View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOREIGN AID — SOME ISSUES AND PROBLEMS IN
ASSESSMENT

Wilson Schmidt, associate professor of economics, the George
Washington University
In public discussion, foreign aid is in a class with the Yankees—
blisteringly hated or ardently loved. Yet unreserved convictions are
unwarranted on whether or not foreign assistance is an efficient allo­
cation of American resources. Aid involves intractable uncertainties
and inherent difficulties of assessment. This paper deals largely with
some basic obstacles to firm conclusions on whether or not the benefits
from foreign aid exceed the costs.
T h e P eace E ffects

The main thrust of foreign assistance is to maintain peace, or at
least to avoid a major nuclear war, and to preserve and expand the
number of countries which are friendly, or at least not hostile, to the
United States. T hat is the way one State Department-International
Cooperation Administration staff memorandum put it.
The means by which aid serves these ends are roughly as follows.
Foreign aid appropriations equip and train Allied forces. In 1956,
over 60 percent of net United States grants and credits took this form,
though, for the postwar period, military aid constitutes about onethird of the total. Some allies (now prim arily Turkey, Pakistan,
Taiwan, Korea, and Vietnam) receive economic aid for it is felt that
they cannot support their own defense efforts without nonmilitary
help from us.
Government grants and credits, partly out of foreign aid appro­
priations but also from the Export-Im port Bank and from the pro­
ceeds of the sale of agriculture surpluses overseas, provide capital
and finance the transfer of technical know-how to assist the long-term
economic growth of certain underdeveloped countries. The Secretary
of State recently stated that, unless the aspirations of the people of
underdeveloped countries for greater growth are met, they may install
governments which are unfriendly if not violently opposed to the
United States.
Foreign aid appropriations also provide emergency assistance to
shaky governments to sustain them during imminent internal threats.
Examples include recent assistance to Jordan during an internal
crisis, to Guatemala after the overthrow of its pro-Communist gov­
ernment, to Iran after the ouster of Mossadegh, and to Bolivia. In
these instances, the likely alternative government was thought to be
less favorable to the United States.
Economic assistance has also been used in an attempt to prevent
countries (Afghanistan for example) from becoming entirely de­
pendent on Soviet aid. And both economic and military aid were
used to support Tito’s withdrawal from the Soviet camp.



627

628

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Some general 'problems in assessment

One major difficulty in determining whether aid constitutes an
efficient allocation of resources is that, as between individual Ameri­
cans, peace is indivisible. Unlike peas and carrots, it cannot be di­
vided and sold to individual consumers by the pound. Consequently
it cannot be produced in response to individual consumer demand as
in a market place. Therefore, one cannot say th at more or less re­
sources are used in gaining security than individual consumers in
total would want.
Another major problem is the difficulty of knowing what the
policies of other countries would be in the absence of aid, which in­
volves a difficult estimate of the behavior of other governments.
Three examples show the relevance of this.
(1) An assessment of aid requires knowledge of the effect of aid
on Sino-Soviet policies. M ilitary strength is purely a relative m at­
ter. Few benefits would be gained from an increase in the m ilitary
posture of the free world if this induced the Red bloc to raise its
defense expenditures to maintain the previous ratio of strength.1
Hence, any assessment of increased aid must involve some assumption
about the Communist response. Obviously, the appropriate assump­
tion is difficult to determine.
^2) An assessment of aid requires a judgment of the effect of aid
on the balance of power within aided countries and the consequences
of any shift in that balance. For example, in one Latin American
country, United States assistance supports a government which, in
its ideological outlook, is probably not predisposed to the United
States. The withdrawal of aid probably would bring down that
government, for aid provides half of its revenues. Among the pos­
sible alternative governments are ones which are more and less favor­
able to the United States. But which would come to the top in a
revolution set off by the weakening of the present government ?
(3) An assessment of aid requires an estimate of what the govern­
ment in power in fact does with the aid. A given type of assistance
may produce an unrelated type of benefit. Yet, discussions of aid
often assume that the benefits are directly related to the type of
assistance provided. The transfer of m ilitary items to allies, for
example, increases their m ilitary strength and consequently we are
supposed to gain certain defense benefits. But, at least in principle,
all m ilitary aid could in fact result in economic assistance and all
economic aid could provide m ilitary assistance. The nature and
complexity of this problem was developed in a recent colloquy be­
tween Congressman Otto Passman, chairman of the subcommittee
in charge of foreign-aid appropriations, and Mr. John Hollister,
then director of the agency which administers part of United States
foreign assistance:
Mr. P a s s m a n . * * * In the past, practically all nations
have budgeted a certain amount of their national income
for national defense, and when we go in and pick up mili­
1 This m ust be qualified for the p ossibility th at increased Communist defense expendi­
tures could sap the economic strength of the Sino-Soviet bloc more than additional aid
would weaken our strength. T his would restrain the growth of the bloc’s productive
capacity and thereby affect its ability to increase its m ilitary strength in the future or
reduce its w illingness to offer grants and credits to underdeveloped countries as an
instrum ent of p olitical penetration.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

629

tary checks, it releases the money that country normally
would spend fo r national defense fo r economic purposes or
other purposes. In effect it is helping the economy o f the
country.
Mr. H o l l i s t e r . Perhaps I do not follow you. Y ou mean
in a country where we help them militarily we assist the
economy by our military expenditures ?
Mr. P a s s m a n . Yes. I f we are paying for their tanks and
planes and ships for national defense, that releases the
amount o f money which before that time they had spent for
national defense for such things as flood control, irrigation,
and so forth, to strengthen their economy.
Mr. H o l l i s t e r . In some cases. In other cases the whole
point o f our military expenditures is for the military de­
fense o f the United States.
Mr. P a s s m a n . That is the claim, but it certainly helps the
economy o f a country to be relieved of the responsibility o f
spending its own money fo r armament and military pur­
poses; it releases that money to strengthen its economy.
Mr. H o l l i s t e r . That must be counterbalanced in that
everything you put into one o f those countries in the way
o f a military establishment increases the cost o f keeping
that military establishment going. The people in the m ili­
tary services must be fed and clothed; they are taken out
o f economic pursuits, et cetera. So it is one o f those com­
plicated questions you cannot give a direct answer to.
Mr. P a s s m a n . That is right. It is like the old saying you
can take figures and do anything you want to with them.
Mr. H o l l i s t e r . Yes. Here is a country that has a certain
appropriation 011 the military side and a certain appropria­
tion 011 the economic side. I f we say, “ Raise your military
budget, and we will increase your economic aid,” it looks
like we are raising the economic aid. I f we say, “ Put more
money in your economic budget, and we will give you more
military aid,” it m ight look the other way.2
The disparity between the kind o f aid and the type o f benefit ap­
pears in another way. F or its mutual-security program fo r fiscal
year 1958, the administration had to divide nonmilitary aid into that
which supported United States military objectives and that which
aided economic development. Officials were frank to say that the
distinction was exceedingly difficult to make. I-Cstiniates o f the economic-development content o f previous nonmilitary aid to countries
with whom we had mutual-security treaties ranged from 20 percent
to 60 percent. Tw o examples will suffice to show the problem. A s­
sistance to build a road serves military objectives since the road fa ­
cilitates troop movements; but it also provides economic benefits since
the road permits more internal and external trade. A id for the m od­
ernization o f the Turkish Arm y, while increasing military strength,
also released surplus soldiers fo r civilian uses.
Unless one assumes that an equivalent amount o f military aid and
nonmilitary aid bring exactly equal benefits to the United States, the
2 H earings, Mutual Security Appropriations for 1958, Subcommittee of the Committee on
Appropriations. H ouse of Representatives, pp. 7-8.




630

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABHJTT

disparity between the mixture of aid provided and the type of result­
ing benefits makes assessment of the aid program difficult.
Without attempting a balanced presentation of pros and cons, let
us consider some basic uncertainties regarding military and develop­
mental assistance.

Problems in determining the benefits from m ilitary assistance
It is tempting to assert that the United States must obtain net bene­
fits from military aid because the Department of Defense plans and
administers the program. Presumably DOD would allocate funds
between foreign and domestic expenditures in a way designed to maxi­
mize United States national security. However, the Special Senate
Committee To Study the Foreign Aid Programs contends that it
has not:
Expenditures on military aid must be weighed primarily
against the return which could be expected if these funds
were spent directly on the National Defense Establishment.
The committee is not satisfied that this principle is now being
followed under present procedures. Military aid appears to
be considered as an end in itself, insufficiently related to the
total problem of national defense and its cost.
The committee also expressed some doubt about the relationship be­
tween military aid and the strategic concepts of United States defense.
T h e T y pe o f W

ar

The benefits gained from military assistance depend on the type of
war we may have to fight. Obviously this is difficult to predict. For
all-out nuclear war, military aid is perhaps largely wasted since it
consists to date entirely of conventional weapons. Yet, some persons
see a need for some conventional forces in a nuclear war, if for
nothing else than mopup and occupation.
In any event, under present circumstances, our ability to threaten
massive retaliation depends significantly on access to overseas bases.
Sufficient intercontinental bombers and guided missiles are lacking.
The fact that we can disperse our retaliatory forces instead of con­
centrating them in the United States is itself an advantage. Military
assistance arms and trains forces which provide some protection for
overseas bases. And our rights to those bases may depend on aid.
This was the case in Spain, where we bought the base rights with aid,
having little intent of using Spain’s troops in the integrated defense
of Western Europe.
In Western Europe, United States assistance is a relatively small
part of the recipients’ gross national product—probably no more than
2 percent in any country and less than one-half of 1 percent in several.
Hence, it is difficult to argue that these allies could not possibly pro­
vide their own defense now, assuming, of course, that they put their
dollar balance in order so that they might purchase equipment from
us. But it is also difficult to know what their reaction with respect
to base rights would be if we withdrew our assistance. Some might
hope to avoid national demolition if the Russians move by evicting
American forces; others might conclude that their ultimate defense
depends upon the ability o f the United States to threaten massive
retaliation and would therefore not take such drastic action. Their



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

631

response would also be affected by their interpretation of United
States policy: Does the withdrawal of United States aid indicate that
we would not assist in their defense ? Clearly, the effect of a cessation
of military assistance would depend on what other commitments we
would undertake and how it is done.
To the extent that we simply have exchanged aid for bases, the
transaction is a bilateral bargain. The price is indeterminate and
could fall anywhere within a significant range. We may have paid
more than we need have to gain the bases; i. e., some of our aid brings
us no benefits. But without knowing the minimum price of our land­
lords, one could not tell for certain.
Any assessment of military aid in respect to a limited war—con­
ventional or tactical nuclear—is uncertain because there is no cer­
tainty that such wars will remain at the subhydrogen level. One
bomb leads to another, bigger each time, and the war, almost unwit­
tingly, is dragged into the superhydrogen era. This would suggest
reliance on a trip wire—not extensive force buildups—to unleash
massive retaliation. Against this, some argue that neither side would
dare use the ultimate weapon in fear of the consequences of retaliation.

But suppose this uncertainty is settled in favor of a limited war.
The value of m ilitary aid remains subject to doubt. The defense
efforts of our allies in Western Europe have fallen far short of their
commitments and their plans. The NATO commander stated th at
an irreducible minimum of 30 divisions is necessary for the defense of
Western Europe; at present he has only 15, of which probably only
the American divisions are ready for immediate combat. The De­
fense Committee of Western European Union recently excoriated
NATO members for their failure to achieve essential force goals, to
cooperate adequately in planning, logistics, and supply; it suggested
that failure to attain higher force levels might require a fundamental
shift in military strategy in Western Europe.
Outside of Europe the ability of aided countries to stop an allout at­
tack is also in doubt. But the key issue is not, however, what is neces­
sary to beat back aggression but what is needed to prevent it. Forces
insufficient to win may nonetheless deter aggression by making it just
slightly too expensive for the Communist bloc. The point at which
this line is crossed is a neat judgment, especially since it must be an
estimate of the judgment of a potential aggressor of the benefits and
costs of aggression. Furthermore, even if local forces cannot prevent
aggression and if United States national security requires the defense
of every country on the Soviet-Sino rimland? local troops can slow the
Communist drive until American help arrives and any quantity of
local forces would assist United States troops.
T h e S avings

Proponents of m ilitary assistance assert th at it would cost us many
times more than present aid expenditures to achieve the same m ilitary
strength through our own efforts as is now provided from a combina­
tion of aid and allied forces. Admiral Radford guessed it would cost
4 or 5 times as much to replace the 21 Korean divisions with American
troops, and one estimate suggested an overall saving of $25 billion
per annum. The cost of maintaining a foreign soldier falls fa r below



632

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

the cost fo r an American soldier, and the cost to the United States in
aid o f arming a foreign soldier is much less than that o f an American
soldier because foreign governments bear part o f the burden. Hence,
we save resources through m ilitary assistance.

Despite the frequent implication th at the saving measures the bene­
fits we derive from foreign aid, such figures do not faithfully serve
that purpose. I f we compare the cost of obtaining a given level of
m ilitary strength through a combination of aid and United States
and allied forces with the cost of obtaining the same strength through
our own efforts, the difference measures the benefits of aid to us only
if United States national security remains constant. B ut this cannot
be assumed with certitude. The training levels of foreign troops are,
with some exceptions, lower than ours, and in some instances the for­
eign forces are structured for internal security missions rather than
combat in the common defense. The United States Government has
complete control over its own forces whereas its control over foreign
troops is much less firm. The obvious, and extreme, example where
our aid may have low productivity for United States security is Y u­
goslavia. Assistance to Tito may have preserved him and thereby
helped to create dissension in the Communist bloc. But it may also
have helped to arm a potential enemy.
Despite the foregoing, the saving figures are not necessarily an
overestimate. The United States Government does not obtain all o f
its m ilitary personnel in the free market so that the real cost o f United
States defense expenditures is somewhat higher than suggested by
monetary data.

Proponents of military assistance frequently note th at for every
dollar of aid since the Korean war, our allies have spent $5.50 on
defense and th at they have increased their ground forces by 1.3
million men. United States aid stimulated this or made it possible,
according to some proponents. Assuming that we must have, to main­
tain our security, forces equivalent to those now financed by our allies,
such figures would seem to suggest the benefits we derive from mili­
tary assistance. But they fail because, as a few administration w it­
nesses admit, we do not know what level of expenditures or forces
would be undertaken by our allies in the absence of aid. There is
even the possibility, suggested by the colloquy between Passman and
Hollister, that our aid substitutes in p art for m ilitary expenditures
which our allies would otherwise undertake. Unless one knows what
would have been done in the absence of aid, one cannot calculate the
payoff from aid.
T h e S ide E ffects

M ilitary assistance has numerous side effects, all of which must be
considered in assessing its value to the United States. F or example,
aid to ex-mother countries has adversely affected our political rela­
tions with ex-colonial territories. The use of American equipment
by the British and French in their African actions dramatized this
issue, and brought formal complaint from Arabs. Also military
assistance to Pakistan incensed India, and, according to the American
Ambassador, the difficulties between India and the United States
“grew chiefly” out of our aid to Parkistan. Another alleged effect has
been to slow the economic growth of underdeveloped countries receiv­



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

633

ing m ilitary assistance. They have been obliged to provide comple­
mentary resources to make use of aid items in order to achieve
established force goals. W ithout additional growth their political
stability is allegedly threatened to the detriment of United States
interest. Thus, an assessment of military aid requires an estimate
of the significance of the adverse political consequences of military aid
and it requires a judgment of the relative importance of various
countries to the United States.3 None of these are easy.
P roblem s in detei'm ining the benefits fr o m developm ental assistance

The uncertainties surrounding aid for development involve three
separate issues.
W ill develo pm ent p er se, bring p olitical benefits? —An early
rationale for foreign aid was that poverty breeds communism. But
the facts began to deny this generalization. The frustrated intellec­
tual was seen as the germ carrier of communism. Paradoxes were
noted where the richer part of a nation would show the greatest Com­
munist strength while the most conservative influences were found in
the poorest, backward areas.
Now, a new rationale prevails. W ithout adequate rates of economic
growth, the newly restless people of the underdeveloped world may
install governments unfavorable to the United States. Unemployed
intellectuals can find satisfying work in connection with development
programs and projects. The very fact of getting on with develop­
ment breeds hope for the future. Yet, while development may satisfy
the discontented, it may also create new sources of discontent and,
therefore, induce political instability. Development restructures
peoples’ wants and needs. I t rips them out of their traditional wavs
and cuts their previous ties, creating insecurity. Development is
change, and change creates dissatisfaction which can be exploited by
unfriendly parties to propel themselves to power.
Forced economic growth is occurring in many of the aided nations.
Does aid in its present amounts or forms raise the tempo of progress
beyond the discontent-creating level or is that level not yet reached?
The tools of social science are not now sharp enough to provide a firm
answer.
H o w m uch developm ent w ill aid induce? —I t is not certain that a
given amount of aid always constitutes an equivalent net increment
in the amount of resources used for development in the recipient
country. F or example, to what extent does aid allow the recipient
governments to divert their tax moneys away from development pur­
poses? And to what extent does aid allow them to relax their efforts
to obtain resources through other means—higher taxes, removal of
restrictions on private foreign investment, and increased reliance on
indigenous private initiative? I t is a rare underdeveloped country
that could not make some additional gains in these ways.
Furthermore, because .aid is largely channeled through govern­
ments, less meaning may attach to economic growth made possible by
United States aid than to development which results from voluntary,

,

3 A n in te r e s tin g b e n e fit a lle g e d by p ro p o n e n ts o f m ilita r y a s s is ta n c e is t h a t th e m ilita r y a s s is ta n c e a p p r o p r ia tio n s , w h ic h fin a n c e d th e p u rc h a s e o f m ilit a r y e q u ip m e n t fro m th e
a rm e d s e rv ic e s , h e lp e d to m o d e rn iz e U n ite d S ta te s fo rc e s b e ca u se th e f u n d s re c eiv ed w ere
u s e d to b u y n e w e q u ip m e n t. I f th is is v a lid , i t im p lie s t h a t C o n g re ss w a s m o re w illin g to
v o te f u n d s f o r fo re ig n a id th a n f o r d o m e stic d e fe n se , f o r w h y else u se th e c irc u ito u s m e a n s
o f m o d e rn iz in g U n ite d S ta te s fo rc e s ?




634

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

market-determined decisions. A rise in national income resulting
from state-induced expenditures must be adjusted in some degree for
the fact that individual consumers have not passed judgment on the
increment in output. This is of some importance to the earlier ques­
tion of the political benefits resulting from development because, if
those benefits derive from the increased well-being of individuals, the
favorable effects of aid-induced growth would be less than they might
first seem.4
Finally, population growth permitted by the economic growth which
may be caused by aid inhibits a rise in per capita income. We know
relatively little about the response of population to increased real
income. Total income may outrace population growth if a massive
initial increase in income occurs. B ut the kind of data necessary to
determine accurately the required initial rise in income or the amount
of aid necessary to bring it forth simply do not exist. Aid short of
the required amount is wasted. This does not suggest th at more aid
necessary, because any proposed increment may also fall short of
the required amount and, therefore, also be wasted.
W ill aid, per &e} bring political benefits?—I t is contended th a t aid,
independently of its effect on economic growth, gains cooperation, or
at least a favorable attitude toward the United States, from key groups
within the governments of the recipient countries. (This also applies
to m ilitary assistance where political leadership or strength rests with
local m ilitary personnel.) Aid strengthens the government in
power—against internal subversive forces and, in some degree, against
other political parties. While we need not be reluctant to gam the
enmity of the subversive groups—we have already got th at—our sup­
port lo r the present government may backfire when other political
parties or persons finally ascend to power, believing th at United States
aid helped keep them out before or supported corrupt and inefficient
governments. While gaining cooperation now, is United States aid
creating political troubles for the future ?
I t is not really certain th a t we only gain cooperation or favorable
attitudes. Aid must be divided. B ut there are no purely technical,
objective formulas for the allocation of aid among countries.5 I t
must be a political decision. Those who get less than they think they
deserve are miffed. The Arabs complained of the amounts received
by Israel. The Latin Americans were embittered by the sums pro­
vided to Europe. We must say “No” to some requests. The Lebanese
in 1953 wanted more aid than our Government thought advisable.
* This 1b not conclusive. Aid may substitute for higher taxes and Increased reliance on
private enterprisers. Therefore, aid may indirectly affect the distribution of income,
which may Itself affect the political benefits derived from development as well as the ra te
of development.
5 The use of absorptive capacity to allocate aid, as suggested In recent proposals, Is
deficient because It takes the form of aid as given. If a country cannot absorb a given
Item, th is may reflect a failure to provide, through aid, sufficient quantities of comple­
m entary resources or services. A nation’s ability to absqrb trucks w ithout wheels Is prob­
ably zero, but why provide trucks w ithout wheels? Any lim it on th e am ount of technical
service and advice which we will provide in the construction and operation of aid projects
could not be founded on technical or engineering criteria. And, if such lim its were
imposed, any consequent lim itation on am ounts of other assistance provided would merely
Indicate th a t the advice content of the projects selected was too high. Different projects
could be undertaken to perm it g reater am ounts of aid unless the recipient country literally
could do nothing w ith any aid item s w ithout foreign supervision. Clearly, there Is no
lim it to the am ount of aid a nation could absorb if it were given in th e form of free dollars
which could be disposed of as th e Government sees f i t ; consequently, lim itations on absorp­
tive capacity m ust stem from the specification of the types of goods to be provided or the
end use of aid. U nfortunately, such lim itations a re nontechnical.



635

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

American technicians were, in opposition quarters, charged as spies,
and frequent demands were made that the Americans go home.

The presence of American technicians, some of them not too well
equipped for representation of the United States and most of them
living at higher standards than the bulk of the local population, has
created difficulties, though there also have been some outstanding
successes.
W ith the Soviet Union extensively in the aid field, we run the risk
that the beneficiaries of United States aid may thank the Russians
for it rather than us, on the argument that our fear of Russian pene­
tration induced our gifts.
One could go on with additional adverse effects, but little purpose
is served. The point is th at foreign aid does have unfavorable side
effects and, until one can estimate the extent and importance of these
and cast them in balance with the favorable results, no firm assessment
of aid is possible. Even if one were reasonably certain that the pro­
gram produces net benefits, it does not necessarily follow th at those
benefits would be sufficient to cover the cost.
D

oes

A

m e r ic a n

H

u m a n it a r ia n is m

J u s t if y A

id

?

Do the United States aid programs constitute an efficient allocation
of resources in respect to our humanitarian desires? The Secretary
of State, in defending the aid programs, once said th at the United
States could not live happily as an island of prosperity in an ocean
of poverty. But, even if true, this does not necessarily justify aid.
I f one thinks of charity as an act which provides satisfaction to
the giver, we do ourselves a favor by relieving overseas poverty and
helping others protect themselves from communism. In principle,
to create an efficient allocation of resources, the United States Gov­
ernment should give just th at amount of money which American citi­
zens want to give to satisfy their desire to be charitable. But why
won’t the American people give that sum individually? Why it is
necessary to tax them to do so ? There is an element of compulsion
over the individual in every tax bill. How, then, can one contend th at
tax-financed aid simply reflects the humanitarianism of the American
people? Doesn’t taxation indicate th at people are being forced to
give more than they actually want to give ?
Two possible answers exist, neither of them very helpful. One is
that the Government may collect and administer money for charity
more efficiently than private charities can. Obviously, it is cheaper
for an American citizen to give charity when he pays his tax bill,
since he has to pay some taxes anyway. The alternative is to write
(requiring additional effort) a separate check (wasting paper), with
additional ink (wasting ink), and mail it (at an additional cost of
3 cents) to his favorite charity or the embassy of his favorite country.
The saving in stamps alone could run to $2 million. Against these
savings, one must allow for the administrative expenses of United
States Government aid—about $32 million for ICA alone in fiscal
1938—which would not be required under individual charity if Ameri­
cans would send freely disposable funds to their favorite embassies.
(Private charity would not compare as well, however, if Americans
insist, as does the Congress, on American supervision of aid.)



636

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Even if there is a saving through Government, is it worth the risk
that the Government may be overtaxing the individual in terms of
his desire to help others ? And, if it is cheaper to use the Government,
why not establish a separate Government fund to receive voluntary
additions to one’s tax bill ?
A second possible answer is that a gift to an underdeveloped country
from one American would bring satisfaction, by relieving overseas
poverty, to other Americans who are distressed by foreign squalor,
i. e., an act of charity by one American benefits other Americans as
well as the benefactor. No individual benefactor would necessarily
allow for these “neighborhood” or “external” effects in determining the
level of his charity. There is no evidence th at such effects exist. But
if this interdependence held among all taxpayers, it might be sensible
to tax all of them in order to subsidize their individual expenditures
for charity or in order to carry out more charity through government
aid than they would undertake individually. But, in view of the
numerous complaints against foreign aid, it is doubtful that such a
strong interdependence assumption can be made.
These issues can be avoided by assuming that humanitarianism
toward foreigners is a duty which the American people will not com­
pletely fulfill individually. A t one extreme, ancient Christian p rin­
ciples are invoked to support the view th at aid is a d u ty ; at the
other extreme, modern gimmicks of welfare economics and the inter­
national demonstration effect are called in support. This approach
leaves some key questions unsolved: How much money does Christian
duty (or welfare economics) require? Whose conception of duty
shall we use—the foreigner’s or that of certain Americans? And this
approach does not explain why individual Americans must be forced
to do their “duty” through taxation instead of being persuaded to do
so voluntarily by the proponents of this view. Again, it may be
cheaper to have them convince some key Congressman and Govern­
ment officials rather than millions of individual Americans, but is the
saving worth the risk implicit in the use of compulsion? And does
an apparent act of charity have any ethical content when the burden
is largely borne by persons other than those who decide to provide
charity? And in what sense has a taxpayer fulfilled a moral obliga­
tion if he is compelled to do so by law ?
T h e C ost of A id

Do aid figures provide an accurate measure of the money cost of
assistance provided by the United States Government? And do they
faithfully show the real loss of goods and services by the United
States? No detailed analysis is possible in this brief space, but the
following comments will show some of the problems and uncertainties
involved.
T h e m-oney cost o f aid

The public and the Congress generally hear two figures. One is the
President’s request for the mutual security program, and the other is
the sum of net utilized grants and credits reported by the Department
of Commerce.
Whether or not these figures accurately show the money cost of aid
depends on how one defines aid. For example, if one regards military



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

637

grants as aid, then the cost of the Korean war might properly be
included since it too involved the transfer of United States resources
overseas to serve the cause of peace and freedom. In addition, be­
cause United States law permits American firms operating overseas to
offset certain foreign taxes against their United States tax liability,
the burden of increased foreign taxes is sometimes borne by the United
States T reasury; in a sense, this drain could be regarded as foreign
aid. Finally, loans are included in figures popularly regarded as aid.
Yet the aid element in loans, in the sense of resources given up, is less
than that in grants since some of the loans will be repaid, i. e., the
resources are not given up forever. On this argument, perhaps the
only aid in loans is the difference between the interest rate that the
borrower would have had to pay to private lenders and the amount
charged by the government plus defaults. The correct determination
of items to be included is obviously of significance since the size of
foreign aid is a politically sensitive issue. Unfortunately, no clearcut criteria exist which admit of straightforward application.
W ithout attempting to define aid, several exclusions from the popu­
lar figures should be noted. The Department of Commerce net grants
and credits figure is deficient with respect to assistance related to the
surplus agricultural disposal programs. Under the Agricultural
Trade and Development Act of 1954, and section 402 of the Mutual
Security Act of 1954, the United States sells surplus stocks of agri­
cultural commodities overseas for foreign currencies and claims and
then grants and/or lends part of the proceeds to foreign countries.
The disbursement of the proceeds has lagged far behind the sale so the
United States has accumulated foreign currencies and claims. By
failing to use those proceeds, we have provided over $1 billion of
short-term aid to foreign countries. While it is not suggested that this
lag will create a permanent revolving fund of aid, it is not unlikely
that this assistance will grow for some time. The necessary adjust­
ment for this aid can be readily made because the Department of Com­
merce, having recognized this deficiency, provides the data in the same
source from which the net grants-and-credits figure is drawn.
Another large understatement of the money cost of United States
aid stems from the pricing policies on agricultural surplus. The sur­
plus products are sold overseas for less than their cost of acquisition
and shipment. I f one is interested primarily in determining the
money cost of aid to the taxpayer, then the money value of the loans
and grants made out of the proceeds of the sale of agricultural prod­
ucts should be increased by the pro rata “loss” suffered by the Com­
modity Credit Corporation. The CCC is reimbursed for this loss
but the amount is not included in the foreign assistance figures. U n­
der agreements signed through mid-1957, the loss will equal about
$900 million.
The President’s mutual security request does not include the fore­
going items. Nor does it include such important items as loans by
the Export-Im port Bank ($233 million gross in 1956) and loans and
grants out of the proceeds of agricultural surplus sales ($74 million
in 1956). The growing importance of the latter ($1.8 billion is
planned for this purpose under sales agreements signed by mid-1957)
will make the President’s request a less and less accurate measure
of United States Government aid.
97735—57------42



638

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

The real cost of aid
The true cost of the aid program is the amount of real goods and
services which the United States would have had in the absence of
the aid program. A thorough analysis of whether or not the money
cost accurately reflects the true cost would require a detailed analysis
of the American economy in relation to the aid program. F o r ex­
ample, one would need to consider the possibility th at the aid p u r­
chases from certain industries brought greater economies of largescale production than those lost through the contraction of demand
suffered by other industries because of the additional taxes or reduced
nonaid government expenditures necessary to finance the aid. No such
detailed effort is attempted here. Rather, two matters of recent dis­
cussion and one long-held complaint will be considered.
M

il it a r y

A

s s is t a n c e

According to several proponents of military assistance, a serious
overstatement of the cost of m ilitary items shipped overseas has oc­
curred in the past because of incorrect pricing. This raises doubt
about aid figures.
The military items transferred overseas come from new United
States production and from the armed services’ stocks. P a rt of that
obtained from stocks is called excess by the Department of Defense
and is defined by law as stocks exceeding DOD’s mobilization reserve
requirement. Prim a facie, it would seem th a t in giving away excess
items we, in fact, give up nothing of value to us. B ut the Department
of Commerce figures include excess items at their original cost. Con­
sequently, the real cost of foreign aid is overstated oy $787 million.6
The validity of this assertion depends on the accuracy and nature of
the mobilization reserve requirement. First, it takes account of the
time required to procure goods after M-day. Therefore, any item
which is “excess” need not be useless but only easily procured. Sec­
ond, its size shifts with political and m ilitary estimates so th a t it in­
volves a forecast. I t is evident th at some of the excess items could be
used in a conventional war. Therefore, one cannot contend unequivo­
cally th a t the cost of the aid program is overstated in respect to excess
items.
Entirely apart from excess items, the real cost of some of the mate­
rial obtained from the mobilization reserve may have been lower than
the money cost reported to the Department of Commerce by DOD.
The armed services, in effect, sell mobilization-reserve items to the
military-assistance program and use the receipts to replace their
stocks. Until 1956, the law required the armed services to charge the
military-asistance appropriation for such items a t their replacement
cost. B ut the replacement items were sometimes significant improve­
ments over the material shipped overseas. Therefore, some of the
items provided to our allies were in some degree obsolete in terms of
United States needs.7 They should, therefore, have been priced below
replacement cost. A small flurry was created in 1956 when the Comp­
troller General testified th at much of the m ilitary assistance had con•T h is ig the difference between original cost and the cost of repair and rehabilitation
from the beginning of the program through March 1957. T here is also an overstatem ent
for m ilitary-equipm ent loans. O verstatem ent does not occur in the m utual security appro­
priation for only funds for repair and rehabilitation are requested.
’ This does not mean they were obsolete in respect to the allies’ needs and capacities to
nse equipment.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

639

sisted of World W ar I I items, many of which were not being issued
to United States forces. He estimated an overcharge in excess of $1
billion. Recent reports have made much of this point in supporting
military-aid appropriations.
I f the Comptroller General’s estimate were accurate, the combined
overcharge on excess items and mobilization-reserve material would
exceed 10 percent of the total military-assistance progrem—a not in­
significant overstatement. However, the Comptroller General’s esti­
mate cannot be used because the overcharge was estimated against
original cost. Suppose there had been no qualitative improvement in
the replacement items but replacement costs doubled because of gen­
eral inflation. Charges against the military-assistance appropriations
which equaled original cost would provide the armed services with
funds only sufficient to replace half of the items delivered abroad.
Since the armed services would need to replace the other half (because
they came from the mobilization reserve), additional appropriations
directly to them would be required. These should, however, be conidered as part of the cost of the military-assistance program. There­
fore, while the substitution of improved equipment for military-aid
items at replacement cost has caused an overstatement of the true cost
of the aid program, the precise amount cannot be indicated.
Still another source of overstatement relates to overseas procure­
ment of items given to Allied Nations. The United States Govern­
ment has paid over $2 billion for such goods and, to the extent that
those dollars have been used by foreign nations to purchase United
States goods and services, this type of assistance constitutes a d raft on
our resources. Because, however, of the growth in the value of inter­
national trade since the beginning of offshore procurement, trading
nations find it necessary to hold larger dollar reserves than they other­
wise would. Therefore, and for other reasons, it is not impossible
that some of the dollars spent for overseas procurement lie unused, in
which case such aid has not cost us real goods and services. Two of
the major recipients of such dollars, Belgium and Italy, increased
their reserves significantly since the start of the program. I t is im­
possible, however, to estimate the amount of offshore procurement
which has not resulted in a demand for United States goods.
Against these possible overcharges, one major understatement must
be put. The salaries of military personnel in the program are not
charged against the military-assistance appropriation. And no allow­
ance is made for the time spent by individuals who work on various
aspects of the program but who are not employed directly in it. Since
virtually everyone in the Pentagon, from the janitor to the Chairman
of the Joint Chiefs of Staff, spends part of his time on the program,
the understatement of the cost could be significant.
A

g r ic u l t u r a l

S urplus D

is p o s a l

While the money cost of foreign assistance through surplus disposal
is greatly understated, on one line of argument the money cost seri­
ously overstates the true cost of foreign aid. Given the pnce-support
programs, the surplus stocks dispatched to foreigners could not be
used by the American people. Therefore, these aid programs do not
reduce the amount of real goods and services otherwise available to
the United States.




640;

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

A t minimum, this is misleading. The disposal programs restrain
the growth of surplus stocks. All other things equal, present CCC
investment would have been more than $4.2 billion higher, or 57
percent higher, in the absence of the special, foreign-aid related pro­
grams.8 I f the continued accumulation of surplus would bring a
taxpayers’ revolt against the agriculture support programs, then the
aid-disposal programs cost the American people something because
they help to preserve, for some indeterminate period, the uneconomic
allocation of resources inherent in the domestic farm-subsidy program.
A more direct cost stems from the relationship between the aiddisposal programs and the level of support prices. Under the law,
within limits, the support price rises as surplus stocks fall. When
the disposal program reduces surpluses to the point of raising the
support level, as it has in cotton and rice, an additional incentive is
given to farmers to invest more capital, better seed, more effective
pesticides, and fertilizers in agriculture. Resources are, therefore,
diverted from more economic uses, increasing the real cost of foreign
aid.
Against the foregoing, the disposal-aid programs may save real
goods and services by reducing regular foreign-aid appropriations.
This is just another way of saying that it is better to give away goods
one cannot use than goods one can use. By generating local currency
to finance projects which might otherwise be financed with regular
aid moneys, we oblige the recipient to accept goods less useful to us
than he might otherwise get. ICA guessed th at their request for
fiscal year 1957 would have been $50 million greater in the absence
of the Agricultural Trade and Development Act of 1954. I t was not
stated, however, th at a substitute aid appropriation would have been
spent for nonsurplus commodities.
The real cost of loans

A frequent charge against the aid program is “We’ll never get the
money back.” To the extent th at loans become grants through de­
faults, the real cost of foreign assistance is increased.
In the literal sense, this charge is undoubtedly exaggerated unless
war, a serious depression, or a strongly unfavorable shift in political
relations with our debtors ensues. In comparison with $18.2 billion
loans since 1940, only $8 million of loans have been charged olf and
$107 million of principal and interest due remains unpaid for 90 days
or more—less than 1-percent loss assuming the worst for those loans
not charged olf but due.
B ut in the sense of never getting goods and services back, the charge
has real foundation. Continued world inflation will further convert
United States loans into grants.
A million-dollar loan allows foreigners to buy an equivalent amount
of real goods and services from the United States.9 We eventually
regain goods and services with interest because, to accumulate the dol­
lars with which to repay us, the foreigners who borrowed the money
must export more to the United States (providing us with additional
.8T his-statem ent assumes th a t all of Public Law 480, title I, exports were attributable
to the aid portion of the transactions. W ith some exceptions this is not an unreasonable
assum ptions, because the aid element apparently constitutes the m ajor attrac tio n to fo r­
eign “buyers.” The data include secs. 550 and 402 transactions under the M utual Security
Act.
8 Assuming th a t the loan has a negligible effect on United S tates im port and export
prices.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

641

foreign goods) or must import less from us (leaving us with more of
our own goods). But if inflation intervenes between the date on
which the proceeds of the loan are spent by the borrower and the date
of repayment, we regain, aside from interest payments, fewer real
goods and services than we initially give up. For example, if the
prices of United States imports double, foreigners need export only
half as many additional real goods to us to obtain the required dollars
to repay the loan. I f the prices of United States exports double, a
dollar reduction in foreigner’s purchases from us leaves us with only
half as many additional goods as would have been the case if prices
had not risen.
Inflation hurts the creditor. But within nations, the creditor’s loss
is the debtor’s gain so that the total supply of goods and services in
the country remains the same, save for the effect of inflation on pro­
duction. But between nations, a whole nation loses.
From the date that England drew out the last of the British loan
of $3.75 billion (March 1948) to the time that repayments first began
(December 1951), we had lost over one-quarter of the real value of
the loan in terms of United States import prices. W ith respect to
United States export prices, the loss was “only” 2y2 percent. Since
1948, United States import and export prices have risen about 25 per­
cent and 10 percent.
In a world of forced-draft development and high employment pol­
icies, secular inflation is quite conceivable. We must therefore re­
member, in judging foreign aid, that inflation adds to the burdens of
foreign assistance and the uncertainty over future price levels further
adds to the difficulty of assessing aid. Many of our recent loans have
maturities of 30 or more years so that inflation can take a very heavy
toU.
Finally, a special problem in repayment may arise as a result of
the surplus agricultural disposal program. Under that program the
borrowing nation is given the option of repaying in dollars or, at a
higher interest rate, in foreign currency. In principle, the economic
problem of repayment is exactly the same. The borrower must in­
crease its exports and/or reduce its imports. Hence, there will be no
more economic difficulty in regaining goods and services from local
currency loans than from dollar loans. But there may be more polit­
ical difficulty. Since the United States Government will receive local
currency it will have to begin the process of transferring goods to the
United States by spending the money itself or selling it to American
importers. Therefore, the onus of any ensuing increase in the dollar
balance-of-payments problem of the country will fall on the United
States. To preserve good political relations, the result may simply
be relending (a euphemism for default) of the local currency. In
sum, the real cost of these loans is also uncertain.
C o n c l u s io n

Aristotle summarized the theme of this paper when he w rote:
to give money away is an easy matter, but to decide to whom
to give it, and how large a sum, and when, and for what pur­
poses, and how, is neither in every man’s power, nor an easy
matter. Hence, it is that such excellence is rare and praise­
worthy and noble.