responsibility, and
so forth. F or example, as communication, commerce, and industry
became more interstate in character, the Federal Government was
forced to expand its regulatory role—just as it did, through the es­
tablishment of the Federal Bureau of Investigation, as crime also
became a serious interstate matter. In fact, the Federal Government
stepped in mainly where there was strong public pressure to which
the State and local governments could not, or would not, give effective
satisfaction.
Actually, the importance of these extensions of Federal Government
activity was perhaps greatest in th at they represented cumulatively a
considerable expansion of established limits for Federal Government
concern. Court decisions subsequent to cases arising from instances
of Federal Government action also added markedly to the recognition
of Federal powers—and their potential.
Thus, while the expenditure comparisons for this period show a
much greater growth for the State and local governments, the Federal
Government was having initiative forced upon it for the assumption
of new functions, many formerly State or local.
As we have previously noted, however, the development of both
increased expenditure and increased scope took place prior to the twen­
ties. In fact, from 1923 to 1929, the Federal Government not only cut



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

33

expenditures, but also reduced its debt by about $1 billion, on the
average, each year. Andrew W. Mellon, Secretary of the Treasury,
summarized general policies when he wrote in 1924:
Since the war, two guiding principles have dominated the
financial policies of the Government. One is the balancing of
the budget, and the other is the payment of the debt.33
Thus, while the Federal Government was enjoying prosperity—
taking in more than it spent—the State and local governments were
already caught in a squeeze between burgeoning expenditure require­
ments and limited fiscal capacity. The growth of public demand—for
schools and highways, especially—was so rapid in the first half of
this century that public adjustment to the concurrent need for higher
taxes apparently could not keep pace. This was particularly true for
the local governments. As school and local service expansion neces­
sitated large outlays for plant and equipment, they were forced to
borrow more heavily. Total State and local debt rose from $2.1
billion in 1902 to $14.9 billion by 1927, and the local share of that total
went from roughly 80 to 87 percent. School districts, special districts,
and cities shared the bulk of the increase34 as they did the bulk of
functional responsibility. Many were faced by serious financial prob­
lems before 1929.
Summary— The background for crisis
Federal, State, and local relations. F or the period under review

as a whole, and particularly after World W ar I, there was a dispro­
portionate growth of expenditures and revenues for the Federal and
State and local governments. The Federal share of total tax receipts
went up, while its share of total expenditures went down, and, con­
versely, as the State and local share of all taxes went down, their
share of all expenditures went up. Consequently, during the twenties,
the Federal Government was able to reduce its indebtedness by about
$1 billion, on the average, annually. Its credit position, always good,
was made even better. The State and local governments, whose credit
was never as good as that of the Federal Government, increased their
indebtedness by about $1 billion annually, causing the total of Govern­
ment obligations outstanding to remain about the same with a shift
toward more State and local debt in the total, local debt particularly.
The Federal share of tax receipts went up as a result of the Federal
Government’s exploitation of income and profits taxes after 1913. The
prosperity of the twenties caused increased yields for these taxes, even
after wartime rates were cut. The State and local governments, on
the other hand, still depended mainly on property taxation for their
revenues. The States also drew heavily on vehicular taxes during the
twenties, but in that otherwise prosperous decade the value of farm ­
lands and buildings declined substantially and, in the aggregate, the
property tax lost much of its yield elasticity. In a great many locali­
ties, it was already proving to be overburdened.

&

83 C ite d in M a in C u r r e n ts in M o d ern E c o n o m ic L ife , vol. I I , H o ra c e T a y lo r , e d ito r,
U a r c o u r t, B ra c e
Co., N ew Y o rk , 19 4 1 , p . 280.
34 F r o m 1902 to 19 2 2 , s c h o o l- d is tric t d e b t ro s e fr o m 2.1 to 11 p e r c e n t o f t o t a l S ta te
a n d lo c a l d e b t : s p e c ia l- d is tr ic t d e b t fro m 0.2 to 6.2 p e r c e n t ; c o u n ty d e b t fro m 9.3 to 13.5
p e r c e n t ; a n d c ity d e b t, th o u g h i t fe ll fro m 7 3 .2 to 56 .6 p e rc e n t, h a d by f a r th e la r g e s t
d o lla r in c re a s e — a b o u t $ 4 .2 b illio n . C f., H is to r ic a l R ev iew o f S t a t e a n d L o c a l F in a n c e s ,
S p e c ia l S tu d y 25, B u r e a u o f C en su s, W a s h in g to n , 1948.




34

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Despite revenue surpluses, the Federal Government avoided any
significant increase in functional responsibility and expenditure after
World W ar I. From 1922 to 1929, in fact, it was able to reduce ex­
penditures as war-connected charges declined. The State and local
governments, on the other hand, were unable to resist a substantial
expansion in expenditures for their traditional responsibilities—
mainly highways and education. During the twenties, therefore, the
Federal Government hewed closely to a laissez-faire financial policy,,
while the State and local governments, often against strong opposition
from tax-conscious groups, increased their involvement in basic gov­
ernmental services.
State-local relations.—The big difference between the situation of
the States and that of most local governments was that the States, by
tradition, were one step further removed from the demand for most
governmental services. Outlays by the States for education and high­
ways, which accounted for more than 70 percent of the growth in total
State expenditures (including aid to localities) between 1902 and
1927, remained small compared to local outlays (less than one-half in
1927) for the same purposes. The local governments also had to face
the great bulk of increased costs for public welfare, sanitation, recrea­
tion, police, and fire protection, etc. The States, insofar as they were
able to disassociate themselves from local problems, had no pressing
financial problem. Kevenues from motor-vehicle taxes met the great­
est p art of highway requirements, and other revenue resources more
than took care of other direct State expenditures. Despite their p ar­
ental obligations, the States, in fact, generally did resist local demands
for more aid and even for more “home rule.” They showed great re­
straint in the use of the State tax power and left local responsibility
largely intact.
The local governments were severely limited in the kinds of revenue
sources they could tap, not only because (a) most State constitutions
or statutes restricted local tax and borrowing authority, but also be­
cause ( i ) the growth of a truly national economy made it more diffi­
cult for smaller jurisdictions to use new taxes on business and persons
whose activities were not restricted by political boundaries. The re­
sult was that the local governments faced an ever bigger job with rela­
tively little additional help. Thus, while, from 1900 to 1929. the
number of pupils enrolled m public schools increased by 10 million,
motor-vehicle registrations grew from a few thousand to more than
26 million, and urbanization multiplied the need for local services,,
the local governments still depended on the property tax for more than
two-thirds of all their revenue. The aid they received through grants
from the States, and a little additional from the Federal Government,
grew, but never even approximated the volume that would have been
required to balance local budgets. So, the local units continued to
borrow heavily, even during the prosperous twenties, and found them­
selves, even here, restricted by assorted local debt limits in State
statutes.
By 1929, therefore, as the country stood on the brink of what we call
now, somewhat optimistically, the great depression, the maladjust­
ment of governmental functions and financial resources was already
clear. The obverse to the financial problems we have explored is the
matter of the Government spending which never took place and which,
now it is generally agreed, would have well served the national inter­



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

35

est. Before one-third of the Nation also became “ill clad and ill
nourished,” it was already ill housed, ill schooled, and ill protected
from sickness and disaster.

,

T h e great depression 1929-jft

The “great crash” of the New York stock market in October 1929
resounded throughout the financial world. Although it heralded
greater tragedy to come, the financial panic and the downward spiral
of employment and income took a little time to gather full momentum.
But by 1932 the situation was tragically clear to the country at large.
Unemployment had risen from 1.5 million in 1929 to 12.1 million by
1932, so that one-fourtli of the civilian labor force was without work.
Personal consumption expenditures had dropped by more than onethird in actual dollars, and by almost one-fifth in constant (1947)
dollars. Gross private domestic investment had gone down from over
$16 billion to less than $1 billion, and the Federal Reserve Board Index
of Industrial Production showed a drop from 110 to 58 (1935-39 =
100). The gross national product had fallen from $104.4 billion to
$58.5 billion, and per capita personal income from $684 to $320. Even
correcting for the 20-percent drop in consumer prices, per capita in­
comes had fallen by more than 40 percent. In that brief span, from
1929 to 1932, the forced sales of farms—foreclosures—doubled, per­
sonal savings turned negative, even the marriage rate went down by
more than 20 percent, and the birth rate also dropped noticeably.
The depression, obviously, also had devastating effects on Govern­
ment revenues. All Government tax collections dropped, between
1929 and 1932, by 17.3 percent. Federal tax receipts, heavily depend­
ent on cyclically responsive income and profits taxes, fell most sharply,
by 47 percent. The States, whose income came largely from motor
vehicles and property taxes, lost 3.1 percent of their tax receipts; and
the local governments, depending almost exclusively on property
taxes whose yield is relatively insensitive to changes in business condi­
tions, lost less than one-half of 1 percent of their tax receipts. Even
with this drop in receipts, tax collections in 1932 amounted to 19 per­
cent of the national income as opposed to 12 percent in 1929—an in­
crease of more than 50 percent in the tax burden relative to the
national income.
In previous depressions, when it was felt that conditions were suf­
ficiently bad, local governments had supplemented private charity
with work relief and small amounts of poor relief. The States did
very little, if anything, and the Federal Government had abided by
Grover Cleveland’s admonition that “though the people support the
Government, the Government should not support the people.”
This was a new kind of depression—much more severe and much
more persistent than any the Nation had known. Great changes
which had marked our growing output and wealth now became spec­
ters : industrialization and urbanization meant that most of the people
now depended on wages and lived in cities, and when they lost their
jobs, they were left without means to obtain food, shelter, and other
necessities; the growth of a national economy and technological prog­
ress meant, among other things, the commercialization of agriculture
and consequently a crucial relationship between farm product prices
and costs of production, in which fixed mortgage payments and inter­
est figured heavily and led to so much hardship. In general, greater



36

ECONOMIC GROWTH AN D STABILITY

economic interdependence spread the deepening blight more widely
throughout the economy, and the need for emergency relief alone was
beyond the capacity of most State and local governments to meet.
F or the State and/or local governments to cope with the new kind
of depression emergency they would have had to have greatly in­
creased financial support from either much higher tax collections or
increased borrowing. In fact, neither was really possible.
The tax structure of most of the States, as we have seen, had not
been strongly developed by 1929, and with the onset of depression
conditions it became more difficult to apply effectively new levies or
strengthen old ones. Between 1929 and 1932, 4 States added mod­
erate income taxes, 2 States added death taxes, some scattered excises
appeared, but the several motor-vehicle taxes were the only ones whose
revenue yield grew at all and, as we have observed, total State tax
revenues fell by some 3 percent. Conditions were such th at even had
the States possessed the ability to levy new taxes, the total economic
base was shrinking so rapidly that there was hardly a spot which could
conceivably carry increased taxation without adding to the disaster.
W ith income, employment, sales volume, inventory, and property
values all spiraling downward, where could additional taxes be
placed ? Even with a determination born of ignorance and obstinacy,
which was at times evidenced, the States could not meet large-scale
emergency fiscal needs by raising additional revenues from tax sources
while the economy was still moving down into the deep trough of the
depression.
Clearly, too, the local governments were in an even more difficult
situation than the States with respect to tax-raising capacity. A l­
though the property tax had the most stable yield record of any tax,
it had become terribly burdensome as personal and business incomes
fell. Even though the total assessed value of all taxable property had
been reduced by $28 billion—from $169.3 billion in 1930 to $141.3 bil­
lion in 1933—market values of property and, more important, the
capacity of property owners to pay taxes had fallen much more. In
fact, tax delinquency became a major problem, rising for 150 of the
largest cities from 10.1 percent in 1930 to 26.3 percent in 1933.35
W hat about increased borrowing to meet emergency needs?
Both the State and local governments were relatively eager to in­
crease their debt obligations to meet emergency relief costs despite the
prevalence of orthodox views on the need for annually balanced budg­
ets. Throughout most of the previous decade they had sold debt obli­
gations on the security market at the rate of roughly $1 billion an­
nually, and through 1931 they were able to continue borrowing at
about the same level. But then they were brought up short by two
im portant barriers: (1) Since 1842, when Rhode Island wrote a bor­
rowing lim it into its constitution, the practice had grown so th a t some
form of debt limitation was a p art of nearly all State constitutions.36
The result was that most of the States could not borrow on the neces­
sary scale without referral to the public or other difficult and time­

&

85 C f., S ta te a n d L o c a l F in a n c e s in t h e N a tio n a l E c o n o m y , A lv in H . H a n s e n a n d H a r v e y
S . P e r l o f f ; W . W . N o rto n
Co., N ew Y o rk , 19 4 4 , p. 51. T h is p io n e e rin g w o rk is s till, to
a r e m a rk a b le e x te n t, c o n s id e rin g 4II t h a t h a s h a p p e n e d s in c e i t w a s w r itt e n , tim e ly a n d
in s tr u c tiv e .
36 C f., C o n s titu tio n a l D e b t C o n tro l in th e S ta te s , T h e T a x F o u n d a tio n , In c ., N e w Y o rk ,
19 5 4 . A t p r e s e n t a ll b u t 5 S ta te s h a v e s u c h l i m i t a t i o n s : C o n n e c tic u t, M is s is s ip p i, N e w
H a m p s h ir e , T e n n e ss e e , a n d V e rm o n t.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

37

consuming preliminaries. Local government borrowing was also
sharply limited by State jurisdiction. Not only was new borrowing
thus restricted, but the decline in assessed values forced localities to
contract existing debt margins and undermined their credit standing.37
(2) The State and local governments were dependent for their borrow­
ing, in the main, on the willingness of banks and private investors to
accept their debt obligations. There were established criteria of
soundness set up in the security market and “adequate” security usu­
ally meant a favorable economic background, good tax collections, a
low volume of tax delinquency, balanced budgets, and self-liquidating
projects. Although these criteria were more strictly held for local
governments, the States had to meet substantially the same require­
ments and it became almost impossible to borrow even under very
costly terms. By 1932, in fact, 78.7 percent of all State and local is­
sues bore interest rates of 4.5 percent and higher.
Even with these high interest rates the localities, in particular, had
to meet additional rigorous requirements set up by the banking com­
munity. These usually involved economy provisions cutting back
activities and expenditures, agreements on tax collection and tax de­
linquency policies, etc. All of these provisions were made, for exam­
ple, in the so-called bankers agreement under which New York City
was enabled, after some difficulty, to fund its pressing short-term debt
obligations. The New York State Legislature also obliged the city by
reducing the mandatory pay scale for teachers so that the city’s ex­
penses could be more readily reduced. In Detroit, Chicago, and other
cities, heavy cuts were forced in relief payments and other city expend­
itures in order to enable them to place loans and qualify for tempo­
rary credit in the financial market.
H igh interest rates, short-term maturities, and severe contractual
agreements for the borrowing governments were still inadequate for
enticing an adequate supply of private funds into the security market
during the rough years of the depression, 1932 to 1934. Investors had
become ultraconservative and were even leery of State and local gov­
ernment obligations, especially after 3 States, Arkansas, Louisiana,
and South Carolina, and 37 large cities, were forced to default on
their debts. A t one point, in fact, defaults reached approximately 15
percent of outstanding local debt issues. Not surprisingly, therefore,
in 1932, 697 issues totaling $260 million could not be sold; in 1933,
528 issues totaling $212 million failed to find buyers—even though
these issues included debt obligations of such governments as Buffalo,
Philadelphia, Cleveland, Toledo, Mississippi, and Montana.
In summary, then, the State and local governments could not, in
general, muster large additional revenues during the trough years of
the depression either by taxation or borrowing. Local governments,
carrying the greatest part of the unemployment relief burden, were
forced to slash public services to meet emergency needs, and the
States, too, were forced to adopt strong deflationary policies at a time
when private spending was already hitting bottom. In addition to
those States and localities which were forced to default on their debt
obligations, many others came dangerously close to bankruptcy—a
word which had become common currency with reference to public as
well as private institutions.
97 M u ch o f th i s s e c tio n o n d e b t fin a n c e by S ta te a n d lo c a l g o v e rn m e n ts is ta k e n a lm o s t
v e r b a tim fro m H a n s e n a n d P e rlo ff, op. c it.




38

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

W hy the Federal Government grew

The Federal Government, as opposed to the State and local gov­
ernments, was sheltered for a brief time (1929-30) from the effects of
the deepening depression. I t was not immediately faced with rapidly
rising emergency relief demands—those were still local matters—nor
were there any other sizable increases in expenditure impending in the
proximate future, and anticipated tax receipts remained high. The
Federal surplus for the fiscal year 1929 had been about 185 millions,
and Andrew Mellon, the Secretary of the Treasury, expected higher
Treasury receipts in the following year.38 President Hoover, acting
on the advice of his Secretary of the Treasury, accordingly suggested
to the Congress that income tax rates on 1929 income, payable in 1930,
be cut in order to relieve the taxpayers. W ithin a month, on Decem­
ber 1929, Congress enacted a new tax bill which followed the Presi­
dent’s recommendations and cut the normal tax rates on individual
income from 1.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent to 0.5 percent, 2 per­
cent, and 4 percent, respectively, and the corporate tax rate from 12
to 11 percent. Even with this tax cut, Federal revenues at $3.6 billion
for the fiscal year ending June 1930 were higher than those of previous
years and the surplus, $184 million, was only slightly below the level
of the year before.39 W ithin 1 year, however, the picture was com­
pletely changed. For the fiscal year 1931 the Federal Government
showed a gross deficit of $902 million, and it was clear that the unex­
pected decline in business and personal incomes had cut the Federal
tax base much more heavily than had been anticipated.
Despite the deficit, Federal expenditures were allowed to move up­
ward during 1931 as aid to agriculture and veterans was somewhat in­
creased and public-works enterprises were moderately expanded in the
hope that they would stimulate business and help rebuild confidence in
the economy’s future.
The economy continued downward, however, and the pressure for
increased Federal action to speed relief and recovery grew rapidly.
Faced with a prospective deficit of almost $3 billion developing for
the fiscal year 1932,40 the Hoover administration, following accepted
doctrine, moved to return to a balanced budget by raising taxes and
cutting expenditures. President Hoover concisely summarized his ad­
ministration’s point of view when he declared, in January 1932, that
“we cannot squander ourselves into prosperity.” 41 But, in the same
month, the Reconstruction Finance Corporation was created with a
Government-subscribed capital of $500 million. Under the RFC,
home-loan banks were organized, the Federal farm-loan system was
expanded, and relief and public works activities were somewhat en­
. 38 C f., A m e ric a n T a x a tio n , I t s H is to r y a s a S o c ia l F o r c e in D e m o c ra c y , S id n e y R a tn e r ,
W . W . N o rto n & Co., N ew Y ork, 1942, pp. 4 3 7 ff.
391, e., th e s u rp lu s o f T r e a s u r y re c e ip ts o v e r T r e a s u r y e x p e n d itu re s , in c lu d in g d e b t
r e tir e m e n t e x p e n d itu re s . T h is is th e " g ro s s ” s u r p lu s a s c o n tr a s t e d to “ n e t ” s u r p lu s (o r
“ n e t ” d e fic it) w h e re p u b lic -d e b t r e tir e m e n ts a r e d e d u c te d fr o m t o t a l e x p e n d itu re s .
40 T h e d e fic it f o r 1932 w a s $ 2 ,8 8 5 .4 m illio n , o r a lm o s t $2 b illio n m o re th a n f o r 1931.
O r d in a ry re c e ip ts d e c lin e d by a b o u t $1.2 b illio n , a n d e x p e n d itu re s in c r e a s e d b y $787
m illio n . T h e in c re a s e d e x p e n d itu re w a s a c c o u n te d f o r la rg e ly by a $500 m illio n s u b s c rip ­
tio n to th e c a p i ta l sto c k o f th e n e w ly fo rm e d R e c o n s tru c tio n F in a n c e C o rp o ra tio n , a n d a
s u b s c rip tio n o f $125 m illio n to th e c a p i ta l s to c k o f th e F e d e r a l la n d b a n k s. T h e s e e x p e n d i­
t u r e s w e re m a d e in th e e ffo rt to e x p a n d c r e d it f a c ilitie s a n d r e p r e s e n te d th e g r e a t b u lk o f
re c o v e ry a n d re lie f s p e n d in g f o r th e tim e , a lth o u g h th e E m e rg e n c y R e lie f A c t ( J u ly 1 9 3 2 )
a ls o p ro v id e d f o r F e d e r a l lo a n s to h e lp lo c a l g o v e rn m e n ts c a r r y t h e i r r e lie f lo a d s. A n
$8 0 3 m illio n d ro p in in c o m e -ta x c o lle c tio n s w a s th e m o s t i m p o r ta n t f a c t o r in t h e d e c lin e
o f o r d in a r y re c e ip ts . C f., F e d e r a l F in a n c e , 1 9 2 3 -3 2 , N a tio n a l I n d u s t i i a l C o n fe re n c e B o a rd .
In c ., N ew Y o rk , 19 3 3 , p p . 6 0 -6 4 .
M itc h e ll, op. c it., p. 37.

u




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

39

larged. To compensate for the Government’s depression spending
activity, however, the Revenue Act of 1932, which became law on
June 6, 1932, sharply raised all income-tax rates, lowered exemptions
and deductions for individuals and corporations, doubled the estatetax rates, restored the gift tax, and imposed excise taxes on a wide
variety of goods and services. This tax legislation represented one of
the sharpest increases in tax rates and liabilities ever enacted in time
of peace—so great was the drive for a balanced budget even as the
national economy plummeted downward.
In the ensuing fiscal year, 1933, receipts from income and profits
taxes fell, nevertheless, by about one-quarter of a billion dollars to
one-third of their 1930 level, and were not quite offset by increased
receipts from the excises and other special levies, so that total tax
revenues dropped by about $15 million.42 Even though expenditures
for the same year Avere reduced, there was another deficit of over $2.6
billion, and the Federal debt grew to $22.5 billion. The Hoover gov­
ernment, unhappy though it was with unbalanced budgets, also could
not raise large, additional tax revenues during the downswing of the
depression while the national income was being cut in half.

,

T h e N ew D eal 1933-1^0

The spring of 1933 marked the lowest point of the great depression.
State and local governments, as we have seen, were largely without
resources to meet emergency relief needs, and the Congress, after the
November 1932 elections, was dominated by “lame ducks” who re­
fused to take any vigorous action to ease the crisis. Not only was a
fourth of the Avork force unemployed and essential credit f o r farmers
mid businessmen unavailable, but the whole banking system was in
danger of imminent collapse as bank after bank Avas forced to close its
doors during the month preceding Franklin D. Roosevelt’s inaugura­
tion. A sense of extreme national crisis pervaded the entire country.
R oosevelt assumed the Presidency on M arch 4, 1933, and the new
adm inistration moved Avith unparalleled speed in an effort to achieve
“ relief, recovery, and re fo rm ” through “ the farflung, h ig h ly varied,
sometimes con tradictory p rogram know n as the NeAv D eal.” 43

The emergency relief nature of the expansion of Federal Govern­
ment activity in the first years of the New Deal is amply clear from
the titles and purposes of the principal agencies created to handle the
job: (1) The Federal Emergency Relief Administration (May 1933)
was established by Congress for the purpose of assisting the States
and localities in furnishing outright relief to the needy. The States
Avere given grants of Federal funds to supplement relief funds a\rail-able from State and local sources, Avith the provision that one-lialf of
the funds was to be matched on the basis of $1 Federal for every $2
from State and local sources. By the end of 1935, when liquidation
of the agency was begun, the F E R A had funneled more than $3 billion
to the States. (2) The Civil Works Administration (November 1933)
Avas designed to employ 4 million jobless men on Avork projects which
could be promptly organized. Appropriations for this program came
entirely from the Federal Government, while State CWA authorities
passed on projects which were generally sponsored and supervised by

42

Of. C o st o f G o v e rn m e n t in th e U n ite d S ta te s . 1 9 3 3 —35, N a tio n a l I n d u s t r i a l C o n fe re n ce
B o a rd , In c ., N ew Y o rk , M ay 19 3 6 , p. 4 1 . T h is d ro p in t a x re c e ip ts ta k e s in to a c c o u n t
s u b s e q u e n t re f u n d s o f in c o m e a n d p ro f its t a x re c e ip ts .
45 R a tn e r , op. c it., p. 4 5 3 ff,




40

ECONOMIC GROWTH A N D STABILITY

local governments. Repair and improvement of roads, streets, school
buildings, and community facilities figured prominently in the work
undertaken, as well as park, stadium, and airport construction. I t
was closed out on March 31, 1934, after having spent about $1 billion
on work relief. (3) The Federal Emergency Administration of P ub­
lic Works, known popularly as the PW A, was established under the
National Industrial Recovery Act (June 1933) to forward publicworks activities as a means of offering employment to the unemployed
and aid to State and local governments for their public-works needs.
Many of these measures were never intended to be anything more
than temporary relief expedients. The speed with which they were
established, revised, abandoned, or replaced stands in the legislative
record book as a commentary on the vigor, if not the certitude, with
which the Roosevelt administration met the worst period of the de­
pression emergency. “I t is evident,” writes Professor Hansen, “that
the major effort was directed toward salvaging human and capital
resources.” 44
The character and scale of almost all these emergency salvage
activities were something new to Federal Government experience, and
both administrative and policy shifts were, in the early years, in­
evitable. Along the line, too, the fiscal commandment for an annually
balanced budget lost much of its sanctity, and new ideas on the role
and method of Government finance in the economy came to the fore.46
Beginning with the 1934 budget, the first New Deal budget, the
Federal Government’s role in the national economy assumed a signifi­
cance which had been visible previously only briefly during severe w ar
emergencies. From 1933 to 1934, Federal spending increased by over
$2 billion, most of the increase coming through grants to the States
and localities under a variety of emergency relief programs. These
grants jumped by more than 9 times in 1 year, from $201 million in
1933 to $1,848 million in 1934, and accounted for almost 30 percent
of total State and local expenditures. Approximately 60 percent
of all Federal appropriations were for “recovery and relief,” " and
Federal appropriations, exclusive of those for the Reconstruction
Finance Corporation, conservation, flood control, public works other
than through the Public Works Administration and work-relief pro­
grams, amounted to 43 percent of total Federal expenditures. The
Federal deficit for 1934, at $3.6 billion, was a billion dollars higher
than in 1933, and the public debt at the close of the year stood at a
record height of $27.1 billion—higher even than in 1919.
In 1935, Federal expenditures rose by about $1 billion, grants to
States and localities accounting for somewhat less than half of the
rise, and the “relief and recovery” programs, even with the exclusions
noted above, took an even greater share—almost 58 percent of total
expenditures. By 1935, however, the national income was well on its
44 H a n s e n , F is c a l P o lic y a n d B u s in e s s C ycles, op. c i t , p . 89. P r o f e s s o r H a n s e n c a t e ­
g o riz e d a s ch ie fly a “ s a lv a g e ” o p e r a tio n th e b u lk o f F e d e r a l p o lic ie s d u r in g th e th ir tie s .
45T h e e ffe c t o f J . M. K e y n e s ’ in flu en c e , e sp e c ia lly a f t e r h is v is it to W a s h in g to n in J u l y
19 3 4 , a n d th e A m e ric a n p r o p o n e n ts o f th e “ n e w e co n o m ics,” p a r t i c u l a r l y P r o f e s s o r H a n se n *
is to o w e ll k n o w n t o re q u ire e v en a f o o tn o te re fe re n c e .
46 H o ra c e T a y lo r , op. c it., p . 229.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

41

■way back up,47and Federal revenues increased, so th at the deficit was
some $0.8 billion smaller than in the preceding y ear; 1935 was also an
important year for reappraisal and consolidation of Federal relief
activities. F irst, on A pril 8, Congress passed the Work Relief Act,
which substituted the Works Progress Administration (W PA ) for
the Federal Emergency Relief Administration (F E R A ). W ith the
establishment of the W PA, the Federal Government took responsi­
bility for the unemployed who were employable, but left to the States
and localities responsibility for all other relief programs.
State and local government relief responsibilities were promptly
and substantially modified by the passage of the Social Security Act
on August 14 of the same year.18 This was the most significant piece
of welfare legislation in the Nation’s history, but at the time it was
adopted it was closely related to the new work-relief program.
While the Social Security Act of 1935 was a major New Deal
achievement, it was largely a synthesis of earlier proposals, antecedent
State laws, and similar programs long established in other countries.
The British compulsory unemployment insurance law dated from
1911; during the twenties unemployment compensation was adopted
in many other countries; and Wisconsin had enacted an unemploy ment-compensation law in 1932. Also, by 1925, 22 foreign countries,
among them France, Germany, Italy, Russia, and Argentina, had com­
pulsory old-age insurance and, following Arizona’s 1915 act, by 1933,
46 States had some form of old-age pension program. Other parts
of the social-security program enacted in 1935 and adjusted in 1939
had similar historical precedents.
In retrospect, it was only to be expected that the adoption of unem­
ployment and old-age insurance and the other welfare-aid programs
would come with the great depression. F or the first time in our na­
tional history, we were faced with persistent mass unemployment, and
the depression forcefully highlighted basic economic changes which
had been underway for many years and which mandated a new con­
ception of personal and family security requirements.49 I t was not by
accident that the original Social Security Act was intimately con­
nected with the Work Relief Act passed a few months earlier, and
neither was the great depression merely a historical accident.
Actually, the Social Security Act was the second major depression47 N a tio n a l-in c o m e e s tim a te s by th e D e p a r tm e n t o f C o m m erce f o r th e y e a r s 1 9 2 9 -4 1 a r e
a s f o ll o w s :
[B illio n s]
$ 4 9 .0 1 93 9
192 9
$87. 8 193 4
$ 7 2 .8
193 0
75. 7 1 9 3 5
57. 1 1 9 4 0
81. 6
193 1
59. 7 1 9 3 6
64. 9 1 9 4 1
104. 7
193 2
42. 6 1 9 3 7
73. 6
193 3
40. 2 1 9 3 8
67. 6
48 F o r a n e x c e lle n t b r ie f s u m m a ry o f th e S o c ia l S e c u rity A ct, cf. W illia m A n d e rso n , op.
c it., p p . 3 0 -3 9 . F o r a d e ta ile d a n a ly s is o f th e g r a n ts p ro g ra m s , p a r tic u la r ly t h e ir c y c lic a l
a s p e c ts , cf. J . A. M ax w ell, F e d e r a l G r a n ts a n d th e B u s in e s s C ycle, op. c it.
49 S p e a k in g o f th e s o c ia l- s e c u rity le g is la tio n w h ic h i n itia te d th e s y ste m o f g r a n t s to th e
S ta te s a n d f o r o ld -a g e a s s is ta n c e , d e p e n d e n t o r c rip p le d c h ild re n , th e b lin d , e tc ., a n d th e
o ld -a g e a n d s u rv iv o rs in s u ra n c e p ro g r a m s , th e r a ilr o a d r e tir e m e n t p ro g r a m , a n d th e
u n e m p lo y m e n t in s u r a n c e p ro g ra m s , P r o f e s s o r K e n d ric k s t a t e s : “ I n v ie w o f th e p ro g r e s s
t h a t h a d a lre a d y b een m a d e in th i s c o u n tr y to w a r d p u b lic a c c e p ta n c e o f th e p u rp o s e s se rv e d
hy s u c h le g is la tio n , a n d in v ie w o f th e a c t u a l a p p lic a tio n o f s im ila r le g is la tio n in v a rio u s
f o r e ig n c o u n trie s , i t a p p e a r s f a ir l y c e r ta in t h a t , irr e s p e c tiv e o f th e s ta t e o f e m p lo y m e n t
find tr a d e , s o c ia l le g is la tio n o f t h e c h a r a c te r d e sc rib e d w o uld, a t som e tim e , h a v e been
e n a c te d . T h e d e p re ss io n , h o w e v e r, c a u s e d th e p a ss a g e o f th e s e m e a s u re s to com e s o o n er
th a n o th e rw is e , a n d , a lm o s t c e r ta in ly , o p e ra te d to in c re a s e th e fin a n c ia l p ro v is io n f o r th e ir
im p le m e n ta tio n .” C f. K e n d ric k , A C e n tu ry a n d a H a lf o f F e d e r a l E x p e n d itu r e s , op. c it.,
pp. 3 5 -3 6 .




42

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

stimulated program which was to have lasting impact on the budget
of the Federal Government.
The first such program was embodied in the A gricultural A djust­
ment Act of 1933, which, when it was declared unconstitutional in
1936, was immediately followed by the Soil Conservation Act (1936)
and, in 1939, by the Agricultural Adjustment Act. All of these acts
were designed to provide (a) temporary subsidies through income
supplements, and (b) long-range output readjustment by subsidies
and production restrictions.50 The support of farm income through
income supplements was adopted as an emergency measure, but it be­
came a regular feature, and in many instances the main issue, in sub­
sequent agricultural legislation. Long-range readjustments were to
be obtained by subsidizing the shift from cotton growing to dairying
or grasslands farming, for example, and although some success was
achieved in the conservation aspects of the program, later develop­
ments, notably World W ar I I requirements, reversed much of the
movement.
The agricultural legislation of the New Deal firmly established
broad-scale Federal responsibility for the economic welfare of a siz­
able portion of the agricultural population, but the approach here, too,
was not at all revolutionary. The agricultural sector of the economy
had been in a sad state since 1921. During W orld W ar I, agricultural
output had been greatly increased, mainly to meet the demand for
foodstuffs from the warring nations whose own output had been
sharply cut. Farmers borrowed in order to bring more land under
cultivation and to use the new equipment which the continuing agri­
cultural revolution produced. Commercial farm ing became increas­
ingly more important, and, after the war was over, agricultural pro­
duction continued to rise as the tractor replaced the horse and electri­
cal and mechanical innovation accompanied general scientific progress
in soil chemistry, animal husbandry, seed selection, etc. While farmcapital requirements and production kept rising, the market for out­
put constricted. Foreign purchases of United States farm surpluses
fell off sharply as European production wTas restored, and as Europe’s
purchasing power in the United States was cut when United States
loans abroad were reduced, and our tariff barriers against foreign im­
ports were raised. A fter 1925, because of the disparity in price move­
ments between agricultural goods and manufactured goods, farm costs
increased relative to farm prices, and the condition of agriculture
worsened even more.
The “farm bloc” in Congress was actively engaged in the pursuit of
aid for agriculture from the early twenties on.51 Emergency agricul­
tural tariffs, marketing regulations, increased farm credit and aid to
farm cooperatives all figured in legislative proposals and were all
defeated. The McNary-Haugen bills vetoed by President Coolidge in
1927 and 1928 proposed the establishment of an “equalization fee”
which would compensate farmers for losses sustained in selling sur­
pluses abroad at low prices while they obtained higher prices from
segregated domestic sales. The domestic prices w7ere to be raised at
least high enough to restore the purchasing power parity between ag­
50 M itc h e ll, op. c it., ch . V I, p r e s e n ts a th o ro u g h a n d liv e ly d is c u s s io n o f t h i s p a r t o f N ew
D e a l p o lic y .
51 C f. H . G. H a lc r a w , A g r ic u ltu r a l P o lic y o f th e U n ite d S ta te s , P r e n tic e - H a ll, N ew Y ork,

1953.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

43

ricultural and industrial prices which had existed in 1909-14. The
National Grange supported another scheme which provided, in effect,
for a Federal subsidy on agricultural expoits to be paid out of tariff
receipts. Another plan, backed by the Farmers Union, provided for
a reduction of farm output through “domestic allotment.”
Despite the spate of suggestions and recommendations, no action
was taken, except for some small aid to cooperatives and an extension
of farm credit, until President Hoover established the Federal Farm
Board in 1929. This agency undertook to stabilize prices of some
farm products through a subsidized-storage system for surpluses,
but it soon proved inadequate in the face of mounting difficulties which
followed the crash of 1929. Experience with the Federal Farm Board
indicated that a surplus-storage program could not effectively con­
trol farm prices unless it was coupled with production controls. When
the New’ Deal Congress undertook to meet the farm problem, it adopted
the previously proposed principle of domestic allotment through
acreage and output adjustments in the first Agricultural Adjustment
Act, and, by Executive order, the President established the Com­
modity Credit Corporation (CCC) to loan money on farm commodi­
ties held in storage.
W ithout going into all the details of the first and subsequent New
Deal agricultural programs, it is clear that the basic outlines of its
policy had strong antecedent roots. The whole field of agricultural
aid had become a matter of Federal concern during the twenties, and,
while it was the intensified misery of the depression that forced vigor­
ous Federal action, it seems clear that long-range maladjustments in
the agricultural sector would ultimately have brought Federal parti­
cipation anyway. I t had long since been clear that no independent
State or local action would suffice, and the “farm problem” thus
achieved a lasting importance in Federal Government operations, just
as the industrial sector wTas provided for under the Social Security
Act.
In fact, the agricultural-aid and social-security programs (plus the
Railroad Retirement Act of 1939) together represent the bulk of
New Deal legislation which has had a lasting impact on the Federal
budget, and, though both programs were induced by the depression,
they had longer run justification in the great changes in the American
economy as well as previous histories here and abroad.
_In much the same way, we could trace through the history of
virtually every New Deal program. The TVA, for example,"was
made more expedient by the need for public-wTorks projects in 1933,
but agitation for such a Government program dated back at least to
Senator George W. Norris’ proposals from 1921 on, and similar de­
velopment for the St. Lawrence seaway, Boulder Dam, and the Colum­
bia River also had all been widely discussed well before the New Deal
came to power.
T h e p a ttern o f governm ent expenditures

The outstanding fiscal development of the depression period was,
of course, that Federal spending on civil functions—direct and through
grants-in-aid—increased eightfold between 1929 and 1940. Total Fed­
eral spending rose from $2.9 billion in 1929 to $4.8 billion in 1932 and
then doubled to $9.6 billion in 1940. Of this overall increase of $6.7
billion, civil spending accounted for more than $5.7 billion. The Fed­



44

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

eral Government in 1940 spent $1.9 billion on relief and work relief,
$1.4 billion on aid to agriculture, $1 billion on social-security programs,
interest on depression debt, and public-works administration.52 Other
sizable amounts went for conservation, flood control, and other pro­
grams which also had been initiated during the depression.
In contrast to the great rise in Federal spending, State and local
government spending remained below the 1932 level of $8.4 billion
until 1935-36, and then rose gradually to $11.2 billion in 1940. A
considerable p art of this rise was made possible, however, by the ex­
pansion of Federal aid to State and local governments, and State and
local government spending exclusive of Federal aid did not recover to
the 1932 level until 1937-38, and by 1940 stood at $10.3 billion.
By 1940, total State spending was higher than in 1932 by $2.4 billion.
But the greatest p art of this rise, some $1.4 billion, was accounted for
by expenditures under the unemployment-compensation programs of
the social-security system, increased spending for public welfare by
the States directly, and increased aid to localities for their relief and
welfare activities.
State aid to localities for education also ran higher by $300 million
in 1940, but it was mainly expenditure on relief and welfare that
brought State spending up. The States themselves had not under­
taken any other significant programs and, aside from their direct
and contributory relief activities, they had left local responsibilities
virtually unaltered.
Total local government spending was $1.3 billion higher, at $7.7
billion, in 1940 than in 1932, but net of Federal and State aid which
had been increased by $1.1 billion, it barely exceeded its 1932 level in
1940. F or most of the regular local-government functions—police,
fire protection, sanitation—expenditures had been cut during the
worst years of the depression and recovered only gradually after 1935.
Highway expenditure, which had amounted to $1.3 billion in 1927, had
fallen to $898 million in 1932 and remained below that level until
1946. The only important rise in local government general expendi­
tures, especially for the large cities, came in public welfare. There
was also increased spending on such things as housing and community
redevelopment, natural resources, electric power services, and transit
facilities, but this spending also was largely a function of emergency
aid programs developed by the Federal Government and drew special
revenues through service charges. The chief strain on local budgets
continued to come from the relief and welfare needs of a large number
of depression victims and the indigent who were not covered by the
several programs of the Social Security Act. The local governments
still carried the great bulk of the general assistance relief burden as
well as their traditional functional responsibilities.
In brief, by 1940, Federal spending had advanced very much more
than State and local spending and reflected the new quantitative im­
portance of Federal Government activity in public works and welfare
activities—which previously had been prim arily the preserve of the
States and localities—and in agricultural aid—which had been rela­
tively unattended. Other than for these changes which were, of
53 Public-works adm inistration took $348 m illion ; social-security grants to S tates took
$369 m illio n ; old-age retirem ent took $28 m illion ; railroad em ployees’ retirem ent and
unemployment paym ents took $136 m illion ; and interest on depression debt w as $247
m illion. Of. Kendrick, op. cit., p. 32.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

45

course, quite considerable, the spending pattern and functional respon­
sibilities of all three levels of government were not significantly
altered.
W ith respect to a quantitative measure of the changed relative im­
portance of Federal and State and local expenditures, however, there
is no clear line along which a completely unambiguous conception of
relative growth can be drawn. That part of the growth in Federal
Government spending which developed via the expansion of grants in
aid to the States and localities should not, for example, be considered
solely as a measure of Federal growth. Although in most cases Fed­
eral action was critical in the establishment of grants programs, and
Federal controls were exercised in their administration, the use of
grants also enhanced the powers and responsibility of the States and
the localities. F or many purposes the final spending units—the States
and localities in the case of Federal grants—gained as much effective
power as did the Federal Government. Public-assistance grants under
the social-security system, for example, are handled through the States.
The needy aged, dependent children, the blind, and since 1950 the per­
manent and totally disabled, deal directly with their State govern­
ments and not with Washington, D. C. Similarly, grants which make
possible improved public works, highways, housing, and community
redevelopment, etc., add to the governing capacity and to the effective
authority of State and local governments as well as to that of the
Federal Government.
In summary, increased Federal spending was the outstanding fea­
ture of depression period finance, and the consequent growth in rela­
tive importance of the Federal Government was most striking. But,
in absolute terms the State and local governments also emerged with
increased expenditure budgets and with a broader range of responsi­
bilities—particularly in the field of public welfare.
From the vantage point of historical perspective it might appear
that alternatives could or should have been developed allowing for
more independent State and local fiscal action in the latter thirties.
But, whatever alternatives might have been developed were inhibited
by a postcrisis lethargy among State and local governments. The im­
press of the depression was fresh upon them, indeed they were not
yet free of emergency needs, and their major effort was in striving to
regain their sense of fiscal security by a return, in general, to stricter
practices of fiscal orthodoxy. Their alleged profligacy during the fat
years of the 1920’s was not to be a charge which could be Drought
against them in the lean years of the 1930’s. A t the same time the
Federal Government was able and willing to expand its own efforts—
and it was infinitely easier to supplicate Washington for help than it
was to provide it from resources within most State and local jurisdic­
tions.
The great growth of the Federal Government during the decade of
the thirties frequently is referred to as the start of “the march of
power to Washington.” 53 The growth of the Federal Government
during the depression epic might be described at least as accurately
as “the flight of responsibility to Washington.” Any lasting signifi­
cant increase in Federal activity or power came about as a corollary to
its assumption of responsibility for functions which the States and
53 Cf., for example, White, The States and the Nation, op. eit.
07735— 57-------5




46

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

localities could not by themselves, or would not, undertake—and which
the public demanded from government.
W

orld

W

ar

II

D

evelo pm ents:

1940-46

Federal Government -finances

The absolute and relative growth of the Federal Government during
the depression decade appears very small, indeed, when compared
with what happened in the war years: total Federal spending rocketed
from $9.6 billion to a high of $95.2 billion in 1945; net budget receipts
jumped from $5.4 billion to $46.5 billion; Federal debt outstanding
went from almost $43 billion to over $279 billion in 1946. Ju st the
change in sheer money magnitudes should be enough to give a sense
of the impact of (then) modern w arfare on the national economy.
But dollar volumes alone actually understate substantially the war­
time participation of the Government in the daily life of the Nation.
Aside from spending, taxing, and borrowing on a plane th at would
have defied imagination even as late as 1940, the Federal Government
had to undertake to control virtually everything that was controllable.
Prices, wages, rents, profits, the distribution of consumer goods, and
the allocation of productive resources—all came under the purview
of the Federal Government because they were critical factors in the
prosecution of full-scale warfare.54
Federal spending
The war effort completely dominated the Federal budget from 1941
through 1946. The height of the war effort came in fiscal 1944 and
1945, but the budget for fiscal 1946 was still prim arily a war budget.
Through these years civil expenditures only advanced some $1.6 bil­
lion, and much of this rise was due to the effects of inflation and to
the extension of services which, although they are classified as civil,
were closely related to the war effort. In constant (1926) prices,
per capita expenditures on the civil functions actually fell from $63.40
in 1940 to a low of $41.03 in 1945—but recovered to $53.56 in 1946.
Similarly, as a percentage of the gross national product, spending
on civil functions dropped from 6.5 percent in 1940 to 3.9 percent
in 1946. The major reductions came, of course, in spending for relief
and work relief, public works, aid to agriculture.
Because so much of Federal welfare spending was in the form of
grants-in-aid established during the depression, the grants programs
underwent substantial alteration as first the defense, and then the
war boom brought the economy out of the persisting doldrums of
depression. Unemployment, still above 8 million in 1940, dropped to
670,000 in 1944, and Federal spending for emergency grants was
sharply cut. Total Federal grants had reached their peak at $2.9
billion in 1939, were cut to $2.4 billion in 1940, and petered down to
$900 million in 1946.55
The emergency grants—those instituted to provide relief and wel­
fare aid during the depression—brought the total down as they fell
54 However, w hile the major policy decisions and regulations were form ulated in W ash­
ington, S tate and local governm ents carried considerable responsibility for the adm inistra­
tion of many war programs. Civil defense, selective service, rationing, and price control
w ere among the programs undertaken cooperatively by Federal and S tate and local govern­
m ental agencies.
55 D ata from Maxwell, Grants in Aid and the B usiness Cycle, op. cit.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

47

from $2.3 billion in 1939 to $151 million by 1946. The regular grants,
on the other hand, ran substantially higher during the war years—
averaging about $743 million from 1941 to 1946 as compared with
$488 million in 1938 and $616 million in 1939.
Spending through grants was increased mainly for such things as
defense housing and transportation and the training of defense work­
ers. National-defense requirements governed Federal spending
through grants just as they did direct Federal spending, and the ex­
pansion of grants which resulted from the exigencies of war was
essentially of a temporary nature.
I t is unnecessary to detail the other wartime expenditures of the
Federal Government, the bulk of which obviously was for direct mili­
a r y needs. But the magnitudes are interesting. Spending for war
activities, as defined in the annual statement of the Secretary of the
Treasury, rose from $1.7 billion in 1940 to a high of more than $90
billion in 1945. In constant (1926) dollars, per capita spending for
military purposes, interest on the debt, and international affairs, rose
from $14.49 in 1940 to a high of $585.39 in 1944, and tapered down to
$285.93 in 1946. Again, as a proportion of the gross national product,
spending for these functions rose from 3 percent to almost 26 percent.
The tremendous rise in purely military expenditures deserves spe­
cial mention. In constant (1926) prices total m ilitary spending in­
creased from under $2 billion in 1940 to over $80 billion in 1944 and
1945, and the cost per serviceman rose from almost $5,000 in 1940 to an
annual average of $8,741 for the years 1941 through 1945.56 Actually
the sharp upward movement of m ilitary spending measured by cost
per serviceman, or by any other index, was p art of a trend th at started
at least a century and a half earlier. Toward the latter p art of the
19th century the upward movement became more pronounced and the
cost per serviceman (in 1926 prices) moved from the vicinity of $1,500
after the Civil W ar to over $2,500 by the early 1900’s. W orld W ar I
boosted the figure to over the $3,000 mark, and during the 1930’s the
annual average was close to $4,000. Professor Kendrick writes as
follows:
* * * the great increase * * * in the cost per serviceman
over the century and a half cannot be explained by rising
prices. Doubtless p art of the upward movement is accounted
for by a trend toward higher pay and better clothing, food,
and medical care. But by no means all the increase can be so
explained.
* * Rather, the chief reason lies in the mounting
and ultimately immense technological advance in the weapons
and equipment of the Armed Forces. * * * I t is clear that an
important, and probably the major, explanation of the rising
cost per serviceman over our history has been the continuing
increase in the quality, kinds, and quantity of weapons and
equipment, and of ammunition and supplies. The rate of this
increase, slow at first, has mounted from period to period
with the rising tempo of research and invention. And as
the improved and more expensive military goods have been
adopted, the old have been discarded. Thus not only has the
cost of the original equipment been increasing, but the useful
56 D ata from Kendrick, A Century and a H alf of Federal Expenditures, op. cit.




48

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

life of the units acquired has been becoming shorter. Mili­
tary expenditures have increased on both counts.57
This particular aspect of technological advance obviously holds
im portant implications for the future of Federal-State-local fiscal
relations.
State and local government jwmices 68
Spending .—The relative fiscal decline of the State and local gov­
ernments, as opposed to the increased importance of the Federal Gov­
ernment, which began during the depression period, was sharply ac­
centuated during the war years. Despite wartime price inflation,
civil-defense programs, and other war-related expenses, actual dollar
spending by State and local governments was lower for most of the
war period than it had been in 1940. The great drop came in expen­
ditures for capital outlay. Highway and school construction, for
example, were cut to the lowest possible amount, except where they
were directly related to needs arising from the relocation of labor
and other aspects of the defense effort. Total capital outlay fell,
therefore, from over $2.5 billion in 1940 to $379 million in 1944-— the
lowest level by far since W orld W ar I. Other than for the cutback
in capital outlay, however, total spending on almost every function in­
creased somewhat between 1940 and 1946, but not enough to make up
for the drop in capital expenditure. Although the war brought a
tremendous economic revival, even public-welfare spending by States
and localities was a little higher through most of the war period.
W elfare spending was increased to match Federal public-assistance
grants, nullifying a drop in the need for general relief expenditure.
By 1946, however, with capital expenditures again rising to $937
million, and with the enactment of long-deferred increases in govern­
ment pay scales to compensate, at least in part, for the price inflation,
State and local spending took a sharp jump to $14 billion—some $3
billion higher than in 1940. In constant (1926) prices, however, per
capita expenditures were still more than 20 percent below the 1940
level. State spending per capita in 1926 prices dropped from $50.16
in 1940 to $35.86 in 1944, and I'ecovered to $41.27 by 1946. L oca lgovernment spending was cut proportionately more—from $74.01 in
1940 to $49.89 in 1944, recovering on ly to $53.10 in 1946. In short,
State and local spending in real terms, particularly local spending,
was cut substantially during the war, and only partially recovered
in 1946. W ith respect to the gross national p rod u ct, State spending
dropped from 5.2 to 3.4 percent, and local spending from 7.6 to 4.4
percent.
Taxation.—While the cutback in capital outlays kept total dollar
spending down during the war, tax receipts increased steadily. Gen­
eral revenues ran well above general expenditures and, for the first
time in many years, State and local governments experienced budg­
etary surpluses instead of deficits. Between 1941 and 1946, the only
important new tax adoptions occurred when 3 States enacted gift taxes
and 5 States added cigarette taxes. There was, in fact, considerable
pressure for reduction in State taxation as receipts from established
taxes increased with the economic revival. A number of States did
67 Ibid., pp. 45 and 48.
68 For a more complete review of the nature of wartim e problems, cf. the symposium,
W artim e Problems of State and Local Finance, Tax Institute, Philadelphia, 1943.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

49

reduce taxes,59 and the increase in aggregate tax yields resulted almost
entirely from the rise in incomes and consumer spending. F o r the
local governments, the property tax brought in moderately higher
yields, but the greatest increase came from charges and miscellaneous1
revenues. In brief, State and local tax effort was not inordinately
strained during the war—mainly because tax collections grew with
prosperity, and war conditions precluded spending on capital improve­
ments which otherwise would have been undertaken. Also, of course,
States and localities, for the most part, were able to resist maintaining
their wage scales in parity with the inflationary rise of consumeroods prices. Civil servants as a group were among the hardest hit
y the wartime inflation.
Debt policy .—Because capital-investment programs wiere restricted
by war priorities, and revenues exceeded expenditures, from 1940 to
1946 State and local governments were able to effect substantial debt
reductions. Outstanding State debt was reduced by one-third, from
$3.6 billion to $2.4 billion, and local debt by about one-fifth, from $16.7
billion to $13.6 billion.60
Also, because the interest rate continued to decline, States and local­
ities were able to refund some of their higher rate obligations with new
issues carrying lower interest charges. The rate on triple A securities,
for example, according to Moody’s index, dropped from 2.84 percent
in 1940 to 2.53 percent in 1946, and the annual interest cost on com­
bined State and local debt outstanding was cut by about 29 percent—
in greater proportion than the actual reduction in the capital amount
of the debt.61

f

Postwar Federal finances

When the war ended, there was intense pressure for immediate relax­
ation of wartime restraints and controls. Although there were already
threatening signs of growing international tension, public pressure
to return to peacetime living was so great that the decision was made
to demobilize the Armed Forces and to pursue as rapid a transition to
a peacetime economy as could be accomplished without engendering
severe economic dislocations. Once again, and quite understandably,
the Nation wanted a “return to normalcy.” But, clearly, not to the
prewar normalcy of many millions unemployed and relief or makework programs. Even during the years of extreme war effort, nation­
al consumption of consumer goods and services in real terms had
increased by over 16 percent, and there was no disposition to allow
military victory to diminish the glory or dimension of national pros­
perity. Both major political parties joined in enacting the Employ­
ment Act of 1946, which set forth the following declaration of policy:
The Congress declares that it is the continuing policy and
responsibility of the Federal Government to use all practi­
cable means consistent with its needs and obligations and other
essential considerations of national policy, with the assistance
and cooperation of industry, agriculture, labor, and State and
50 As early as 1942, for example, New York reduced its personal-income tax by 25 per­
cent ; in 1943, Iowa follow ed w ith a 50-percent cut, Maryland w ith a one-third cut, South
Dakota and W est Virginia elim inated their personal-income taxes completely, while Illin ois
lowered its general sales tax, Indiana Its gross-receipts tax, etc. Cf. H ansen and Perloff,
op. cit., pp. 8-9.
60 These figures include enterprise debt.
61 Combined S tate and local debt outstanding dropped from $20.3 billion to $15.9 billion,
or by about 2 2 percent.




50

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

local governments, to coordinate and utilize all its plans,
functions, and resources for the purpose of creating and main­
taining, in a manner calculated to foster and promote free
competition enterprise and the general welfare, conditions
under which there will be afforded useful employment oppor­
tunities, including self-employment, for those able, willing,
and seeking to work, and to promote maximum employment,
production, and purchasing power.62
Only a brief moment of reflection is all th at is required to recognize
how much different is this bipartisan view of Federal responsibility
for national economic welfare from the view that prevailed prior to
1933. The specter of a possible postwar depression was perhaps a
more powerful influence than systematic economic logic in obtaining
almost unanimous support for the Employment Act, but, nevertheless,
the result gave clear, statutory voice to the universal postwar question:
I f we can have high-level prosperity in time of war, why not in time of
peace ?
Actually, the fear of depression in the immediate postwar situation
was quite misplaced. The problem was inflation. There was a huge
backlog of pent-up demand for consumer goods, particularly auto­
mobiles, household appliances, and other durables whose production
had been eliminated or severely curtailed during the w ar; similarly,
for housing to meet the requirements of a population grown by 9
million since 1940, and showing new high rates of family formation
and b irth s; for public works, especially roads, hospitals, schools, etc.;
and, in greater or lesser degree, for the whole range of private and
public goods and services which constitute our proud standard of
living.
To back up their material wants, the consuming public had large
accumulations of buying power in the form of wartime cash savings,
convertible Government securities, and high current incomes from
employment and investment. State and local governments had im­
proved tax yields, strengthened credit positions, and a receptive
m arket for their debt obligations. And, while money and credit were
plentiful, it took time for industry to retool and reorganize to meet
peacetime demands. Consequently, we experienced an inflationary
disturbance in postwar years that heightened the trend begun in 1940,
when we had started seriously to prepare for war. The buying power
of the dollar, which had dropped by 35 percent, as measured by whole­
sale prices between 1940 and 1946, dropped by another 25 percent
between 1946 and 1948. The buying power of the consumer dollar
had dropped by 28 percent between 1940 and 1946, and it, too, dropped
by another 25 percent in the 2-year span between 1946 and 1948.63 The
price rises which caused this depreciation of the dollar came despite
the temporary extension of many price and wage controls—some in
attenuated form—and the maintenance of fairly rigid rent controls.
But the new, almost refreshing, experience with inflation added another
dimension to Federal responsibility for the economic welfare; stability
in the relationship between prices, wages, and other costs, was recog­
62 The Em ployment Act of 1946, approved February 20, 1946, sec. 2, 15 TJ. S. C. 1021.
The act also provided for the establishm ent of the Council of Econom ic Advisers in the
E xecutive Office of the President, the subm ission of the P resident’s Econom ic Report, the
establishm ent of the Joint (Senate-H ouse) Committee on the Econom ic Report, and pro­
vided for attendant staff needs, etc.
83 D ata from S ta tistical Abstract of the United States, 1955, op. cit., p. 316.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

51

nized as another important objective of national, peacetime economic
policy. Thus, in a very few years, as our perspective fought free of
narrow concentration on deep depression, fiscal and monetary meas­
ures were turned increasingly on the threat of inflation. In sum, the
Federal Government now carries a more general responsibility for
maintaining a sound and healthy economy—to avoid excessive infla­
tion as well as depression—by the use of all the fiscal and monetary
means which such a complete objective required.64 B ut inflationary
pressures in the postwar years caused considerable difficulty for all
three levels of government. And, obviously, the degree of difficulty
varied inversely with the intensity of demand for expenditure and
increases in responsiveness of their respective tax structures to price
and income changes.
Spending

Once actual hostilities ceased, the first order of Federal fiscal busi­
ness was a sharp cutback in military spending. From a high of al­
most $85 billion in 1945, m ilitary spending was cut to $45 billion in
1946 and down to $12 billion in 1947 through 1950. B ut even with
this sharp drop in m ilitary spending, the Federal budget was to re­
main many times larger than ever before in time of peace. A rthur
Smithies w rites:
W ith the end of hostilities, the President’s budget returned
to the center of the stage. In fact, in a different political
context the attitudes toward the budget in the late forties
were not unlike those of the twenties. Demands for cuts in
expenditures and taxes were insistent, but this insistence was
to yield more frustration than it did in the twenties. The
President discovered that much of the budget was uncontrol­
lable. The interest bill was of course regarded as a contrac­
tual obligation. Expenditures under the G I bill were con­
sidered in much the same light and were likewise exempted
from the competition of the budgetary process. Aid to agri­
culture was largely determined by the price-support legisla­
tion. A large backlog of public-construction authorizations
made it impossible for the President to resist expansion in
th at area. The main areas left for budgetary debate were the
international programs and national defense.65
The decision to demobilize and the concurrent reduction of m ilitary
spending were effectuated, as we have already noted, almost simulta­
neously with the end of actual fighting. The international programs
were increased almost fourfold, however, and rose from just under
$1.5 billion in 1946 to an average of over $5.8 billion for the years 1947
through 1950. Yeterans’ benefits became a major budgetary factor and
took slightly less than $7 billion in each year from 1947 through 1949,
and were up to $9.3 billion in 1950. Interest charges went from $2.8
billion in 1945 to about $3.8 billion until 1950, when they reached $4.3
billion. Taken together, expenditures on the military, international
affairs, interest, and veterans accounted for over three-fourths of total
64 For a measure of the announced devotion to th is responsibility see, for exam ple, any
of the letters of transm ittal accom panying the Economic Report of the P resident since
1947— and enduring past the change of adm inistration in 1952.
65 Arthur Sm ithies, the Budgetary Process in the United States, McGraw-Hill Book CoNew York, 1955, p. 121.




52

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Federal spending from 1946 through 1950. B ut in each of those years
the relative share taken by these categories of expenditure declined as
follows:
Percent

Percent

73
194 6
87 194 9
71
194 7
80 195 0
194 8
78
Civil expenditures thus increased in relative importance in each of
the postwar years through 1950. But, actual spending, as opposed
to budgetary authorization, for civil functions was below the 1946
level o f $8.2 billion until 1949, when it jumped to $11 billion, and then
to $12.5 billion in 1950. The more important increases in civil spend­
ing between 1946 and 1950 came in support of agricultural prices and
farm income—which fluctuated widely depending on farm prices and
in the years cited went from $452 million to $1.8 billion; natural re­
sources—from $251 million to over $1 billion; social security, welfare
and health—from $738 million to $1.6 billion, and transportation and
communication, particularly increased highway aid and a larger postal
deficit, from $817 million to $1.8 billion. Much of this increased
spending came in the form of increased grants to the States and to
local governments—grants-in-aid rose from $900 million in 1946 to
$2.3 billion in 1950, and shared revenues from $12.4 million to over
$20 m illion66—with the localities getting direct help for such things
as hospitals, airports, housing and redevelopment, and the States the
great bulk of the aid for education, highways, social welfare, health
and security.
Although civil spending in dollar terms showed a 50 percent jump,
from $8.2 billion in 1946 to $12.5 billion in 1950, in constant (1926)
dollars the change was only from $7.6 billion to $8.1 billion; and, in
constant per capita dollars there was virtually no difference—from
$53.56 to $53.60. In fact, civil spending in constant per capita dollars
was less in 1947 and 1948 than it had been for most of the 1930’s. As
a percentage of the gross national product, however, civil spending
rose from 3.9 percent to 4.4 percent, less than its proportion in the
thirties, but roughly six times greater than in the twenties, while in
the same terms other Federal spending dropped from 26 percent to
under 11 percent, still a substantial share of the national product.
The tendency of civil expenditures to increase, and m ilitary expend­
itures to decrease, both absolutely and relative to total spending, after
major wars has been established as p art of the historic pattern of
expenditure growth.67 But, such budgetary adjustments were never
fully accomplished until after several years of transition to peace.
Although there was a very sharp drop in purely military spending
immediately after W orld W ar II , there really was no adequate period
of time within which a new peacetime budgetary philosophy could be
developed. The initial drive was “to reduce the budget total to some
figure that was tolerable.” 68 The administration was in accord with
80 D ata are from annual budgets.
67 Cf, Kendrick, A Century and a H alt of Federal Expenditures, op. cit.
08 Sm ithies, op. cit., p. 122. Sm ithies con tin u ed : “During the entire discussion no one
produced any definition of tolerable, and It rested on no economic an alysis w orthy of the
name. B ut the com bination of in tu ition s and prejudices of those In authority produced
the conviction th a t $40 billion of expenditures w as definitely too high.” And later he
sta tes : “The m ethods employed (to cut the budget) would have delighted P resid en ts Hard­
ing and Coolidge, although they would have been stupefied by the size of the budget after
a ll cu ts had been made.” Ibid., p. 122.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

53

the Congress and the business community on the imperative nature of
cutting Federal spending.
But the shape of postwar events hardly allowed enough time for a
full reduction of m ilitary spending to a stable peacetime level. In ­
ternational tension between the Soviet Union and the Western Powers
began to mount even before final peace had been established, and
with the crisis in the spring of 1948 the United States decided to
rearm immediately. Although budget authorizations for 1950 were
raised, actual spending was not substantially increased until later,
when we were already involved in the Korean war, because of the lags
between authorization, programing expenditure, and actual produc­
tion of material.
In brief, although we were not in a shooting war between 1946 and
1950, the United States never got back to a peacetime budget. From
cold war we went to Korea and hot war, and any potential long-run
budgetary readjustments to a stable peacetime situation were thus
foreclosed. Aside from the rise in military spending which came
mainly after 1950, there were other factors which operated against
expenditure reduction.
First, there were the fixed costs and contractual obligations we
mentioned above; second, inflation raised the cost of Government pur­
chases of goods and services as well as consumer goods prices; third,
even aside from inflation-caused price increases, the rate of techno­
logical advance in the weapons and other equipment of war was so
great in the short span between 1946 and 1950, that m ilitary costs
moved higher than ever. For example, the outfitting of an infantry
division cost $40 million in World W ar I I and $200 million in 1950.139
Je t planes, rockets, atomic bombs—all added to the cost of waging
war and maintaining peace. In sum, despite a deep and widespread
conviction that the level of Federal spending should be reduced more
than it was actually at any time after World W ar II , it seems clear
that a conspiracy of events with the fiscal heritage of the past war com­
bined to frustrate efforts at further large budget reductions.
Although the Korean war, which lasted roughly 3 years, was on a
much smaller scale than World W ar II , its effects on the economy and
on Government finance were quite profound. Unemployment, which
had mounted to a postwar high of 3.4 million in 1949, declined to 3.1
million in 1950,1.9 million in 1951, and to 1.6 million in 1953. Indus­
trial production (1947-49 = 100) rose from 97 in 1949 to 134 in 1953.70
The national income rose from $216.2 billion in 1949 to $303.6 billion
by 1953, and after their brief respite in 1949-50, inflationary pres­
sures resumed and the price level climbed again.71
Underlying the renewed upward surge of the economy was the sharp
increase in spending for national defense. Defense spending was
budgeted at $13 billion for 1950, but was raised to $22.3 billion in 1951,
$43.9 billion in 1952, and $50.3 billion in 1953. Also, although spend­
ing on international programs and for veterans’ services and benefits
69 Kendrick, op. cit., p. 60.
70 D ata from the Economic Almanac, 1956, the Conference Board, T. Y., Crowell & Co.,
New York, 1956, pp. 316-317.
71 The Bureau of Labor S tatistics index (1947-49 = 100) showed wholesale commodity
prices up from 99.2 in 1949 to 103.1 in 1950, 114.8 in 1951, down to 111.6 in 1952, and
relatively stable between 110 and 112 through 1955. Consumer prices advanced from a
1949—50 level of roughly 102 to a 1953-55 level of about 114.5— w ith a mild upward
tendency since mid-1955.




54

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

dropped off rapidly, Federal spending for almost every civil function
of government increased steadily during the Korean war years. By
1953 total Federal expenditures stood at $76.6 billion.
W ith the end of the Korean war in early 1953, spending for national
security was again cut back. But, unlike the situation immediately
after W orld W ar I I , when m ilitary spending was cut from a war-year
level of $85 billion in 1945 to only $12 billion in 1947, major national
security spending was only reduced from $50.3 billion in fiscal 1953
to $46.5 billion in 1954 and has since kept in the vicinity of $40 billion.
And, of course, there is little prospect that national-security spending
can be cut in the proximate future. Civil spending, since 1954, has
also reached new highs. From about 20 percent of the budget in 1954,
civil spending grew to 27 percent in 1956, and is estimated to reach
about 30 percent in fiscal 1958.
In the decade of the 1930’s civil spending took 61 percent of the total
budget, but national defense expenditure, of course, was very small.
A t our new high budget levels, the high proportion of defense and
defense-connected spending relative to civil spending represents a situ­
ation unlike any this Nation has faced before. Although civil spend­
ing accounted for only 20 percent of the Federal budget for the decade
of the 1920’s, the proportionate difference then was due not nearly as
much to the large volume of defense spending as it was to the extreme­
ly low level of nondefense spending. W ith present high levels of mili­
tary spending superimposed on civil spending, which has itself
grown greatly since the thirties, we are actually in a new budgetary
epoch.
Postwar /S'tate and local finances
To many observers the financial position of State and local govern­
ments at the close of the war appeared better than it had been for
many decades. Tax collections reflected full and overtime employ­
ment at high wages, rising real property values, high consumption
levels for taxed commodities and services. The States had a combined
cash surplus of about $3 billion, which exceeded their gross indebted­
ness by more than $500 million, and the cost of borrowing for States
and localities was down to a point where, in January 1946, the net in­
terest cost to the borrower was less than 1 percent.72
I t was clear, of course, that State and local governments would have
to make large expenditures on capital plant and equipment to catch up
on public improvements put off during the war years. In anticipation
of their postwar needs many States and localities had reduced their
outstanding debt or set aside a wartime revenue surplus; and in 1945,
when the end of the war seemed reasonably close at hand, there was a
concerted rush of planning and preparation for large-scale capital in­
vestment programs. Even the foreseeable heavy expenditure needs
of the States and localities did little to dampen the optimism of most
observers. State and local government capital expenditures would
help cushion the widely expected postwar economic decline, the Fed­
eral Government was expected to assist generously in financing these
expenditure programs, and the market for State and local debt obliga­
72 Cf. M onthly N ew sletter of th e N ational City Bank of N ew York, February 1946, p. 22.
Also, the gross debt of S tates and localities had been reduced by over 18 percent since 1940,
and troublesom e short-term debt had been cut from $315 m illion to about $25 m illion.
The States had contributed only about 30 percent of the to ta l reduction in dollar term s,
but percentagew ise had made about tw ice the progress of local governm ents.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABIMTT

55

tions was more than receptive—especially since these issues carried
exemption from Federal income taxation and income tax rates were so
high. Furthermore, the financial position of the States, particularly,
was felt to he so strong that in their financial estimates they antici­
pated meeting upward of 80 percent of their capital needs from accu­
mulated surpluses, another 11 percent was to come from Federal aid,
and only 5 percent from bond financing.73 “Pay as you go” seemed to
have a ring as true as it was pleasant, and the financial community was
concerned more than a little lest there be a dearth of State and local
bonds offered in the market.
But, almost as soon as the cheers on V J-D ay joined the historical
echoes, it became apparent that the contented look of State and local
affairs was largely unwarranted. Prices, and consequently govern­
ment costs, rose substantially in 1946 and 1947. Wage scales, including
now—with some vengeance—government wage scales, were forced up­
ward, labor remained scarce instead of unemployed, and construction
materials were so vigorously bid for by private enterprise in gray or
black markets, as well as through normal channels, that they were
hard to obtain and far more costly than had been anticipated. In
many cases costs rose so rapidly during the inevitable interval between
project planning and project authorization that the whole process
had to be repeated and scaled down on the basis of new cost esti­
mates, with the result that heavy expenditures to meet the backlog
of capital needs were delayed. Also, State bonuses to veterans caused
a sharp increase in the need for cash, and, for this and other purposes,
as early as 1947 State and municipal bond issues for new money totaled
over $2.3 billion—approximately double the $1.2 billion in 1946 and
by far the highest volume ever recorded in any one year.74 The interest
rate on State and municipal bonds also rose sharply during the years
from 1946 through 1948, and, according to the Dow-Jones service
and other such agencies, the rise amounted to about 85 percent of
the average rate on tax-exempt issues. The interest cost was still
low in a historical sense, but substantially higher than it had been.
In brief, the States and localities were not able to accomplish the
capital improvements and additions which they needed as rapidly and
as easily as they had hoped. The record high tax receipts which had
nourished so much optimism during the war period soon appeared
inadequate again in the face of postwar inflation and the magnitude
of capital requirements. By 1947, State and local debt outstanding
was growing again and accumulated wartime surpluses were being
reduced year by year to meet general spending requirements.75 And,
as if to punish us for our earlier optimism, new expenditure demands
appeared at a faster rate than the wartime backlog could be dis­
posed of. By 1954, most States found their general fund balances
dropping sharply, or depleted, as the upward climb of revenues slowed
while increased needs for schools, highways, and other institutions
were exerting even greater pressure on State and local budgets.
Thus, State and local expenditures are being forced upward (from
$37 billion in 1954 to $43 billion in 1956, for example) by a complex
73 Ibid., p. 23.
74 Ibid., issue of March 1948, p. 34.
75 The Korean war provided a revenue w indfall to the States as tax receipts, which had
been leveling off between 1948 and 1950, rose rapidly as a result of a renewed inflationary
upsurge. The w in d fall allowed some further revenue surpluses, but its benefit w as illusorv
in the long run.
*




56

ECONOMIC GBOWTH AND STABIMTY

of causes which are basically related to the following: The need to
make up for the deficiencies in capital programs during the war
period; the growth and shifts of population; and, of course, inflation.
To these, we must add the influence of our increased real wealth.
The public demand in the postwar period, as never before, had been
for better as well as more public services. W ith personal income up
from $78.7 billion in 1940 to $178 billion in 1946 and to $327 billion
in 1956, our tastes have become more expensive than ever. And, our
tastes for publicly provided goods and services have reacted in essen­
tially the same way as our tastes in private consumption. So far,
although at rising interest costs, our State and local governments have
been able to debt-finance much of their capital spending. B ut cur­
rent operating costs, which account for two-thirds of the increased
total State and local spending, have added huge pressures to State
and local finance. There does not yet appear to be any substantial
movement toward effective rationalization of their financial systems.
The problem today

The skeletal history presented in the preceding pages aimed at
defining (1) the im portant underlying causes of the overall growth
of government in the past half century; (2) the principal factors
which determined the distribution of that growth between the Fed­
eral Government and the State and local governments; (3) the fiscal
problems which developed in the course of events. Our major pur­
pose was to document these summary conclusions:
The growth of government was a necessary concomitant to the
overall growth o f the country. That is, the rise in total government

spending from an amount equal to roughly 7 percent of the gross
national product in 1902 to almost 28 percent in 1956, and the con­
sequent rise in taxes from something like 8 percent of the national
income to about 25 percent, are best explained in terms of the basic
factors which shaped our h istory: Population growth, technological
advance, urbanization, increased productivity and wealth, increased
interdependence in the national and world economies, the course of
international affairs—a depression of unprecedented severity sand­
wiched between two world wars and followed by persisting cold war,
a little hot war, and the ever-present threat of atomic and hydrogen
annihilation.
The spectacular growth 'of the Federal Government since 1929,
which brought such a striking shift in the relative magnitudes of
Federal and State and local government operations, represents a nec­
essary response to changed national circumstances. First, the depres­

sion dramatized the high degree of interdependence of all groups in
the economy, the practical impossibility of developing local solutions,
and, consequently, the need for a new national approach to problems
of economic security. Second, W orld W ar I I and the absence of real
peace after victory brought the full cost of advanced m ilitary tech­
nology into a position of persistent dominance in the Nation’s eco­
nomic budget. Furthermore, the technological requirements of mod­
ern war, or preparing for defense against it, ram ify quickly to all
aspects of life in our society, and, hence, to almost all reaches of social
policy. Only the National Government can handle this responsibility,




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

57

and it has had to expand its eoncern over a broad range of activities
as they have become closely correlated with national defense and
national security.
Despite the overwhelming impression o f the increased importance
o f the Federal Government, domestic governmental functions are still
handled primarily at the State and local level. In fact, more than

four-fifths of the growth in Federal spending since 1929 is attributable
to national defense and national security programs, and less than
one-fifth to expanded civil functions.
Thus, while the Federal Government in 1956 spent an amount equal
to 4.8 percent of the gross national product on civil functions, the
States and localities spent an amount equal to 10.4 percent. Although
the Federal Government’s influence on internal functions may be
greater than the proportion of its expenditure indicates—through
controls over grants-in-aid and subsidy programs, for example—the
States and localities are themselves doing more in both scope and scale
than they have ever done before. In constant (1926) dollars since
1927, for example, their spending has increased by 2.6 times and their
tax collections have almost doubled.
As a result of population growth , inflation, and higher standards of
public demand, the burden of civil functions resting on State and local
governments for education, highways, welfare, health, hospitals, hous­
ing , protection , etc., has grown faster thorn, State and local revenue.
Although disparity between spending needs and revenue sources has
characterized almost the entire half century, the situation of the States
and localities has been made more critical since World W ar II. The
fact is that Federal financial requirements for the support of national
defense and security programs have become so great they made in­
creased State and local taxation more difficult.76 States and localities,
in addition to rising operating costs, still have a backlog of capital
investment needs dating from depression and war years wThich is
being augmented constantly at a rapid rate by neAV plant and equip­
ment requirements.
On the basis of these conclusions, it seems clear that the future
course of intergovernmental relations wTill depend in greatest measure
on the degree of success the States and localities achieve in meeting
their pressing fiscal problems. The issue, in purely pragmatic terms,
is whether and how the States and localities can develop the fiscal
resources they will need to finance a satisfactory level of service in the
functions for which they are responsible. In other words, wTe know
for certain that Government spending for most domestic purposes will
have to go up by large amounts in the coming years, but we are not
nearly so certain that the States and localities can meet the challenge.
To the extent that they fail, the Federal Government will have to fill
the breach.
70
War-connected purposes required about 2 percent of the national income at the turn
o f the century and 4 percent in 1940, but in recent years have amounted to between 18
and 20 percent. Roger A. Freeman writes : “This prior claim on the output of goods and
services and the concom itant tax burden inevitably depress our ability to support more
liberally other public services. * * *” Cf., Crisis in School Finance, Part I, N ational Tax
Journal, vol. IX, No. 1, March 1956, p. 4.




58

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T a b l e I .— Government expenditures, selected years, 1902-56
[In m illions of dollars]
Federal

Y ear

1902..
1913-.
1922..
1927­
1929..
im .
1938­

1940..

1944..
1946­
1948—
1950—
1952..
1954..
1956­
1958 e.

State and
local,3
total

T o t a l1

C ivil

485.2
725.0
3,296. 0
2,774.0
2,900.0
4,800.0
7, 200.0
9,600.0
93,956.0
61,738.0
36, 524.0
43,160.0
67,968.0
71,868.0
72.611.0
82.970.0

149.1
273.0
677.0
699.0
821.0
2,455.0
4,684. 0
6, 550.0
7, 237.0
8,170.0
7,926.0
12,459.0
12,602. 0
13,953. 0
19,792. 0
25,331.0

State 4

Local 3

2

1,095
2,257
5,652
7,810
(8)
8,403
9,988
11,240
10,499
14,067
21, 260
27,905
30,863
36,607
43,152

188
388
1,397
2,047
(8)
2,829
4,598
5,209
5,161
7,066
11,181
15,082
15,834
18,686
21,686

959
1,950
4,567
6,359
(J)
6,375
6,906
7,685
7,180
9,093
13,363
17,041
20,229
23,814
23,273

1 T otals for fiscal years 1902 through 1952, from M. Slade Kendrick, op. cit., table B - l ,
pp. 76—77. Kendrick's figures are adjusted from Treasury data to come as close as he could
make them to the measure of actual cash paym ents to the public. See h is appendix B for
detailed notes on sources and method, pp. 63-73. For later fiscal years Special A nalysis A,
Receipts From and Paym ents to the Public, Budget of the United States, 1955 and 1958.
8 R esidual after deducting sum of expenditures for m ilitary purposes, veterans, interest,
and after 1915, foreign affairs.
3 D irect expenditure, as defined by the Bureau of the Census, includes all general gov­
ernm ent expenditure plus u tility, liquor store, and insurance tru st expenditures. These
figures are not com pletely consistent with the actual cash paym ents measure used in the
Federal Government column, but they represent the best comparable long series for S tate
and local governments. Cf., H istorical S tatistics on State and Local Government F i­
nances, 1902-53, tables 1, 2, and 3, and Summary of Governmental Finances in 1954, 1956,
U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, W ashington.
4 Total State expenditure including paym ents to local governm ents. N ote th a t totals of
colum ns 5 and 6 exceed column 4. This is due to the inclusion of S tate paym ents to local
units in both expenditures of State and local governm ents.
* N o t available on census basis.
6 E stim ate from the Budget of the United States, 1958.
T a b le

II. — Government expenditures as percent of gross national product—
selected years 1902-56

Y ear

1902......................
.....................
1913..
1922......................
1927..
.....................
1929-.
1932........................
.....................
1938..
1940-.....................
1946..
__ ________ __
1950..
.....................
1952..
___ ___________
1954..
1956..

Gross
national
product
in current
prices
(billions of
dollars)

20.7
40.1
68.4
89.6
104.4
58.5
85.2
100.6
209.2
285.1
345. 5
361.2
414.7

Percent of gross national product

Federal

2.34
1.81
4.82
3.10
2.78
8.20
8.45
9. 54
29.51
15.14
19.69
19.94
17.5

C ivil

0.72
.68
.99
.78
.79
4.20
5.50
6. 51
3.91
4.37
3.65
3.87
4.8

State and
local

State

5.29
5.63
8.26
8.72
0)

14.36
11.73
11.17
6.72
9. 79
8.94
10.15
10.2

Local

0.91
.97
2.04
2.28
0)

4.83
5.40
5.18
3.38
5.29
4.59
5.18
5.2

4.63
4.86
6.68
7.10
0)

10.89
8.11
7.64
4.35
5.98
5.86
6.61
5.6

i N o t available.
Sources: Gross national product for 1929-56, Survey of C u rrent Business, D ep artm en t of Commerce.
Gross national product for 1922-27, N ational P ro d u ct Since 1869, K uznets, N . B. E . R ., N . Y ., 1946, p.
51, an d gross national product for 1902 and 1913 were estim ated from p. 119. (T he 1902 figure w as found
b y interpolation of th e 2 overlapping 10-year estim ates, 1899-1908 average equal to $21,580,000,000, and
1894-1903 average to $15,700,000,000.)




59

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

T a b l e 111— Percentage distribution of all government taxes— selected years

1902-56
Year

Federal

State and
local

1902........................................... ....................... ....................
38.0
29.2
1913-...................................... ...... .............................. ........
1922___________________ _______________________
46.9
1927......................................................... ...........................
36.3
1929.................................................................. ..................
35.5
1932___________ _____ ______ _____ ______________
23.4
1934______________ ___________- ___________ ____
33.5
1936 ................... ............................................................
36.7
38.2
1940 ....................................................................................
79.6
1946.............. ............. ...... ............................... .............. .
69.8
1950........ ....................... .................................................
1952_________ _____ — ........ ................... ................. .
76.0
73.9
1954................................... ...... ...........................................
1956.......................................................................................
71.2

62.0
70.8
53.1
63.7
64.5
76.6
66.4
63.3
61.8
20.4
30.2
24.0
26.1
28.8

State

Local
50.8
57.6
40.5
46.9
45.0
53.1
44.2
38.6
35.6
10.4
15.2
11.8
13.5
14.2

11.3
13.2
12.5
16.8
19.6
23.5
22.2
24.7
26. 2
10.0
15.1
12.3
13.6
14.6

Sources: A nnual R eports of the Secretary of th e T reasury on the State of the Finances. H istorical Sta.
tistlcs of th e U nited States 1789-1945, U. S. B ureau of the Census, W ashington, 1945, Series P 90-131, pp ,
298-304. Sum m ary of G overnm ental Finances in the U nited States: 1956, U. S. B ureau of the Census
W ashington, 1957.

T a b l e TV.— International comparisons of public finance and

national

product, fiscal year 1951

C ou n try

U nited States_______ _______ - ......................
C anada .............................................................
D en m ark .............................................................
G reat B rita in .....................................................
Belgium ..........................- .................. . ..........
.....................
N o rw ay .............................
F r a n c e ...............................................................
N e th erlan d s........................................................
G erm any..............................................................
.................
Ita ly .
. _ _
.................................................
A u stria ..
P ortugal...............................................................
Greece......... .........................................................
T u rk ey .................................................................

Percent of gross national product
Gross
national
product per Taxes of
N ational
Defense
N ational
govern­
capita
all govern­
expendi­
govern­
m ents
m ent ex­
tu re
m ent gross
penditure 1
debt
$2,023
1,432
800
792
779
760
736
690
529
509
324
308
285
243
161

22.3
23.1
19.7
19.0
34.4
25.0
26.1
29.8
29.0
31.0
20.7
30.9
9.7
16.7
17.9

15.1
2 17.0
12.4
14.9
27.3
24.0
16.0
25.5
24.7
21.7
19.3
34.0
7.6
33.7
20.1

7.1
4.7
1.6
6.7
2.9
2.8
7.8
4.2
4.9
4.2
.9
2.1
9.8
6.5

83
(8)

42
21
188
75
65
47
130
23
34
31
16
10
18

1 “ N ational” refers to the central governmental authority; in the U nited States it refers to the Federal
G overnm ent.
2 Prelim inary figure,
s N ot available.
Source: Division of Statistics and Reports, M utual Security A dm inistration (table IV , D ew hurst, opj
cit., table 236, p. 579).