View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

GOVERNM ENT IN T E R E S T PA Y M EN TS: T H E IR R E L A ­
T IO N S H IP TO ECONOMIC GROW TH AND S T A B IL IT Y
James R. Schlesinger, assistant professor of economics, University of
Virginia
Any study which attempts to examine the ways in which the pattern
of Government expenditures may contribute to the achievement of
the twin goals of economic growth and economic stability must come
to grips with the problem of interest payments. The magnitude and
variability of interest expenditures have made them a budgetary prob­
lem of the first order and have increasingly attracted to them the
attention of both public officials and students. In analyzing the
interest issue, one must examine the role of the rate of interest, the
relationship between the interest expenditures and the Nation’s fiscal
capacity, and, finally, alternative means of monetary organization
which may hold out the possibility of alleviating the burden of the
debt. P rior to the investigation of the analytical issues, however, it
is desirable to view our present interest problem in the light of
history.
Since the onset of the depression, despite a sharp decline in the
average rate of interest paid on the public debt, the sums spent by
the Federal Government m the servicing of its debt have crept steadily
upward. The increased interest expenditures reflect the vast expan­
sion of the public debt which resulted from the emergency expendi­
tures of the thirties and the immense cost of the Second W orld W ar.
In the past 12 years, the rise in interest charges has also reflected the
gradual increase of the interest rate from the lows reached during
the period of wartime controls. In table I will be found the basic
data relevant to the rise of the public debt and of interest expendi­
tures and, in addition, statistics on budget expenditures and the
gross national product. Interest charges during the current fiscal
year are anticipated to be $7.4 billion, more than 10 percent of total
budget expenditures. I t will be recognized, however, th a t relative to
the total budget, interest charges are now lower than they were in the
twenties and even in the period prior to the Korean war. This simply
reflects the lower level of total expenditures during these earlier
periods. Relative to total output, interest payments are now about
1.8 percent of gross national product—a level 3 times greater than
that prevailing in 1929. They have, however, declined from the high
point, 2.3 percent of gross national product, which was reached in
.

1946\

.

.

I t is useful to view current interest charges in historical perspective,
since this helps to dissipate some of the more frenetic attitudes on the
subject th at have been generated by the continual increase of the abso­
lute amount of interest payments. From the standpoint of history,
the present costs of servicing the debt are not unduly heavy relative to
our capacity.
404



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

405

Nevertheless, the increased charges should not be viewed with com­
placency. In national income accounting, Government interest pay­
ments are viewed as transfer payments. They add to personal in­
come, but they do not—in contradistinction to other interest—add to
national income, since they are not paid for services currently rendered
in thfe productive process. Government interest payments serve no
productive function. F or the most part, the public debt is a kind of
spurious capital. Since it has arisen largely as a result of war ex­
penditures, it has, unlike private debt, little counterpart in real pro­
ductive assets. National income statisticians make no attempt to im­
pute a return to socially owned capital. The servicing of the debt
constitutes a drain on the budget, absorbing funds which might other­
wise be used for different purposes. I t represents a burden for the
taxpayer. W hat purposes, then, do Government interest payments
serve in the maintenance of strong economy ?
T h e R ole

of t h e

R ate

of

I nterest

A t the present time, the chief variable influencing the magnitude of
Government interest expenditure is the rate of interest. I f the money
market is not to be disrupted, the rate of return on governments must
be consistent with th at available on other instruments. Variability
of Government interest payments reflects the changes in the rate of
interest. The rate of interest on Government obligations cannot be
“pegged” without simultaneously stabilizing the rate of interest gen­
erally, and, on the other hand, if the general rate of interest is per­
mitted to vary, the rate paid on governments must also vary. In order
to understand why the rate of interest must vary and, therefore, in
order properly to assess the function of interest payments, we must
indulge in a theoretical digression on the question: the role of the rate
of interest.
According to the traditional view, the chief function of the rate of
interest is to serve as a deterrent to the desire to borrow. In this way
it governs the demand for investable funds, thereby limiting aggregate
spending from borrowed funds. In recent years it has been recognized
that the effective mechanism may be something more than the deter­
rent effect upon potential borrowers resulting merely from an increase
in the cost of borrowing. Borrowers may still wish to borrow, despite
the increased cost, but are unable to find lenders. In any event rising
rates of interest do imply the cutting off of fringe borrowers.




406
T

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

I . —Amount of interest-tearing public debt, interest on the public debt,
budget expenditures, gross national product, and their relationship, 1929-57

able

Interestbearing
debt

1929........................
1930........................
1931........................
1932........................
1933........................
1934........................
1935........................
1936........................
1937........................
1938........................
1939........................
1940........................
1941........................
1942........................
1943........................
1944........................
1945........................
1946........................
1947........................
1948........................
1949........................
1950........................
1951........................
1952........................
1953........................
1954........................
1955........................
1956........................

Interest on
the public
debt

Budget ex­
penditures

M illions

M illions

M illions

$16,639
15,922
16,520
19,161
22,158
26,480
27,645
32,756
35,803
36,576
39,886
42,376
48,387
71,968
135,380
199,543
256,357
268, 111
255,113
250,063
250,762
255,209
252,852
256,863
263,946
268,910
271,741
269,883

$678
659
612
599
689
757
821
749
866
926
941
1,041
1,111
1,260
1,808
2,609
3,617
4,722
4,958
5,211
5,339
5,750
5,613
5,859
6,504
6,382
6,370
6,787

$3,299
3,440
3,577
4,659
4,623
6,694
6,521
8,493
7,756
6,792
8,858
9,062
13,262
34,046
79,407
95,059
98,416
60,448
39,032
33,069
39,507
39,617
44,058
65,408
74,274
67,772
64,570
66,540

Interest
charge as
percent of
budget ex­
penditures

20.6
19.7
17.1
12.8
14.9
11.3
12.6
8.3
11.2
13.7
10.6
11.5
8.4
3.7
2.3
2.7
3.7
7.8
12.7
15.7
13.5
14.5
12.7
9.0
8.8
9.4
9.9
10.2

Gross
national
product

M illions

$104,436
91,105
76,271
58,466
55.964
64,975
72,502
82,743
90,780
85,277
91,095
100,618
125,822
159,133
192,513
211,393
213,558
209,246
232,228
257,325
257,301
285,067
328,232
345,445
363,218
361,167
391,692
414,686

Budget ex­
penditures
as percent
of gross
national
product

3.2
3.8
4.7
7.9
8.3
10.3
9.0
10.2
8.5
8.0
9.7
9.0
10.5
21.4
41.4
45.1
46.2
28.9
16.8
12.5
14.9
13.9
13.4
18.9
20.4
18.7
16.3
16.4

Source: Annual Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the State of the Finances for the fiscal year
ending June 30,1956. Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business, July 1957.

The supply of investable funds need not be affected. As a weapon
of control, the interest rate does not affect the allocation of resources
between investment and consumption activities save insofar as it af­
fects the society’s willingness. The interest rate is simply a surface
[phenomenon—underlying the monetary relationships are the real
forces which, in the final analysis, determine the allocation of re­
sources between present and future needs. O f main importance in this
respect, during periods of full employment, is the willingness of the
citizenry in their individual and corporate capacities to free resources
for investment activity by voluntarily refraining from consumption
expenditures. In this inclination, they may be abetted by the will­
ingness of the Nation as a whole to save, as reflected by a surplus in the
Government budget.
Taken in conjunction with “th rift”—the source of funds—the de­
mand for funds (which is largely a reflection of the expected produc­
tivity of capital) tends to determine the rate of interest. I f we assume
full employment, there is considerable tru th in the idea, developed by
K nut Wicksell, of a natural rate of interest determined by the real
forces of demand and supply. I f we are willing to tolerate inflation,
the market rate of interest may be held down, and more investment
may be carried on through the process of forced savings. I t may be
assumed, however, that normally, we would wish to avoid inflation.
Though serving temporarily to supplement the resources devoted to
investment, inflation is undesirable on long-run grounds since it serves
to dry up the chief source of investment resources—i. e., voluntary



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

407

savings. Inflation causes an inequitable redistribution of income and
wealth; it may also, therefore, be considered abhorrent on moral
grounds.
In the contemporary economic context, the chief contribution that
interest rates may make to economic stability is in controlling the in­
flationary process. During periods in which there is some danger
that resources may fall idle, interest rate should be lowered in order
to encourage additional investment activity. B ut our present-day
problem is not one of idle resources. The interest rate must be used
as the vehicle for curtailing investment demand within the limits of
the available supply of resources. I t may be that present inflationary
symptoms are due to the upthrust of wages and other costs, but this
hardly implies th at we should wish to superimpose a demand inflation
upon a cost inflation. Use of the rate of interest does imply a ration­
ing of credit through the price mechanism among the various claim­
ants to resources. I t may well be that those claimants excluded from
access to investable funds are just those individuals and firms that
could use capital most productively and would add most to the longrun growth of the economy. To this possibility we must return later.
I t is desirable to keep in mind that the interest rate is a two-edged
weapon, having side effects which tend to spur, as well as control,
inflation. To the extent that prices are administered in accordance
with a cost-plus formula rather than being set by competitive forces, a
rise in the rate of interest by adding to costs may be reflected directly
in a marking up of prices. This is particularly true in a highly oligopolized economy operating under a full-employment guaranty. In
addition, it has been pointed out, government interest payments are
a p art of personal income, but are not a part of national income—
they do not constitute payments for services rendered in the turning
out of national production. An increase in government interest pay­
ments may, therefore, swell demand without swelling output; by thus
serving as a feedback to demand they may add to inflationary pressure.
From this standpoint, a rise in the interest rate may be viewed as a
built-in destabilizer, adding gradually to demand as inflationary
pressures rise. Some protection against this destabilizing effect may
be obtained by the funding of the Federal debt into long-term issues.
Nevertheless, it may be seen that a rising rate of interest has offsetting
facets which tend to spur inflation to some extent on both the demand
and cost sides.
On balance, it is generally believed, the offsetting facets are of minor
importance—the function of the interest rate in the control of invest­
ment demand is the crucial one. Interest costs are a minute percentage
of the final cost of finished goods. In certain sectors of the economy, a
small, once-for-all increase in prices may occur in order to bring about
equilibrium in the markets concerned. I t may be regarded as the price
paid to bring to an end inflation as a continuing process of rising
prices. I t is desirable to keep in mind the distinction between higher
prices and rising prices. On the demand side, some portion (perhaps
30-40 percent) of additional interest payments will be recaptured by
the Government in taxes; some will be saved. This is, of course, true of
any increase in spending that gives rise to an increase in income. I t
does suggest, however, that, even if interest payments were to rise by
a billion dollars, the net addition to effective demand would be in the



408

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

order of perhaps $500 million—an infinitesimal sum relative to the
total demand for final goods and services, which is well over $400
billion. The curtailment of investment demand is, therefore, of criti­
cal importance. Its relative importance should not be lost sight of
because it is only one of a complex of influences emanating from a
change in the rate of interest, from which no one part can be disasso­
ciated.
Though occasionally we may like to fool ourselves on the issue,
there is, in reality, no acceptable alternative1 to flexible interest-rate
policies. To approach the problem from another direction may help
to cast it in the proper perspective. In the absence of direct controls,
which are probably unacceptable to the American people, in a period
of rising demand for investable funds, the maintenance of a fixed in­
terest rate would simply imply the abandonment of control over the
supply of money and the creation by the banking system of all the
additional purchasing power that all potential borrowers m ight de­
sire. W ithout direct controls, it is impossible to control both the price
and the quantity of any commodity. The implication of a fixed inter­
est rate in the face of rising investment demand is a permanently en­
larged money supply with consequential inflationary repercussions.
T hat there is really no issue seems to be confirmed by the recent report
of the Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy to the Jo in t Economic Com­
mittee.2
I

n ter est

P

aym ents and

the

N

a t i o n ’s

F

is c a l

C

a p a c it y

Granted that flexible interest-rate policies are essential in the
attempt to stabilize a free-enterprise economy, and that interest pay­
ments must, therefore, rise on occasion, one cannot disregard the
relationship of the interest burden to the total budget and to national
income. On the other hand, before reaching the conclusion th at it is
always most desirable to cut interest payments, one must keep in mind
that there are valuable educational, charitable, and commercial in­
stitutions which are, in part, dependent upon interest income for sup­
port. Yet, the general presumption must remain th at reduction of the
interest burden is to be desired since it will alleviate budgetary
pressures.
Economists have gotten over their infatuation with the idea th at
a domestically held public debt is no burden because “we owe it to
ourselves.” Because a burden is “merely financial,” it does not mean
that it cannot be burdensome. The element which we term the
Nation’s fiscal capacity” is an essential ingredient of a discussion of
any major component of the budget. This concept refers to the fact
1 In theory, fiscal policy could serve as a com plete substitute for m onetary policy. In
principle, the Interest rate could be held a t a predetermined level by the adoption of
appropriate tax and expenditure policies. To the extent th at a restrictive fiscal policy is
adopted during periods of rising demand, the need for interest-rate variation w ill be
lessened. As an instrum ent of control, however, fiscal policy is crude in operation and
cumbersome in adm inistration. P olitically, it is not suitable for quick adjustm ents. As
a practical m atter, it cannot cope w ith the delicate regulation of demand th at is required.
To imply the contrary is to expect too much of fiscal policy, a “p erfectionist” attitu d e
rem iniscent of Beveridgism. A more refined tool is needed. In practice, therefore, it is
necessary to use monetary policy.
2 F iscal Policy Im plications of the Economic Outlook and Budget Developm ents, Report
of the Joint Economic Committee to the Congress of the United States, June 26, 1957.
See, especially, p. 5, on which it is stated “* * * public policies to cope w ith increases in
the price level m ust take the form of general fiscal and m onetary restrain ts on the expansion
of total spending.”




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

409

that there exist economic limits and even more stringent political
limits on the Nation’s capacity to tax its citizens. F or brief periods,
under certain circumstances, this limit may run as high as 40 to
50 percent of gross national product. In the United States, and for
extended periods of time, it is likely to be significantly smaller. The
existence of a limit on the capacity to tax imposes a limit on (noninflationary) government spending. The higher interest payments
are, therefore, the less will be the funds that are available for other
purposes. I t is conceivable that, when no consideration is given to the
growth of the public debt, an intolerable budgetary situation may de­
velop in which interest payments, in addition to other necessary ex­
penditures, add up to more than the amount supportable by the state’s
fiscal capacity, with the implication that the debt must perennially
grow. Something of this sort did develop in France during the 17th
and 18th centuries, and was in no small measure a cause of the
revolution. We must remember, however, that the fiscal capacity of a
modern state is vastly greater than that of an 18th-century state.
Another related danger which is more germane to the United States
is the menace of building in inflation via the public debt. In its
ultimate form, the Nation faces the dilemma whether to service the
debt by borrowing or to hold down the rate of interest and, therefore,
expenditures through its control of the central bank. Rising prices
bring about a rise in the natural rate of interest, which tends to in­
crease the burden of servicing the debt. This contingency may be
countered by holding down the market rate of interest and thereby
stimulating excessive spending, further spurring on the inflation and
so on. Happily, we seem to be nowhere near this state of affairs at
the present time, though we may have been caught in its toils for a
brief period after the Second W orld W ar. The rapid fall of the
burden of .the debt (relative to gross national product) in the last
decade has steadily reduced the urgency of this problem.
T h e C o n t r ib u tio n

to

S t a b ilit y

a n d to

G row th

In attempting to summarize the relationship of government interest
payments to stability and growth, it must be observed at the start that
their main direct relevance is the vital role they play in stabilization.
In order to contribute to stabilization, interest payments must be
accommodated to the natural tendencies of the rate of interest. The
obstinate desire to hold down the interest rate on the public debt may
simply bring inflationary consequences.
Interest payments are the price of proper debt management. Debt
management ought to be designed to relate the liquidity of the debt to
the liquidity needs of the economy. Short-term debt or long-term
debt with pegged prices is highly liquid; an excess of such instruments
adds to the inflationary bias of the economy. To reduce liquidity, a
large proportion of the debt must be put into the hands of “firm
holders”—preferably on a funded basis. So long as our present
monetary arrangements last, adequate interest payments are essential
to the achievement of a firm holding of the public debt. I f Treasury
issues are obliged to compete with private issues for the available
funds, the interest rate on government securities must be competitive
and must, therefore, reflect market forces. Once again it appears that



410

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

there is no alternative to a flexible interest rate, and in this respect,
rising interest payments in good times are a sine qua non of stabiliza­
tion policy within our present monetary framework.
In regard to growth, interest payments can contribute little save
indirectly. To the extent th at destabilization militates against growth,
the contribution that interest payments make to stabilization may be
essential to growth in the long run. In the short run, however, the
rate of growth is largely dependent upon the rate of capital forma­
tion—and thus merely reflects the resources made available through
nonconsumption of national output. I t is sometimes asserted that
the capital-rationing process associated with rising interest rates
discriminate unduly against the type of investment which in the
long run is most productive both industrially and socially—to wit,
construction, railroads, public utilities, and borrowing by local school
boards. There is certainly some tru th in this assertion since these are
the segments of the capital market most sensitive to changes in the
interest rate. Unless we are willing to accept direct controls for the
allocation of capital with all th at this implies, there is, however, no
alternative. From the economic standpoint, the proper remedy is to
increase the rate of saving, by supplementing private savings via a
surplus in the Federal budget. The rationing process is implicit
in the interest-rate mechanism.
T h e Q u e st io n

of

A l tern ativ es

Since there is little doubt that present interest payments do consti­
tute a drain on the resources available for other governmental activi­
ties and a burden on the taxpayer, can anything be done to lower the
cost of servicing the debt ? Since the interest rate, in itself, ought not
to be controlled, are there possibilities for the reformation of our
monetary framework which might alleviate the burden o i the debt?
Over the long run, it is worthy of note, the growth of Government
tru st funds promises to promote an attenuation of the problem. The
social-security fund is now approximately $24 billion and, it is hoped,
it will continue to grow for the rest of the century. In all, trust funds
and other accounts of the Government hold some $53 billion worth of
Federal securities. The Federal Reserve System, which remits 90 per­
cent of its profits to the Treasury, holds an additional $24 .billion.
As the holdings grow, increasingly the effect of interest payments is
to swell!the size ox the funds, thus perm itting a level of social-security
taxes somewhat lower than they might otherwise be (and also, lower
insurance deductions for Government employees and others). Pay­
ments to the Federal Reserve System are in large measure simply
paper expenditures. As the proportion of the public debt in the
hands of the trust funds and the Federal Reserve System increases,
it implies (a) a lessened net drain on resources, and (£>) firmer hold­
ing of the public debt, reduced shiftability, and, therefore, lessened
danger of a liquidity time bomb.”
"Set, on the other hand, interest rates are rising internationally.
This may reflect rising demands for capital, the inflation itself, and,
perhaps, some fall in the tendency to save. The Congress, in fram­
ing new banking legislation, may wish to keep this problem of alter­
natives in mind. In a modem economy the money supply in no
inconsiderable measure is created through the monetization of public



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

411

credit. When the commercial banks monetize public credit, they
receive the interest payments; when the Federal Reserve monetizes
the public credit, most of the interest payments revert to the Treas­
ury. I f the burden of servicing the public debt is regarded as too
onerous, the Congress might desire to force a larger portion of the
debt into the Federal Reserve System. This could be accomplished
by raising reserve requirements and, thereby, reducing the expansion
power of the banking system. The Federal Reserve would then find
it necessary to supply additional reserves and in the process would
acquire additional debt. F o r example, the required reserves of the
member banks are at present about $18 billion; doubling of the present
reserve requirements would imply that the Federal Reserve System
would expand its debt holdings by an approximately equal amount.
Such action would imply a retreat from the fractional reserve sys­
tem. Before embarking on such a course the advantages of the frac­
tional reserve system ought to be weighed. I t is more flexible and
better adapted to the needs of the economy than, for example, is a
100-percent reserve system relying solely on the monetization of pub­
lic credit. I t has the advantages of the status quo; it is understood; it
is institutionalized. Any attempt to change it would be vigorously
resisted. Yet, it is true th at one way of dealing with the problem of
a large interest-bearing public debt is to reduce the burden by mov­
ing away from the fractional reserve system. W hether the benefits
are equal to the costs is a question of political judgment.
In mentioning this possibility of institutional change, it m ight be
in order to reiterate th at short of outright inflation there is no real
alternative to permitting variation of the interest rate under our
resent institutional arrangements. Interest-rate variations, it may
b demonstrated, have some inflationary impact in themselves, yet
these side effects are negligible when compared to the loss of control
over the money supply. Interest-rate variation means changing
interest payments, and the latter are indispensable to the maintenance
of economic stability. Restraining increases in interest payments by
funding the debt, however, may serve to protect the process of economic
growth.

E