View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

GOVERNMENT BUDGETS AND T H E IR R ELA TIO N
TO NATIONAL ACCOUNTS
Richard Ruggles, professor of economics, Yale University, and
Nancy D. Ruggles, Bureau of Economic Affairs, United Nations
T

he

C h a n g in g R

ole of t h e

G

overnm ent in

the

E

conom y

In the last 25 years, outlays by Federal, State, and local govern­
ments have risen over 10 times, from about $10 billion to over $100
billion. The rise in gross national product has not been as precipi­
tous; on a comparable basis it has risen sevenfold, from about $60
billion to about $420 billion. There are, of course, many reasons for
this changed relationship. A brief examination of some of them will
give some insight into just how the role of government has changed,
and the consequences of this change in terms of the need for budgetary
information.
In 1929, total government outlays amounted to about $10 billion,
at a time when gross national product was $105 billion. The expendi­
tures of the Federal Government accounted for only $2.5 billion of
this, and thus constituted only about 25 percent of total government
expenditures. Over the next decade there was relatively little change
in State and local expenditures, despite the depression, but the Federal
Government more than tripled its expenditures. Much of this in­
crease in Federal expenditure was due to measures instituted as seda­
tives or cures for the depression. Thus the W PA, AAA, and even
social security were introduced to provide relief and to help the econ­
omy back on its feet. By the late 1930’s, however, there had been no
appreciable dip in Federal expenditures; the new responsibilities that
the Government had taken on prim arily to combat the depression were
continued even after substantial recovery had taken place.
W orld W ar I I brought with it, of course, extremely large expendi­
tures for national defense. Federal expenditures rose to over $95
billion. A t the same time, in spite of rising costs, State and local
expenditures were held down even below the levels of the late 1930’s;
they did not even exceed the 1929 level by much more than 10 percent.
By 1944, expenditures of the Federal Government constituted over 90
percent of all government expenditures. A fter World W ar II, there
was a sharp rise in State and local expenditures as these governments
attempted to make up for the expenditures which they had postponed
during the war. Simultaneously, the Federal Government sharply
curtailed its expenditures for national defense, and its total expendi­
tures were cut by over 50 percent. Nevertheless, in 1947, when Fed­
eral Government expenditures reached their lowest point, they were
still double those of State and local governments. This is in contrast
with the year 1929, when Federal expenditures were one-third of
State and local, and with the immediate prewar period, when they
were about equal to State and local expenditures. Again, thus, the



483

484

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

increased responsibilities which the Federal Government had as­
sumed during the war were continued into the postwar period. Since
1947, problems of national defense have again swelled Federal ex­
penditures, and they have once more increased relative to State and
local expenditures. There seems to be no indication th a t the Federal
Government will shed these responsibilities, or play a less im portant
role in the economy, in the future.
A discussion of the Government’s role in terms of the expenditure
of money, furthermore, does not convey the entire extent of the
growth in the Government’s influence in the economy. In the past
25 years, the Government has assumed more and more responsibility
for the economic health of the Nation. The problems of maintaining
full employment and avoiding continued inflation are now accepted
by the Federal Government as prim ary responsibilities. The tenor of
recent congressional committee hearings indicates th at the Govern­
ment is concerned about the degree of supervisory control it must
maintain over big business and big labor. This, coupled with com­
mitments regarding social security, education, highways, urban rede­
velopment, etc., suggest that in a decade’s time the role of the Federal
Government may be even greater.
Many of us have considerable qualms about this trend. We see
before us a specter of big government. Yet the individual decisions
th a t lead to this trend are the result of the considered judgment of
intelligent men in both the executive and legislative branches of the
Government. The logic of the Federal Government’s responsibilities
in certain of these areas is compelling. Few would question the need
of the Federal Government to provide adequate defense and to main­
tain a healthy economy and avoid inflation. The majority of the
voters are for such things as social security, new highways, and better
health protection.
I t is unfortunately true that in some quarters the reaction to this
dilemma has been to deny the facts, and so avoid the necessity of fac­
ing reality. This is an ostrichlike approach based on the hope that
if the problem is ignored it may go away. B ut a little reflection
should make it obvious that unless there is a sound basis for believing
th a t the Government’s role will become less important in the future,
it is necessary to do everything possible to make sure th at the impor­
ta n t decisions the Federal Government must make are made with the
aid of all the relevant information. The denial of tools for policy­
making will not reduce the amount of policymaking; but it will mean
that the policies adopted may be harmful. Economic policies must
be based upon a realistic understanding of the different facets of the
economy and the Government’s relation to them.
N

a t io n a l

E

c o n o m ic

A

c c o u n t in g a n d

E

c o n o m ic

P

o l ic y

This changing role of government in the economy has had a pro­
found effect both upon economic analysis and upon the framework of
data about our economy. And conversely, the development of a com­
prehensive national economic accounting framework has had consid­
erable impact upon the procedures for determining Federal spending
programs. The evolution has been such th at today the Government
is looked upon as a sector of the economy interacting with the private
producing and consuming sectors and having as its basic accounts



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

485

the budgetary data arising from tax receipts and the expenditures
of the various agencies of the Government. In this process, it is prob­
ably true to say that theoretical economics has not led the way, but
rather circumstances and events themselves have led to the develop­
ment of the required analytical tools. This is not to say th at the tools
have always been available when they were needed—hindsight shows
us that our present degree of sophistication in the use of tools would
have been very helpful had it been available in previous periods. But,
even though the economist has not been able to show the way, in the
sense of providing a well-developed analytical framework ready-made,
it is, I think, fair to say that the economist has been an important p art­
ner in this development, and has made significant contributions to it.
A brief examination of the evolution of national income accounting
over the past 25 years will show the development of its relationship to
the Government accounts and its use as a tool in analyzing Govern­
ment expenditure.
National economic accounting had its roots in the national income
work carried out by academic economists and research foundations
both in the United States and in Europe early in this century. These
early contributions were mainly concerned with establishing the abso­
lute level of the Nation’s income and the changes in this level from
year to year. The national income was defined as the sum of the in­
comes of the people. Although measurement of national income is
prim arily a phenomenon of the last 30 years, the concepts were de­
rived from the classical economics of Bentham, Mill, and Pigou.
The Federal Government did not become interested in national in­
come until the great depression. In 1932 the Senate passed a resolu­
tion which resulted in the publication, in 1934, of a report on national
income, and from th at time onward there was an increasing interest
in this subject. The depression posed many problems which necessi­
tated the formulation of specific economic policies. The Government
became interested in the changing level of income from year to year,
and in the relation of its own expenditures and tax receipts to the na­
tional economy. B ut the early annual estimates were very sketchy in­
deed, and concentrated entirely on national income, omitting national
product.
The natural evolution of national income accounting in the late
1930’s was greatly stimulated by the mobilization needs of World
W ar II. The defense effort was of a magnitude th at required a much
more complete understanding of the operation of the economy and
the repercussions that various government taxing, spending, and bor­
rowing policies might be expected to have. All the armament produc­
tion plans had to be considered together, to make sure that the re­
sources of the economy were sufficient to carry them all out. The total
quantity of resources obviously had a limit, and total production had
to be designed to fit within this limit. To schedule more production
would not only be unrealistic, it would cause serious bottlenecks in
some areas and useless oversupply in others. To schedule less produc­
tion than the available resources would permit, on the other hand,
would be to operate at a level lower than full capacity. Accordingly,
data on such things as the distribution of manpower among indus­
tries and national income originating in the various industries became
of extreme importance. For any realistic appraisal of the problem,



486

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

furthermore, current consumption had to be taken into account. Not
all production could be devoted to war purposes; the civilian popula­
tion had to be supported. An examination of the minimum level of
goods and services needed for consumption was therefore necessary,
and national income accounting was again called upon to show the
interrelationships among the end uses of production.
The task of deciding how the production plans were to be imple­
mented, as well as the determination of the potential level of pro­
duction, also required major economic policy decisions. The war
expenditure had to be financed, and the method of financing to be
used was one of the more important questions th at had to be faced.
I t was obvious that taxation should be increased. But how much
could it be increased and how much additional tax revenue could be
expected from the fact th at the economy was working at a higher level
of activity? And for the p art of war expenditures th a t could not
be financed out of taxation, how and from whom should the requisite
funds be borrowed? W hat different repercussions on the economy
would result from borrowing from banks as opposed to individuals,
and what effect would such borrowing have upon the incomes of
individuals and upon prices ? In similar manner, how far could the
price incentive be used to move resources such as labor from unessen­
tial to essential industries? Income payments obviously would be
affected by any such use of the price incentive, and it was necessary
to know the extent of the inflationary influence to be expected and
whether means were available to offset it successfully. Finally, to
what extent and by what means should civilian consumption be re­
stricted to necessities? Relying on the price mechanism to provide
the restriction again might result in a disastrous inflation, so that
it was necessary to decide in what areas rationing and price control
might be necessary.
I t is obvious that all these problems are highly interrelated, and
that they can be solved satisfactorily only if they are considered
within one framework of data. Under wartime pressures national
income accounting was developed to provide such a framework.
W ith this framework it became possible to relate the total available
resources to the planned production for war and for civilian con­
sumption, and to examine the income payments and prices th at
would necessarily result from the adoption of any specific system of
taxes, borrowing, incentive payments, price control, and rationing.
By the end of the war national income accounting had thus emerged
as an essential tool in the formulation of economic policy. Since
the war, the national income and product accounts have been further
developed as a tool for determining Federal expenditure policy, and
by now the data in the accounts have become fam iliar to the reading
public in newspapers and news magazines.
The account for the Government sector is an essential component
of the national income framework as it has developed. In addi­
tion to the Government, three other sectors of the economy are dis­
tinguished : households in their role as consumers, businesses in their
role as producers, and foreign countries insofar as they trade with
the United States. In addition, an account is drawn up to show
saving and investment. In this national income accounting system,
Federal, State, and local governments are consolidated into a single



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

487

sector, but detailed classifications within the account provide sig­
nificant breakdowns of different kinds of transactions at the Federal,
State, and local levels.
Since the war, other forms of economic accounting have been de­
veloping to meet specific needs. Thus for example a study of post­
war patterns of employment was undertaken with the aid of inputoutput data. A few years ago the flow-of-funds work of the Federal
Reserve Board was initiated to provide data on the sources and uses
of funds by various sectors of the economy, as an aid in examining
credit and financial policies. Even more recently pioneering work on
national wealth and national balance sheets has been undertaken by
private research organizations.
During the past year, the Bureau of the Budget set up a com­
mittee to review, appraise, and make recomendations with respect to
the national economic accounts of the United States. On October
29-30, 1957, hearings were held by the Subcommittee on Economic
Statistics on the National Accounts Review Committee’s report and
recommendations.
In its review of national economic accounting, the National Ac­
counts Review Committee emphasized the very central role which
the Government accounts play in all schemes of national economic
accounting. There is a great need for reform of the Government budg­
et to permit its integration with the national accounts. One of the
major recommendations which the Committee made was that the
different forms of national economic accounts should be integrated
into a single national economic accounting system th at would include
the fiow-of-funds, input-output, balance of payments, balance sheet,
and national wealth data, as well as the current income and product
accounts. This would simplify the accounts th at are needed for the
Government sector; one presentation of the Government accounts
would meet both the requirements of economic accounting and the
needs of budgetary presentation. A t the present time, many different
Government accounts are compiled for various purposes. Besides
the regular Government budget, Government accounts are compiled
for national income accounting, flow-of-funds accounting, and inputoutput tables. All of these differ in some respects, and can be made
comparable only through rather elaborate reconciliations.
The National Accounts Review Committee sought to remedy this
situation by developing a single system of economic accounts contain­
ing an integrated set of Government accounts which would serve the
needs of national income accounting, input-output tables, flow-offunds accounting, and national balance sheets. The integration makes
elaborate reconciliation between the various forms of the accounts un­
necessary, and permits the user to move easily from one aspect of the
Government account to another. The National Accounts Review Com­
mittee did not take the additional step of integrating the Government
accounts as given in the national income accounts with those given in
budget hearings and those shown in the Daily Treasury Statement.
I t is obvious, however, that a closer integration between the nationa]
economic accounts and the Government budget would be a great help
to both the legislative and the executive branch in evaluating past
performance and making reasoned judgments about future appropria­
tion?. One of the barriers that has stood in the way of such an in­



488

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

tegration is the different systems of classification used in the different
accounts. The Committee has gone a long way in overcoming this
difficulty by recommending the inclusion of a functional classification
in the economic accounts, i. e., a classification showing the purpose of
the expenditure, such as education, highways, etc. I t is also true
th a t an economic classification of expenditures—in terms of wage pay­
ments, purchases of goods, transfer payments, subsidies, etc.—would
be useful in an appropriations budget, in helping to make reasoned
evaluations and in analyzing the impact to the expected.
N

a t io n a l

E

c o n o m ic

A

ccounts and

B

udgetary

R

eform

The present form of the Government budget is itself an evolution,
shaped to meet certain needs. The primary requirement which it is
organized to fulfill is th at of accountability. While it is obvious that
accountability must be a function of the accounts, it is also obvious
that developing accounts solely for this purpose is being penny wise
and pound foolish. Actual fraud and dishonesty represent only a
fraction of what could be wasted through unwise action. Additional
expenditure in developing Government accounts th a t would be more
useful both for evaluating past expenditures and for budgeting future
expenditures would be many times repaid through more intelligent
and economical decisions. One frequently hears from the legislative
branch the complaint that they cannot deal adequately with budget
requests. This is in large p art a fault of the accounting procedures
employed—a defect in linking the individual parts of the program
with the overall. There is at the same time a need to deal with a
large amount of detail and a need to place the Government expenditure
program in the broader perspective of the economy as a whole. Some
improvement in this area can be expected through developing better
national economic accounting systems which tie in with existing Gov­
ernment accounting procedures. However, the basic problem does
not lie in a superficial adaptation to inadequate accounting procedures,
but in a reform of the basic accounting itself, so that more meaningful
results can be achieved. I t will take a great deal of work to develop
accounting systems and controls that will serve the needs of the indi­
vidual agency and at the same time feed into the more comprehensive
economic accounts required for the examination of national policy, but
such budgetary reform is very badly needed.
The nature of the needed reform can best be shown by a considera­
tion of its major objectives. I t must accomplish four things, in
addition to providing for accountability with at least as much efficiency
as at present: (1) it must distinguish among different kinds of Govern­
ment economic activity; (2) it must provide a classification system
that will show both the purpose of a transaction and its economic
nature; (3) it must develop the accounts for individual accounting
units in such a manner that they can be combined and consolidated at
various levels to provide meaningful summary accounts that will fit
into the national economic accounting system; and (4) it must pro­
vide a more informative treatment of transactions which are of a
capital rather than a current nature.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

489

Definition o f accounting units in Government economic activity

The Government engages in many kinds of economic activity. I t
may be directly engaged in the sale of goods and services to the public
at prices intended to cover costs of operation. I t may run ancillary
operations similar to those found in business, but exclusively for its
own internal use. I t may take on the nature of a financial enter­
prise, buying and selling securities on the open market. Finally, it
may of course be engaging in a purely governmental activity, hiring
employees and performing legislative, executive, or judicial functions.
Some of the present forms of Government accounts do implicitly rec­
ognize some of these differences. For example, receipts from sales
of goods are treated differently for certain Government units than
for others. B ut present definitions of Government economic activi­
ties are not very clear-cut, and need careful reconsideration.
Government enterprises, for instance, are separated from general
Government in all of the accounts, but questions can be raised both
about the manner in which the sales and transactions of these groups
are handled and about the activities that are treated as Government
enterprises. I f these Government-run units are to be considered enter­
prises, they should operate as enterprises, in that their accounts should
include payments for services they now render free of charge to other
Government agencies. In the case of the Post Office, for example,
some progress has been made by requiring at least partial payment by
the executive agencies for mailing privileges. Such reform should
be extended to other branches of the Government, and appropriations
to those branches made accordingly larger to finance payment. On
the other hand, the accounts of Government enterprises should also
cover more fully the economic costs they incur. The Post Office, for
instance, should take account on a current basis of the cost of the
buildings it occupies, in terms of either depreciation or rent, and also
of a reasonable accounting allowance for local property taxes. Only
in such a manner is it possible to evaluate the cost of the operation
in terms of what it might be under other conditions. This argument
is, of course, made much of with respect to the TVA.
Similar accounting procedures, furthermore, m ight well be ex­
tended to the ancilliary agencies such as the Government Printing
Office, and even the General Services Administration. These agencies
have as their customers prim arily other Government agencies, but
their charges should be such as to cover the total cost of the resources
used in a fair and equitable manner. F or instance, the present treat­
ment of Government buildings might be mentioned. Government
agencies that occupies buildings paid for by past appropriations are
at the present time receiving the benefit of these past appropriations
without any evidence of this in the size of current appropriations. A
new agency, on the other hand, will be forced to supply its own office
space and other facilities, so th at it will be paying for its space out
of current appropriations. One of the things that impreses a visitor
to Washington is the relative spaciousness of those agencies which
have existed for some time and have their own buildings, versus those
agencies that rent their space commercially. I t can be argued that
this is not coincidence, but is due to the form of the accounting system.
An accounting reform that would require all agencies to include in
their budgets a fair market rental for the space they occupy might



490

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

well lead to a more rational distribution of resources. Such a reform,
for instance, could be achieved by consolidating all Government build­
ings under the control of a single ancillary agency, which would rent
the properties to the agencies wishing to occupy them. Thus all
Government agencies would be forced to make an explicit decision on
whether the cost of additional space was worth the price th at must be
paid to obtain it. There are many similar problems in other areas. In
meeting them, what is needed is closer attention to the principles of
direct costing.
Economic and functional classifications o f Government transactions

Defining the basic accounting units for Government economic
activity and outlining the scope of the accounts within these units is
of major importance, but it still leaves unsettled the problem of the
internal classification of transactions within this framework. The
purpose of such classification is to yield pertinent data for evaluating
efficiency in performance of specific programs and the economic effects
which these programs have on the rest of the economy. Two different
kinds of classification are involved. Expenditures must be classified
(a) by programs and projects within programs according to the p u r­
poses of the operation—agriculture, education, and so forth—and
( b ) by the economic nature of the expenditure—wages, interest, com­
modities, transfer payments, and so forth.
W ith respect to classification by program and project, many
dilemmas arise. Appropriations are made in terms of fairly broad
programs, and the basic accounting should be in terms of these pro­
grams. A t the same time, it can be argued that a classification system
should be developed in which the same function carried out in a num­
ber of different places within the Government is brought together
under a single heading. Thus, for example, school building may be
aided by, a number of different agencies at different levels of Govern­
ment. I t is, therefore, suggested that, in addition to the program or
project, there should be a classification by function th a t cuts across
programs. A true classification by purpose, however, raises many
problems. Members of the legislative branch have different purposes
in mind when they vote for a specific program, and in this sense it may
be that any refined approach to purpose is too subjective to serve as a
basis for accounting, and th at we may have to rely upon the legislative
framework, accepting as a consequence the lack of comparability
among agencies.
The classification of government transactions by economic nature is
necessary to show the economic activity of the Government in relation
to the working of the economy as a whole. One way in which this
could be achieved simultaneously with a program classification would
be to develop a rather elaborate cross-classification showing both the
economic nature of transactions and the program of which they are a
part. A t the most general level such a cross-classification would prob­
ably be very useful, and the basic accounts in government units should
perhaps be kept on this basis. But there is a great danger th at such
a system of cross-classification will get out of hand, presenting masses
of detail which are essentially of no interest.
The integration and consolidation o f the accounts

I t is clear th a t this is the heart of the problem of government
budgeting, since it is immediately obvious in view of the conflicting



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

491

demands that any single account or tabulation is insufficient for the
evaluation of government economic activity. An accounting frame­
work must be developed in which it is possible to move simply and
easily from the detailed accounts of individual agencies to summary
levels showing the relation of the Government as a whole to the rest
of the economy. Neither the detailed accounts or the summary ac­
counts by themselves are sufficient. The detailed data yield large
volumes of paper in which all perspective is lost and which cannot
be digested. Summary accounts hide much important and useful
information in their totals. The combination which is now avail­
able—a variety of detailed and summary tables which do not mesh—
creates further frustrations through the need for complex reconcilia­
tions and the existence of apparent paradoxes. W hat is required is a
gradual consolidation and combination of data at several levels, culmi­
nating in a single summary account for all government transactions
that will mesh with the summary accounts for the other sectors of the
economy.
Capital versus current expenditure

One of the most frequent criticisms of the present government ac­
counts has been that, unlike business enterprises, the Federal Govern­
ment budget does not recognize the existence of capital. I t is fre­
quently pointed out that government accounts in many other countries
make a distinction between current transactions and capital trans­
actions, and that in the interest of sound accounting practice the
United States should consider the merits of adopting a capital budget.
In its review of national economic accounting, the National Ac­
counts Review Committee gave considerable attention to this problem.
I t became evident that there are two fairly strong arguments in favor
of capital budgets. First, it cannot be denied that many of the ex­
penditures which the Government makes are of a lumpy nature. The
construction of a new building or the purchase of machinery and
equipment is essentially similar to the purchase of buildings or equip­
ment by business enterprises, in that the expenditures are intermittent
rather than continuing, and should not all be attributed to the account­
ing period in which they are made. Second, the Government does own
assets, and if, as has been recommended, national balance sheets are
drawn up, these government assets should be shown. In strict ac­
counting logic, if these assets had been considered as purchased on
current account, they would have been expensed, and could not appear
on the balance sheet.
Further discussion by the committee, however, brought out some
equally strong arguments on the other side, which cast serious doubt on
the meaningfulness of capital budgets as an analytical tool. W ith
respect to the first argument concerning the lumpiness of expenditures
for durable goods, it was pointed out that this criterion should not be
restricted to items made of metal, wood, and concrete. There are
similar lumpy expenditures of an invisible nature which also give off
services in the future. An example is the recent cost of polio injec­
tions. I t can be expected that this expenditure will have future bene­
fits, and that smaller expenditures will be required at future dates.
Similarly, other expenditures in such areas as education, health, and
national defense, could logically be included in the capital category,



492

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

in terms of both their lumpiness and their future effects. I f it is
argued that education will be required every year, the same argument
can also be extended to government buildings, since for the Govern­
ment as a whole it is reasonable to assume th at the wearing out will
occur every year. There is no reason to expect, furthermore, th a t the
growth required in government buildings would be much different
from the growth required for education. The committee concluded
therefore that the introduction for general government of a capital
budget restricted to durable goods would not be a useful device in
developing criteria for government spending. In fact, if such a cap­
ital budget were taken seriously, it was generally agreed that it would
be harmful. F or these reasons, the committee retained the concept
of a single account for government outlays, showing distinctions among
kinds of expenditure as a p art of the classification system.
The committee was impressed, however, by the argument relating
to the need for a government balance sheet, and, breaking with trad i­
tional accounting procedure, decided to retain an accounting or inven­
tory of assets, despite the fact that the expenditures for acquiring
these assets were treated as current outlays.
A thoroughgoing budgetary reform of the nature suggested in the
preceding sections would, however, help to solve this dilemma. I f
the concepts of government enterprises and ancillary agencies were
introduced on a consistent basis, purchases of buildings and capital
equipment could be treated as investment expenditures by these gov­
ernment enterprises and ancillary agencies. F or these groups, capital
accounts would be entirely proper, having the same meaning that they
do for private enterprises—expenditures that are expected to yield
future incomes, and so to be self-liquidating. Payments or transfers
from general government to these groups would be current transactions
in the general government accounts. Furthermore, assets of a non­
income-producing nature owned by the general government, especially
such things as parks and roads, would not be considered capital goods
in the normal sense of the term, nor would they be considered m ar­
ketable assets. All marketable assets and self-liquidating capital
goods would be segregated into the ancillary agency and government
enterprise accounts, where they could be treated as capital. From a
budgetary procedure point of view, therefore, it would not be neces­
sary to make a distinction between capital and current expenditures in
the general government accounts.