View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

T H E FO R EIG N A ID E X P E N D IT U R E S O F
T H E U N IT ED STA TES
Robert E. Asher, the Brookings In stitu tio n 1
In determining the level and distribution of foreign aid appropria­
tions, political, strategic, and humanitarian considerations have Deen
more important than purely economic criteria. In fact, it would
be naive to think that economic considerations could be governing
in this kind of situation. How can one estimate accurately the value
to the United States of preserving the independence of country A in
the face of Communist aggression? How measure in dollars and
cents the importance of helping to satisfy in some measure the revo­
lution of rising expectations that has two-thirds of the world writhing
in its grip ?
A fresh analysis of the full case for and against foreign aid might
be a valuable service, but such analysis is not the function of mis
article. In this review of foreign aid as an item of Federal expendi­
ture, I propose first to recall certain outstanding features of the aid
programs as they have developed over the years. I intend them to
examine in turn the impact of foreign aid programs on the American
economy, on world trade, and on the economies of recipient countries.
In discussing foreign aid and the economies of recipient countries, I
do not intend to evaluate aid programs in particular areas, but
rather to analyze a few recent developments of economic interest—
specifically, the difference to the recipient nation between m ilitary aid
and economic aid, the problems of relying increasingly on loans as the
technique for providing economic aid, and the special problems con­
nected with the extension of loans repayable in local currencies.
E

v o l u t io n o f

A

id

P

rogram s

The term “foreign aid” has been used loosely to encompass a
variety of military, economic, technical, and humanitarian activities.
The mixture has changed as the international environment, or the
American appraisal thereof, has changed. The aid programs have
been justified at different times and by different groups on different
grounds. They have included at least three totally different under­
takings: rehabilitating and reconstructing the economies of wardevastated allies, strengthening and subsidizing the m ilitary defenses
of the free world, and promoting economic growth and political de­
mocracy in underdeveloped areas.
Repairing the ravages of war was the purpose of the United Na­
tions Relief and Rehabilitation Administration and of the Marshall
plan. By and large, this purpose was successfully achieved during
1 The view s expressed in th is paper are those of the author. They do not necessarily
reflect the view s of other members of the Brookings staff or o f the ad m inistrative officers
of the institution.

570



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

571

the course of the European recovery program initiated in 1948. Be­
fore the end of its allotted 4-year period, however, an extensive pro­
gram of m ilitary aid had been undertaken. M ilitary aid is an invest­
ment in the mutual security of the United States and the recipient
nation. Its duration depends primarily on the duration—and the
nature—of the Soviet threat. Aid for the promotion of economic
growth along democratic lines in areas that have long been stagnant
requires American participation in an extremely complex under­
taking. On this delicate taskj only a beginning has been made.
A t first the job of facilitating economic development was thought
of prim arily as one for the International Bank, which would make
loans for specific development projects, repayable in the currencies
borrowed. When it became apparent that the underdeveloped coun­
tries were in need not only of power, transportation, and basic facili­
ties but also of information and know-how, the technical assistance
program was initiated.2 Technical assistance was at first thought
of prim arily as the provision of scientific know-how, of information
concerning hybrid com, DDT, rinderpest vaccine, simple hand tools,
and similar matters. Only gradually did the world begin to realize
the extent to which development was hampered also by deep-seated
social and institutional barriers. More technical assistance was then
devoted to the creation of climates and institutions believed favorable
to growth and progress—community development programs, land
reform programs, rural credit institutions, and aids to small business.
In addition to technical assistance and so-called hard loans for
approved projects, loans repayable in local currencies have been au­
thorized. The authority to make loans on easier terms than those of
the International Bank and the Export-Im port Bank is being ex­
tended and given added importance through the development loan
fund provided for in the Mutual Security Act of 1957.
Over the years, much has been learned about both the process of
economic growth and the manner in which foreign aid can contribute
to such growth. Much still remains unknown, however, and time must
elapse before any particular theories will be fully validated by events.
A t their peak in 1953, expenditures for foreign assistance (net grants
and credits utilized) reached $6.3 billion. Foreign assistance then
fell off to an average of $4.4 billion for the years 1954-56, inclusive.
During this period, military assistance comprised a larger proportion
of total assistance, and economic and technical aid a smaller propor­
tion, than during other postwar years. The disposition of agricultural
surpluses was pushed with vigor and nonmilitary assistance to friendly
countries consisted to a growing degree of surplus commodities and,
toward the end of the period, of grants and loans of local currencies
received as a result of sales of surplus commodities. Local currencies
were accumulated by the United States at a much more rapid rate than
they were reloaned or otherwise used, with the result that the United
States claims on and holdings of foreign currencies arising from agri­
cultural commodity sales reached the equivalent of $1.3 billion by
March 31, 1957.3
a There were, o f course, some sm all-scale precedents in the field of technical assistance
and p o litical as w ell as economic reasons for giving new em phasis to th is form of aid in
1949.
8 U. S. Departm ent of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, Foreign Grants and
Credits by the United S tates Government, March 1957 Quarter, p. 4.




572

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

During recent years also the Soviet Union stepped up its efforts to
penetrate the underdeveloped countries by strategically timed offers
of m ilitary assistance, trade agreements, gifts, loans, and technical
and cultural exchanges.
F

o r e ig n

A

s s is t a n c e a n d t h e

A

m e r ic a n

E

conom y

In absolute terms, $58 billion is obviously a substantial sum. I t is
the approximate amount of foreign assistance provided by the United
States during the 11y2 years that ended December 31, 1956. Of that
total, $26.3 billion—an average of $5.3 billion per year—was used dur­
ing the period July 1, 1945, to June 30, 1950, and $31.3 billion—an
average of $4.8 billion per year—was granted or loaned in the postKorean years.4 The post-Korean total is about equal to the national
income of Pakistan, a nation of more than 80 million people, and
exceeds the national incomes of Venezuela or of Denmark, for the
period in question. In the perspective of our enviable American
economy, however, it has not been a very significant item. I t is con­
siderably below the amount received by a single American corpora­
tion, the Standard Oil Company of New Jersey, during the corre­
sponding 6y2 years, from its sales of crude oil, products, and services.
Foreign aid may be defined in various ways. I f a foreign country
assumes the risks involved in providing the United States with the
site for a major airbase and in a separate transaction obtains an aid
grant, has the United States made a gift or has it compensated the
foreign nation for risks assumed ? I f the United States Government
makes a dollar loan which is to be repaid in full, should the principal
amount of the loan be regarded as foreign aid ? The figure $58 billion
given above treats the airbase transaction as a grant and includes loans
until they are repaid. I t would be considerably smaller if it excluded
outstanding loans and considerably larger if the calculation were
based on gross grants and credits instead of net grants and credits.
Theoretically “aid may be defined as a transfer of resources, either
in goods and services or in money, without a commensurate retrans­
fer either simultaneously or in the future. In the case of loans, the aid
component may be considered to be the difference between the actual
interest rate charged by the Government and the one which would
have to be charged if the loans had to be made through commercial
channels.5 (But if the loans could not have been obtained through
commercial channels, is it not appropriate to consider the principal
amount also as aid? W hat would have been the interest rate on a
commercial loan to Italy or to China in 1946 ?)
“I t is the purpose of aid to raise the recipient country’s resources so
that the total of its consumer, business, and government expenditures
can be higher than its total production without such aid.” 6 To this
end, the United States in 1946 dedicated 2.6 percent of its annual pro­
duction of goods and services. In the flourishing economy of the
postwar period, the gross national product of the United States
has mounted rapidly, with the result that foreign aid dropped in 1956
4 See table II. The figures exclude the United S tates Government investm ent of $3.4
billion in the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, the International
M onetary Fund, and the International Finance Corporation.
6 W alther Lederer, Foreign Aid and the United S tates Balance of P aym ents, Social
Science, vol. 29, No. 4, October 1954, pp. 231-232.
« Ibid.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

573

to only 1 percent of total output. In relation to the expenditures of
the Federal Government, expenditures for foreign assistance declined
from nearly 17 percent of the total to less than 6.5 percent.7
The impact of the foreign aid programs on the domestic economy
has been analyzed in a recent report prepared for the Senate Special
Committee To Study the Foreign Aid Program. This report, other
highlights of which are noted below, points out that
Since on the average about 1.5 percent of United States
production has been involved in foreign aid, it is difficult to
claim that domestic employment, prices, or consumption as
a whole could have been seriously affected, for better or
worse, by foreign aid expenditures. The impact on employ­
ment varies from one region to another, depending upon the
commodity * * * and the effects differ during periods of in­
flation and recession. On the whole, however, the infla­
tionary or stabilizing effects have been very slight.8
Nevertheless, foreign aid programs are not without costs. During
a period of inflationary pressures, they contribute to such pressures.
A t any time, their discontinuance and a corresponding increase in
other economic, social, or security programs of the Government could
speed the attainment of other desirable objectives. A tax reduction in
the amount of the foreign aid program would be widely welcomed.9
The report estimates that about 600,000 workers have been em­
ployed each year, directly and indirectly, as a result of foreign aid ex­
penditures. Goods and services vitally important to friendly nations
have been provided. These in turn have helped to increase the reverse
flow of necessary commodities and raw materials to the United States.
Our programs may in some cases have aided industries abroad which
compete with similar industries in the United States. A t the same
time, however, they have helped to expand the level of economic ac­
tivity abroad, thereby increasing overall demand for the goods and
services of this country.10
Government grants and loans are usually tied to specific goods and
services. Many man-hours are devoted to firming up these ties and
insuring that funds will be expended only for the agreed commodities
and services. I t is natural to assume that, if the aid funds are used
to buy wheat, the result will be to increase our exports of wheat and
the recipient country’s imports of an essential foodstuff. Because aid
funds are rarely the only funds available to a nation, the assumption
oversimplifies the relationships.
Foreign aid, for example, has played an important role in financing
American agricultural exports but probably a less important one than
that indicated by the statistics on commodities obtained with aid
funds. Government procurement is a complicated, costly, and time­
consuming process. Every aid administrator learns quickly that send­
7 N a tio n a l P la n n in g A ss o c ia tio n , T h e F o r e ig n A id P r o g r a m s a n d th e U n ite d S ta te s
E c o n o m y , a s tu d y p re p a re d p u r s u a n t to S. R es. 285, 8 4 th C ong., a n d S. R es. 35, 8 5 th
C ong., p. 53.
8 Ib id ., p. 2.
9 Ib id ., p. 12.
10 Ib id ., p p . 3, 7. R e g a rd in g a s s is ta n c e re c eiv ed b y in d u s tr ie s c o m p e tin g w ith s im ila r
o n e s in th i s c o u n try , th e r e p o r t n o te s t h a t th is does n o t n e c e s s a rily m e a n t h a t th e fo re ig n
p ro d u c e r h a s o b ta in e d a c o m p e titiv e a d v a n ta g e o v e r A m e ric a n p ro d u c e rs a s a r e s u lt of
A m e ric a n a id . E v e n w h e n A m e ric a n a s s is ta n c e ta k e s th e fo r m o f a g r a n t to th e fo re ig n
g o v e rn m e n t, th e fo re ig n b u s in e s s m a n p a y s h is g o v e rn m e n t, in th e c u rre n c y o f h is c o u n try ,
f o r th e e q u ip m e n t h e re c e iv e s (p . 1 5 ).
97 7 3 5 — 57------- 38




574

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

ing a shipload of wheat abroad is easier than spending an equivalent
sum for a list of manufactured products having complex specifications.
The convenience of everyone except the recipient government appears
to be served by using aid funds to procure agricultural commodities
in bulk wherever feasible, and requiring the recipient nation to finance
other essential imports from its free dollars. A t the same time, this
minimizes the volume of aid funds utilized for purposes th at m ight
be construed as competitive with domestic industry.
When aid funds have the indirect effect of helping other countries
to build up their gold and dollar reserves, the effect on the United
States economy is not the same as when foreign reserves are being
depleted. D uring the early postwar years, European countries were
drawing down their reserves. The aid extended during this period
of declining reserves “resulted in an increase in United States exports,
although not necessarily of the goods originally financed by the aid
and, perhaps, not even to the countries to which the aid was given.
Because the recipient country did not have to pay for aid-financed
imports, it may have used dollars from its reserves or from current
sales for purchases from third countries, which in turn could use these
dollars to increase their imports from the United States.” 11
During the period 1950 to 1953, foreign nations taken together con­
sidered it more important to replenish their depleted reserves than to
step up the level of imports from the United States by the full amount
of aid received from this country, although they also relaxed their
restrictions on dollar imports. In the absence of aid, United States
exports might have dropped significantly but the presence of aid ap­
pears to have resulted in large p art in an increase m foreign reserves,
although not necessarily in the countries to which the aid was given.
A t the present time, foreign countries are again liquidating reserves,
and aid may again be regarded as expanding American exports. The
effect, however, is less expansive than in 1946-49, not only because there
is less aid, but also because our total exports are greater. Aid-financed
exports even if they had remained constant, would represent a smaller
proportion of total exports.
The greater expansion of American exports than of imports is due
to various factors. Rich in resources, immensely diversified, and ex­
ceedingly productive, the United States has less need for imports than
most countries and superior capacities for meeting export demands.
Though its record leaves a good deal to be desired, it has also been
more successful than the majority of its trading partners in holding
down inflationary pressures. P a rt of the currently widening gap
between exports and imports, however, is due to the fact th a t the
foreign economic policy of the United States—in trade, aid, and in­
vestment—is oriented toward, and more successful in, promoting
exports than in enlarging imports.
The exports procured with foreign aid funds during 1948-55 have
accounted for as much as 46 percent and as little as 25 percent of total
United States merchandise exports. D uring 1948-50, the average
ratio of foreign aid shipments to total commodity exports was 41
percent, while for the period 1951 to 1955 the ratio was 30 percent.12
11 W alther Lederer, loc. cit., p. 234.
» NPA, loc. cit., p. 13.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

575

Under the European recovery program, large quantities of United
States agricultural commodities were purchased with aid funds. D ur­
ing 1948-51, inclusive, more than $1.8 billion of aid funds were used
directly to purchase bread grains and flour from the United S tates;
approximately $500 million to purchase coarse grains; nearly $1.5
billion to purchase cotton; and nearly $450 million to purchase tobacco
and tobacco products. In the 3 years 1948-50, more than half of the
total exports of bread grains, coarse grains, cotton, and tobacco were
foreign-aid shipments.13
During the early postwar years, when the world food crisis was at
its height, the United States made intensive efforts to increase its
production as well as its exports of essential foodstuffs. The United
States replaced Manchuria as the major exporter of soybeans and
became an important exporter of rice. Prices to wheat farmers rose
substantially and output expanded. In other exporting nations, in
which government policies made it more difficult for farmers to obtain
the immediate benefits of rising demand, comparable increases in
wheat output failed to occur. When prices remained high, however,
others also expanded their production and surpluses began to accumu­
late. F or several years after 1950 there was no agricultural commod­
ity group in which aid-financed exports exceeded 50 percent of total
United States exports.
The purpose of government financing of agricultural exports dur­
ing the early postwar years was to meet the urgent food requirements
of foreign countries. In recent years the major purpose has been to
relieve the domestic economy of some burdensome surpluses. As a
result of the expansion of surplus disposal programs since 1954, the
United States Government has again assumed a major role in financ­
ing agricultural exports. Farm exports under government grant
credit, and sales programs reached approximately $1.4 billion in 1956,
half again as much as in 1955. Agricultural shipments, moreover,
comprised 50 percent of the gross deliveries and cash payments under
the nonmilitary programs of the Government, as compared with onethird in 1955.14 Agricultural surpluses nonetheless continue to present
major problems for the domestic economy, which have not been, and
cannot be, solved satisfactorily by foreign assistance measures.
Surpluses are no longer mounting rapidly, but some of the heaviest
have not been greatly reduced. Despite the fact that wheat is the
most widely used commodity in the disposal programs, the wheat sur­
plus remains enormous. The supply of feed grains is sufficient
to meet all prospective requirements for domestic use and for exports,
and still to leave a large carryover. On the other hand, surpluses of
rice, cotton, and dairy products are being reduced.15
In 1948, there were eight groups of manufactured commodities in
which aid-financed exports were greater than those privately financed.
By 1955, when foreign aid consisted primarily of military assistance,
there were three product groups in which aid shipments accounted
for 50 percent or more of total exports: construction, mining, and
13 Ibid., p. 41.
14 U. S. Departm ent of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, Foreign Grants and
Credits by the United States Government, December 1956 Quarter, p. 5.
16 N ational P lanning A ssociation, Agricultural Surplus Disposal and Foreign Aid, a study
prepared pursuant to S. Res. 285, 84th Cong., and S. Res. 35, 85th Cong., pp. 5-6.




576

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

conveying equipment; aircraft engines and p a rts; and ships and other
transportation equipment.16
Although foreign aid expenditures have been significant for certain
categories of Commodities, the overall effects of the foreign-aid pro­
grams on the American economy have, as indicated earlier in this
article, been minor and currently involve only about 1 percent of our
gross national product. The report on the Foreign Aid Programs
and the United States Economy prepared for the Senate Special Com­
mittee To Study the Foreign Aid Program concludes not only that the
total burden of the aid programs on the American economy has been
slight, but also that—
Assuming a gross national production level by 1965 of
$565 billion (in 1955 prices), the United States could double
the present size of the foreign aid program by then with little
additional impact on the United States economy.17
F

o r e ig n

A

s s is t a n c e a n d

W

orld

T

rade

Although foreign assistance is comparatively unim portant to the
American economy, it has important effects not only on the level of
economic activity in recipient countries and on their imports and
exports, but also on the overall volume and direction of international
trade. In the first place, it has continued to be a significant factor in
the world supply of dollars. Secondly, if affects world trade in p ar­
ticular commodities, most notably agricultural commodities that are
also exported in quantity by other friendly nations. In the third
place, some of the legal and administrative regulations governing the
operation of the aid program insure that it will maximize American
exports of goods and services without correspondingly increasing the
capacity of other nations to earn the dollars with which to pay for
those exports. In this respect, aid policies reinforce trade and loan
policies of the United States Government that likewise tend to pre­
serve or to widen the gap between American exports and imports.
Spending by the United States Government has been an essential
lubricant of world trade. In addition to the human misery that it has
relieved, government spending has helped reduce trade barriers that
would otherwise have been raised in efforts to protect the foreign ex­
change reserves of vulnerable countries. Over the past 9 years,
about 25 percent of the dollars available to foreign countries has be­
come so as a result of United States Government spending. Govern­
ment grant and loan programs (if it is proper to include grants of
m ilitary supplies and services in the total) are consequently second
only to our merchandise imports as a source of dollars for a dollarhungry world. In this sense, aid programs are more important to
the stability of international trade than to the stability of the American
economy. The “large fraction of the dollar supply accounted for by
Government payments makes the total dollar supply at least as sensi­
tive to political decisions as to minor cyclical fluctuations.” 18
18 N ational P lanning Association, The Foreign Aid Programs and the United States
Economy, p. 14.
17 Ibid., p. 2.
18 J. J. Polak, The Repercussions of Economic F luctuation in the U nited States on Other
P arts of the World, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, vol. V, No. 2, A ugust 1956,
p. 283.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

577

The decision to embark on a broad program for the disposition of
surplus agricultural commodities has increased the United States
share in world trade in these commodities. During the past 3 years,
the United States share in world wheat exports has risen rapidly.
The United States was the biggest contributor to the increase in
world exports of rice during 1956. I t has raised its share of the
world trade in corn, and has recently regained the position it held
in the early postwar years as the supplier of nearly half of the inter­
national cotton trade.19 Total agricultural exports from the United
States for the fiscal year ending June 30,1957, reached a record high,
estimated at $4.7 billion, compared with $3.5 billion in the fiscal year
1956, and less than $3.2 billion in the fiscal year 1955.20
The Agricultural Trade Development and Assistance Act of 1954
(Public Law 83-480), an important source of foreign assistance, has
been a major factor in increasing agricultural exports. Shipments
abroad under this law accounted for 13 percent of our total farm
exports in the fiscal year 1955, 28 percent in 1956, and 32 percent
in 1957. In the most recent fiscal year, they accounted for 57 percent
of wheat exports, 43 percent of corn, 81 percent of rice, 30 percent of
cotton, and 47 percent of cottonseed and soybean oil.21
In this process there may have been some displacement of normal
exports of other nations. Their fears that American export pro­
grams would drive down international price levels or reduce dras­
tically the actual volume of their exports have not been justified by
events to date. W hat has happened for the most p art is that the
United States has prevented some price increases that might other­
wise have occurred and has obtained a larger share of the growing
international market than might otherwise have come to it.
Mutual security appropriations have provided additional assist­
ance for American agricultural exports. Contrary to popular im­
pression, the aid programs of the United States do not generally
take the form of dollar checks to recipient governments, which they
bank and draw against. Instead, our Government procures com­
modities produced in this country or, in certain cases, from other
producer nations able to supply on a competitive basis. The cost of
the commodities is then charged to the aid allotment of the recipient
government. The effect is roughly equivalent to that of supplying
the foreign treasury with dollars.
Nevertheless, the effect is not identical, and the existing procedure
gives the United States Government a greater voice in determining
how American producers and exporters will be affected by foreign
aid. I f foreign governments were in all cases supplied directly with
dollars, they might prepare their specifications differently and ob­
tain more of their essential requirements from nations other than
the United States, thereby reducing their need for American aid and
possibly (but not necessarily) the overall level of American exports.
They might also concentrate more heavily on building up domestic
production of items exported by the United States, a practice dis­
couraged by aid administrators.
19 C o n tr a c tin g P a r t i e s to t h e G e n e r a l A g re e m e n t o n T a riffs a n d T r a d e , I n te r n a tio n a l
T r a d e , 19 5 6 , p p . 5 1 -5 7 .
20 S ix th S e m ia n n u a l R e p o r t on A c tiv itie s U n d e r P u b lic L a w 480, 8 3d C ong., A s A m e n d ed
(8 5 th C ong., 1 s t s e s s .), H . D oc. N o. 212. p. 4.
21 Ib id ., p. 4.
(T h e fig u res in c lu d e b a r t e r t r a n s a c tio n s u n d e r t i t l e I I I o f t h e a c t.)




578

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

The restraints on East-W est trade, introduced and maintained for
security reasons, have a t times likewise appeared to foreign countries
to reduce their capacity to earn foreign exchange in international
trade and to increase their dependence on the American market for
essential imports. Legislative requirements concerning the use of
American vessels for the transportation of aid shipments have a simi­
lar effect. Like the international competitive bidding procedure, the
offshore procurement procedure, under which significant sums from
our mutual security appropriations were committed for purchases
from European producers in 1952 and 1953, has operated as an off­
set to aid policies that can be interpreted as promoting American
exports.
The United States also provides dollars to the rest of the world
by buying its merchandise and its services, by furnishing private
capital for investment in foreign lands, and by private donations.
Our imports of goods and services have been increasing but so have
our exports. In fact, the latter—exclusive of grant-aid shipments of
m ilitary supplies—have been rising more rapidly than tne former
and, in 1956, the surplus on goods and services was greater than in
any year since 1949. By the last quarter of 1956, transactions with
the United States were again resulting in a depletion of the gold and
dollar assets of other nations.22
In these circumstances, it is ironic th at our basic trade policy as
well as our aid policy is directed toward promoting exports. The
Trade Agreements Act adopted by the Congress has only one stated
urpose: the expansion of foreign markets for products of the United
tates. The “concession” we demand in trade negotiations is the op­
portunity to sell additional American commodities to others; the
reciprocal “concession” that we resist is the opportunity for Amer­
ican producers and consumers to buy additional commodities from
cheaper sources of supply. Even in a period of inflation, a negotia­
tion that permitted more goods to enter the American market than
were expected to be shipped out of it would be regarded as a failure.
The Trade Agreements Act has, of course, contributed substantially
to the general expansion of international trade, even if it has not con­
tributed to a reduction of our export surplus.23
Properly speaking, trade—which involves a two-way exchange of
resources, cannot replace aid, if aid is defined as a transfer of re­
sources to a foreign country without a commensurate retransfer from
the foreign country to the United States. Nevertheless, the slogan

g

“ See table I.
“ Commodity trade—World and United States:
1950

World exports (in billion dollars, f. o. b.).......-...............United States exports (in billion dollars, f. o. b.).............
United States Imports (in billion dollars, e. 1. f.)______
United States as percent of world imports........................

$56.64
$10.28
$59.36
$9.60
18.1
16.2

1956

$93.35
$19.08
$97.92
$13.75
20.4
14.0

1957 (2d
quarter at
annual rate)
$101.00
$21.86
$109.00
$13.94
21.6
12.8

Source: International Monetary Fond, International Financial Statistics, vol. X, No. 10 (October
1957), pp. 28-29.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

579

“trade not aid” can be made more meaningful than it has yet been
allowed to become. A creditor nation such as the United States, in­
terested in securing a better allocation of resources within the free
world, could well afford to take unilateral action to liberalize im­
ports and thus help foreign nations earn a larger proportion of their
dollar requirements from commodity sales in the American market.
Adjustment assistance could be made available to American workers,
communities, enterprises, and industries substantially injured by p ar­
ticular reductions in import barriers. The last few years, however,
have seen a mushrooming of protectionist demands and a number
of concessions to them. Continued prosperity in the United States
will enable our friends and allies to earn more dollars, but may not
help them to balance their acounts by earning, through trade, a larger
share of their dollar spendings.24
In theory, the Export-Im port Bank exists to finance imports as
well as exports. In practice, the loans of the bank are export credits.
Im port financing has played a very minor role in the history of the
bank, prim arily because of the availability of private credit for this
purpose.25 Indirectly, the loans of the Export-Im port Bank facilitate
capital formation in other lands, but the direct contribution of this
institution to the world supply of dollars since 1953 has been negative.
Credits utilized amounted to $716 million during the years 1954-56,
inclusive, while principal repayments came to $920 million and inter­
est collected to nearly $260 million.
The United States could maintain an export surplus on goods and
services without causing balance-of-payments crises for the rest of the
world, taken as a whole, if American exports of private capital reached
a high enough level. Private foreign investment since the end of the
Second W orld W ar has accounted for only a very small proportion,
usually less than 10 percent, of the annual world supply of dollars.
I t is an extremely volatile item.26 Fortunately, it increased sharply
and encouragingly in 1956. The result was a slight narrowing of the
gap between (1) dollars supplied to foreign nations through private
investment plus payments for imported goods and services and (2)
dollars required by foreign countries to pay for American exports of
goods and services, exclusive of military aid shipments. The private
investment total for 1956, however, contained several nonrecurrent
items and was, as usual, heavily concentrated in a few areas which,
for the most part, were already areas of financial strength.
Private investment, like foreign trade and unlike foreign aid, can­
not be directed in accordance with the requirements of American for­
eign policy. So long as foreign policy considerations make it im­
perative for us to provide resources for the development of nations
unable (or, in some cases, unwilling) to compete in the market place
24 “To make m atters worse, the fringe skirm ishes in the constant w ar of commercial
policy are all going in favor of the protectionists. There is no longer much doubt th at
oil im ports w ill be cut back, one way or the o th e r ; the current ‘voluntary’ restrictions
are so close to Government-imposed quotas, company by company, and area by area, as to
be alm ost indistinguishable. And it has been oil th at has provided the greater part of
w hat year-to-year increases American im ports have been able to show. The new tariffquota on foreign woolens, Japan’s ‘voluntary’ agreem ent to curb its exports of textiles
and of a few other item s, the impending, and alm ost certainly successful, appeal for tariff
relief for lead and zinc— all are m aking their contributions to keeping the total of
American im ports from show ing much energy.” The Econom ist, Sept. 14, 1957, p. 844.
25 See Olin S. Pugh, The Export-Im port Bank of W ashington, U niversity of South Caro­
lina, Bureau of B usiness and Economic Research, E ssays in Econom ics No. 5, June 1957.
* See table I.




580

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

for private capital, even a doubling of the current relatively high out­
flow of private investment funds would not necessarily eliminate the
need for foreign aid.
F

o r e ig n

A

s s is t a n c e

and

the

E

c o n o m ie s

of

R

e c ip ie n t

C o u n t r ie s

In foreign aid, as in other aspects of foreign policy, urgent short­
term considerations often interfere with the realization of long-range
objectives, and means and ends become confused.
Among the more frequently cited short-run objectives of assistance
programs have been: repairing the ravages of w ar; preventing fam­
ilies and precipitous declines in levels of living; disposing of agricul­
tural surpluses; shoring up the independence of one-time members
of the Soviet bloc; making allies out of neutrals; strengthening the
m ilitary and economic defenses of our allies; and obtaining bases
abroad for the United States. Longer term objectives have included:
containing communism; promoting economic growth and democratic
institutions in underdeveloped areas of the free w orld; extending the
free enterprise system or paving the way for its extension; develop­
ing sources of raw materials, markets tor American products, and
opportunities for mutually beneficial capital investments; serving
broad humanitarian purposes through helping needy members of the
international community to overcome poverty, hunger, and disease and
enter an era of self-sustaining growth with maximum freedom for
their individual citizens.
These and other objectives, explicit and implicit, deserve examina­
tion, individually, in relation to each other, and in relation to overall
foreign policy. The maintenance of a stronger M ilitary Establish­
ment may prevent economic growth in areas in which the latter is
more important than the former. M ilitary aid may be used to main­
tain a totalitarian government in power instead of to prevent one
from assuming power. Economic development is not a universal an­
tidote for communism; Communist movements may become stronger
during certain st ages of economic development. Newly independent
nations may exercise their sovereignty in ways that are harm ful to
the United States.
A more fundamental dilemma arises out of the fact th a t foreign
aid programs have been justified at home on the ground th a t they
promote the American national interest, defined in fairly immediate
and concrete terms. The very grounds on which they are justified
at home tend to make them suspect abroad. For why should others
be grateful for the incidental benefits of steps th a t are taken pri­
marily in our own self-interest? U ntil we agree on a rationale in
which our national interest does not appear to conflict unnecessarily
with the national interests of others, our programs are bound to en­
counter resistance abroad.
An analysis of the situation during the last few years would prob­
ably show that the necessary rationale is gradually emerging, espe­
cially if m ilitary aid is handled in a defense rather than an aid context
and foreign aid is limited primarily to economic development assist­
ance. H arlan Cleveland, an experienced practitioner and perceptive
writer in this field, has recently summarized it this w ay:
I t is in the United States national interest th a t the new
societies of Asia and Africa succeed in meeting the challenge



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

581

ahead of them, * * * without coming under the domination
of any outside power and without adopting a repressive sys­
tem of internal regimentation. To promote this interest re­
quires the maintenance of a military shield, and we will have
to be reconciled to bearing a disproportionate share of the
cost * * * of erecting and maintaining the shield—just as
the British did, partly in behalf of our own newly develop­
ing Nation, during the 18th and 19th centuries. To promote
this national interest of ours will also undoubtedly require the
effective use of our great economic strength through trade,
aid, and investment. But these are tools, not 'aims; the aim
is a successful India, a successful Indonesia, a successful
Egypt * * *—successful in the sense th at the constituted au­
thorities are governing effectively and by consent, and are
anxious to live with other free nations in freedom and co­
operation. 27
Others—among them the International Development Advisory
Board, the Mansfield Subcommittee on Technical Assistance, and Drs.
Hoselitz, Millikan, Rostow, and Staley in their writings—are saying
about the same thing.
I f the development of a successful India, Indonesia, and so forth,
proves acceptable to the American people as a rationale for foreign
aid, several questions that have been highly controversial in the past
should become less so in the future. These include the question of aid
for neutrals, the use of multilateral channels for economic develop­
ment assistance, and American attitudes toward industrialization in
areas heretofore overwhelmingly agricultural. On the other hand,
the question of how much aid, how to allocate it geographically and
functionally, and many other questions will not be answered merely
because ultimate objectives have been clarified. The broad terms in
which the long-range goals must be stated will still leave ample room
for debate about intermediate action.
In recent years the predominant form of aid has been military.
Since 1952, about 60 percent of our total foreign aid expenditure has
been for m ilitary supplies and equipment provided by the Department
of Defense. The bulk of the aid provided by the International Co­
operation Administration has also been dedicated to the support of
m ilitary establishments in nations with which the United States has
defense pacts. Emergency relief, economic development assistance,
and technical assistance have accounted for only a small share of total
assistance rendered since 1952.
W hatever the form in which foreign aid is extended by the United
States, it usually has at least one important educational effect in the
recipient nation. I t forces the country to look more searchingly at
its requirements and resources than would otherwise be the case.
Plans and cost estimates have to be made, specifications for equipment
developed, market prospects analyzed, inflationary or deflationary
effects forecast, innumerable forms completed in quintuplicate, and a
subsequent stream of inquiries answered. Always time consuming,
frequently demanding the services of personnel needed in an under­
developed country for other equally vital tasks, and sometimes unnec­
27 H arlan Cleveland, The Theory and P ractice of Foreign Aid, a paper prepared for the
special-studies project of the Rockefeller Brothers Fund, November 1, 1956, pp. 31-32.




582

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

essarily humiliating, the process nevertheless forces nations to examine
every project proposal with meticulous care. Some of this essential
discipline carries over into other activities and helps underdeveloped
countries train the necessary corps of public administrators and assign
economic priorities in more realistic fashion.
From the point of view of the economy of the recipient nation, it
makes a great deal of difference whether foreign assistance takes the
form of m ilitary aid or of economic aid. U nder military aid, the
foreign country receives a grant—an addition to its resources without
an obligation to make repayment—but the grant is employed for eco­
nomically unproductive purposes. The United States gives the nation
planes, tanks, guns, and m ilitary hardware th at it would not otherwise
be able to obtain or would not choose to obtain in preference to exist­
ing claims on its budgetary resources. The recipient of m ilitary aid
is assisted in building up a larger defense force in a better state of
readiness. To the extent th at this deters aggression and Communist
subversion, the security of the United States is enhanced.
American m ilitary aid may permit the recipient nation to concen­
trate more of its own resources on economic development. The aid
may incidentally serve to train new leadership in the recipient country,
to teach new skills and new patterns of behavior, to interest an impor­
tant segment of the population in modem ways of doing things, and to
increase popular demand for higher standards of living. The pur­
pose of the aid, however, is not to help other nations improve local
standards of living, or bridge a gap in their balance of payments, or
enlarge their capacity to service foreign loans. The future of m ilitary
aid as an item of Federal expenditure does not depend, therefore,
upon economic considerations as much as upon an assessment of the
nature of the Soviet threat and of the points at which armed resist­
ance to foreign aggression or to subversion from within is most
important.
M ilitary aid cannot be expected to end merely because the agreed
buildup of foreign forces has been achieved. M ilitary equipment
becomes obsolete more rapidly than other capital equipment and tends
to require replacement with ever more costly equipment. If, during
the period o f buildup, the United States and the foreign country are
sharing the increased expense on a 50-50 basis, it may well be that,
after the buildup, the cost of maintaining the larger force unaided
would be a greater burden on the foreign country than the cost to
that country of its present share of the buildup.
I t can be argued th at an equivalent American investment in de­
veloping the economies of friendly underdeveloped countries would
contribute more to the security of the free world than the investment
in the buildup of their armed forces is contributing. Some coun­
tries, as notea above, are perhaps being saddled with m ilitary estab­
lishments more costly than those they can be expected to maintain
out of their own resources at any time in the foreseeable future.
Others, it is feared, may employ their newfangled equipment against
their neighbors instead of against the common enemy. This possi­
bility provokes demands from the neighbors for comparable assistance
in order to maintain a m ilitary balance in the region. Other regions
may then feel discriminated against and step up their demands for
military assistance, to the detriment of their economic development.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

583

and without significantly increasing the security of the free world as
a whole.
F or each of these hazards, there are analogous hazards in the field
of economic assistance. The risks might nevertheless be better dis­
tributed if American foreign aid were not concentrated so heavily
on military assistance. In light of the enormous need for help in
overcoming poverty, hunger, and disease, a prosperous nation that
devotes only a small proportion of its foreign assistance to economic
and social programs would appear well advised to reexamine its
priorities with a view to upgrading development assistance.
The amount of foreign aid being expended for economic develop­
ment—i. e., to help build up the capital stock (including the human
skills) in underdeveloped countries rather than to equip military
forces or meet urgent consumption requirements, is very small. Firm
figures are not available, chiefly because of the difficulty of isolating
the portion of defense support devoted to activities th at clearly
strengthen the civilian economies of nations receiving such support.
Development assistance in 1956 probably did not exceed $400 million.
The military-aid figures shown in tables I, I I, and I I I , following the
text of this article, refer only to military equipment and services sup­
plied to foreign governments through the Department of Defense.
Much of the assistance furnished by the International Cooperation
Administration is also required for the support of national defense
establishments. The major recipients of ICA assistance during the
fiscal years 1955 to 1957 are shown in table IV, with assistance to the
countries in question classified accordinng to the ICA categories of
direct forces support, defense support, development assistance, and
technical cooperation. Of the $4 billion obligated by ICA on behalf
of non-European nations during the 3 years, 60 percent went to 5
countries with which the United States has military pacts: Korea,
Vietnam, Taiwan, Turkey, and Pakistan. There were relatively few
additional countries on behalf of which obligations in excess of $50
million for all so-called nonmilitary assistance were incurred during
the 3-year period.23
Development assistance could be extended either on a grant or a loan
basis. Loans must be repaid, however, and, from an economic point
of view, a grant that does not have to be repaid ought to be more val­
uable to the recipient than a loan that has to be amortized.
*
* * Obviously if foreign assistance must be repaid, the
debtor country will have a correspondingly smaller amount
of resources available for further capital formation. I t
would seem to follow from this that the main factor in the
decision as to whether a country should get a loan or a grant
depends upon the magnitude of its need for capital. The
adequacy of its resources in relation to the rate of capital for38 The direct forces support program, con stitutin g grants and supplies directly and
exclusively for the m ilitary forces of friendly countries, w as transferred to the Department
of D efense a t the beginning of the 1956 fiscal year. “Defense support” is aid given by the
ICA which is not for the direct and exclusive use of the m ilitary establishm ents of allied
nations, but is intended to help such nations m aintain a level of defense expenditures that
would not otherw ise be m aintained, or to help them undertake defense activities th a t would
not otherw ise be undertaken. Defense support includes some aid for economic develop­
m ent purposes, for example, in the fields of transportation, power, and port improvement.
“Developm ent assistan ce.” in ICA terminology (as in table rV accom panying th is article),
norm ally m eans assistan ce in im proving the capital stock of nations w ith which the U nitea
States does not have bilateral security pacts. “Technical cooperation** is the program
originally known a s “technical assistance.”




584

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

mation that is regarded as desirable seems to be a far more
basic test of whether it can repay foreign assistance, and
whether it should be asked to repay it, than is its balance of
payments position. In particular, its immediate balance of
payments position is irrelevant to the question of loans versus
grants, since the difference between loans and grants becomes
im portant only over a period of future time. Even a projec­
tion of the long-term balance of payment outlook, if based
on current trade patterns and resources, is not very relevant to
whether a country should be asked to repay. The basic ques­
tions are rather how im portant it is to have the country use
for further capital formation the additional resources that
would be at its disposal if repayment is not required, and how
likely it is th at these resources will actually be used for that
purpose. In some cases, resources that would be needed to re­
pay loans would be a substantial portion of an underdevel­
oped country’s net capital formation, and the need to repay
might significantly slow up the development process.29
A t the end of 1956, the United States Government already had the
equivalent of more than $11.7 billion outstanding in credits, exclusive
of those extended as a result of the F irst W orld War. Since 1954,
repayments of principal, largely by European governments, on post­
war American loans have each year exceeded new credit utilizations.
In addition, substantial interest payments have been made. I f col­
lections are made as scheduled, the United States Government will
receive in 1957 (in addition to the return of silver lend leased to India
and certain other nations) $458 million in principal repayments and
$269 million in interest, a total of nearly three-quarters of a billion
dollars. During the 6-year period ending in 1962, the Government is
scheduled to collect more than $4 billion of principal and interest on
the credits outstanding at the close of 1956. Annual principal re­
payments will range from $458 million in 1957 to $374 million in 1962,
and interest from $269 million to $217 million.30
In the immediate future, development assistance from the United
States will be available only in the form of loans. Pressure in this
direction had been building up for some time before the establish­
ment of the development loan fund in the Mutual Security Act of
1957, and other recent acts had required that not less than some fixed
percentage of nonmilitary aid be extended in the form of loans. The
decision to put development assistance entirely on a loan basis was not
reached through studies of the debt-9ervicing capacities of under­
developed countries or of the rates of development that would best
serve the interests of the free world. I t was based rather on strong
feelings that grants-in-aid should not be allowed to become a normal
feature of international economic relations.
Loans may be made repayable either in the currency of the lender or
that of the borrower. Loans that are repayable in dollars require the
borrower to increase its exports to the United States or otherwise earn
28 W alter S. Salant, Some B asic Considerations of Public Finance in the Econom ic Develop­
m ent of Underdeveloped Countries, a paper presented to the annual m eeting of the Inter­
national In stitu te of Public Finance, London, September 1951, pp. 1 1-12 (m im eo). Mr.
Salant calls attention in a footnote to the Report to the P resident on Foreign Economic
P olicies (th e Gray report), 1950, p. 67, where a sim ilar point of view is expressed.
” U. S. Departm ent of Commerce, Office of B usiness Economics, Foreign G rants and
Credits by the U nited S tates Government, December 1956 Quarter, p. 9.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

585

the dollars needed to pay off the loan. I f this results in too slow a
rate of capital formation, the extension of aid on a grant basis may
prove to have been preferable. The mutual strains involved in the
relationship of donor and recipient could be reduced by several devices,
including greater use of multilateral machinery.
In the effort to find a middle ground between outright grants and
loans repayable in dollars, the United States developed one of the out­
standing innovations of the postwar world of inconvertible currencies,
the loan repayable in the currency of the borrower—in rupees, rials,
pesos, or other monetary units.
In such cases, the commodities received from the United States by
the borrower, whether in the form of agricultural surpluses or indus­
trial goods, constitute an addition to its real resources. The use to
which these additional resources are put can be planned iointly with
the United States. Corollarv exports by the borrower (for example,
those resulting from the triangular trade arrangements sometimes
made) subtract from its real resources. Payment of local currency
into a United States account within the country provides the United
States with a cash asset. While the United States account is building
up, no real resources are being lost to the borrower, but some of its
currency is being sterilized and this may help to combat inflation in
the area.
I t follows also that there will be no addition to the real resources
of the country when the local currency accumulation in the United
States account is released to the coun+rv as a loan. The occasion
nevertheless offers the United States a fresh opportunity to share in
planning the most productive uses for the currency beinpr released. I f
exercised with discretion and skill. American participation in the
domestic affairs of countries in different stages of economic develonment can be an im portant influence for the common prood. I t would
appear to be sound policv. therefore, for the United States to con­
tinue making loans rer>avable in local currencies and relendino- the
nroreeds UTitil such time as the borrower is able to repav in dollars.
This is possible under the development lr>nn fnnrl of the latest Mutual
Seonritv Act. hiif not in prvnner'tion with development loans made
under the aoricd+nral snrnlns disnosnl leo'ial"tion. Tf thp an+horitv
to relend werp hroarlened. consideration mi^ht ncofnllv be rriven to
m«kino- the orifinal loans for shov+pj- tpr-rnq than at rcrpsent. acraimnlatino1local currencies more ranidlv. and advanpinrr the date at which
ioint programing with the borrowing country would again be necessarv.
rTThe American mo^ivntion fo r embarking on a lar<re-scale nrofram
o f loans repayable in local <mrrereies was the desire to dispose o’f
mounting agricultural sim ilises. T3v 19K3. the disposal problem had
become acute, and the rVmsress inserted in the Mutual Security Act
a n-rovicinn remiirino- that, during the fiscal vear 19?'4 not less than
m illion o-f thp -funds apnropriatpfj -for foreio'n aid bp nspd +o bn v
su rp lu s aiTT'ionlt'iral prodnetq w h ich could he sold abroad fo r fo^ei071
niirrnnnioc! si S im ila r -provisions specifvinQ - th a t lnr,<rer snm s bp so
rispd h a ve been included in snbsennent, a cts.32 W hereas th e cou n ter­
p a rt fu n d s gen erated b y g ra n t aid belong, w ith m in o r exceptions, to
81 Mutual Spcnrftv Act of 10R 1, as
s p c . KRO.
” Mutual Security Act o f 1954, as amended, sec. 402.




586

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

the foreign government, the local currencies received in payment for
surplus commodities belong to the United States, for use pursuant to
agreements with the borrowing countries. By March 31, 1957, total
foreign currency proceeds received since July 1, 1953, under sections
550 and 402 of the different Mutual Security Acts and available to
the International Cooperation Administration amounted to the equiva­
lent of $1 billion.33
Paralleling and in many respects dwarfing the surplus-disposal pro­
visions of the mutual security acts have been the provisions of the
previously mentioned Agricultural Trade Development and Assist­
ance Act of 1954 (Public Law 83-480). These provisions authorize
sales of surplus commodities for foreign currencies, grants for emerency relief purposes, donations to nonprofit voluntary agencies, and
arter deals. Although the basic purpose of Public Law 480 is to
facilitate the movement of surplus agricultural commodities, it has
become a major source of foreign assistance. U nder title I of the
law, agreements for the sale of agricultural commodities for foreign
currencies had by June 30,1957, been made with 34 countries for com­
modities worth $3 billion at Commodity Credit Corporation cost,
or $2.1 billion at export-market value. The larger figure represents
the cost of the commodities to the CCC, including investment, proc­
essing, handling, and other costs. The export-market value reflects
the price at which the commodities are sold by United States exporters
under the program.34
The act specifies a number of purposes for which the foreign-currency receipts may be used. By far, the most important of these is
“loans to promote multilateral trade and economic development” (sec.
104 ( g ) ). The ICA may make such loans without an equivalent pay­
ment to the CCC in appropriated dollars. By June 30, 1957, sales
agreements involving the loan of $1.2 billion in foreign-currency pro­
ceeds had been signed.
Although more than half of the local currency accumulated under
title I of Public Law 480 is being lent back for “multilateral trade and
economic development,” about one-quarter of the total is being used
for the payment of United States expenses abroad, a catchall category
th at includes some local expenses of American embassies, the local
travel expenses of congressional committees, and a number of other
expenditures authorized by the act. Another one-eighth, the equiva­
lent of $244 million, is being devoted to m ilitary procurement abroad.
Under ordinary circumstances, the United States would—
pay for the upkeep of a diplomatic mission or pay troops
stationed abroad in dollars. These dollars are paid into the
economy of the receiving country, and may be used to p u r­
chase any article moving in world trade (or to bolster re­
serves) . The chances are th at some of the dollars would be
spent for United States goods. When, instead, we pay for­
eign expenses in local currencies, we lessen our chances of
making sales through normal export channels, because no
dollar exchange is created. * * * Critics of the title I pro­
grams make much of this point, stressing it as a detriment to

f

• International Cooperation Administration, Counterpart Funds and ICA Foreign Cur­
rency Accounts, Data as of March 81, 1957, pp. 18-17.
MSixth Semiannual Keport on Activities Under Public Law 480, 83d Cong., as Amended
(85th Cong., 1st sess., H. Doc. 212), p. 2.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

587

normal trade and to United States firms with an interest in
foreign markets. * * * The stated purpose of the programs
would be better met if more local currencies were assigned for
economic development.35
Surplus commodities also provide an im portant source of grant aid.
Deliveries for emergency relief and other assistance abroad under
title I I of Public Law 480, as of June 30,1957, totaled $260 million at
CCC cost. Cumulative shipments for foreign relief through nonprofit
voluntary agencies and intergovernmental organizations (primarily
the United Nations Children’s Fund) under title I I I totaled $600 mil­
lion. Whereas the emphasis in title I I is on emergency relief in times
of flood, famine, and other disasters, the purpose of the donations to
voluntary agencies is to permit free distribution to needy individuals.
The processing, packaging, and related costs—and, more recently, part
of the ocean freight as well—are paid by the United States Govern­
ment.
W hether in surplus agricultural commodities or in other forms,
nonmilitary grant aid is now limited largely to the prevention of
starvation, the relief of personal poverty, and the avoidance of politi­
cal crises. The assistance usually goes directly into consumption,
where it serves a critical, short-term need. The long-term require­
ment of the underdeveloped countries is to increase the level of invest­
ment and thus improve the capital stock that will permanently raise
standards of living. To achieve the increase, simultaneous action on
many fronts is needed:
* * * Too little capital is by no means the only problem
facing the leaders of the less developed areas. But it is the
one problem th at the United States can most readily do some­
thing about. * * * The literature on this subject is well sup­
plied with estimates of the appropriate size for a larger pro­
gram. * * * Any of the figures * * * mentioned would De a
great deal better than the actual total today, and none of them
would make a noticeable dent on what is available for domes­
tic consumption in the United States or for investment in our
own growth.36
P

resen t

S tatus

of

F

o r e ig n

A

id

U ntil only a few months ago, foreign aid seemed to have established
itself as a major feature of American foreign policy. Despite the
emergency character of the operation and the absence of authorization
legislation for the most important types of assistance, the level of for­
eign grants and credits had been running between $4.2 billion and
$6.3 billion per year for more than a decade. In late 1956 and early
1957, the program had been subjected to the most widespread and
searching analysis since the inception of the Marshall plan.
Although congressional opposition to a mere continuation of the
pre-1957 program had been growing, the initial reception for the new
and more imaginative proposals put forward by the administration in
the spring of 1957—largely as a result of congressional prodding—
was cordial. There seemed to be broad agreement on the desirability
86 N ational P lanning Association, Agricultural Surplus D isposal and Foreign Aid, p. 24.
M H arlan Cleveland, Theory and P ractice o f Foreign Aid, pp. 63-64.




588

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

of putting the aid program on a longer term basis, separating m ilitary
and economic aid, establishing a new loan fund for development as­
sistance, and endowing the fund with sufficient resources to perm it the
underdeveloped countries of the free world to plan ahead with greater
assurance than heretofore. Fulfillment of their aspirations for more
rapid economic and social progress admittedly carried certain risks,
but the risks involved in American failure to help them realize their
legitimate aspirations seemed even greater.
The process of attaining a self-sustaining rate of growth had been
compared by W. W. Rostow to the takeoff of an airplane; unless the
plane attained a certain momentum, it would never leave the ground.
To reach the takeoff speed, most underdeveloped countries needed out­
side aid and, unless the amounts were sufficient, there would be no
takeoff. A number of the recently published investigations and re­
ports, consequently, recommended increases in the current levels of
economic and technical assistance.
The task in south Asia was considered especially urgent. India,
with the largest population in the free world and one of the poorest,
has been trying desperately to meet the comparatively modest goals
of its second 5-year plan without resorting to totalitarian means.
To the north and east, Communist China has been proceeding by the
more ruthless tactics of totalitarianism and at fearful cost in human
liberty and dignity, to invest perhaps twice as large a proportion of
its gross national product as India. Unless India overcomes its pres­
ent serious difficulties, the outlook for democracy, according to many
experienced observers, will be considerably bleaker.
The Congress, by sharply reducing the amount of new money appro­
priated for the mutual security program in 1958, has left a clearer
field for the Soviet Union and made plain its own reluctance to accept
sizable m ilitary and economic aid programs as normal, peacetime
methods of achieving our foreign-policy objectives. The future of
foreign aid, consequently, cannot be forecast with any confidence. A
few conclusions can be drawn from the record to date, however.
Foreign aid has not been a great burden on the American economy.
The case for assuming the burden has rested on general foreign-policy
considerations, political, military, and humanitarian, as well as eco­
nomic. To concede that it was necessary and desirable for the United
States to undertake such programs is not to say th at the programs
have been brilliantly administered, that the divisions between different
forms of aid have been wise, or that the conflicting objectives of the
various aid laws can all be realized.
The bulk of the aid furnished by the United States has been spent to
equip and support the m ilitary forces of friendly nations. In the
absence of such expenditures, the domestic defense expenditures of the
United States would, almost certainly, have been higher. The decision
having been taken to build up the defense establishments of the nations
most vulnerable to external aggression, it would seem sensible to insure
that the newly erected establishments are maintained until the danger
of armed attack subsidies. The cost of maintaining such establish­
ments makes it unlikely th at the nations in question will be able to
bear them unaided. W hether the defense expenditures of the free
world can safely be reduced should depend upon a reassessment of
the nature and character of the Soviet threat, not upon the weight
of the current economic burden.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

589

In theory, the sums invested by the United States in nonmilitary
aid could be used to a much greater extent than heretofore to expand
American imports. Stockpiles could be established or expanded and
other devices employed to provide dollar earnings for countries that
the United States wanted to help. In practice, the aid programs of
the United States have been oriented in the direction of expanding
American exports, and, in this respect, have been in tune with a world­
wide desire to solve economic problems by protecting domestic markets
while seeking to expand foreign markets.
Much of the economic aid has been devoted to maintaining con­
sumption instead of increasing investment. Relatively little has been
allocated to the most important long-range economic and political
problem facing the free world as a whole: permanently improving
standards of living where the economy has for long been at a bare
subsistence level and where, because of the relentless pressure of popu­
lation, considerable investment is required merely to maintain present
standards. W hether in such areas the foreign contribution can be
limited to loans is problematical.
When the United States lends to a country that could not have
borrowed through commercial channels, and the country erects a
powerplant and later repays the loan with interest, both will have
gained as a result of the transaction. I f the loan is really a loan,
however, repayment must be made in real resources. I f the total
resources available to the borrowing country are likely for some time
to come to be inadequate for purposes of capital formation, it may be
better to extend grant aid. The lending of local currencies accumu­
lated in payment for previously received agricultural or industrial
commodities provides fresh opportunities for joint programing, but
such loans neither add to the already available real resources of the
borrower nor help it to obtain additional capital equipment from
abroad. In cases in which grant aid is deemed necessary, strings that
require cooperative planning can be attached without arousing undue
resentment.
The most efficient use of our foreign aid resources is that which
best achieves the objectives of our foreign policy. To me at least, it
seems unlikely that the United States will be able to live in real peace,
either with itself or with the rest of the world, until the energies of
both are harnessed more firmly to the constructive and challenging
task of raising levels of living in areas no longer resigned to grinding
poverty and subordinate status.

97735—57------39



590

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

T a b l e I .— U n i t e d S t a t e s s u r p l u s o f e x p o r t s a n d m e a n s o f f i n a n c i n g c a l e n d a r
y e a r s 1948-^57

[In billions of dollars]
Calendar year
Lin*
No.

Item
1957
(1st
qtr.)

1948

1949

1950

1951

1952

1963

1954

1955

(1)

Exports of goods and services,
total.................... ....................... 17.1

16.0

14.4

20.3

20.7

21.3

21.1

22.0

26.1

7.2

(2)
(3)
(4)

Merchandise exports.......... 13.2
Services................................. 3.6
Military transfers under
aid programs (net)........ —
.3

12.1
3.7

10.1
3.8

14.1
4.7

13.3
47

12.3
4.8

12.8
5.1

14.3
5.6

17.3
0.2

5.1
1.5

.2

.5

1.5

2.6

4.3

3.2

2.1

2.6

.6

(5)

Imports of goods and services,
total................... ....................... 10.3

1956

9.7

12.0

15.1

15.7

16.6

16.1

17.9

19.8

5.0

(6)
<7)
(8)

Merchandise imports..........
Services.. .........................
Military expenditures 1.......

7.6
1.9
.8

6.9
2.2
.6

9.1
2.4
.6

11.2
2.6
1.3

10.8
2.9
2.0

11.0
3.1
2.5

10.4
3.1
2.6

11.5
3.6
2.8

12.8
4.1
2.9

3.3
.9
.8

(9)

Surplus on goods and services,
total..........................................

6.8

6.3

2.3

5.2

5.0

4.7

5.0

4,1

6.3

2.2

(10)

Surplus on goods and serv­
ices, exclusive of military
transfers...... ......................
Surplus on merchandise
exports.. .........................

6.5

6.2

1.8

3.7

2.4

.4

1.9

2.0

3.7

1.6

5.6

5.2

1.0

2.9

2.5

1.3

2,4

2.8

4.5

1.8

(11)

MEANS OF FINANCING SURPLUS
ON GOODS AND SERVICES

(Surplus=line 9=lines 12+ 16+
17+18+19)
(12)

U. S. Government grants and
loans, net total.........................

5.2

5.9

4.2

47

5.0

6.3

4.7

43

4.9

1.2

(13)
(14)
(15)

Grants of military supplies
and services2......... ...........
Other grants..........................
Long- and short-term loans
(net)...................................

.3
3.9

.2
5.0

.5
3.5

1.5
3.0

2.6
2.0

4.3
1.8

3.2
1.6

2.1
1.9

2.6
L7

.6
.4

1.0

.7

.2

.2

.4

.2

- .1

.3

.6

-2

.5

1.3

1.1

1.2

.4

1.6

1.2

3.0

.8

.6

.5

.5

.6

.6

.6

.6

.6

.2

.1 - 3 .7
-.8
(*>

- .5
- .5

- 1 .2 - 2 .3 - 1 .8 - 1 .5 - 1 .5
- .5 - .3 - .2 - .5 - .7

.3
-.4

(16)
(17)
(18)

(19)

Long- and short-term private
capital (net)................... .........
.9
Private remittances and U. S.
Government pensions...........
.6
Foreign liquidation of gold and
dollar assets (minus sign indi­
cates gold and dollar gains by
foreign countries)..................... 1.2
Errors and omissions........... ...... -1 .2

i Includes personal expenditures of American troops in foreign countries.
J The differences between the U. S. Government grant and loan figures shown here and those given in
tables II and III are due to differences in accounting procedures and definitions. For example, foreign
currencies acquired through the sale of surplus agricultural commodities but still unspent enter into the
balance-of-payments accounts as short-term assistance to foreign countries. Such amounts are not incorpo­
rated into the foreign grant and (long-term) credit data summarized in tables II and III, however, until
the foreign currencies are expended as grants or credits.
3 Less than $50,000,000.
N ote.—Because of rounding to nearest $100,000,000, figures may not add up correctly. When figures in
each column are fully extended—
Line (l) = (2)-K3)+(4)
Line (5) = (6)+(7)+(8)
Line (9) = (1) —(5) = (12)+(16)+(17)+(18)+(19)
Line (10) = (9)-(4)
Line (11) = (2)-(6)
Line (12) = (13)+(14)+(15)
Line (13)=line (4).
Sources: U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, Balance of Payments, 1919-53,
table 1 (for figures pertaining to 1948-52), Survey of Current Business, June 1958, table 3 (for 1953-55),
Survey of Current Business, June 1957, table 2 (for 1956-57).




591

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T a b le II.— TJ. 8 . G o v e rn m e n t: F o r e ig n grcm ts a n d cre d its , J u l y 1 ,
Deo.

to

[In billions of dollars]

Line
No.

Item

( 1)

Net foreign grants and credits,
total1........... ..........................
Grants:
N et.................... .................
Gross (new)........................
Military supplies and
services2....................
Other *..........................
Less: Reverse grants and
returns *.............. - ...........
Military supplies and
services......................
Other............................
Credits utilized:
Net.................... - ..............
Gross (new)........................
Export-Import Bank
program.....................
Mutual security pro­
gram*......... ..............
Other______ _______
Less: Principal collections.
Export-Import Bank

(2)
(3)

(4)
(5)
(6)

(7)

( 8)
(9)

( 10)
( 11)
( 12)
(13)
(14)
(15)

5 years:
years: July 1 ,1950-Dec. 31,1956
July 1,
Total
194511**
June 30, July 1,
I960
1960-Dec. 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 Total
31,1950

S. 35

4.63 5.04 6.35 4.74 4.22 4.34 31.31 57.66

18.32
19.26

1.94 4.51 4.64 6.12 4.86 4.31 4.37 30.75 49.07
2.01 4.65 4.79 6.28 4.93 4.38 4.45 31.50 50.76

1.51
17.75

17.30 18.81
.42 1.49 2.73 4.34 3.21 2.42 2.
1.59 3.16 2.06 1.94 1.72 1.96 1.76 14.20 31.95
.15

.17

.07

.07
.08

.06

.01 .01 .01

.43

.40
.83

.23 - .1 1 -.0 9
.71 .39 .41

.20

.48

.07
.07
.87
8.03
9.33

(»)

.02

.06
.05
.20

2.65
5.69
1.

.04
.16

.63

.12
.12

’."67

.07

.06

.06

.07

.65

.28

.21

.09

.19

.23

.31

.35

.31

.43

.13

.27

.18

.16

.18
.57

.25
1.44

.56 8.59
3.45 12.78

.21 .33 .05
.02 .01 .01

(16)
(17)

.10

.07

2.13

4.78

.01 .02
.50

.51

1.19
.13
2.

2.18
5.82
4.19

.31

.27

1.72

2.36

.01 .01 .01

.02

.06

.06
1.77

.16

.02

.50

.14

.18

1.10

i The differences between U. S. Government grant and credit figures shown here and those shown in
table I are due to differences in accounting procedures and definitions. For example, foreign currencies
acquired through the sale of surplus agricultural commodities but still unspent enter into the balanee-ofpayments accounts (table I) as short-term assistance to foreign countries. Such amounts are not incor­
porated into the foreign grant and (long-term) credit data included above, however, until the foreign
currencies are expended as grants or loans.
3 Defense Department is operating agency providing most of military aid reported on this line.
a Provided primarily by International Cooperation Administration (ICA) and its predecessors: Foreign
Operations Administration (FOA), Mutual Security Administration (MSA), and Economic Cooperation
Administration (ECA). Includes grants for defense support, technical assistance, emergency relief, and
contributions to international organizations for Palestine refugees and Korean reconstruction.
* Includes counterpart funds received by U. S. Government.
« Less than $5,000,000.
• Includes loan activities of ICA, FOA, MSA, and ECA.
N o t e .— Because of rounding to nearest $10,000,000, figures may not add up correctly. When each
figure is fully extended—
Line (l) = (2)+(9)
Line (2) = (3)-(6)
Line (3)ss(4)+(5)
Line (6)=(7)+(8)
Line (9) = (10)-(14)
Line (10) = (11)+(12)+(13)
Line (14)=(15)+(16)+(17)
Source: Report of the National Advisory Council on International Monetary and Financial Problems,
85th Cong., 1st sess., H. Doc. 200, table C-4. Data are based upon those published by the Department of
Commerce, Office of Business Economics, in the quarterly report Foreign Grants and credits by the United
States Government.




592
T a b le

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

III.— 77. 8. Government: Net foreign grants and credits, by area, 1951-56
[In billions of dollars]

Line
No.

Calendar year
Item

(1) All areas (net grants and
credits utilized).1
(2)
Grants (net total)...........
Military supplies
(3)
and services.
(4)
Other2.......................
(5)
Credits (net)....................
(6) Europe (total)*___________
Grants..............................
(7)
Military
supplies
(8)
and services.
Other.........................
(9)
Credits.............................
(10)
(11) Asia (total)3...........................
(12)
Grant?..............................
Military
supplies
(13)
and services.
Other.........................
(14)
(15)
Credits.............................
(16) Latin America (total)...........
(17)
Grants....................... ......
Military
supplies
(18)
and services.
Other.........................
(19)
(20)
Credits.............................
(21) Africa (total nonmilitary) 3_.
(22)
Grants (other than mili­
tary).
(23)
Credits.............................
(24) Other *.................................
(25)
Grants..............................
(26)
(27)
(28)

M ilitary
supplies
and services.
O ther...........................
C redits................................

1951

1952

1953

1954

Total
1955

1956

1951­
53

1954­
56

1951­
56

Line
No.

4.63

5.04

6.35

4.74

4. 22

4.34

16.02

13.30

29.32

(1)

4.51
1.48

4.64
2.66

6.12
4.28

4.86
3.20

4.31
2.41

4.37
2. 67

15.27
8.42

13.53
8.28

28.81
16.71

(2)
(3)

3.04
.12
3. 37
3.49
1.08

1.98
.40
3.75
3.63
2.18

1.84 1.66 1.90 1.69
.23 -.1 1 -.0 9 -.0 3
4.41 3.12 2.41 2. 21
4.58 3.36 2. 59 2.41
3.44 2.35 1.78 1.94

6.85
.75
11.53
11.70
6.71

5.25
- .2 3
7.74
8.35
6.07

12.10
.51
19. 27
20.06
12.78

(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)

.47
.81
1.45 1.13 1.01
.11 -.1 7 -.2 3 -.1 8 -.2 0
1.00 1.40 1. 37 1. 54 1.81
.83 1.39 1.32 1.47 1.63
.38
.77
.79
.58
.65

4.99
- .1 7
3.40
3.06
1.45

2. 29
- .6 2
4.72
4.42
2.02

7.28
- .7 9
8.12
7.48
3.46

(10)
(11)
(12)
(13)

2.41
- .1 2
.99
.85
.29
.56
.15
.16
.08
.06

.44
.17
.13
.08
.06

.61
.02
.40

.01
.08
.01

(9)

.03

53
.05
.13
.09
.05

.89
.06
.10
.10
.03

.98
.18
.11
.14
.06

1.62
.34
.70
.22
.16

2.40
.29
.34
.32
.13

4.02
.63
1.03
.55
.29

(14)
(15)
(16)
(17)
(18)

.02
.05
.06
.01

.03
.34
.04
.01

.04
.04
.05
.01

.07
<«)

.09
.05

.08
- .0 3
.07
.05

.07
.47
.11
.02

.19
.02
.20
.11

.25
.49
.31
.13

(19)
(20)
(21)

<*>

.10

.05
.10

.03
.08

.04
.08

.03
.09

.02
.14

.09
.29

.18
.59

(23)
(24)

.09
.04

.09
.04

.08
.03

.08
.02

.09
.02

.14
.02

.09
.30

.27

.11

.32
.07

.59
.17

(25)
(2b)

.05
.01

.06

.05
(4)

.07
.06
W - .0 1

.11
(*)

.16
.03

.25
-.0 2

.41
.01

(27)
(28)

W

.01

.06

(22)

1 T h e differences betw een U . S. G overnm ent grant an d credit figures show n here and those shown in
tab le I are due to differences in accounting procedures and definitions. F or exam ple, foreign currencies
acquired through th e sale of surplus agricultural commodities b u t still un sp en t enter into the balance-ofpay m en ts accounts (table I) as short-term assistance to foreign countries. Such am ounts are no t incor*
porated in to th e foreign grant an d (long-term) credit d a ta included above, however, u n til the foreign
currencies are expended as grants or loans.
8 Includes grants for defense support.
* E uropean totals include assistance to certain European dependents in Asia a n d Africa. A m ounts for
Asia an d Africa are correspondingly understated.
* E quals less th a n $5,001),000.
* Includes C anada, A ustralia, N ew Zealand, an d certain international organizations.
Source: R eport of th e N ational A dvisory C ouncil on In tern atio nal M onetary and Financial Problem s,
85tb Cong., 1st sess., H . Doc. No. 200, tables C -l, C-2, an d C-3. D a ta are based upon those published
b y th e D ep artm en t of Commerce, Office of Business Economics, in the q u a rte rly report Foreign G rants
and C redits by the U . S. G overnm ent. Because of rounding to nearest $10,000,000, figures m ay n o t add
u p correctly. W hen each figure is fully extended:
Line (l) = (2)+(5) = (6 > + (ll)+ (16)+ (21)+ (24).
Line (2) = (3)+(4) = (7)+(12)+(17)+(22)+(25).
Line (3) = (8)+(13)+(18)+(26).
Line (4) =*(9)+(14)+(19)+(22)+(27).
Line (5) - (10)+(15)+(20)+(23) + (28).




593

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T a b l e TV.— 10A aid to selected areas for fiscal years 1955-57, by type of

assistance1
(Obligations, in millions of dollars]1
Fiscal year
Region an d country

T otal, excluding E u ro p e.
D irect forces su p p o rt s_._
Defense su p p o rt 3..........
D evelopm ent assistance..
Technical cooperation__
O th er....................................
F a r E a st (to tal).
D irect forces su p p o rt___
Defense su p p o rt________
D evelopm ent assistance..
Technical cooperation__
O th e r_________ ____ ___
C am bodia (to tal).

1955

1956

$1,422

$1, 251

1,361

$4,035

81
986
236
115
3

<-3
992
148
113

1,045
115

78
3,022
586
342

912

739

811

2,462

56
833

4-3
706

1957

201

20

31

770
5
36

38

45

34

1

2

4

1

Defense su p p o rt.........
Technical cooperation..
V ietnam .
D irect forces s u p p o rt...
Defense su p p o rt......... .
Technical cooperation..

41

134

41

131
2

324

202

785
20

20

199
3

255
4

4-22

Indochina (u n d istrib u ted ).
Defense su p p o rt______
C hina (T aiw an).

53
2,309
9

114
4

Defense su p p o rt______
Technical cooperation..
Laos.

1955-57

757
8

38
38

-2 2

132

<-1

D irect forces su p p o rt...
Defense su p p o rt______
Technical cooperation..

28
247

68

3

K orea..

10

324

Defense su p p o rt....... ...
Technical cooperation..
O th e r..............................

317
5

1

300
5

P h ilip p in es.

190

Defense su p p o rt________
D evelopm ent assistance..
Technical cooperation__
O th er....................................

246
223
64
2

59

In d ia ..

214

D evelopm ent assistance..
Technical cooperation__

See footnotes at end of table.




3

73
18

South Asia (to tal)________

Defense su p p o rt______
Technical cooperation..
O th er_______________

11

90

Defense su p p o rt......... .
Technical cooperation..

P a k ista n ..

853

182
32
63

106
97
8

1

99

267
246
19
2

594

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T a b l e IV .— 10A aid to selected areas for fiscal years 1955-51, by type of

assistance1—Continued

[Obligations, in millions of dollars] *
Fiscal year

Region and country
1955
Near East (total).
Direct forces support___
Defense support............
Development assistance..
Technical cooperation__

1956

1957

299
25
144
34

27

34

27

Greece.
Defense support...........
Technical cooperation..

1955-57

218

756

127
69

25
412
240
79

22

26

26

84

65

189

(»)
73

Iran..
Defense support_______
Development assistance..
Technical cooperation__

102

53
34
41

Israel.

92

Development assistance..
Technical cooperation__

87
5
90

TurkeyDirect forces support...
Defense support...........
Technical cooperation..

107
105

79

194
84

1

(«)
13

Bolivia..

Defense support..............
Development assistance..
Technical cooperation.....

25
225
7

49

Defense support...............
Development assistance..
Technical cooperation__
Other................................

Africa (total).

56

2

Latin America (total).

Defense support...............
Development assistance..
Technical cooperation__
Other_________ _____ _

256

20

32

(«)

(*)
13

62
7
54
27

1 Countries selected are those outside ICA European region, on behalf of which obligations in excess of
$50 million were accumulated during the period June 30, 1955 to June 30, 1957. ICA includes Greece and
Turkey in Near East region. European figures, which are not yet available, would add Spain, Yugo­
slavia, and possibly Germany (Berlin and East German relief) to the list.
2 Figures are preliminary. Obligations precede expenditures and provide a useful measure of current
trends. Because of rounding to the nearest million, columns and lines may not add correctly.
3 Both direct forces support and defense support are designed to make possible the creation or mainte­
nance of a certain level of military forces. Direct forces support does so by providing, or paying for, goods
or services that physically reach or benefit the forces involved. Defense support contributes to this objec­
tive more indirectly through providing resources which either enable the recipient country to maintain
a level of defense expenditures or undertake defense activities that would not otherwise be possible. The
program of direct forces support (e. g., clothing, rations, petroleum, medical supplies, etc. used directly
and exclusively by the military forces) was transferred to the Department of Defense at the beginning of
the 1956 fiscal year. Defense support includes some assistance (e. g., in transportation, electric power, or
port improvement) which might also be classified as aid for economic development. It has its specific
military impact as a country's economy is rendered capable of sustaining the desired enlargement of its
defense burden.
4 Negative figure means deobligations exceeded obligations of new funds or reobligations of old funds.
« Less than $500,COO.
Source: International Cooperation Administration, Office of Statistics and Reports.